You are on page 1of 9

See discussions, stats, and author profiles for this publication at: https://www.researchgate.

net/publication/230663892

Applications of Duality Theory

Chapter · January 1974

CITATIONS READS

346 7,901

3 authors, including:

Walter Erwin Diewert


University of British Columbia
458 PUBLICATIONS 22,869 CITATIONS

SEE PROFILE

Some of the authors of this publication are also working on these related projects:

Price index research View project

The Digital Economy, GDP and Consumer Welfare View project

All content following this page was uploaded by Walter Erwin Diewert on 10 September 2014.

The user has requested enhancement of the downloaded file.


Frontiers of Qumtitatiue Economics. Volume IT, ed. M. D. Infriligaforand D.A. Kerldrlck. Applications of duality theory
0 1974 North-Holland Publishing Company.
en coordonnker ponctuelles, cer nouvelles relations pr6sentant l'avantage de fournir
e-,,,!.
,
!.-:.A '

!
explicitement h quantitks en fonction du revcnu et des prix.
Ainsi parait s'ouvrir un champ fkcond d'investigations pour les Cconombtres.
'
: !..it
.;v$
(Roy 1947, p. 225).
, .! :$$,
..,
.,. ~..
,?.,
- ; -

,.;&'-,
. k?',;.
-8 I
. . ..,. One of the first authors to appreciate the usefulness of duality theory in
: deriving systems of factor demand functions in the context of producer
.. , theory was McFadden (1966, p. 13):
...
.,
~

CHAPTER 3 The introduction of cost, revenue and profit functions into production theory yields a
theoretical return and several practical advantages. Most of the qualitative results of
production theory follow from properties of these functions, without restrictive
APPLICATIONS OF DUALITY THEORY * assumptions on the divisibility of commodities and convexity and smoothness of
production possibilities.
W.E. DIEWERT The principal practical advantage lies in the simple relation between these func-
tions and the corresponding demand and supply functions. For example, differentia-
Department of Manpower and Immigration, Ottawa tion of the profit function yields net output supply functions, and summation.,of
Department of Economics, University of British Columbia prices times net output supply functions yields the profit function.

The second principal advantage of duality theory is that it enables us to


derive in an effortless way the "comparative statics" theorems originally
0. Introduction deduced from maximizing behavior.' This second principal advantage has
its origins in the work of Hotelling (1932, pp. 594, 597). McFadden (1966,
There appear to be two principal practical applications of duality theory in 1970) has extensively pursued this second principal advantage.
economics. In sections 1,2 and 3 of the present paper, we provide some examples of
The first principal application of duality theory is that it enables us to the first principal advantage of duality theory, while sections 4, 5 and 6
derive systems of demand equations which are consistent with maximizing or provide some examples of the second principal advantage of duality theory.
minimizing behavior on the part of an economic agent, consumer or pro- In section 1, we study the duality between unit cost functions and constant
ducer, simply by differentiating, a function, as opposed to solving explicitly returns to scale production functions. The duality which is developed in
a constrained maximization or minimization problem. Perhaps the first section 1 was known to SamuelsonZ(1953) and can be obtained by special-
person to appreciate the econometric implications of the above statement in izing Shephard's (1970) more general results. However, our present method
the context of consumer demand theory was Rent Roy (1942): of developing the duality theorem is somewhat more direct than Shephard's
Cette conception conduit k I'emploi de coordonndes tangentielles pour la dkfinition des method, since we proceed directly from the cost function to the production
surfaces d'indifference et elle offre ainsi la possibilitk d'obtenir pour I'optimum du function via definition (8). In the appendix to this paper (section lo), we
consommateur, de nouvelles relations d'kquilibre, homologues des relations obtenues
outline a proof of a theorein which appears in the main text of the paper, ft
(i) the theorem contains a "new" result3 or (ii) the proof is new (and hope.
* This research was partially supported by a Canada Council grant. In the five years
that 1 have been studying duality theory, many people have assisted me: S.N. Afriat, That the assumption of maximizing behavior implies certain restrictions on con-
E.R. Berndt, L.R. Christensen, M. Denny, L. Epstein, M. Fuss, Z. Griliches, R.E. Hall, sumer demand functions was known to Antonelli (1968, pp. 33-39) (originally published
G. Hanoch, R. Harrls, D.W. Jorgenson, L.J. Lau, M. Nerlove, D. McFadden, P.A. 1886) and Pareto (1971, pp. 417-426) (originally published 1906), but the first rigorous
Samuelson, R. W. Shephard, R. M. van Slyke, E. Wiens and A. D. Woodland. The edito- comparative statics result was obtained by Slutsky (1915). Hicks (1946) and Samuelson
rial assistance of M. lntriligator is also greatly appreciated. My thanks also to Lise Bldoo (1947) systematically used the assumption of maximizing behavior in order to obtain
for typing a difficult manuscript.Jhe views expressed are solely those of the author and comparative statics theorems.
do not necessarily correspond to any policy or position of the Department of Manpower Samuelson does not provide a proof of the theorem.
a r ~ dImmigration. Of course, many "new" results are straightfonvard modifications of known results.
.*
W.E. Diewert

