You are on page 1of 42

P1: JLS

Journal of Archaeological Research [jar] pp1095-jare-479712 April 12, 2004 10:36 Style file version Nov 28th, 2002

Journal of Archaeological Research, Vol. 12, No. 2, June 2004 (


C 2004)

Modeling the Roles of Craft Production


in Ancient Political Economies
Edward M. Schortman1,2 and Patricia A. Urban1

Ongoing debates over the significance of specialized production in ancient po-


litical economies frequently hinge on questions of whether elites or commoners
controlled craft manufactures and whether the material or ideological import
of these production processes was more significant in deciding power contests.
Though long recognized, such queries were traditionally answered in relatively
straightforward economic terms. Recently, these time-honored approaches have
been questioned. An ever increasing number of authors are promoting varied takes
on the causal linkages between political forms and processes, on the one hand,
and patterns of production, distribution, and use of craft goods, on the other. The
literature generated by these discussions is extensive, vibrant, and often confusing.
Rather than trying to synthesize all reports and essays dealing with specialized
manufacture, this paper highlights general interpretive trends that underlie and
structure current debates. The concluding section offers suggestions for how stud-
ies of relations among crafts, power, and social heterogeneity might be pursued
profitably in the future.
KEY WORDS: craft production; political economy; power; specialized manufacture.

INTRODUCTION

The significance of craft production in the genesis and functioning of an-


cient sociopolitical structures has been one of the most hotly debated topics in
archaeology over the last two decades. Issues of power, agency, resistance to dom-
ination, and the cultural significance of daily practice that are so pervasive in the
archaeological literature all converge in discussions of specialized manufacture.
1 AnthropologyDepartment, Kenyon College, Gambier, Ohio.
2 To
whom correspondence should be addressed at Anthropology Department, Kenyon College,
Gambier, Ohio 43022; e-mail: schortma@kenyon.edu.

185
1059-0161/04/0600-0185/0 
C 2004 Plenum Publishing Corporation
P1: JLS
Journal of Archaeological Research [jar] pp1095-jare-479712 April 12, 2004 10:36 Style file version Nov 28th, 2002

186 Schortman and Urban

The manner in which these subjects are combined and recombined by scholars
examining diverse manufacturing processes occurring in varied settings and time
periods creates a volatile and dynamic mix of approaches that resists synthesis. It
is easy to be overwhelmed by this diversity, to believe that there are no themes
undergirding craft production studies. We attempt to counter that impression.
Archaeologists traditionally relegated specialized manufacture to the eco-
nomic realm. Artisans produced material surpluses essential to the functioning
of state institutions and meeting the needs of their burgeoning populations (e.g.,
Childe, 1950, 1956). Craft industries and political formations were linked in these
early formulations through economic forces of supply and demand (Wailes, 1996).
Diverging from this trend were V. Gordon Childe’s pioneering investigations
into relations among craft production, patronage, market demands, technological
innovation, and the implications of all these factors for social evolution in the an-
cient Near East and Europe (e.g., Childe, 1942, 1956; Wailes, 1996). In general,
Childe argued that concentration of wealth and power in the hands of Bronze Age
Sumerian magnates thwarted the development of a broad market for craft goods.
This, combined with the estrangement of artisans from their products, the latter
controlled exclusively by rulers and their agents, retarded economic expansion and
technological innovation. Europe’s itinerant smiths, at the same time, fashioned
and distributed their wares largely free of elite supervision. This relatively egali-
tarian context encouraged scientific progress, technological experimentation, and
the development of more dynamic sociopolitical structures (Childe, 1942, 1956;
Trigger, 1980, pp. 108–109). Though the above model is now acknowledged to
be overly simplistic, the distinction Childe drew between independent commoner
artisans (of Europe) and client specialists working for elites and state institutions
(in Sumeria) continues to pervade the craft production literature, as will be seen
later (Wailes, 1996).
Childe’s insights have been taken up and elaborated upon by those seeking
to understand the roles craftworkers played in the creation of ancient societies, in
general, and the fashioning of hierarchy, in particular. This reimagining of rela-
tions among specialized manufacture and sociopolitical processes is driven by a
burgeoning database and an increasing emphasis on the importance of individu-
als and factions in the production and reproduction of social and cultural forms
(Bourdieu, 1977; E. Brumfiel, 1992; Giddens, 1984; see papers in E. Brumfiel
and Fox, 1994). The importance of craft manufacture to long-term economic pro-
cesses is not denied. What is being challenged is the notion that fabricating items
at any scale can be understood as a purely economic activity that solely generates
surpluses to meet market demands. Instead, artisans are increasingly envisioned
as having actively participated in fashioning the social and cultural worlds they
inhabited. How they went about this creative process, and how much freedom they
enjoyed in its enactment, are hotly contested.
This debate has generated a voluminous and diverse literature, and writing
on the topic shows no signs of abating (see Costin, 2001, for an excellent recent
P1: JLS
Journal of Archaeological Research [jar] pp1095-jare-479712 April 12, 2004 10:36 Style file version Nov 28th, 2002

Modeling the Roles of Craft Production in Ancient Political Economies 187

review of the general craft production literature). Such variety reflects great intel-
lectual vigor but also obscures the basic issues being considered and the directions
investigations are taking. We highlight some of these topics and trends, construct-
ing a model that focuses on the instrumental quality of specialized manufacture,
how researchers imagine that artisans and their products figured in power contests.
Like all conceptual frameworks, this one simplifies a complex reality in order to
identify patterns. The resulting summary is not definitive, not the statement on craft
production. It is a review that, hopefully, clarifies some points while suggesting
areas where future research may yield fruitful results.

BASIC TERMS AND THEMES

The model outlined here focuses on how researchers, since 1982, have imag-
ined the place of craft manufacture in ancient, hierarchically structured political
economies, those imperfect, negotiated, dynamic relations that exist among pro-
cesses of production, consumption, and distribution, on the one side, and the or-
ganization and use of power, on the other (J. Arnold and Munns, 1994; Cobb,
1993; Hayden, 1995; Pauketat, 1997; Poole, 1991). Craft specialization, the el-
ement of production dealt with here, is defined as fashioning items at volumes
above and beyond the needs of the producing individual or group for exchange
with those engaged in complementary economic pursuits (Clark, 1986, p. 45; Clark
and Parry, 1990; Cobb, 1993, p. 66; Costin, 1991, 2001; Inomata, 2001, p. 322;
Stein, 1994, 1996, 1998). Attention, therefore, centers on how researchers have
drawn connections among the fabrication, distribution, and use of specific goods,
on the one hand, and, on the other, processes of political centralization (the extent
to which power is concentrated in a few hands), social differentiation (variation
in the identities assumed by members of a polity based on combinations of social
[e.g., kinship], economic [e.g., occupation], and/or ideological factors [e.g., affil-
iation with specific cults]), and inequality (whether, and to what extent, holders
of these identities have unequal access to resources, including power) (Balandier,
1970; de Montmollin, 1989; Feinman and Neitzel, 1984; Hayden, 2001; McGuire,
1983; Nelson, 1995; Paynter, 1989; Paynter and McGuire, 1991).
Values for these six variables, each treated as a continuum, are outlined in
Table I. The form any one factor takes at a specific place and time is related to
those assumed by the others, albeit in a nonmechanistic manner. The six domains
briefly outlined earlier and in Table I were selected because their importance in
the study of ancient political economies is reflected by the considerable attention
they have received over the last two decades.
Each researcher who deals with specialized manufacture handles the above
relations in a distinctive manner. We cannot do justice to this full range of vari-
ation here. Instead we will group recent investigations of crafts and political
economies under several broad headings that highlight similarities in the ways
P1: JLS

188

Table I. Components of the Various Processes Emphasized in Craft Production Studies


Variable Continua of variation

Manufacturing processes
Raw material sources Local Foreign
Journal of Archaeological Research [jar]

Acquisition strategies Simple, easily mastered, require Complex, hard to learn, need the coordinated
little coordinated effort work of many individuals
Production skills Easily learned and used Hard to learn, need considerable practice to maintain
Scale of production Few people, limited steps, Numerous artisans, complexly organized
little energy investment production steps, major energy expenditures
Time devoted to craft production Part-time Full-time
(Intensity)
Physical setting (concentration) Dispersed Aaggregated near elite compounds and administrative
centers
pp1095-jare-479712

Institutional setting (context) Independent of direct elite conrol Attached to, and supported by, elite patrons
Primary identity of the artisan Not tied to craft production As an artisan participating in a specific craft
Consumption and distribution processes
Restrictions on the distribution None, decentralized Significant, determined by elites
and use of particular goods
Demand Low and intermittent High and constant
April 13, 2004

Purposes to which goods are put Daily maintenance chores Political domination and resistance to same
Relation of producers and Equal Unequal
consumers
Political structure and process
16:51

Centralization Power is diffused and situationally Power is concentrated and institutionalized


deployed
Differentiation Relatively few distinguishable Numerous distinct identities
identities
Inequality Access to resources relatively Resource access restricted to people holding
open to all certain affiliations
Schortman and Urban
Style file version Nov 28th, 2002
P1: JLS
Journal of Archaeological Research [jar] pp1095-jare-479712 April 12, 2004 10:36 Style file version Nov 28th, 2002

Modeling the Roles of Craft Production in Ancient Political Economies 189

in which political and economic processes are linked. The four themes singled out
for discussion here deal with craft goods as sources of economic power, founts of
ideological preeminence, means to achieving a degree of household and commu-
nity autonomy, and essential in creating and reproducing cultural frameworks of
meaning and affiliation. Pervading these intellectual motifs is a set of frequently
repeated oppositions that pit elites against commoners and an object’s meaning
against its economic significance. These enduring archaeological dichotomies en-
courage researchers to return time and again to two major questions: “Who controls
and/or benefits to the greatest degree from craft production, elites or commoners?”;
and “Are craft goods primarily used to convey meaning or to achieve economic
ends?” How investigators respond to these queries shapes their understandings of
a craft’s significance within ancient political economies. The utility of maintaining
such distinctions is considered at the essay’s conclusion.
The aforementioned themes are used to organize a complex, burgeoning lit-
erature into a manageable form, not as pigeonholes for classifying research on
specialized manufacture. Particular investigators do not blindly follow one theme
to the exclusion of all others. Many, in fact, address several of these motifs si-
multaneously or at different points in their careers. Rather than categorizing re-
searchers and their efforts, our goal is to highlight issues to which scholars fre-
quently refer when examining how the manufacture, distribution, and use of crafted
goods are related to processes of political centralization, social differentiation, and
inequality.

CRAFT PRODUCTION AS A MEANS TO POWER

The first two themes alluded to above directly implicate craft production
in processes of political centralization and the creation of inequality. Elites are
perceived as active agents in the formulations summarized later, their manipulation
of specialized manufacture precipitating dramatic and enduring transformations
of extant political arrangements. Scholars pursuing this line of inquiry also stress
the functional significance of craft production, asking how this activity serves
to promote the interests of some at the expense of others. A concern with what
specialized manufacture “does” in political economies encourages the formulation
of cross-cultural generalizations. The search for these regularities is based on the
premise that the creation of hierarchy poses certain universal challenges, the most
pressing of which are how to convert equals into subordinates and encourage their
acquiescence to these radically changed circumstances. Faced with such recurring
problems, it is argued, would-be rulers consistently and independently fashion
similar solutions that involve craft production. These research themes diverge
over the relative weight attributed to the economic and ideological significance of
the goods artisans fashion. Many scholars, however, synthesize both approaches
in their studies of specific cases.
P1: JLS
Journal of Archaeological Research [jar] pp1095-jare-479712 April 12, 2004 10:36 Style file version Nov 28th, 2002

190 Schortman and Urban

Creating Power Through Dependency

The use of craft production as an economic resource employed in elite domina-


tion strategies is most systematically expressed in “prestige goods theory” (Dupre
and Rey, 1973; Ekholm, 1972, 1978; Frankenstein and Rowlands, 1978; Friedman,
1982; Friedman and Rowlands, 1978; Kristiansen, 1991; Meillassoux, 1981; see
also the concept of “wealth finance” advanced by Costin and Earle, 1989; D’Altroy
and Earle, 1985; Earle, 1987, 1991, 1994, 1997, 2001). Power, in this framework,
depends on control over labor and its products (J. Arnold, 1993, 1995, 1996; Cobb,
1993; Earle, 1991, 1997; Hayden, 1995, 1998, pp. 17–18; 2001, pp. 254–255). In-
dividuals and factions who can secure privileged access to the productive efforts
of the majority are, therefore, well begun on their political ascent.
But given that all involved are committed to protecting their labor and its fruits,
how is such control established and institutionalized? The answer lies in the ability
of emergent elites to undercut the autonomy of their subordinates by monopolies
over the local, intrapolity distribution of those goods that all need to reproduce
themselves socially (i.e., objects that figure in displays and transactions that affirm,
create, and formalize interpersonal ties) (J. Arnold, 1996; E. M. Brumfiel, 1987;
E. Brumfiel and Earle, 1987; Hayden, 1998, 2001, p. 258; Kim, 2001; Pauketat,
1997, pp. 42–48; Saitta, 1994; 1997, p. 14; 2000; Stein, 1996, p. 32; 1998; Trubitt,
2000). If a few can monopolize these essential commodities, then the majority
become dependents of the monopolists (J. Arnold, 1995; Bayman, 1996; Clark
and Blake, 1994; Earle, 1987; Stein, 2001, pp. 364–365; Tosi, 1984). Under such
conditions, most members of a population surrender labor, loyalty, and surpluses
in return for goods they desperately need and which are only obtainable from
those occupying the hierarchy’s apex. Unrepayable debt leads to dependency that
is, in turn, bathed in the soft glow of mutual exchange (J. Arnold, 1996; Hayden,
1995, 1998). Though subordinates receive less than they give, all parties to the
transactions are giving and receiving something. Experience of exploitation is,
therefore, muted even if in reality rulers are systematically enriched at the expense
of their followers (Earle, 1997, p. 67).
There are several routes to this end. Magnates can exert exclusive control
over the parochial disbursement of finished exotics important to local social pro-
cesses and even physical survival. For example, those occupants of California’s
Channel Islands who could monopolize the means for traversing the dangerous
straits separating these isles from the mainland were able to reconfigure politi-
cal and economic relations in their favor during the period AD 1150–1300. They
alone became the sources of assets from the mainland needed by island populations
(J. Arnold, 1993).
Alternatively, elites could monopolize the fashioning of essential commodi-
ties in workshops staffed by their clients (Clark and Parry, 1990; Earle, 1991, 2001;
Feinman, 1991, 1995; Hayden, 1994, 1995, 1998; Peregrine, 1991a,b; Stein, 1998;
P1: JLS
Journal of Archaeological Research [jar] pp1095-jare-479712 April 12, 2004 10:36 Style file version Nov 28th, 2002