f d y simpler than existing proofs). In any case, the reader who is primarily
1g Applications of duality theory

production function satisfies certain regularity conditions, then we may


interested in applying the existing body of duality theory can read the paper calculate the producer's total minimum cost function C(y ;p l ,p 2 , ...,pN)=
independently of proofs, while the reader who is interested in modifying the
existing theory in order to suit his particular needs will probably find it 4
j@ 2
F;*,
+-
= C(y; p), where p = (p, ,p,, ...,p,) is the vector of input prices, as the
solution to the following constrained minimization problem:
useful to peruse the proofs.
In section 7, we briefly survey the nonparametric methods of obtaining C(y;p) = minx {pTx: f (x) 2 y).
systems of derived demand equations which are consistent with maximizing i In other words, the producer takes prices as given and attempts to minimize
behavior. the cost of producing a specified output level, y. In general, total cost C
In section 8, we note how duality theory can make the variable coefficients depends on y, the chosen output level; p, the given vector of input prices;
simplex algorithm as simple to use as the ordinary simplex algorithm for and f, the given production function.
linear programming. A production function f determines a cost function C through definition
, From a mathematical point of view, duality theory rests on a theorem due (1). What is not as well known, is the converse, that a cost function satisfying
to Minkowski (191 1): every closed4 convex5 set in R~ can be characterized certain regularity conditions determines a production function; that is, there
as the intersection of its supporting half space^.^ We shall see how this theo- is a duality between cost and production functions. Given one of these func-
rem from mathematics creeps into economics in the following two sections. tions, under certain regularity conditions, the other can be uniquely deter-
Notation: x 2 0, means each component of the vector x is nonnegative; mined, a result originally due to Shephard (1953) and Samuelson (1953-4).
ON is an N-dimensional vector of zeroes; x > ON means x 2 ON, but x # ON; The production function can in general be obtained from a cost function
x D ON means each component of x is positive; E means "belongs to"; satisfying the appropriate regularity conditions as the solution to the follow-
xTy is Zxiyi, the inner product of the vectors x and y ; Vf(x) is the gradient
vector of first order partial derivatives o f f evaluated at x ; V2f(x) is the
Hessian matrix of second order partial derivatives o f f evaluated at x ;
S u T means the union of the sets S and T; and Sn T is the intersection of I
-
ing constrained maximization problem:
f * ( ~ ) max, {y: C(y; p) _< p T for
~ every p 2 ON), (2)
where R = (Z,, Z,, ..., ZN)is a given vector of inputs and C is the given cost
S and T. function. Note that problem (2) has an infinite number of constraints.
A geometric interpretation of the maximization problem (2) can be ob-
tained as follows: for every vector of factor prices p > ON,we can graph the
1. Duality between unit cost and production functions I set of input combinations x such that pTx = C(y; p) for some fixed output
level y. Since C(y;p) is supposed to represent the minimum cost of producing
Assume we are given an N factor production function f, where y =f(x, , output y given prices p, it is reasonable to assume that the set L(y) =
x2, ...,xN)=f(x) means y is the maximal amount of output which can be = {x:f(x) 2 y) lies within the halfspace H(y; p) = { X : ~2~C(y; X p)). In
produced during a given period of time using xi units of input i for i = fact, we may define the envelope production possibilities set L4(y) as the
= 1,2, ..., N, where x = (x,, x,, ...,
xN) is the vector of input levels. If the intersection over all price vectors p > 0, of the halfspaces H(y;p); i.e.,
L*(y) = " p > ON H(y; p). Now choose j so that Z belongs to the boundary
A set S in RN (Euclidean N space) is closed if 2'E S for n = 1,2, ..., lim x"= x0
of L* ( j ) ,and we have determined j =f(Z) using only the given cost function
implies x0 E S. C. Moreover, we will have C(7; p) = pTZ for some p > ON,where C(j;p) 5
A set S in RN is convex if for every x E S, y E S and scalar 1 such that 0 51_< 1, S p T 2 for every p 2 ON. Notice that we have defined the set L"(y) as the
we have k + ( l - 1 ) Y E S.
A halfspace in R N is a set of'the form { x : a T x 5 k } , where aTx =
intersection of a family of halfspaces, where each halfspace was defined by an
a,xl is the
inner product of the vectors a and x. See Fenchel(1953, pp. 48-50) or Rockafellar (1970, isocost surface. In order for the envelope production possibilities setL* (y) t o
pp. 95-99) for a treatment of Minkowski's theorem. coincide with the "true" production possibilities set L(y) = {x:f(x) 2 y),
/
>
is,-