Modeling the Roles of Craft Production in Ancient Political Economies 191

Trubitt, 2000; Wattenmaker, 1998). In either case, it is not necessary that magnates
supervise entire production and distribution processes to undermine successfully
their followers’ independence (Earle, 1994, p. 451; 2001; Lemonnier, 1992, p. 22).
Controlling strategic points in one of the sequences will suffice.
For example, the Inka managed to exert tremendous influence over the dis-
tribution of metal tools and ornaments within their extensive empire by replacing
copper with tin–copper alloys. This shift effectively reduced the ability of local
populations to make status-defining items of social display from widely available
copper sources as the limited supplies of Andean tin were under imperial control
(Earle, 1994, p. 456; Earle and D’Altroy, 1989, p. 203).
It would be naive and misleading to surmise that all scholars pursuing the pres-
tige goods theme consistently arrive at similar conclusions. Still, they share certain
understandings of how the political and economic variables outlined in Table I are
related. Specifically, prestige goods models posit elite patronage of crafts that use
imported raw materials and, most importantly, have high skill requirements. These
two factors facilitate monopolization of the manufacturing process, or important
steps within it, as access to essential physical and intellectual resources can be
centrally monitored (DeMarrais et al., 1996, pp. 22–23; Earle, 1994, p. 446; 1997,
pp. 197–199; Gibson, 1996, pp. 110, 114–115; Hayden, 1995, pp. 22, 44; Kenoyer,
2000; Moholy-Nagy, 1997, p. 309; Peregrine, 1991a, pp. 2–3; Spielmann, 1998,
2002; Wattenmaker, 1994, p. 118; 1998). For example, Harappan elites in the Indus
civilization during the 3rd millennium BC exclusively controlled the fashioning of
socially important items from locally available assets through the use of complex
firing technologies that they and their client artisans alone had mastered (Stein,
1998, pp. 22–23). This ability to monopolize technical knowledge contributed to
the creation of political hierarchies underwritten by debt and dependency (Stein,
1998, pp. 22–23).
Paramount funding of artisans, coupled with the high technical demands of
their professions, encourage full-time specialization and the physical congregation
of workshops within or near elite power centers. Distribution of political valuables
is also monopolized by rulers who thereby guarantee that they alone control who
receives, and in what quantities they receive, the goods in question. Demand,
therefore, tends to be limited but constant, resulting in production scales that are
relatively modest. Small groups of people laboring full-time for patrons yield sur-
pluses that are both sufficient and not so large as to swamp the market, thereby
reducing the rarity, and hence the political importance, of social valuables. In ad-
dition, the fewer people involved in the production process, the easier they are to
monitor (Costin and Hagstrum, 1995). When and where consumption levels are en-
hanced, the number of artisans, and their outputs, may well increase. This situation
could arise because the items involved are fragile and require frequent replacement
and/or they are regularly removed from circulation through, say, inclusion as burial
furniture. Such augmenting of the workforce might pose problems for controlling
P1: JLS
Journal of Archaeological Research [jar] pp1095-jare-479712 April 12, 2004 10:36 Style file version Nov 28th, 2002

192 Schortman and Urban

production as growing numbers of craftworkers are difficult to oversee (Costin and


Hagstrum, 1995).
These economic processes are closely wedded to both political centralization
and inequality. Prestige goods given to followers transform independent agents
into dependent clients whose labor and its products are now owed, in part, to their
“benefactors.” Unable to secure on their own those items that make social life
possible, subordinates must turn to the monopolists for these necessities and “pay
their price.” Loathe to alienate their patrons, the majority surrender at least some
of their autonomy and acquiesce to the demands of their leaders. Debt is the key
to dependence, which, in turn, is the foundation of power and the infrastructure of
hierarchy.
The link between the manufacture of prestige goods and social differentiation
is not as clearly or consistently drawn in the literature. Certainly, the development of
full-time artisans attached to elite patrons implies the emergence of social identities
that distinguish craftworkers from the rest of the population (Inomata, 2001; see
papers in Costin and Wright, 1998). The output of their manufacturing tasks is
also instrumental in forging novel elite affiliations overtly raised above those of
their subordinates. Beyond these developments, however, social differentiation is
not explicitly implicated in prestige goods politicoeconomic processes.

The Meaning of Power

The prestige goods approach stresses economic dependency as central to the


creation of political hierarchy. Recently, the symbolic content of political valuables
has come in for closer scrutiny. This research starts from the observation that
such objects are often highly decorated, creating visual impacts that are obvious
and strong, even to this day (Clark, 1996; Hayden, 1998). In traditional prestige
goods theory, this “hypertrophic” quality is seen as part of the effort to ensure that
political valuables are difficult to replicate because of the skills and mastery of
complex symbolic vocabularies involved in their creation (Clark, 1996, pp. 189–
193; Clark and Parry, 1990, pp. 296, 319; Hayden, 1998). Elites alone command
these intellectual resources and so can deny them to potential usurpers.
Increasingly, however, investigators are considering the possibility that the
complex designs adorning prestige goods were intended to convey information
crucial to bolstering ideologies of power and inequality. Deriving considerable
inspiration from Structural Marxism (e.g., Godelier, 1977), these researchers ar-
gue that centralized control over economic resources alone is insufficient for the
establishment of institutionalized power differentials (Giddens, 1984, pp. 258–
261). If these distinctions are to survive the demise of their creators, they must
be perceived as legitimate by all members of society. Naked exploitation rankles
and encourages covert resistance, if not outright revolt. Prestige goods, along with
P1: JLS
Journal of Archaeological Research [jar] pp1095-jare-479712 April 12, 2004 10:36 Style file version Nov 28th, 2002

Modeling the Roles of Craft Production in Ancient Political Economies 193

a variety of other practices, help conceal and/or rationalize inequality precisely


because of their information content.
Prestige goods, like all artifacts and constructions, materialize beliefs, making
the abstract tangible and, therefore, compelling (Baines and Yoffee, 2000, p. 15;
Bayman, 2002; A. Cohen, 1979; DeMarrais et al., 1996). If every cultural creation
conveys meaning, it is equally true that some objects are more potent symbols than
others. These are items that, for example, effectively synthesize important social
values and powerful emotional states, infusing one with the other (E. M. Brumfiel,
1987, 2000, p. 134; A. Cohen, 1979, p. 105; Turner, 1964). Whoever controls the
production of these potent symbols is in a position to, literally, fashion reality and
make their version believable (E. Brumfiel, 2000, p. 131; Clark, 1996; Clark and
Parry, 1990; Costin, 1996; DeMarrais et al., 1996; Dobres and Hoffman, 1995;
Earle, 1997, p. 10; Emerson, 1997, p. 214; Hayden, 1995, 1998; Inomata, 2001;
Joyce, 2000, pp. 71–72; Kim, 2001, pp. 462–464; Lechtman, 1993; Morrison, 1994,
pp. 41–42; Pauketat, 1997, pp. 42–48; Peregrine, 1991a, pp. 1–2; Pfaffenberger,
1992, pp. 503–507). They can write their preeminence into the “natural” order of
the universe using material culture, thereby rationalizing inequality and justifying
their power (Baines and Yoffee, 1998). The route to political control, therefore,
lies through monopolies over the fabrication of objects that convey, in emotionally
compelling ways, sociopolitical values that work to the advantage of the monopo-
lists. Failure to control exclusively the manufacture of these crucial symbols holds
the same threat that economic decentralization has in prestige goods models. In
this case, the danger is less that usurpers can short-circuit debt obligations than
that they can rewrite social relations to a script of their own choosing.
Elites frequently use their control over the creation and distribution of po-
tent material symbols to fashion and proclaim identities to which the powerful
alone can belong. These affiliations, hedged round with striking physical markers
accessible only to those of highest rank, often have local and regional signifi-
cance (Baines and Yoffee, 1998, 2000; Schortman, 1989). They both delimit the
boundaries of privilege within a polity and link paramounts in one realm with their
counterparts in another. For example, lords throughout the Maya Lowlands dur-
ing the Middle Preclassic through Late Classic periods (800 BC–AD 900) shared
distinctive features of dress, writing, and belief prominently displayed in public
settings (Freidel, 1986; Joyce, 2000; Sabloff, 1986). Many of the objects involved
were made by skilled clients of the rulers, or the elites themselves, as were the
stone and stucco monuments on which the relevant symbols were often embla-
zoned (Inomata, 2001). Such physically prominent expressions of identity served
to distinguish the ruling class from those who could not command the intellectual
and physical assets needed to participate in these displays. Explicit manifestations
of rulership using similar symbols also linked magnates from different polities,
providing them with a common vocabulary with which to engage in transactions,
ranging from commerce to marriage exchanges, crucial to sustaining their power.
P1: JLS
Journal of Archaeological Research [jar] pp1095-jare-479712 April 12, 2004 10:36 Style file version Nov 28th, 2002

194 Schortman and Urban

The result was an elite “culture” that transcended political boundaries and survived
intersocietal combat (Freidel, 1986; Sabloff, 1986). Comparable processes, some-
times glossed as “interaction spheres” (Caldwell, 1964), are attested to in a diverse
array of world areas and time periods (Lamberg-Karlovsky, 1993; Schortman,
1989).
This research raises questions of audiences, acceptance, and the kinds of
goods best suited to the tasks of over-awing and convincing the populace (Baines
and Yoffee, 1998, 2000). Addressing the last question first, these valuables should
have physical qualities that are naturally striking (such as the visual brilliance
of gold or the aural tones achieved with copper and bronze [Appadurai, 1986;
Hosler, 1994; Levy, 1999, p. 210; McAnany, 1993, pp. 74–75; Renfrew, 1986]) or
can reach that state through considerable labor investments (Hayden, 1998). Such
objects engage the senses and rivet attention on the messages they convey (Costin
and Hagstrum, 1995, p. 623).
The audiences addressed through displays of valuables differ significantly
depending, in part, on the size and overall visibility of the pieces and their contexts
of use. Following Wobst’s discussion of the communicative quality of material
items, large, ostentatious objects easily seen and recognized at a distance were
probably employed in public exhibitions in which sizable proportions of the total
population participated (Wobst, 1977). These artifacts, therefore, were deployed in
strategies aimed at achieving broad consensus concerning the ideas and relations
they manifest (DeMarrais et al., 1996). Items that might only be seen in more in-
timate settings, such as objects used in household tasks or small pieces of jewelry,
would speak to different audiences. Here, the goal may have been to solidify sup-
port for elite identities, and ensure cooperation, among holders of these affiliations
in contests for power and resources with those of lower status (Abercrombie et al.,
1980; Baines and Yoffee, 1998, 2000; Bowser, 2000; E. Brumfiel, 1996; DeMarrais
et al., 1996, pp. 25–26 Gilman, 1991, pp. 150–151). This distinction is not mutu-
ally exclusive. Imposing goods used conspicuously could simultaneously convey
messages to entire populations, legitimizing hierarchy, while reinforcing the im-
portance of cooperation among elites in safeguarding their shared preeminence.
In all cases, however, the central objective is to maintain centralized and exclusive
control over the production and display of symbolically rich items through which
power is expressed and rationalized.
The question of who accepts elite-sponsored messages and to what extent
they are believed is usually an open one. It is difficult enough to make such deter-
minations when we have access to living informants let alone in situations where
we must make due with archaeology’s mute remains. Symbols are susceptible to
multiple interpretations, overtly or covertly expressed (Bourdieu, 1979; Gailey,
1987; Moore, 1996, p. 171; Schortman et al., 2001, p. 314; Scott, 1985). Even
the cleverest strategies of the most charismatic individuals are not likely to win
everyone over to their way of thinking. We are left, therefore, with the remains
P1: JLS
Journal of Archaeological Research [jar] pp1095-jare-479712 April 12, 2004 10:36 Style file version Nov 28th, 2002

Modeling the Roles of Craft Production in Ancient Political Economies 195

of efforts to construct and promote dominant ideologies; their success, like the
meanings of the symbols themselves, cannot be assumed.
Connections among the economic and political processes listed in Table I are
much the same here as they are in prestige goods models, though in this theme they
are mediated more through meaning than economic dependency. Elite patronage
of attached specialists ensures monopolies over the use and distribution of their
politically charged output. This situation tends to involve fairly small numbers of
full-time specialists who live and work near the residences and administrative nodes
of their patrons. The objects, themselves, are almost invariably made from exotic
materials, always transformed through technologically complex, labor-intensive
steps requiring considerable skill (Clark, 1986; Hayden, 1998). As noted above,
these raw material and technological features greatly facilitate control over the
manufacturing process by those few who can acquire the needed resources and
master the appropriate techniques. Such considerations also help ensure that pres-
tige goods are rare and valuable, thus heightening the impact of their messages.
Effective monitoring of the production process gives those in charge a decided
advantage in, if not absolute control over, disseminating messages that privilege
their position in the world.
Once again, the issue of social differentiation and its relation to specialized
manufacture has come in for less attention than have questions of power concen-
tration and inequality. Artisans and elites separate themselves out from the rest of
society, partly by virtue of craft activities, but no other social distinctions seem to
follow from these economic processes.
The models outlined thus far stress a top–down perspective on political
economies. Agency and innovation are certainly stressed, but the agents and in-
novators are almost invariably members of the upper class. Those they seek to
dominate are left as either hapless dependents, selling their labor for a particularly
fine pot, or dupes bedazzled by information dazzlingly expressed. The above state-
ment simplifies what are often sophisticated and nuanced theories. It does raise
the question, however, of whether or not commoners were going gently into their
own exploitation.