W. E. Diewert i,&- Applications of duality theory 177


[ g?
Mangasarian, O.L., 1969, Nonlinear Programming, New York, McGraw-Hill. 4 @
I 25. Second, the set of production possibilities is assumed to be contained in
Rockafellar, R.T.. 1970, Convex Analysis, Princeton, New Jersey, Princeton University
-{z
{b "I:- <.. R"+', that is, there are (n+ 1) distinct commodities.
Press.
Shephard, R.W., 1953, Cost and Production Functions, Princeton, New Jersey, Princeton
Universitv Press.
r$.
i .!j
Third, the function which gives the value of the supremum of the negative
+
of the quantity of the (n 1)st commodity contained in the set of production
Shephard, R. W., 1970, Theory of Cost and Production Functions, Princeton, New Jersey,
Princeton University Press. .-- possibilities for given values of the quantities of the remaining n commodities
is defined as the production function and denoted F(y), where y is a vector
F P O X ~+,c 0&MQrsk+Q+;Ja Eco*-;c~ % 1 x)&dB
* :
~
M m - r ~BY LAWRENCE J. L A U ~
1 ' in Rn having as its elements the quantities of the 11 remaining commodities.
haD*Te+ri / ; It is assumed that the (n + 1)st commodity is variable and freely disposable.'
Stanford University
3 The reader will note that this function reduces to the negative of the conven-
0. Introduction tional production function in the one-output case. Other terminology for
F(y) includes the joint production function, the production possibility
Professor Erwin Diewert has provided us with a very sweeping survey of the frontier and the transformation function.' I shall refer to this function as the
applications of duality theory in the many different and seemingly unrelated production function.
areas of economics. His survey serves to give us a flavor of what can be done Fourth, the productibn function F(jl) is an extended-real-valued function,
with duality theory. And the potential appears to be unbounded. He has that is, it is permitted to take infinite values. F(j1) is said to be proper if it is
included in his survey, not only the results of published research, but also finite for some y and does not take the value minus infinity anywhere.
many as yet unpublished original results of his own. We should thank Fifth, the conjugate convex function of F(y), denoted F*(y*), is given by
Erwin Diewert for this very excellent survey of a relatively new area of
research which will be useful for years to come. F*(Y*) = sup { ( y , Y*) - F ( Y ) ) ,
Y
In what follows I would like to put forth my own views on duality
theory, which, I hope, complement Diewerts' survey, and clarify some where (,) denotes the inner product operation and they" may be interpreted
issues. My comment can be divided ~ n t ofour sections: (1) Some definitional, as normalized prices, that is, the prices of the commodities divided by the
methodological and terminological issues; (2) Implications of duality for price of the (n+ 1)st commodity. It may be referred to as the normalized
applied econometrics; (3) More applications of duality theory; and (4) profit function because it can be identified with the profit function, a function
Directions for related research. , of (n+ 1) prices, if the price of the (n+ 1)st commodity is set equal to unity.
I I
Other terminology for F* (y*) includes the Unit-Output-Price of UOP profit
f ~ n c t i o n I. ~shall refer to the F* (y*) as the normalized profit function.
1. Some definitional, methodological and terminological issues Sixth, of special interest is the case in which the quantities of a subset of
the commodities are fixed. Adhering to the convention of always choosing
1 .O. Some preliminaries a variable and freely disposable commodity as the (11 + 1)st commodity, one
Before taking up the issues, a few preliminary remarks about conventions and may partition a given y into two mutually exclusive subsets, y', which
notations used in this comment are in order. consists of variable commodities, anti z, which consists of fixed commodities.
First, the quantities of commodities are measured with positive signs
when they are net outputs and negative signs when they are net inputs. f r c c disposal of the (,I+I)st commodity is requircd for the one-to-one correspon-
dence betwen a closed, convex set of production possibilities and a closed, convex function
* The author thanks Erwin Diewert, Arthur Goldberger, Dale Jorgenson and Daniel F(y). If the free disposal assumption is droppcd, two I'unctions, F+(y) and F-(y) will be
McFadden for very useful discussions but retains full responsibility for any error contained required to characterize the convex set of production possibilities completely.
herein. Financial support from the National Science Foundation through Grant No. GS- This terminology is uscd by Diewert (1973). However, i t is different from ;L related
2874-A1 to the Institute of Mathematical Studies in the Social Sciences of Stanford concept by the same name used by Mcfitdden (19734.
University is gratefully acknowledged. This terminology is used in Lau (1969).
Applications of duality theory 179

The conjugate convex function of F(y', z), considered a function of y', :I its modern form, this theory states that given F(y), a closed, proper and
denoted F* (y'*, z), is given by convex function, its conjugate dual, defined as
f $
. F*(Y*) = sup {(Y,y*) - F(y)}
Y
E r

I is also a closed proper convex fu~~ction.


Moreover, the dual of the dual,
where the y'* may again be interpreted as normalized prices. It may be ! defined as
referred to as the normalized restricted profit function: because it can be
identified with the restricted profit function if the price of the (n+ 1)st
commodity is set equal to unity. Other terminology for the restricted profit is equal to F(y):
function include gross profit function,' partial profit f ~ n c t i o n and
, ~ variable
F * * ( ~ )= F(y).
profit function.' We note that in the case that z is a vector of outputs, and y'
is a vector of inputs, F* (yl*, z) is the negative of the normalized cost func- Hence there is a one-to-one correspoi~dencebetween F(y) and F*(y*).
tion; in the case that z is a vector of inputs, and y' is a vector of outputs, Economically, this implies a one-to-one correspondence between the
F*(yl*, z ) is the normalized revenue function; in the case that the quantities production function and the normnlized profit function under the assumption
of all commodities are variable, the normalized restricted profit function is of closure, properness, and convexity. The precursor of this conjugacy
the normalized profit function. correspondence is of course the classical Legendre transformation. This
Seventh, the subgradient of a convex function F(y) at y, denoted y*, is transformation was implicit in the pioneering work of Hotelling (1932) on
defined by the system of inequalities the normalized profit function. This line of reasoning was taken up by
Samuelson (1953) and Lau (1969) for the differentiable case, and by Jorgen-
F(x) 2 F(y) + (y*,x-y) Vx. son and Lau (1973) for the general case. One may add that with the additional
The set of all subgradients at y denoted aF(y) is referred to as the subdiffer- assumption of nonproducibility of the (n+ 1)st con~modity,that is, it must
ential of F(y) at y. If the subdifferential at y consists of only one element, it is be used as an input, the properties of F(y) and F*(y*) are completely
equal to the gradient of F Q at y, denoted VF(y). Given the subdifferential, identical - they are both nonnegative and are equal to zero at the origin.'
a closed, proper and convex function is determined up to a n additive g Any function that can be used as a production function can also be used as a
constant. normalized profit function, and vice versa, and the duality is completely
symmetric.
The second group of approaches is based on the symmetric duality
1. I. Alternative approaches to duality theory between gauge functions', or distance functions, or polar cones of convex
There are as many alternative approaches to duality theory as there are sets. Shephard (1953) was the pioneer of this group. He proved the duality
individuals working in the field of duality theory. These different approaches theorem between production and cost functions under the assumption of
may be approximately classified, at the risk of gross simplification, into three differentiability employing the concept of distance functions. Other scholars