PROTECTING AUTONOMY

Though most efforts to model the place of craft production in ancient polit-
ical economies concentrate on elite strategies and actions, some researchers have
been asking whether, how, and why commoners might have participated in spe-
cialized manufacture. This work takes several forms. Most investigators pursuing
the topic posit that the crafts in which nonelites engaged are characterized by the
use of easily accessible, widely dispersed raw materials extracted using relatively
simple techniques; skills that take little time to learn and do not need constant
P1: JLS
Journal of Archaeological Research [jar] pp1095-jare-479712 April 12, 2004 10:36 Style file version Nov 28th, 2002

196 Schortman and Urban

practice to maintain; a concern to locate workshops near sources of the bulkiest


raw materials used in the manufacturing process and close by potential consumers,
usually resulting in dispersed distributions of artisans; manufacture for a market
in which demand was constant, moderately high, and widespread; and distribution
negotiated among producers and consumers largely, or completely, free of elite
intervention (Fry, 1981; Gibson, 1996; Hayden, 1994, 1998; Pool, 1992; Saitta,
1994, pp. 216–217, 1997; Wattenmaker, 1998).
Production scales of commoner crafts vary from individuals fashioning a few
items on the side for occasional exchanges with their peers to larger manufacturing
enterprises organized on the basis of communities or in factories directed by a
few entrepreneurs (Costin, 1991; Peacock, 1981). Where any craft falls out along
this continuum depends on a variety of factors of which consumer demand may
be the primary one. No matter what the production scale, those not funded by
elites try to reduce their labor costs and increase the efficiency with which they
fashion items in volume, seeking maximum return for invested effort (Costin,
1991; Costin and Hagstrum, 1995; Hagstrum, 1988; Hayden, 1998, pp. 2–9; but
see Lemonnier, 1992). The resulting products, therefore, tend to be fairly simple in
shape and decoration, their appearance informed more by functional considerations
of shipping and use than their suitability for transmitting information.
These crafts, in short, fall at opposite ends of the continua outlined in Table I
from prestige goods production processes, yielding utilitarian items, not wealth
(White and Pigott, 1996). Raw material, labor, and skill requirements make such
activities relatively open to all while aspects of demand and distribution ensure
that craftworkers exercise considerable autonomy in pursuit of their own agendas
(Hagstrum, 2001). To be sure, paramounts may benefit from these transactions and
manufacturing activities through, say, taxes levied on market exchanges (Morrison
and Sinopoli, 1992; Sinopoli, 1988). The point, however, is that control over pro-
duction, consumption, and distribution is vested in non-elite hands.
The above features generally characterize the organization of non-elite craft
production. The question of why people would become artisans is addressed in
several ways. As was the case with the elite-centered models discussed earlier,
these approaches can be divided into those stressing the economic significance
of craft manufacture and those emphasizing its ideological import. In either case,
functionalist concerns with the uses of specialized manufactures dominate. Cross-
cultural generalizations are also encouraged by the notion that commoners, like
elites, consistently face certain oft-repeated challenges that are handled in similar
ways. Here the problems involve meeting basic subsistence needs and defining
one’s place within ever more complex social and political structures.

Working for a Living

Perhaps the most long-standing approach to the study of non-elite involve-


ment in craft production is the one that envisions this activity as a response to
P1: JLS
Journal of Archaeological Research [jar] pp1095-jare-479712 April 12, 2004 10:36 Style file version Nov 28th, 2002

Modeling the Roles of Craft Production in Ancient Political Economies 197

straightened economic circumstances. Where land is insufficient to meet local


subsistence requirements, at least some people may fashion utilitarian goods on a
part-time basis to satisfy their essential material needs through market exchanges.
Craft production, therefore, is the profession of (near) last resort (D. Arnold, 1985,
1993; Fry, 1981, p. 151; Kramer, 1985, p. 80; McCorriston, 1997, p. 533; O’Brian,
1999; Pool, 1992; Stark, 1991; Stark and Heidka,1998, p. 509).
Related to this position is the argument that scheduling conflicts, resulting
from increased investments of time in subsistence pursuits, make it difficult for
farmers and herders to find enough hours in the day to produce all the goods they
need (Mills, 1995). Such time-management problems create a steady demand for
items that specialists, ever more estranged from the land themselves, can work to
fulfill.
The political consequences of these processes are not clearly outlined in most
of the literature. Potentially, at least, artisans working outside direct elite control
could use craft production to enhance their material circumstances above basic
subsistence needs. Those individuals or groups with access to the widest array of
raw materials and the skills to transform them into finished goods could siphon
off resources from less favorably endowed households whose members engaged
in fewer crafts. The latter would have to surrender some portion of their labor
and surplus to obtain what they require from the former. Though no one need be
in thrall to their exchange partners, slight discrepancies in production potentials
among households could add up to significant differences in material gain over the
generations. The result would be a mosaic of household material well-being rather
than an economically homogenous class of equally impoverished commoners. How
marked these distinctions might become depends, in part, on the ability of domestic
units to meet their subsistence requirements by their own efforts. If that capacity
was seriously compromised, even the most productive commoner artisans could
find themselves economically marginalized, sacrificing labor just to get enough to
eat.
No matter how these processes play out, however, the result would be increas-
ing social differentiation. Peoples’ lives would vary by occupation and the amounts
of time invested in specialized production. Those pursuing different crafts, or mixes
of crafts, would, minimally, have to learn varied skills and come to view the world
and its resources from divergent perspectives. If differential involvement in craft
production yielded distinctions in material well-being among domestic units, then
some measure of economic inequality dividing nonelites might ensue. The result-
ing pattern would be more a continuum of differences than the marked distinctions
between elites and commoners imagined in prestige goods models. As long as the
objects being fashioned were not expressions of elite affiliations or used to estab-
lish dependency relations, their significance in promoting or undermining political
centralization seems to have been nil.
Commoner participation in craft production, in these economic models, seems
to be geared towards producing mundane items to buffer artisans and their domestic
P1: JLS
Journal of Archaeological Research [jar] pp1095-jare-479712 April 12, 2004 10:36 Style file version Nov 28th, 2002

198 Schortman and Urban

groups facing uncertain economic environments. Pursuing such eminently practi-


cal concerns enhances social differentiation, may contribute to modest invidious
economic distinctions, and has no discernible (or seriously considered) affect on
power and its concentration (King and Potter, 1994; Stark and Heidka, 1998,
pp. 510–511; White and Pigott, 1996, p. 167).

The Meaning of Commoner Craft Production

Not all views of commoner participation in craft production operate from


so strong an economic stance. Some researchers examine the ideological signif-
icance of, and motivations for, nonelite involvement in specialized manufacture.
One strand in these investigations deals with the question of emulation. Here it
is argued that nonelite attempts to replicate material symbols of paramount privi-
lege, and so partake in some of their charisma, may spur technological innovation
and the creation of new prestige goods industries that are more difficult to copy
(Hayden, 1998, pp. 33–34; Wattenmaker, 1998, pp. 14–15). Commoner craft pro-
duction, then, is not geared exclusively to meeting demands for prosaic items.
It also can be harnessed to the fashioning of symbolically rich objects through
which the disempowered seek to participate in the dominant ideology. Emulating
elite material symbols may qualify as resistance to exclusion from paramount-
controlled discourses while simultaneously reinforcing the importance of those
discourses by imitating their forms.
Others have argued that relations between the scale and intensity of commoner
engagement in specialized production, on the one hand, and social differentiation,
on the other, are mediated through the communicative power of craft products
(Bayman, 2002; Bowser, 2000; Morrow, 1987; Wattenmaker, 1998; Wells, 1988).
As the array of social affiliations proliferates within state-level societies, it is
increasingly important to develop physically overt cues that signal who is party
to any interaction, which identities they are employing, and what can be expected
of them (Barth, 1969; R. Cohen, 1978; Royce, 1982; Wattenmaker, 1998). The
ambiguity inherent in such communication is greatly reduced when the relevant
material symbols are standardized, a condition generally encouraged by specialized
manufacture (Foias, 2002, p. 231; Van Pool and Leonard, 2002; Wattenmaker,
1998, p. 11). Craft production, therefore, is spurred by broad-scale demands for
easily decoded, physically distinctive items useful as explicit markers of social
affiliation. Objects fashioned from widely available raw materials that have high
visibility (such as elaborately embellished pottery vessels made with local clays)
are particularly susceptible to production by a large number of artisans laboring
to meet the needs of a sizable market (Wattenmaker, 1998, pp. 202–203). Elite
supervision of these manufacturing processes is probably minimal given difficulties
in controlling local access to both essential, widely dispersed raw materials and the
relatively simple manufacturing techniques used to fashion the items in question
P1: JLS
Journal of Archaeological Research [jar] pp1095-jare-479712 April 12, 2004 10:36 Style file version Nov 28th, 2002

Modeling the Roles of Craft Production in Ancient Political Economies 199

(Wattenmaker, 1998, pp. 202–203). Despite their ubiquity and apparent simplicity,
these seemingly mundane objects can effectively delimit social boundaries, though
without any necessary implication of inequality among the affiliations they mark
(Bowser, 2000).

Summary of Approaches to Commoner Craft Production

Investigations of commoner participation in craft production converge on the


notion that this activity is both stimulated by, and promotes, differentiation among
heterarchically related social entities, i.e., units that are unranked or capable of
being ranked differently in varied circumstances (Crumley, 1979). The scale and
intensity of specialized manufacture varies with demand and the distribution of
essential raw materials and production skills. The higher the call for a commodity
and the more restricted crucial resources or technical knowledge are, the more
likely full-time specialists will appear. A drop in demand and/or the increasing
accessibility of basic material assets and/or manufacturing techniques encourage
shifts to part-time specialization. In either case, workshops are widely dispersed
and not necessarily situated near elite residences and administrative structures.
Commoner participation in craft activities is not thought to be strongly condi-
tioned by, nor is it given much credit for contributing to, political centralization and
inequality. When addressed, the lack of clear relations between these economic
processes and hierarchy building is highlighted (e.g., King and Potter, 1994; White
and Pigott, 1996). Often, such apparent incongruities are used to stress the impor-
tant point that craft production is not invariably linked to, or a cause of, unequal
power distributions (King and Potter, 1994; White and Piggott, 1996.). In short,
whatever its motivation, nonelite craft manufacture responds, in these models,
more to economic than to political processes and pressures.

CRAFTING THE PROFOUND FROM THE PROSAIC

The last two decades have witnessed an increasing concern with the emic
quality of artifacts, i.e, what these items meant to those who made and used them
(Hodder, 1982, 1986). Specifically, there is a growing sense that the material world
has more than economic significance. Artifacts, through their patterned forms,
arrangements, and uses, materialize values and beliefs distinctive of specific cul-
tures or segments thereof. By making the abstract tangible, artifacts are essential
to inculcating basic cultural premises across the generations and to creating those
meaningful contexts that impart significance to, guide, and motivate patterned hu-
man action (Bourdieu, 1977; Geertz, 1973; Gillespie, 1999; Hodder, 1986; Joyce,
2000; Pauketat and Emmerson, 1999).
This approach marks a profound shift from functionalist arguments that equate
an object’s significance with its use (Hodder, 1986, pp. 20–21). Though allowing
P1: JLS
Journal of Archaeological Research [jar] pp1095-jare-479712 April 12, 2004 10:36 Style file version Nov 28th, 2002

200 Schortman and Urban

that use and meaning are related, archaeologists who examine the emics of craft
production see function as the lesser part of significance. Every object, no matter
how prosaic, is a locus of meaning. All cultural products fashioned in a society
together comprise a symbolic environment whose specific configurations at any
place and point in time encourage certain behaviors and discourage others (Lillios,
1999, p. 174; Robb, 1999). In creating artifacts, therefore, people fashion the very
structures of their existence, expressing and reproducing relations among such
basic concepts as gender, kinship, power, class, and place through the objects
they make and manipulate (Levy, 1999, p. 212; J. Thomas, 1999, p. 73). The
archaeologist’s task is to read these messages that artisans, among others, have left
us.
Not only finished products but also the ways in which these objects were
made are rich in cultural significance (Bernbeck, 1995; Dobres, 1995; Dobres
and Hoffman, 1995; Gosselain, 1993, 2000; Hendon, 1999; Lechtman, 1993;
Lemonnier, 1992; Perles, 1992; Pfaffenberger, 1988, 1992). Since most choices
made in manufacturing processes, or chaines operatoires, are at least partially
culturally conditioned, they contain information about the artisan’s worldview and
basic learned principles of behavior (Childs and Kilbick, 1993; Dobres, 1995;
Dobres and Hoffman, 1995; Gosselain, 1993, pp. 582–583; 2000; Loney, 2000;
López Varela et al., 2001). People understand and express themselves through daily
practice, manufacturing sequences representing conveniently fossilized examples
of those practices (Robb, 1999).
True to their emic roots, researchers pursuing the cultural significance of craft
manufacture and its output stress the historically contingent nature of the meanings
attributed by past peoples to both objects and production processes (Hodder, 1982,
1986). Each culture’s meaningful structure, materialized through artifact forms,
arrangements, and uses, is a product of its unique history. People may face similar
problems in different times and places but their responses are conditioned more
by the historical and cultural factors distinctive of a particular group than by the
universal functional considerations highlighted in the approaches discussed earlier.
Consequently, cross-cultural generalizations concerning artifact meanings are, to
many researchers, impossible.