groups. who have used similar approaches include Gorrnan (1968), McFadden
The&~f,gfrup 2f approaches is based on the conjugacy correspondence (1973a), Hanoch (1973), and Jacobsen ( 1 970, 1972), among others.
developed by ~enchel'(l949,1953) and extended by Rockafellar (1970a). In The third group of approaches is based 011the duality between the set of
prod"&i6n po%sibilitiesand its support function. The work of Uzawa (1964),
McFadden (1966) and Diewert (1971, 1973) may be classified amongst this
This terminology follows McFadden (1973a).
This terminology is used by Gorrnan (1968).
group.
This terminology is used by Lau (1969).
' This terminology is used by Diewert (1973). Unskilled labor appears to be the natural choice for the (?I+ ])st commodity.
67.10 CONJUGATE CONVEX FUNCTIONALS 195

Let y be an arbitrary point in e. Since is (relatively) open, there is a for each a E R. It follows that the set
p > 1 such that By E c. Given E > 0,let 6 > 0 be such that llxll < 6 implies T, = {x : x E C, f (x) I a)
If (x)l < E . Then for llz - yll < (1 - 8-')6, we have is closed.
z =y + (1 - 8-')x = p-'(py) + (1 - p-')x Now suppose {xi) is a sequence from C converging to x E C: Let
b = lim inf f (xi). If b = - co, then x E T, = To for each a E R which is
for some x E c with llxll < 6. Thus z E C and X,+X

impossible. Thus b > - co and x E Tb+£= Tb+£for all E > 0. In other


words, f (x) I lim inf f (xi) which proves that f is lower semicontinuous.
X,+X

Thus f is bounded above in the sphere llz - yll < (1 - 8-')a. It follows Figure 7.9 shows the graph of a convex functionalf defined on a disk C
that for sufficiently large r the point (r, y) is an interior point of [f, C]; in E2 that has closed [f,C] but is discontinuous (although lower semi-
hence, by Proposition 1,f is continuous at y. I continuous) at a point x.
The proof of the following important corollary is left to the reader.
Corollary 1. A convexfunctional defined on a finite-dimensional convex set C
is continuous throughout c.
Having established the simple relation between continuity and interior
points, we conclude this section by noting a property off which holds i j
[f, C] happens to be closed. As illustrated in Figure 7.8, closure of
[f,C] is related to the continuity properties off on the boundary of C.

Figure 7.9

7.10 Conjugate Convex Functionals


A purely abstract approach to the theory of convex functionals, including
a study of the convex set Lf, C] as in the previous section, leads quite
naturally to an investigation of the dual representation of this set in terms
of closed hyperplanes. The concept of conjugate functionals plays a natural
and fundamental role in such a study. As an important consequence of this
Figure 7.8 A nonclosed epigraph investigation, we obtain a very general duality principle for optimization
problems which extends the earlier duality results for minimum norm
Proposition 3. If [f, C] is closed, then f is lower semicontinuous on C. problems.

Proof. The set {(a, x) E R x X : x E X) is obviously closed for each Definition. Let f be a convex functional defined on a convex set C in a
a E R. Hence, if [f,C] is closed, so is normed space X. The conjugate set C* is defined as

[f,C] n { ( a , ~ :)x E X) = { ( a , ~ )x: i C;f(x) 5 a)


c * = {x* E x*:sup [(x, x*>
x EC
- f ( x ) ] < co)
$7.10 CONJUGATE CONVEX FUNCTIONALS 197
and the functional f * conjugate to f is defined on C * as The supremum on the right is achieved by some x since the problem is
finite dimensional. We h d , by differentiation, the solution
f *(x*) = sup [(x, x*) - f (~11.
x 0C = IxrlP-' sgn xi
Proposition 1. The conjugate set C* and the conjugate functional f * are
convex and [f *, C *] is a closed convex subset of R x X *.

Proof. For any x:, x; E X* and any u, 0 < u < 1, we have where l/p + l/q = 1.
Let us investigate the relation of the conjugate functional to separating
SUP {(x, ux:
x 0C
+ (1 - u)x,*) - f (x)) = xsupC {uC(x, x:) - f (x)]
E hyperplanes. On the space R x X, closed hyperplanes are represented by
an equation of the form (r,X) E IRxX
+ (1 - u)C(x, x;) - f (xlll (s,x% RXK*
Or SUP C(x, xr> - f ( 4 1
((b ,X ) , (s,fl>> = sr + (x, x*) =k
x EC
where s, k, and x* determine the hyperplane. Recalling that we agreed to
+ (1 - a) XSUEPC C(x, x;> - f (x)l refer to the R axis as vertical, we say that a hyperplane is nonvertical if it
intersects the R axis at one and only one point. This is equivalent to the
from which it follows immediately that C* and f * are convex. requirement that the defining linear functional (s, x*) have s # 0. If atten-
Next we prove that [f *, C*] is closed. Let {(st, x*)) be a convergent tion is restricted to nonvertical hyperplanes, we may, without loss of
sequence from [f *, C*] with (s,, x:) + (s, x*). We show now that generality, consider only those linear functionals of the form (- 1, x*).
(s, x*) E [f *, C *]. For every i and every x E C, we have Any nonvertical closed hyperplane can then be obtained by appropriate
choice of x* and k.
sr 2 f *($) 2 (x, x:) - f (x). To develop a geometric interpretation of the conjugate functional, note
that as k varies, the solutions (r, x) of the equation
Taking the limit as i -+ a , we obtain
(x, x*) -r =k
s 2 (x, x*) - f (x)
describe parallel closed hyperplanes in R x X. The number f *(x*) is the
for all x E C. Therefore, supremum of the values of k for which the hyperplane intersects [f, C].
Thus the hyperplane (x, x*) - r =f*(x*) is a support hyperplane of
s 2 sup C(x, x*) - f cf, CI.
XEC In the terminology of Section 5.13, f *(x*) is the support functional
from which it follows that x* E C* and s 2 f *(x*). ) h[(- 1, x*)} of the functional (- 1, x*) for the convex set [f, C]. The
special feature here is that we only consider functionals of the form
We see that the conjugate functional defines a set [f *, C*] which is of (- 1, x*) on R x X and thereby eliminate the need of carrying an extra
the same type as [f, C] ; therefore we write [f, a*
= Lf *, C*]. Note that variable.
iff = 0, the conjugate functionalf * becomes the support functional of C. For the application to optimization problems, the most important geo-
metric interpretation of the conjugate functional is that it measures vertical
Example 1. Let X = C = En and define, for x = (x,, x, , . . . , x,), f (x) = distance to the support hyperplane. The hyperplane
l/p x!=, IxllP, 1 < p c a. Then for x* = (5,, 5,, . .. , c,),