Social Identity

Attention in emic studies of craft production has particularly focused on


how manufacturing processes and their resultant objects express social identi-
ties, those cultural categories into which people group themselves and onto which
they project behavioral expectations (Emberling, 1999; Gillespie, 1999, p. 247;
Schortman, 1989; Schortman et al., 2001; Weissner, 1983; Wobst, 1977). The is-
sue of affiliation is also highlighted in those studies of the meanings of prestige
P1: JLS
Journal of Archaeological Research [jar] pp1095-jare-479712 April 12, 2004 10:36 Style file version Nov 28th, 2002

Modeling the Roles of Craft Production in Ancient Political Economies 201

and prosaic goods discussed earlier. The aforementioned analyses, however, focus
on explicit, self-conscious efforts to communicate identities through manipulation
of physically salient features of design and decoration on certain particularly no-
table artifacts (especially pottery vessels and jewellery). While acknowledging the
importance of these overt expressions of affiliation, a growing number of inves-
tigators stress that all items and production steps, no matter how mundane, are
well positioned to convey fundamental aspects of an artisan’s identity (Childs and
Kilbick, 1993; Dobres, 1995; Fotiadis, 1999, p. 395; Gosselain, 2000). This is be-
cause manufacturing behaviors are frequently learned early in life, within domestic
settings, and express ways of acting closely linked to a person’s sense of self as
a member of a particular gender, household, and/or small community (Dobres,
1995; Gosselain, 1993). All objects fabricated in the course of craft production,
therefore, display stylistic features that may subtly, but effectively, convey social
distinctions that were meaningful to their makers and users (Carr, 1995; Weissner,
1983). Artisans need not be explicitly cognizant of the meanings they express.
Habitual manufacturing processes and unobtrusive stylistic elements are often re-
produced and interpreted out of awareness (McCall, 1999; Sackett, 1972, 1982).
Consciously or unconsciously, however, craftworkers signal who they are with
every choice made in production, their compatriots raised under similar circum-
stances readily, if implicitly, decoding their messages. Technology and even the
most prosaic objects, in this view, are as rich in cultural information as any other
aspect of life.
How do insights into the emic meanings of artifacts and production processes
figure in discussions of political economies? To date, relatively little effort has been
made to relate systematically the cultural contents of artifact styles and operational
sequences to other aspects of craft production, on the one hand, and to processes
of political centralization, inequality, and social differentiation, on the other (see
Hodder, 1979; Weissner, 1983 for some exceptions). At the very least, the scale
and intensity of social differentiation might well be discernible in changes within
production processes and increases in the variety of artifact styles. For example,
if manufacturing steps are shaped by cultural, as well as functional, considera-
tions, then proliferation of these processes, even within one industry, could signal
profound, microscale shifts in social affiliations. Such distinctions might not be
overtly expressed in other surviving media because they were generally understood
and required no reinforcement. Explicit communication of social difference also
may have been actively discouraged by elites in the interest of preserving at least a
facade of social unity (DeMarrais et al., 1996, p. 31). In either case, differentiation
in production processes need not be a purely technological phenomenon. Rather,
it could signal, and reinforce, the appearance of new identities as pervasive as they
are subtly expressed.
This perspective raises the intriguing possibility that artifacts used to com-
municate elite-inspired models of the world simultaneously conveyed, through
P1: JLS
Journal of Archaeological Research [jar] pp1095-jare-479712 April 12, 2004 10:36 Style file version Nov 28th, 2002

202 Schortman and Urban

decisions made in the manufacturing process, how the artisans saw themselves
and their places within that world (Hayashida, 1999). These overt and implicit
expressions of meaning need not have been in open conflict, but there is rich po-
tential for at least implicit tensions in their articulation. Such possibilities cannot
be explored, however, unless we complement traditional top–down views of craft
production with bottom–up perspectives on how identities are manifest in daily,
seemingly routine, practices and styles.

PROSPECTS FOR FUTURE RESEARCH

The above review highlights the very general truth that craft production is not
a unitary phenomenon. It is not a diagnostic of political complexity, solely a tool
of elite domination, or exclusively a means for individuals, households, and/or
communities to achieve and maintain their economic autonomy and social dis-
tinctiveness (Saitta, 1999, p. 143). Specialized manufacture can fulfill all of these
roles under certain circumstances. This observation, however, just scratches the
tip of the conceptual iceberg. A brief examination of the floe’s submerged portions
suggests at least two important, general directions for future research: describing
the multifaceted relations among different craft industries and political processes,
each operating at variable spatial and temporal scales, within political economies;
and understanding the forces that generate these diverse interconnections.

Multicentric Political Economies

As a number of authors have commented, political economies are multicen-


tric, with different industries articulated in varying manners with equally com-
plex arrays of political processes and formations (Bayman, 2002; E. Brumfiel,
1998; C. Charlton, 1994; Cobb, 1993, p. 70; Costin, 1996, p. 212; Foias, 2002,
p. 236; Kopytoff, 1986, p. 72; Middleton et al., 2002; Morrison and Sinopoli, 1992;
Sinopoli, 1988, 1998; Stark and Heidka, 1998, p. 512; Stein, 1998, pp. 12–13,
2001, pp. 363–366; Wells, 1996; White and Pigott, 1996; Wright, 1993). In addi-
tion, since power, inequality, and social differentiation are variably manifest and
organized over different spatial and temporal dimensions, how craft manufacture
is integrated with these processes diverges depending on where and when within
political and economic networks we choose to focus (Bayman, 2002; E. Brumfiel,
1998; Cobb, 1993, p. 78; Connell, 2002, pp. 414–415; Ferguson and Mansbach,
1996, p. 32; Inomata, 2001; Nader, 1997; Tringham, 1996; Wattenmaker, 1998;
Wright, 1996, p. 130). For example, gender identities forged within coresident
domestic units may be expressed and reproduced through activities that include,
but are not limited to, specialized manufacturing. What is fashioned, however,
and the volumes at which the goods are produced within these households may
P1: JLS
Journal of Archaeological Research [jar] pp1095-jare-479712 April 12, 2004 10:36 Style file version Nov 28th, 2002

Modeling the Roles of Craft Production in Ancient Political Economies 203

be strongly influenced by political and economic processes operating on a re-


gional scale, including tribute exactions and/or opportunities for exchange. Such
polity-level processes, in turn, are affected by inputs coming from beyond any one
society’s borders, as when local tribute is exported to cement foreign alliances
or long-distance traders enhance parochial demand by participating in regional
markets (T. Charlton, 1994). The simultaneous impact of diverse local, regional,
and interregional forces on any craft makes is difficult, if not impossible, to speak
meaningfully of generic or universal relations among components of specialized
production and political processes.
Instead, comprehending the complex interplay among craftworking and power
concentration, inequality, and social differentiation in any specific case requires:
focusing on each craft individually, describing how relations among production,
distribution, and consumption are organized at all relevant spatial scales; correlat-
ing these features with measures of political centralization, inequality, and social
differentiation as they are manifest in different spatial settings; putting the result-
ing synchronic structures in motion, tracing changes in their components through
time; and being aware throughout these analyses that the resulting structures are
not likely to have been seamless but were, rather, characterized by tensions among,
minimally, artisans, consumers, and middlemen whose different goals were born
of their varying allegiances to kin, place, gender, and class (Costin, 2001, p. 312;
Stein, 1998, p. 19).
Researchers pursuing the themes outlined above view these linkages from dif-
ferent angles, focusing on distinct aspects of ancient political economies. Those
examining the production, distribution, and consumption of prestige goods stress
industries staffed by full-time client-artisans who fabricated objects used to build
hierarchies operating on polity and interpolity scales (e.g., R. Blanton and Feinman,
1984; R. E. Blanton et al., 1996; see papers in Chase-Dunn and Hall, 1991;
Peregrine and Feinman, 1996). Investigators looking into craft specialization
among commoners highlight those specializations open to all members of a society,
usually pursued by part-time artisans dispersed among a wide range of households
and communities. More fine-grained, intrahousehold analyses of social differen-
tiation in particular are encouraged by emic approaches where attention centers
on how an artisan’s identities are expressed and affirmed through basic techno-
logical and stylistic choices. Investigators looking at the function and meaning of
commoner production, regardless of spatial scale, tend to see these crafts as instru-
mental in the creation of heterarchical, not hierarchical, relations (Crumley, 1979).
Dealings among people of roughly equivalent status are emphasized as opposed
to those based on institutionalized inequalities.
Rather than being a cause for concern, such proliferation of perspectives on
specialized manufacture reflects the variable ways political and economic pro-
cesses are articulated at different times and in different spatial and historical
contexts. The danger is less that there are a number of valid approaches to the
P1: JLS
Journal of Archaeological Research [jar] pp1095-jare-479712 April 12, 2004 10:36 Style file version Nov 28th, 2002

204 Schortman and Urban

study of craft production than that one will be mistaken for the sole, or best, way
of dealing with the topic (Costin, 2001).
Multicentric and multiscalar political economies, therefore, require the ex-
amination of craft manufacture from different vantage points to describe relations
among production, consumption, distribution, hierarchy, power, and social dif-
ferentiation. This prescription is ultimately misleading, however, if it encourages
piecemeal approaches focused only on specific crafts (Costin, 2001, p. 312). We
must not forget that our objective is to describe and understand political economies
of which individual industries are components. Ultimately, what we know about
the operation of particular crafts will have to be synthesized into accounts in which
interrelations among diverse manufacturing, consumption, distribution, and politi-
cal processes are specified. Steps in this direction are already being made. Ongoing
analyses of several major prehistoric and early historic states and empires explicitly
address the complex interplay among different industries in the creation of ancient
political economies. Examples of these innovative studies include research con-
ducted on the southern Indian Sri Vijayan Empire of the fourteenth–sixteenth
centuries (Morrison and Sinopoli, 1992; Sinopoli, 1988, 1994; Sinopoli, and
Morrison, 1995), the Inka empire of the fifteenth–sixteenth centuries in western
South America (Costin and Earle, 1989; D’Altroy and Earle, 1985; Earle, 1991),
the 14th–15th century Mexica, or Aztec, empire in Mesoamerica (C. Charlton et al.,
1993; see papers in Hodge and Smith, 1994), the various polities that occupied the
Valley of Oaxaca in Mexico’s southern highlands (Feinman and Nicholas, 2000;
Flannery and Marcus, 1983; Kowalewski et al., 1989; Marcus and Flannery, 1996;
Middleton et al., 2002), and Indus Valley states of the 3rd millennium BC in south-
ern Asia (Wright, 1993). With all due respect to these prodigious efforts, it may
be easier to address such complex relations in smaller, more manageable settings
where it is possible to sample a greater proportion of consumption and manu-
facturing contexts than in spatially extensive, temporally enduring empires and
states. This is especially the case when dealing with prehistoric situations where
the absence of documentary evidence mandates heavy reliance on archaeological
remains in framing interpretations.
Acknowledging the multiscalar, multicentric quality of ancient political
economies is one thing; understanding why processes of production, distribution,
consumption, and power assume such diverse configurations is quite another. Ask-
ing the latter question forces us to go beyond description to confront the wide array
of historically contingent factors that shaped political economies. Researchers pur-
suing the four themes outlined earlier have already made considerable progress
in grappling with this protean issue. Building on their considerable successes, we
suggest two avenues for future research that promise fruitful results: a more sys-
tematic analysis of connections between social identities and craft production; and
rethinking several venerable oppositions that pervade much of the literature on
specialized manufacture.
P1: JLS
Journal of Archaeological Research [jar] pp1095-jare-479712 April 12, 2004 10:36 Style file version Nov 28th, 2002

Modeling the Roles of Craft Production in Ancient Political Economies 205

Crafting a Sense of Self

One element central to the creation of multifaceted relations among spe-


cialized manufacture and sociopolitical processes is the issue of social affiliation.
Researchers of all stripes have looked at how craft manufactures were used by elites
and commoners to signal, explicitly or implicitly, their identities. Those adopting a
top–down perspective stress the deployment of elaborately fashioned exotic goods
in the creation of paramount affiliations that set their members apart from, and
above, those they ruled. Some studies of nonelite households take up this concern,
reminding us that noble scions were not the only ones concerned with delimiting
social boundaries. Hierarchical divisions may have been important parts of the
political landscape, but heterarchical distinctions among roughly equivalent social
entities also were significant to everyone’s sense of self and their place within
the world. Linking these approaches is the notion that abstract concepts, such as
social identities, must be palpable in order to affect human behavior (DeMarrais
et al., 1996; Larick, 1991). Since items of material culture are often instrumental
in making the recondite real, artisans are attributed a major role in fabricating their
culture. Consequently, a concern with social identity, though hardly limited to craft
production studies, is becoming an increasingly important research focus for those
interested in specialized manufacture (see references given in earlier sections).
The varied uses to which craft goods were put by social actors fracture the
unity of specialized production. The political and social significance of different
industries is conditioned, in part, by how their outputs were deployed in diverse
strategies to express and promote specific affiliations. Mining the full potential of
this research theme, however, relies on bearing in mind that identities are not so
much fixed, neatly bounded elements of social structures as guises flexibly used
in dynamic interaction processes.
Any one person subscribes to multiple identities each of which is variably
salient in varying social circumstances, over different spatial scales, and links
that individual to diverse and shifting groups of people. In some contexts, one’s
affiliation to a particular household might be stressed. In another, one’s identity
as a member of a family within such a coresident domestic group could be more
significant. In a third setting, solidarity with all members of a specific polity may
be of greatest importance (Barth, 1969; R. Cohen, 1978; Royce, 1982). Shifting
among these affiliations requires the appropriate manipulation of generally agreed
upon material symbols to signal which identities are relevant in any particular
instance and, hence, the intentions of the interactors and what can be expected of
them. The social boundaries made tangible through the use of goods fashioned,
in part, by artisans, therefore, are flexible and volatile, subject to change at any
moment and over long periods of time.
The fluidity of social identities is related to their strategic use by people of
all ranks in their daily efforts to achieve a wide range of objectives (Barth, 1969;
P1: JLS
Journal of Archaeological Research [jar] pp1095-jare-479712 April 12, 2004 10:36 Style file version Nov 28th, 2002

206 Schortman and Urban

R. Cohen, 1978; Royce, 1982). As these goals and the conditions for their achieve-
ment change, identities and their material markers also will shift. The resultant
sociopolitical configurations need not be stable or in balanced equilibrium at any
one point in time. For example, as crucial as it may be for rulers to set themselves
apart from the rest of the population, they must transcend these hierarchical dis-
tinctions to create a unified polity of which they are also members (Ferguson and
Mansbach, 1996, p. 36; Yoffee, 1991, p. 287). Only by promoting an identity in
which all citizens of the realm participate can some level of stability be achieved
by countering sectarian and class divisions with loyalty to the polity as a whole
(Schortman et al., 2001). Elites, therefore, must balance the potentially conflicting
claims of affiliations that separate them from, and link them to, their subordinates.
Such tensions are mediated through the use of material symbols pertinent to the
identities in play, some of these symbols generated by craft specialists. Though
a level of stability may be achieved through such machinations, the underlying
strains remain unresolved and can form bases for assaults on the status quo when
dissatisfaction with elite actions, and the means to express that discontent, coincide.
At the same time, nonelites are busily constructing affiliations, conveyed
through other material markers, that may be in opposition to, represent compro-
mises with, or operate largely independently of those promulgated from above.
Relations among such identities, the industries generating their symbols of affil-
iation, and elite efforts to build and protect hierarchies are complex and volatile.
This is a far more complicated picture than the traditional one in which popu-
lations within any given society are distributed among enduring identities each
of which has a clear set of relatively stable material signatures. As appealing as
that picture may be, it simplifies reality and encourages us to ignore the mul-
tifarious and dynamic connections among craft goods and the affiliations they
signify.
For example, paramount rulers of the Late Classic (AD 600–900) Naco Valley
in northwestern Honduras apparently used their privileged control over the fash-
ioning of masonry blocks and sculpture to create a set of material symbols that
distinguished them from their lower ranked contemporaries who could not repli-
cate these items. At the same time, all valley residents used a restricted suite of
elaborately decorated ceramics apparently fashioned by client artisans working
under the direction of Naco’s magnates at the regional capital of La Sierra. These
vessels bore a limited, highly redundant set of designs found throughout the valley
but rarely noted outside it. The motifs in question were, arguably, emblems of a
politywide identity in which people of all ranks participated (Schortman et al.,
2001). The collapse of the centralized La Sierra polity during the Terminal Classic
(AD 900–1100) saw the disappearance of paramount elites, politywide affiliations,
and their material expressions. Stone working and large-scale ceramic production
waned as the political conditions that encouraged fluorescences in both crafts were
transformed.
P1: JLS
Journal of Archaeological Research [jar] pp1095-jare-479712 April 12, 2004 10:36 Style file version Nov 28th, 2002

Modeling the Roles of Craft Production in Ancient Political Economies 207

Different industries, therefore, played varied roles in creating social bound-


aries at markedly different scales during the Late Classic in Naco. Such distinctions
undoubtedly strongly affected the meanings and political functions of the objects
in question as well as the social positions of the artisans who made them. Mutatis
mutandis, as Naco’s political structure changed, so too did the identities that were
integral to it and the crafts through which those affiliations were conveyed.
This complex interface among political, economic, and self-identification
processes, as they play out at various temporal and spatial scales, has yet to be
investigated systematically. Though craft production need not be the sole focus
of these studies, it is becoming increasingly obvious that taking it into account
helps clarify the different and fluctuating ways crafts can be related to social and
political processes.

Back to Basics

Fashioning nuanced, realistic understandings of multicentric political


economies also depends on addressing the pervasive influence certain enduring
dichotomies exercise on our understandings of crafts and their political signifi-
cance. Specifically, the neat distinctions we traditionally make between elite and
mundane industries and the ideological and economic significance of artifacts have
long shaped archaeological discussions of ancient political economies. As fruitful
as these discourses have been, we might profitably entertain the notion that the na-
tures of at least some crafts are not captured using such oppositions (e.g., Bayman,
2002; E. Brumfiel, 1998; C. Charlton, 1994; Connell, 2002; Costin, 1998; Lass,
1998; Wells, 1996). These liminal industries, as seen from the perspective of our
conceptual schemes, are not easily modeled using existing frameworks, suggesting
fertile ground for theory development.

Elites Versus Commoners

The pervasive distinction between elite industries used to fashion hierarchy


and mundane crafts instrumental in the proliferation of heterarchical social dis-
tinctions probably simplifies complex ancient realities. We do not deny that some
manufacturing processes functioned primarily in strategies of elite domination.
Similarly, other industries may have been used to express commoner social affil-
iations and meet basic survival needs. Does this dichotomy describe the ways in
which ancient productive relations invariably worked, however, or are we in danger
of forcing crafts into a rigid elite/commoner binary opposition and of assuming
a craft’s political and economic significance from where it was carried out, e.g.,
in humble domestic quarters or in a ruler’s compound? Just because common-
ers operating out of dispersed workshops made an object, was it unimportant in
P1: JLS
Journal of Archaeological Research [jar] pp1095-jare-479712 April 12, 2004 10:36 Style file version Nov 28th, 2002

208 Schortman and Urban

the creation of hierarchy? Do the outputs of workshops attached to elite patrons


always, or primarily, yield valuables used in domination strategies? At present,
we may have answers to these questions that are more ready than reliable. When
asking who made, used, and distributed an item, therefore, we are well advised
to allow for the participation of people from a wide array of ranks in each and
all of these processes (Graham, 2002). Such considerations help us to understand
better the factors shaping multiscalar, multicentric political economies than do
models that posit a craft’s unambiguous and exclusive association with members
of an elite or commoner class. Further advances in understanding ancient politi-
cal economies depend on rethinking this traditional sociopolitical divide between
rulers and ruled. Rather than categorizing people as elites or commoners, we might
profitably think of them as variably disposed along several, potentially competing,
continua of “eliteness,” each related to a different source of power (Mann, 1986;
Miller et al., 1989; Runciman, 1982). In some political economies a few individu-
als may, for a time, institutionalize marked hierarchical distinctions by co-opting
successfully all or most sources of power within a society. In these instances we
can confidently speak of relatively clearly defined elites and commoners. Most
political economies, however, were likely characterized by unresolved tensions
among individuals and social groups who managed to achieve variable degrees
of preeminence through their control of some, but not all, political assets (Mann,
1986; Miller et al., 1989). One faction, for example, might have enjoyed ideologi-
cal advantages through its members’ privileged access to the supernatural. Others
in the same society, bereft of such connections, could have achieved prominence
through military renown. The uses each of these “elites” had for craft goods, and
the meanings such items held for them, likely varied significantly. At the very least,
those seeking privilege through control over the sacred may have tried to monopo-
lize the fabrication of ritual paraphernalia essential to this goal (Spielmann, 1998,
2002). Where martial exploits were important to social advancement, monitoring
the fashioning of weapons, and encouraging the development of more effective
military technologies, might have been key elements in achieving and safeguarding
prominence (Earle, 1997, pp. 205–206; Kim, 2001). Both processes could have
operated simultaneously in one society, yielding a complex, multicentered politi-
cal economy in which no one faction exercised absolute power and different crafts
were harnessed to distinct political agendas (Morrison and Sinopoli, 1992, p. 335;
Wells, 1996, pp. 87–88).
How power is organized also will have an impact on the roles crafts assume
within a political economy. Most research on the political uses of specialized
manufactures is predicated on the notion that charismatic individuals and their
immediate coteries dominated specific societies. Some investigators, however, are
calling attention to hierarchically structured political formations directed by coun-
cillor bodies in which no one person stands out as an overall leader (R. Blanton
et al., 1996; Saitta, 1994, 1997, 1999; Spielmann, 2002). Craft goods in these
P1: JLS
Journal of Archaeological Research [jar] pp1095-jare-479712 April 12, 2004 10:36 Style file version Nov 28th, 2002

Modeling the Roles of Craft Production in Ancient Political Economies 209

contexts would be harnessed not to the enhancement of individual status but to


other societywide goals, such as the creation of objects used in communal offerings
to the supernatural (Saitta, 1994; Spielmann, 2002). Corporate and individualiz-
ing tendencies in power relations may coexist uneasily within a political realm,
representatives of each approach drawing on different industries to achieve their
objectives, possibly at the other’s expense. The result would be to further compli-
cate an already convoluted political economy.
Tensions between corporate and individualizing leadership strategies, as well
as those among different factions deploying varied resources in power contests,
will likely generate unstable conditions prone to change as agents maneuver to
advance their agendas. Crafts, along with other assets, are potential instruments
useful in affecting such transformations. The multifarious relations among specific
industries and political and economic processes at any moment are, therefore,
complicated by imminent and ongoing shifts in the fortunes of those using crafts
to shape and reshape political formations.
Such diversity and volatility in power relations are not easily encompassed by
straightforward elite/commoner divisions (Crumley, 1979; de Montmollin, 1989).
The sources of wealth and power under contention, the varied ways factions orga-
nize to capture these assets, and the uneven success they enjoy in such contests very
likely contribute to the multicentric and dynamic qualities of political economies
noted earlier.

Meaning Versus Function

All objects have meanings, as well as uses, to their makers. Separating the
two components of an item has analytical value as long as it is understood that
neither one alone fully explains an artifact’s roles in a political economy. It may
be, as current trends in the literature suggest, that questions of social affiliation
are best addressed through emic approaches while those concerned with political
centralization lend themselves to perspectives rooted in functional premises. Ulti-
mately, however, differences in power must by integrated within worldviews and
holders of social identities organized to accomplish tangible objectives through the
use, in part, of craft goods. How a workshop’s output figures in a political econ-
omy, therefore, is strongly conditioned by both its locally perceived significance,
i.e., the ways it fits within extant and changing meaningful structures, and how it
functions in economic and political strategies.
Among early nineteenth century Marquesans who lacked locally made fire-
arms, for example, a rifle was a potent military weapon and a symbol of connections
to powerful and distant trading partners. The gun’s political importance derived
from its prosaic and conceptual significance (N. Thomas, 1992). Along the same
lines, obsidian blades in prehistoric southeastern Mesoamerica were prized for their
P1: JLS
Journal of Archaeological Research [jar] pp1095-jare-479712 April 12, 2004 10:36 Style file version Nov 28th, 2002

210 Schortman and Urban

extremely sharp edges and exotic sources. Employed in prosaic domestic chores
by people of all ranks and in ritual bloodletting (Schele and Miller, 1986), these
implements were useful tools charged with meanings born of their associations with
distant places and sacred realms. Artisans who knapped blades from volcanic glass,
therefore, participated in economically and symbolically meaningful activities
that undoubtedly affected how the items figured in political processes, and were
made, used, and distributed. Arguing over whether the meaning or functions of
guns and obsidian blades is more important in understanding their places within
Marquesan and southeastern Mesoamerican political economies is less productive
than developing ways to take both elements into account. The latter approach
conveys a more realistic sense of ancient political economies than do perspectives
that downplay the complex interplay among conceptual and prosaic factors in
shaping any object’s roles in a political economy (Graham, 2002, p. 416).

SUMMARY

In general, the fashioning, use, and distribution of any one craft good may
well involve a wide array of people with diverse identities and interests, variably
organized to achieve their goals, and distributed along several continua of eliteness.
Coordinated or in opposition, it is the activities of these individuals and factions
that simultaneously determine the meanings and functions of crafted items. How
these dimensions of status, meaning, organization, function, production, and distri-
bution articulate strongly conditions the manner in which an industry is implicated
in processes of political centralization, inequality, and social differentiation as
these are expressed at different times and over varying spatial scales. As noted
earlier, we rarely have the luxury of dealing with one industry by itself. Rather,
attention must be paid to how numerous crafts were integrated with each other and
the aforementioned political processes to create a political economy at a specific
moment in time.
The resulting picture is anything but neat and tidy and makes one nostalgic
for those days when specialized manufacture was just another item on a checklist
used to distinguish states from less complex political formations. The attractive
certainty about the nature of states and craft production embodied in that formula-
tion has vanished. Left in its wake is the discomforting realization that the elements
comprising political and economic structures are not neatly correlated internally
or with each other. The configurations they assume in any political economy at any
one time are difficult to describe and even harder to explain. Instead of being dis-
couraged by our growing uncertainty we should take heart that, by breaking unitary
political and economic forms into their components and charting their linkages,
we are finally coming to grips with the intricate, contingent, and volatile relations
that make life, in the past and present, so terribly messy and interesting. We are,
in short, now able to approximate ancient political economies less as simplified
P1: JLS
Journal of Archaeological Research [jar] pp1095-jare-479712 April 12, 2004 10:36 Style file version Nov 28th, 2002

Modeling the Roles of Craft Production in Ancient Political Economies 211

caricatures and more as lived experiences. The research outlined herein suggests
just how confusing our models of craft production and ancient political economies
are likely to get, a good sign that we are on the right track.

ACKNOWLEDGMENTS

We are very grateful to Gary Feinman and Linda Nicholas for the invitation
to contribute an essay to the Journal of Archaeological Research and, just as
importantly, for their patience in awaiting its arrival. The perceptive comments of
Gary Feinman, Timothy Pauketat, Dean Saitta, and Charles Stanish, along with
those of two anonymous reviewers, greatly helped to refine the arguments presented
here, and we deeply appreciate the time and care that went into these assessments.
As should be obvious from the article itself, we are profoundly indebted to all
those scholars who have significantly contributed to the study of ancient craft
production and whose work has been so stimulating to the field-at-large and to
us in particular. Limitations of space and time have meant that some important
studies were given short shrift and the work of every scholar was simplified. As
noted earlier, the model presented here, like all conceptual constructs, is selective
and not all-encompassing. We take full responsibility for the choices made in its
fashioning and for all errors that have infiltrated the construction process.

REFERENCES CITED

Abercrombie, N., Hill, S., and Turner, B. (1980). The Dominant Ideology Thesis, George Allen and
Unwin, London.
Appadurai, A. (1986). Introduction: Commodities and the politics of value. In Appadurai, A. (ed.),
The Social Life of Things: Commodities in Cultural Perspective, Cambridge University Press,
Cambridge, UK, pp. 3–63.
Arnold, D. (1993). Ecology and Ceramic Production in an Andean Community, Cambridge University
Press, Cambridge, UK.
Arnold, D. (1985). Ceramic Theory and Cultural Process, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge,
UK.
Arnold, J. (1993). Labor and the rise of complex hunter-gatherers. Journal of Anthropological Archae-
ology 12: 75–119.
Arnold, J. (1995). Social inequality, marginalization, and economic process. In Price, T. D., and
Feinman, G. (eds.), Foundations of Social Inequality, Plenum, New York, pp. 87–103.
Arnold, J. (1996). The archaeology of complex hunter-gatherers. Journal of Archaeological Method
and Theory 3: 77–125.
Arnold, J., and Munns, A. (1994). Independent or attached specialization: The organization of shell
bead production in California. Journal of Field Archaeology 21: 473–489.
Baines, J., and Yoffee, N. (1998). Order, legitimacy, and wealth in ancient Egypt and Mesopotamia.
In Feinman, G., and Marcus, J. (eds.), Archaic States, School of American Research Press, Santa
Fe, NM, pp. 199–260.
Baines, J., and Yoffee, N. (2000). Order, legitimacy, and wealth: Setting the terms. In Richards, J.,
and Van Buren, M. (eds.), Order, Legitimacy, and Wealth in Ancient States, Cambridge University
Press, Cambridge, UK, pp. 13–17.
P1: JLS
Journal of Archaeological Research [jar] pp1095-jare-479712 April 12, 2004 10:36 Style file version Nov 28th, 2002

212 Schortman and Urban

Balandier, G. (1970). Political Anthropology, Penguin, Middlesex.