intersects the vertical axis (i.e., x =8) at (- f *(x*), 8). Thus, -f *(x*) is
the vertical height of the hyperplane above the origin. (See Figure 7.10.)
198 OPTIMIZATION OF FUNCTIONALS 7 57.1 1 CONJUGATE CONCAVE FUNCTIONALS 199
We prove the converse by contraposition. Let (r,, x,) q! [f, C]. Since
[f, C] is closed, there is a hyperplane separating (r,, x,) and [f,C].
Thus there exist x* E X*, s, and c such that

for all (r, X) E [f, C]. It can be shown that, without loss of generality, this
hyperplane can be assumed to be nonvertical and hence s # 0 (see Prob-
lem 16). Furthermore, since r can be made arbitrarily large, we must have
s < 0. Thus we take s = - 1. Now it follows that (x, x*) - f (x) I c
for all x E C, which implies that (c, x*) E [f *, C*]. On the other
hand, c < (x, , x*) - r, implies (x, , x*) - c > r, , which implies that
Figure 7.10 A conjugate convex functional (r0, xo) $ *[f*, C*l. I
Another interpretation more clearly illuminates the duality between
[f, C] and [f*, C*] in terms of the dual representation of a convex set 7.11 Conjugate Concave Functionals
as a collection of points or as the intersection of half-spaces. Given the A development similar to that of the last section applies to concave func-
point (s, x*) E R x X*, let us associate the half-space consisting of all tional~.It must be stressed, however, that we do not treat concave func-
(r, x) E R x X satisfying tional~by merely multiplying by - 1 and then applying the theory for
(x, x*) - r l s. convex functionals. There is an additional sign change in part of the
Then the set [f *, C *] consists of those (nonvertical) half-spaces that con- definition. See Problem 15.
tain the set [f, C]. Hence [f *, C*] is the dual representation of [f , C]. Given a concave functional g defined on a convex subset D of a vector
Beginning with an arbitrary convex functional cp defined on a convex space, we define the set
subset r of a dual space X*, we may, of course, define the conjugate of cp [g, Dl = ((r, X) : x E D, r Ig(x)).
in X** or, alternatively, following the standard pattern for duality rela-
tions (e.g., see Section 5.7), define the set * r in X as The set [g, Dl is convex and all of the results on continuity, interior points,
etc., of Section 7.9 have direct extensions here.
Definition. Let g be a concave functional on the convex set D. The con-
and the convex functional
jugate set D* is defined as
*cp(x) = SUP C(x, x*) - cp(x*)I
x* € r D* = (x* E X*: inf[(x, x*) - g(x)] > -a),
on * r . We then write *[p, r] = [*cp, *r]. With these definitions we have xeD

the following characterization of the duality between a convex functional and the functional g* conjugate to g is defined as
and its conjugate.
Proposition 2. Let f be a convex functional on the convex set C in a normed
g*(x*) = inf [(x, x*) - g(x)]:,Srp
xeD xcD
-<
f-f~x) X, xc>l
space X. If [f, C] is closed, then [f, C] = *[[f, CI*]. We can readily verify that D* is convex and that g* is concave. We
Proof. We show first that [f, C] c *[f*, C*] = *[[f, CI*]. Let write [g, Dl* = [g*, D*].
(r, x) E [f, C] ; then for all x* E C*, f *(x*) 2 (x, x*) -f (x). Hence, we Since our notation does not completely distinguish between the develop-
have r 2 f(x) 2 (x, x*) -f *(x*) for all x* E C*. Thus ment for convex and concave functionals, it is important to make clear
r 2 sup [(x, x*)- f *(x*)l which is being employed in any given context. This is particularly true when
x* € C* the original function is linear, since either definition of the conjugate
and (r,x) ~ * [ f * ,C*]. functional might be employed and, in general, they are not equal.
View publication stats

You might also like