Barth, F. (1969). Introduction. In Barth, F. (ed.), Ethnic Groups and Boundaries: The Social Organi-
zation of Culture Difference, Little, Brown, Boston, pp. 9–38.
Bayman, J. (1996). Shell ornament consumption in a Classic Hohokam platform mound community
center. Journal of Field Archaeology 23: 403–420.
Bayman, J. (2002). Hohokam craft economies and the materialization of power. Journal of Archaeo-
logical Method and Theory 9: 65–95.
Bernbeck, R. (1995). Lasting alliances and emerging competition: Economic developments in early
Mesopotamia. Journal of Anthropological Archaeology 14: 1–25.
Blanton, R., and Feinman, G. (1984). The Mesoamerican world system American Anthropologist 86:
673–682.
Blanton, R. E, Feinman, G., Kowalewski, S. A., and Peregrine, P. N. (1996). A dual-processual theory
for the evolution of Mesoamerican civilization. Current Anthropology 37: 1–14.
Bourdieu, P. (1977). Outline of a Theory of Practice, R. Nice (trans.) Cambridge University Press,
Cambridge, UK.
Bourdieu, P. (1979). Symbolic power. Critique of Anthropology 4: 77–86.
Bowser, B, (2000). From pottery to politics: An ethnoarchaeological study of political factionalism,
ethnicity, and domestic pottery style in the Ecuadorian Amazon. Journal of Archaeological Method
and Theory 7: 219–248.
Brumfiel, E. M. (1987). Elite and utilitarian crafts in the Aztec state. In Brumfiel, E., and Earle, T. (eds.),
Specialization, Exchange, and Complex Societies, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK,
pp. 102–118.
Brumfiel, E. (1992). Breaking and entering the ecosystem: Gender, class, and faction steal the show.
American Anthropologist 94: 551–567.
Brumfiel, E. (1996). Comment on, Agency, ideology, and power in archaeological theory, a special
section of Current Anthropology 37: 48–50.
Brumfiel, E. (1998). The multiple identities of Aztec craft specialists. In Costin, C., and Wright, R.
(eds.), Craft and Social Identity, Archeological Papers No. 8, American Anthropological Associ-
ation, Washington, DC, pp. 145–152.
Brumfiel, E. (2000). The politics of high culture: Issues of worth and rank. In Richards, J., and Van
Buren, M. (eds.), Order, Legitimacy, and Wealth in Ancient States, Cambridge University Press,
Cambridge, UK, pp. 131–139.
Brumfiel, E., and Earle, T. (1987). Specialization, exchange, and complex societies: An introduction.
In Brumfiel, E., and Earle, T. (eds.), Specialization, Exchange, and Complex Societies, Cambridge
University Press, Cambridge, UK, pp. 1–9.
Brumfiel, E., and Fox, J. (eds.) (1994). Factional Competition and Political Development in the New
World, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK.
Caldwell, J. (1964). Interaction spheres in prehistory. In Caldwell, J., and Hall, R. (eds.), Hopewellian
Studies, Scientific Papers No. 12, Illinois State Museum, Springfield, pp. 134–143.
Carr, C. (1995). A unified middle-range theory of artifact design. In Carr, C., and Neitzel, J. (eds.),
Style, Society, and Person, Plenum, New York, pp. 171–258.
Charlton, C. O. (1994). Plebian and patrician: Contrasting patterns of production and distribution in
the Aztec figurine and lapidary industries. In Hodge, M., and Smith, M. (eds.), Economies and
Polities in the Aztec Realm, Institute of Mesoamerican Studies, State University of New York,
Albany, and University of Texas Press, Austin, pp. 195–219.
Charlton, C. O., Charlton, T., and Nichols, D. (1993). Aztec household-based craft production: Ar-
chaeological evidence from the city-state of Otumba, Mexico. In Santley, R., and Hirth, K. (eds.),
Prehispanic Domestic Units in Western Mesoamerica, CRC Press, Boca Raton, FL, pp. 147–171.
Charlton, T. (1994). Economic heterogeneity and state expansion: The northeastern Basin of Mexico
during the Late Postclassic Period. In Hodge, M., and Smith, M. (eds.), Economies and Polities in
the Aztec Realm, Institute of Mesoamerican Studies, State University of New York, Albany, and
University of Texas Press, Austin, pp. 221–256.
Chase-Dunn, C., and Hall, T. (eds.) (1991). Core/Periphery Relations in Precapitalist Worlds, Westview,
Boulder, CO.
Childe, V. G. (1942). What Happened in History, Pelican Books, Hammondsworth.
Childe, V. G. (1950). The urban revolution. The Town Planning Review 21: 3–17.
P1: JLS
Journal of Archaeological Research [jar] pp1095-jare-479712 April 12, 2004 10:36 Style file version Nov 28th, 2002

Modeling the Roles of Craft Production in Ancient Political Economies 213

Childe, V. G. (1956). Man Makes Himself, Watts, London (originally published in 1936).
Childs, J. T., and Kilbick, D. (1993). Indigenous African metallurgy: Nature and culture. Annual Review
of Anthropology 22: 317–337.
Clark, J. E. (1986). From mountains to molehills: A critical review of Teotihuacan’s obsidian industry.
Research in Economic Anthropology Supplement 2: 23–74.
Clark, J. E. (1996). Craft specialization and Olmec civilization. In Wailes, B. (ed.), Craft Specializa-
tion and Social Evolution: In Memory of V. Gordon Childe, University Museum, University of
Pennsylvania, Philadelphia, pp. 187–199.
Clark, J. E., and Blake, M. (1994). The power of prestige: Competitive generosity and the emergence of
rank societies in lowland Mesoamerica. In Brumfiel, E., and Fox, J. (eds.), Factional Competition
and Political Development in the New World, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK,
pp. 17–30.
Clark, J. E., and Parry, W. (1990). Craft specialization and cultural complexity. Research in Economic
Anthropology 12: 289–346.
Cobb, C. (1993). Archaeological approaches to the political economy of non-stratified societies. In
Schiffer, M. (ed.), Archaeological Method and Theory, Vol. 5, University of Arizona Press, Tucson,
pp. 43–100.
Cohen, A. (1979). Political symbolism. Annual Review of Anthropology 8: 87–113.
Cohen, R. (1978). Ethnicity: The problem and focus in anthropology. Annual Review of Anthropology
7: 379–403.
Connell, S. (2002). Getting closer to the source: Using ethnoarchaeology to find ancient pottery making
in the Naco valley, Honduras. Latin American Antiquity 13: 401–417.
Costin, C. (1991). Craft specialization: Issues in defining, documenting, and explaining the organization
of production. In Schiffer, M. (ed.), Archaeological Method and Theory, Vol. 3, University of
Arizona Press, Tucson, pp. 1–56.
Costin, C. (1996). Craft production and mobilizaton strategies in the Inka Empire. In Wailes, B. (ed.),
Craft Specialization and Social Evolution: In Memory of V. Gordon Childe, University Museum,
University of Pennsylvania, Philadelphia, pp. 211–225.
Costin, C. (1998). Introduction: Craft and social identity. In Costin, C., and Wright, R. (eds.), Craft and
Social Identity, Archeological Papers No. 8, American Anthropological Association, Washington,
DC, pp. 3–18.
Costin, C. (2001). Craft production systems. In Feinman, G., and Price, T. D. (eds.), Archaeology at
the Millennium: A Sourcebook, Kluwer Academic, New York, pp. 273–327.
Costin, C., and Earle, T. (1989). Status distinction and legitimation of power as reflected in
changing patterns of consumption in late Prehispanic Peru. American Antiquity 54: 691–
714.
Costin, C., and Hagstrum, M. (1995). Standardization, labor investment, skill, and organiza-
tion of ceramic production in late Prehistoric highland Peru. American Antiquity 60: 619–
639.
Costin, C., and Wright, R. (eds.) (1998). Craft and Social Identity, Archeological Papers No. 8,
American Anthropological Association, Washington, DC.
Crumley, C. (1979). Three locational models: An epistemological assessment for anthropology and ar-
chaeology. In Schiffer, M. (ed.), Advances in Archaeological Method and Theory, Vol. 2, Academic
Press, New York, pp. 141–173.
D’Altroy, T., and Earle, T. (1985). Staple finance, wealth finance, and storage in the Inka political
economy. Current Anthropology 26: 187–206.
DeMarrais, E., Castillo, L. J., and Earle, T. (1996). Ideology, materialization, and power strategies.
Current Anthropology 37: 15–31.
de Montmollin, O. (1989). The Archaeology of Political Structure: Settlement Analysis in a Classic
Maya Polity, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK.
Dobres, M.-C. (1995). Gender and prehistoric technology: On the social agency of technical strategies.
World Archaeology 27: 25–49.
Dobres, M.-C., and Hoffman, C. (1995). Social agency and the dynamics of prehistoric technology.
Journal of Archaeological Method and Theory 1: 211–258.
Dupre, G., and Rey, P. (1973). Reflections on the pertinence of a theory of the history of exchange.
Economy and Society 2: 131–163.
P1: JLS
Journal of Archaeological Research [jar] pp1095-jare-479712 April 12, 2004 10:36 Style file version Nov 28th, 2002

214 Schortman and Urban

Earle, T. (1987). Specialization and the production of wealth: Hawaiian chiefdoms and the Inka empire.
In Brumfiel, E., and Earle, T. (eds.), Specialization, Exchange, and Complex Societies, Cambridge
University Press, Cambridge, UK, pp. 64–75.
Earle, T. (1991). The evolution of chiefdoms. In Earle, T. (ed.), Chiefdoms: Power, Economy and
Ideology, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, pp. 1–15.
Earle, T. (1994). Wealth finance in the Inka empire: Evidence from the Chalchaqui Valley, Argentina.
American Antiquity 59: 443–460.
Earle, T. (1997). How Chiefs Come to Power: The Political Economy of Prehistory, Stanford University
Press, Stanford.
Earle, T. (2001). Economic support of Chaco Canyon society. American Antiquity 66: 26–35.
Earle, T., and D’Altroy, T. (1989). The political economy of the Inka empire: The archaeology of power
and finance. In Lamberg-Karlovsky, C. C. (ed.), Archaeological Thought in America, Cambridge
University Press, Cambridge, UK, pp. 183–204.
Ekholm, K. (1972). Power and Prestige: The Rise and Fall of the Kongo Kingdom, SKRIV Service
AB, Uppsala, Sweden.
Ekholm, K. (1978). External change and the transformation of central African social systems. In
Friedman, J., and Rowlands, M. (eds.), The Evolution of Social Systems, University of Pittsburgh
Press, Pittsburgh, pp. 115–136.
Emerson, T. (1997). Reflections from the countryside on Cahokian hegemony. In Pauketat, T., and
Emerson, T. (eds.), Cahokia: Domination and Ideology in the Missisippian World, University of
Nebraska Press, Lincoln, pp. 167–189.
Emberling, G. (1999). The value of tradition: The development of social identities in early
Mesopotamian states. In Robb, J. (ed.), Material Symbols: Culture and Economy in Prehistory,
Occasional Papers No. 26, Center for Archaeological Investigations, Southern Illinois University,
Carbondale, pp. 277–301.
Feinman, G. (1991). Demography, surplus, and inequality: Early political formations in highland
Mesoamerica. In Earle, T. (ed.), Chiefdoms: Power, Economy, and Ideology, Cambridge University
Press, Cambridge, UK, pp. 229–262.
Feinman, G. (1995). The emergence of inequality: A focus on strategies and process. In Price, T.
D., and Feinman, G. (eds.), Foundations of Social Inequality, Plenum, New York, pp. 255–
279.
Feinman, G., and Neitzel, J. (1984). Too many types: An overview of sedentary prestate societies
in the Americas. In Schiffer, M. (ed.), Advances in Archaeological Method and Theory, Vol. 7,
Academic Press, New York, pp. 39–102.
Feinman, G., and Nicholas, L. (2000). High-intensity househld-scale production in ancient Mesoamer-
ica: A perspective from Ejutla, Oaxaca. In Feinman, G., and Manzanilla, L. (eds.), Cultural
Evolution: Contemporary Viewpoints, Kluwer Academic, New York, pp. 119–142.
Ferguson, Y., and Mansbach, R. (1996). Polities: Authority, Identities, and Change, University of South
Carolina Press, Columbia.
Flannery, K., and Marcus, J. (eds.) (1983). The Cloud People: Divergent Evolution of the Zapotec and
Mixtec Civilizations, Academic Press, New York.
Foias, A. (2002). At the crossroads: The economic basis of political power in the Petexbatun region.
In Masson, M., and Freidel, D. (eds.), Ancient Maya Political Economies, Altamira Press, Walnut
Creek, CA, pp. 223–248.
Fotiadis, M. (1999). Comparability, equivalency, and contestation. In Robb, J. (ed.), Material Sym-
bols: Culture and Economy in Prehistory, Occasional Papers No. 26, Center for Archaeological
Investigations, Southern Illinois University, Carbondale, pp. 385–398.
Frankenstein, D., and Rowlands, M. (1978). The internal structure and regional context of early
Iron Age society in southwestern Germany. Bulletin of the Institute of Archaeology 15: 73–
112.
Freidel, D. (1986). Maya warfare: An example of peer polity interaction. In Renfrew, C., and
Cherry, J. (eds.), Peer Polity Interaction and Socio-Political Change, Cambridge University Press,
Cambridge, UK, pp. 93–108.
Freidman, J. (1982). Catastrophe and continuity in social evolution. In Renfrew, C., Rowlands, M.,
and Segraves, B. (eds.), Theory and Explanation in Archaeology: The Southampton Conference,
Academic Press, New York, pp. 175–196.
P1: JLS
Journal of Archaeological Research [jar] pp1095-jare-479712 April 12, 2004 10:36 Style file version Nov 28th, 2002

Modeling the Roles of Craft Production in Ancient Political Economies 215

Friedman, J., and Rowlands, M. (1978). Notes toward an epigenetic model of the evolution of civi-
lization. In Friedman, J., and Rowlands, M. (eds.), The Evolution of Social Systems, University
of Pittsburgh Press, Pittsburgh, pp. 201–276.
Fry, R. (1981). Pottery production–distribution systems in the southern Maya lowlands. In Howard,
H., and Morris, E. (eds.), Production and Distribution: A Ceramic Viewpoint, BAR International
Series, No. 120, British Archaeological Reports Oxford, pp. 145–167.
Gailey, C. (1987). Culture wars: Resistance to state formation. In Patterson, T., and Gailey, C. (eds.),
Power Relations and State Formation, American Anthropological Association, Washington, DC,
pp. 35–56.
Geertz, C. (1973). Thick description: Toward an interpretive theory of culture. In Geertz, C. (ed.), The
Interpretation of Cultures, Basic Books, New York, pp. 3–30.
Gibson, D. (1996). Death of a salesman: Childe’s itinerant craftsman in light of present knowledge of
late Prehistoric craft production. In Wailes, B. (ed.), Craft Specialization and Social Evolution:
In Memory of V. Gordon Childe, University Museum, University of Pennsylvania, Philadelphia,
pp. 107–119.
Giddens, A. (1984). The Constitution of Society: Outline of the Theory of Structuration, University of
California Press, Berkeley.
Gillespie, S. (1999). Olmec thrones as ancestral altars: The two sides of power. In Robb, J. (ed.),
Material Symbols: Culture and Economy in Prehistory, Occasional Papers No. 26, Center for
Archaeological Investigations, Southern Illinois University, Carbondale, pp. 224–253.
Gilman, A. (1991). Trajectories towards social complexity in the later prehistory of the Mediter-
ranean. In Earle, T. (ed.), Chiefdoms: Power, Economy, and Ideology, Cambridge University
Press, Cambridge, UK, pp. 146–168.
Godelier, M. (1977). Perspectives in Marxist Anthropology, Robert Brain, translator, Cambridge Uni-
versity Press, Cambridge, UK.
Gosselain, O. (1993). Technology and style: Potters and pottery among Babia of Cameroon. Man 27:
559–586.
Gosselain, O. (2000). Materializing identities: An African perspective. Journal of Archaeological
Method and Theory 7: 187–217.
Graham, E. (2002). Perspectives on economy and theory. In Masson, M., and Freidel, D. (eds.), Ancient
Maya Political Economies, Altamira Press, Walnut Creek, CA, pp. 398–418.
Hagstrum, M. (1988). Ceramic production in the central Andes, Peru: An archaeological and ethno-
graphic comparison. In Kolb, C., and Lackey, L. M. (eds.), A Pot for all Reasons, A Special
Publication of Cerámica de Cultura Maya, Temple University, Philadelphia, pp. 127–145.
Hagstrum, M. (2001). Household production in Chaco Canyon society. American Antiquity 66: 47–
55.
Hayashida, F. (1999). Style, technology, and state production: Inka pottery manufacture in the Leche
valley, Peru. Latin American Antiquity 10: 337–352.
Hayden, B. (1994). Village approaches to complex societies. In Schwartz, G., and Falconer, S. (eds.),
Archaeological Views from the Countryside: Village Communities in Early Complex Societies,
Smithsonian Institution Press, Washington, DC, pp. 198–206.
Hayden, B. (1995). Pathways to power: Principles for creating socioeconomic inequalities. In Price,
T. D., and Feinman, G. (eds.), Foundations of Social Inequality, Plenum, New York, pp. 15–86.
Hayden, B. (1998). Practical and prestige technologies: The evolution of material systems. Journal of
Archaeological Method and Theory 5: 1–55.
Hayden, B. (2001). Richman, poorman, beggarman, chief: The dynamics of social inequality. In
Feinman, G., and Price, T. D. (eds.), Archaeology at the Millennium: A Sourcebook, Kluwer
Academic, New York, pp. 231–272.
Hendon, J. (1999). Multiple sources of prestige and the social evaluation of women in prehispanic
Mesoamerica. In Robb, J. (ed.), Material Symbols: Culture and Economy in Prehistory, Occasional
Papers No. 26, Center for Archaeological Investigations, Southern Illinois University, Carbondale,
pp. 257–276.
Hodder, I. (1979). Economic and social stress and material cultural patterning. American Antiquity 44:
446–454.
Hodder, I. (1982). Symbols in Action: Ethnoarchaeological Studies of Material Culture, Cambridge
University Press, Cambridge, UK.
P1: JLS
Journal of Archaeological Research [jar] pp1095-jare-479712 April 12, 2004 10:36 Style file version Nov 28th, 2002

216 Schortman and Urban

Hodder, I. (1986). Reading the Past: Current Approaches to Interpretation in Archaeology, Cambridge
University Press, Cambridge, UK.
Hodge, M., and Smith, M. (eds.) (1994). Economies and Polities in the Aztec Realm, Institute of
Mesoamerican Studies, State University of New York, Albany, and University of Texas Press,
Austin.
Hosler, D. (1994). The Sounds and Colors of Power: The Sacred Metallurgical Technology of Ancient
West Mexico, MIT Press, Cambridge, MA.
Inomata, T. (2001). The power and ideology of artistic creation. Current Anthropology 42: 321–344.
Joyce, R. (2000). High culture, Mesoamerican civilization, and the Classic Maya tradition. In Richards,
J., and Van Buren, M. (eds.), Order, Legitimacy, and Wealth in Ancient States, Cambridge Uni-
versity Press, Cambridge, UK, pp. 64–76.
Kenoyer, J. (2000). Wealth and socioeconomic hierarchies of the Indus Valley civilization. In Richards,
J., and Van Buren, M. (eds.), Order, Legitimacy, and Wealth in Ancient States, Cambridge Uni-
versity Press, Cambridge, UK, pp. 88–109.
Kim, J. (2001). Elite strategies and the spread of technological innovations: The spread of iron in the
Bronze Age societies of Denmark and southern Korea. Journal of Anthropological Archaeology
20: 442–478.
King, E., and Potter, D. (1994). Small sites in prehistoric Maya socioeconomic organization: A per-
spective from Colha, Belize. In Schwartz, G., and Falconer, S. (eds.), Archaeological Views from
the Countryside: Village Communities in Early Complex Societies, Smithsonian Institution Press,
Washington, DC, pp. 64–90.
Kowalewski, S., Feinman, G., Finsten, L., Blanton, R., and Nicholas, L. (1989). Monte Alban’s Hinter-
land, Part II: The Prehispanic Settlement Patterns in Tlacolula, Etla, and Ocotlán, the Valley of
Oaxaca, Mexico, Memoirs No. 23, Museum of Anthropology, University of Michigan, Ann Arbor.
Kramer, C. (1985). Ceramic ethnoarchaeology. Annual Review of Anthropology 14: 77–102.
Kristiansen, K. (1991). Chiefdom, states, and systems of social evolution. In Earle, T. (ed.), Chiefdoms:
Power, Economy, and Ideology, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, pp. 16–43.
Kopytoff, I. (1986). The cultural biography of things: Commoditization as process. In Appadurai, A.
(ed.), The Social Life of Things: Commodities in Cultural Perspective, Cambridge University
Press, Cambridge, UK, pp. 64–79.
Lamberg-Karlovsky, C. C. (1993). The biography of an object: The Inter-Cultural style vessels of the
Third Millennium B. C. In Luber, S., and Kingery W. D. (eds.), History from Things: Essays on
Material Culture, Smithsonian Institution Press, Washington, DC, pp. 270–292.
Larick, R. (1991). Warriors and blacksmiths: Mediating identity in east African spears. Journal of
Anthropological Archaeology 10: 299–331.
Lass, B. (1998). Crafts, chiefs, and commoners: Production and control in precontact Hawai’i. In
Costin, C., and Wright, R. (eds.), Craft and Social Identity, Archeological Papers No. 8, American
Anthropological Association, Washington, DC, pp. 19–30.
Lechtman, H. (1993). Technologies of power: The Andean case. In Henderson, J., and Netherly,
p. (eds.), Configurations of Power: Holistic Anthropology in Theory and Practice, Cornell
University Press, Ithaca, NY, pp. 244–280.
Lemonnier, P. (1992). Elements for an Anthropology of Technology, Anthropological Papers, No. 88
Museum of Anthropology, University of Michigan, Ann Arbor.
Levy, J. (1999). Metals, symbols, and society in Bronze Age Denmark. In Robb, J. (ed.), Material Sym-
bols: Culture and Economy in Prehistory, Occasional Papers No. 26, Center for Archaeological
Investigations, Southern Illinois University, Carbondale, pp. 205–223.
Lillios, K. (1999). Symbolic artifacts and spheres of meaning: Groundstone tools from Copper Age
Portugal. In Robb, J. (ed.), Material Symbols: Culture and Economy in Prehistory, Occasional
Papers No. 26, Center for Archaeological Investigations, Southern Illinois University, Carbondale,
pp. 173–187.
Loney, H. (2000). Society and technological control: A critical review of models of technological
change in ceramic studies. American Antiquity 65: 646–668.
López Varela, S., McAnany, P., and Berry, K. (2001). Ceramics technology at Late Classic K’axob,
Belize. Journal of Field Archaeology 28: 177–191.
Mann, M. (1986). The Source of Social Power: A History of Power from the Beginning Until 1760,
Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK.
P1: JLS
Journal of Archaeological Research [jar] pp1095-jare-479712 April 12, 2004 10:36 Style file version Nov 28th, 2002

Modeling the Roles of Craft Production in Ancient Political Economies 217

Marcus, J., and Flannery, K. (1996). Zapotec Civilization: How Urban Society Evolved in Mexico’s
Oaxaca Valley, Thames and Hudson, New York.
McAnany, P. (1993). The economics of social power and wealth among eighth century Maya
households. In Sabloff, J., and Henderson, J. (eds.), Lowland Maya Civilization in the Eighth
Century A.D., Dumbarton Oaks, Washington, DC, pp. 65–89.
McCall, J. (1999). Structure, agency, and the locus of the social: Why poststructural theory is good
for archaeology. In Robb, J. (ed.), Material Symbols: Culture and Economy in Prehistory,
Occasional Papers No. 26, Center for Archaeological Investigations, Southern Illinois University,
Carbondale, pp. 16–20.
McCorriston, J. (1997). The fiber revolution: Textile extensification, alienation, and social stratification
in ancient Mesopotamia. Current Anthropology 38: 517–550.
McGuire, R. (1983). Breaking down cultural complexity: Inequality and heterogeneity. In Schiffer,
M. (ed.), Advances in Archaeological Method and Theory, Vol. 6, Academic Press, New York,
pp. 91–142.
Meillassoux, C. (1981). Maidens, Meal, and Money, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK.
Middleton, W., Feinman, G., and Nicholas, L. (2002). Domestic faunal assemblages from the Classic
period valley of Oaxaca, Mexico: A perspective on the subsistence and craft economies. Journal
of Archaeological Science 29: 233–249.
Miller, D., Rowlands, M., and Tilley, C. (1989). Introduction. In Miller, D., Rowlands, M., and Tilley,
C. (eds.), Domination and Resistance, Unwin Hyman, London, pp. 1–26.
Mills, B. J. (1995). Gender and the reorganization of Historic Zuni craft production: Implications for
archaeological interpretation. Journal of Anthropological Archaeology 51: 149–172.
Moholy-Nagy, H. (1997). Middens, construction fill, and offerings: Evidence for the organization
of Classic Period craft production at Tikal, Guatemala. Journal of Field Archaeology 24: 293–
313.
Moore, J. (1996). Architecture and Power in the Ancient Andes: The Archaeology of Public Buildings,
Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK.
Morrison, K. (1994). The intensification of production: Archaeological approaches. Journal of
Archaeological Method and Theory 1: 111–159.
Morrison, K., and Sinopoli, C. (1992). Economic diversity and integration in a Pre-Colonial Indian
empire. World Archaeology 23: 335–352.
Morrow, C. (1987). Blades and Cobden Chert: A technological argument for their role as markers
of regional identification during the Hopewell period in Illinois. In Johnson, J., and Morrow, C.
(eds.), The Organization of Core Technology, Westview Press, Boulder, CO, pp. 119–150.
Nader, L. (1997). Centralizing processes: Tracing the dynamic components of power. Current
Anthropology 38: 711–737.
Nelson, B. (1995). Complexity, hierarchy, and scale: A controlled comparison between Chaco Canyon,
New Mexico, and La Quemada, Zacatecas. American Antiquity 60: 597–618.
O’Brian, R. (1999). Who weaves and why? Weaving, loom complexity, and trade. Cross-Cultural
Research 33: 30–42.
Pauketat, T. R. (1997). Cahokian political economy. In Pauketat, T. R., and Emerson, T. (eds.),
Cahokia: Domination and Ideology in the Mississippian World, University of Nebraska Press,
Lincoln, pp. 30–51.
Pauketat, T., and Emerson, T. (1999). Representations of hegemony as community at Cahokia.
In Robb, J. (ed.), Material Symbols: Culture and Economy in Prehistory, Occasional Papers
No. 26, Center for Archaeological Investigations, Southern Illinois University, Carbondale,
pp. 302–317.
Paynter, R. (1989). The archaeology of equality and inequality. Annual Review of Anthropology 18:
369–399.
Paynter, R., and McGuire, R. (1991). The archaeology of inequality: Culture, domination, and
resistance. In McGuire, R., and Paynter, R. (eds.), The Archaeology of Inequality, Blackwell,
Oxford, pp. 1–27.
Peacock, D. (1981). Archaeology, ethnology, and ceramic production. In Howard, H., and Morris,
E. (eds.), Production and Distribution: A Ceramic Viewpoint, BAR International Series, 120,
British Archaeological Reports, Oxford, pp. 187–194.
Peregrine, P. (1991a). Some political aspects of craft specialization. World Archaeology 23: 1–11.
P1: JLS
Journal of Archaeological Research [jar] pp1095-jare-479712 April 12, 2004 10:36 Style file version Nov 28th, 2002

218 Schortman and Urban

Peregrine, P. (1991b). Prehistoric chiefdoms on the American midcontinent: A world-system based on


prestige goods. In Chase-Dunn, C., and Hall, T. (eds.), Core/Periphery Relations in Precapitalist
Worlds, Westview Press, Boulder, CO, pp. 193–211.
Peregrine, P., and Feinman, G. (eds.) (1996). Pre-Columbian World Systems, Prehistory Press,
Madison, WI.
Perles, C. (1992). In search of lithic strategies: A cognitive approach to chipped stone assemblages. In
Gardin, J.-C., and Peebles, C. (eds.), Representations in Archaeology, Indiana University Press,
Bloomington, pp. 223–247.
Pfaffenberger, B. (1988). Fetishised objects and humanised nature: Towards an anthropology of
technology. Man 23: 236–252.
Pfaffenberger, B. (1992). Social anthropology of technology. Annual Review of Anthropology 21:
491–516.
Pool, C. (1992). Integrating ceramic production and distribution. In Bey, G., III, and Pool, C. (eds.),
Ceramic Production and Distribution: An Integrated Approach, Westview Press, Boulder, CO,
pp. 275–313.
Poole, P. (1991). Domestic Ceramic Production and Spatial Organization: A Mexican Case Study in
Archaeology, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK.
Renfrew, C. (1986). Varna and the emergence of wealth in prehistoric Europe. In Appadurai, A. (ed.),
The Social Life of Things: Commodities in Cultural Perspective, Cambridge University Press,
Cambridge, UK, pp. 141–168.
Robb, J. (1999). Secret agents: Culture, economy, and social reproduction. In Robb, J. (ed.),
Material Symbols: Culture and Economy in Prehistory, Occasional Papers No. 26, Center for
Archaeological Investigations, Southern Illinois University, Carbondale, pp. 3–15.
Royce, A. (1982). Ethnic Identities: Strategies of Diversity, Indiana University Press, Bloomington.
Runciman, W. (1982). Origins of states: The case of Archaic Greece. Comparative Studies in Society
and History 24: 351–377.
Sabloff, J. (1986). Interaction among Classic Maya polities: A preliminary examination. In Renfrew,
C., and Cherry, J. (eds.), Peer Polity Interaction and Socio-Political Change, Cambridge
University Press, Cambridge, UK, pp. 109–116.
Sackett, J. (1972). Style, function, and artifact variability in Paleolithic assemblages. In Renfrew, C.
(ed.), The Explanation of Culture Change, Duckworth, London, pp. 317–328.
Sackett, J. (1982). Approaches to style in lithic archaeology. Journal of Anthropological Archaeology
1: 59–112.
Saitta, D. (1994). Agency, class, and archaeological interpretation. Journal of Anthropological
Archaeology 13: 201–227.
Saitta, D. (1997). Power, labor, and the dynamics of change in Chacoan political economy. American
Antiquity 62: 7–26.
Saitta, D. (1999). Prestige, agency, and change in middle-range societies. In Robb, J. (ed.), Ma-
terial Symbols: Culture and Economy in Prehistory, Occasional Papers No. 26, Center for
Archaeological Investigations, Southern Illinois University, Carbondale, pp. 135–149.
Schele, L., and Miller, M. (1986). The Blood of Kings: Dynasty and Ritual in Maya Art, Kimbell Art
Museum, Fort Worth, TX.
Schortman, E. (1989). Interregional interaction in prehistory: The need for a new perspective.
American Antiquity 54: 52–65.
Schortman, E., Urban, P., and Ausec, M. (2001). Politics with style: Identity formation in Prehispanic
southeastern Mesoamerica. American Anthropologist 103: 312–330.
Scott, J. (1985). Weapons of the Weak: Everyday Forms of Peasant Resistance, Yale University Press,
New Haven, CT.
Sinopoli, C. (1988). The organization of craft production at Vijayanagara, South India. American
Anthropologist 90: 580–597.
Sinopoli, C. (1994). Political choices and economic strategies in the Vijayanagara empire. In Brumfiel,
E. (ed.), The Economic Anthropology of the State, University Press of America, Lanham, MD,
pp. 223–242.
Sinopoli, C. (1998). Identity and social interaction among south Indian craft producers of the
Vijayanagara Period. In Costin, C., and Wright, R. (eds.) Craft and Social Identity, Archeological
Papers No. 8, American Anthropological Association, Washington, DC, pp. 161–172.
P1: JLS
Journal of Archaeological Research [jar] pp1095-jare-479712 April 12, 2004 10:36 Style file version Nov 28th, 2002

Modeling the Roles of Craft Production in Ancient Political Economies 219

Sinopoli, C., and Morrison, K. D. (1995). Dimensions and imperial control: The Vijayanagara capital.
American Anthropologist 97: 83–96.
Spielmann, K. (1998). Ritual craft specialists in middle range societies. In Costin, C., and Wright,
R. (eds.), Craft and Social Identity, Archeological Papers No. 8, American Anthropological
Association, Washington, DC, pp. 153–159.
Spielmann, K. (2002). Feasting, craft specialization, and the ritual mode of production. American
Anthropologist 104: 195–207.
Stark, M. (1991). Ceramic production and community specialization: A Kalinga ethnoarchaeological
study. World Archaeology 23: 64–78.
Stark, M., and Heidka, J. (1998). Ceramic manufacture, productive specialization, and the Early
Classic period in Arizona’s Tonto Basin. Journal of Anthropological Research 51: 497–517.
Stein, G. (1994). Segmentary states and organizational variation in early complex societies: A rural
perspective. In Schwartz, G., and Falconer, S. (eds.), Archaeological Views from the Countryside:
Village Communities in Early Complex Societies, Smithsonian Institution Press, Washington,
DC, pp. 10–18.
Stein, G. (1996). Producers, patrons, and prestige: Craft specialists and emergent elites in Mesopotamia
from 5500–3100 BC. In Wailes, B. (ed.), Craft Specialization and Social Evolution: In Memory
of V. Gordon Childe, University Museum, University of Pennsylvania, Philadelphia, pp. 25–38.
Stein, G. (1998). Heterogeneity, power, and political economy: Some current research issues in the
archaeology of Old World complex societies. Journal of Archaeological Research 6: 1–44.
Stein, G. (2001). Understanding ancient state societies in the Old World. In Feinman, G., and Price, T.
D. (eds.), Archaeology at the Millennium: A Sourcebook Kluwer Academic, New York, pp. 353–
379.
Thomas, J. (1999). An economy of substances in earlier Neolithic Britain. In Robb, J. (ed.),
Material Symbols: Culture and Economy in Prehistory, Occasional Papers No. 26, Center for
Archaeological Investigations, Southern Illinois University, Carbondale, pp. 70–89.
Thomas, N. (1992). The cultural dynamics of peripheral exchange. In Humphrey, C., and Hugh- Jones,
S. (eds.), Barter, Exchange, and Value: An Anthropological Approach, Cambridge University
Press, Cambridge, UK, pp. 21–41.
Tosi, M. (1984). The notion of craft specialization and its representation in the archaeological record
of early states in the Turanian Basin. In Spriggs, M. (ed.), Marxist Perspectives in Archaeology,
Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, pp. 22–52.
Trigger, B. (1980). Gordon Childe: Revolutions in Archaeology, Columbia University Press, New York.
Tringham, R. (1996). But Gordon, where are all the people? Some comments on the topic of craft
specialization and social evolution. In Wailes, B. (ed.), Craft Specialization and Social Evolution:
In Memory of V. Gordon Childe, University Museum, University of Pennsylvania, Philadelphia,
pp. 233–239.
Trubitt, M. (2000). Mound building and prestige goods exchange: Changing strategies in the Cahokian
chiefdom. American Antiquity 65: 669–690.
Turner, V. (1964). Symbols in Ndembu ritual. In Gluckman, M. (ed.), Closed Systems and Open
Minds: The Limits of Naivety in Social Science, Oliver and Boyd, Edinburgh, pp. 20–51.
Van Pool, T., and Leonard, R. (2002). Specialized ground stone production in the Casas Grandes
region of northern Chihuahua, Mexico. American Antiquity 67: 710–730.
Wailes, B. (1996). V. Gordon Childe and the relations of production. In Wailes, B. (ed.), Craft
Specialization and Social Evolution: In Memory of V. Gordon Childe, University Museum,
University of Pennsylvania, Philadelphia, pp. 3–14.
Wattenmaker, P. (1994). State formation and the organization of craft production at third millenium
BC Kurban Hoyuk, southeast Turkey. In Schwartz, G., and Falconer, S. (eds.), Archaeological
Views from the Countryside: Village Communities in Early Complex Societies, Smithsonian
Institution Press, Washington, DC, pp. 109–120.
Wattenmaker, P. (1998). Household and State in Upper Mesopotamia, Smithsonian Institution Press,
Washington, DC.
Weissner, P. (1983). Style and social interaction in Kalahari San projectile points. American Antiquity
48: 253–276.
Wells, P. (1988). Industry and society in late prehistoric Europe. In Gibson, O., and Geselowitz, M.
(eds.), Tribe and Polity in Late Prehistoric Europe, Plenum, New York, pp. 207–218.
P1: JLS
Journal of Archaeological Research [jar] pp1095-jare-479712 April 12, 2004 10:36 Style file version Nov 28th, 2002

220 Schortman and Urban

Wells, P. (1996). Location, organization, and specialization of craft production in late prehistoric
central Europe. In Wailes, B. (ed.), Craft Specialization and Social Evolution: In Memory of V.
Gordon Childe, University Museum, University of Pennsylvania, Philadelphia, pp. 85–98.
White, J., and Pigott, V. (1996). From community craft to regional specialization: Intensification of
copper production in pre-state Thailand. In Wailes, B. (ed.), Craft Specialization and Social
Evolution: In Memory of V. Gordon Childe, University Museum, University of Pennsylvania,
Philadelphia, pp. 151–175.
Wobst, M. (1977). Stylistic behavior and information exchange. In Cleland, C. (ed.), For the Director:
Research Essays in Honor of James B. Griffin, Anthropological Papers No. 61, Museum of
Anthropology, University of Michigan, Ann Arbor, pp. 317–342.
Wright, R. (1993). Technological styles: Transforming a natural material into a cultural object. In
Luber, S., and Kingerj, W. (eds.) History from Things: Essays on Material Culture, Smithsonian
Institution Press, Washington, DC, pp. 242–269.
Wright, R. (1996). Contexts of specialization: V. Gordon Childe and social evolution. In Wailes, B.
(ed.), Craft Specialization and Social Evolution: In Memory of V. Gordon Childe, University
Museum, University of Pennsylvania, Philadelphia, pp. 123–132.
Yoffee, N. (1991). Maya elite interaction: Through a glass sideways. In Culbert, T. p. (ed.), Classic
Maya Political History: Hieroglyphic and Archaeological Evidence, Cambridge University Press,
Cambridge, UK, pp. 285–310.

BIBLIOGRAPHY OF RECENT LITERATURE

Abrams, E. (1996). The evolution of plaster production and the growth of the Copan Maya state.
In Mastache, A. G., Parsons, J. F., Santley, R. S., and Serra Puche, M. C. (eds.), Arqueologı́a
mesoamericana: homenaje a William T. Sanders, Vol. II., Instituto Nacional de Antropologı́a e
Historia, Mexico City, pp. 193–208.
Ames, S. A. (1995). Chiefly power and household production on the Northwest coast. In Price, T. D.,
and Feinman, G. (eds.), Foundations of Social Inequality, Plenum, New York, pp. 155–187.
Archi, A. (1990). The city of Ebla and the organization of the rural territory. In Aertz, E., and Klengel,
H. (eds.), The Town as Regional Economic Center in the Ancient Near East, Leuven University
Press, Leuven, Belgium pp. 15–19.
Anthony, D. W. (1996). V. G. Childe’s world system and the daggers of the Early Bronze Age. In Wailes,
B. (ed.), Craft Specialization and Social Evolution: In Memory of V. Gordon Childe, University
Museum, University of Pennsylvania, Philadelphia, pp. 47–66.
Aoyama, K. (1999). Ancient Maya State, Urbanism, Exchange, and Craft Specialization: Chipped
Stone Evidence from the Copan Valley and La Entrada Region, Honduras, Memoirs in Latin
American Archaeology, No. 12, University of Pittsburgh, Pittsburgh.
Arnold, J. (1991). Transformation of a regional economy: Sociopolitical evolution and the production
of valuables in southern California. Antiquity 65: 953–962.
Arnold, J. (1992). Complex hunter–gatherer–fishers in prehistoric California: Chiefs, specialists, and
maritime adaptations of the Channel Islands. American Antiquity 57: 60–84.
Arnold, P., III (1991). Domestic Ceramic Production and Spatial Organization: A Mexican Case Study
in Ethnoarchaeology, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK.
Arnold, P., III (1996). Craft specialization and social change along the southern Gulf Coast of Mexico.
In Wailes, B. (ed.), Craft Specialization and Social Evolution: In Memory of V. Gordon Childe,
University Museum, University of Pennsylvania, Philadelphia, pp. 201–210.
Arnold, P., III, Pool, C., Kneebone, R., and Santley, R. (1993). Intensive ceramic production and Classic-
period political economy in the Sierra de los Tuxtlas, Veracruz, Mexico. Ancient Mesoamerica 4:
175–191.
Arnold III, P., and Santley, R. (1993). Household ceramics production at Middle Classic period Mata-
capan. In Santley, R., and Hirth, K. (eds.), Prehistoric Domestic Units in Western Mesoamerica,
CRC Press, Boca Raton, FL, pp. 227–248.
Balkansky, A., Feinman, G., and Nicholas, L. (1997). Pottery kilns of ancient Ejutla, Oaxaca, Mexico.
Journal of Field Archaeology 24: 139–160.
P1: JLS
Journal of Archaeological Research [jar] pp1095-jare-479712 April 12, 2004 10:36 Style file version Nov 28th, 2002

Modeling the Roles of Craft Production in Ancient Political Economies 221

Ball, J. (1993). Pottery, palaces, and polities: Some socioeconomic and political implications of Late
Classic Maya ceramic industries. In Sabloff, J., and Henderson, J. (eds.), Lowland Maya Civiliza-
tion in the Eighth Century A. D., Dumbarton Oaks, Washington, DC, pp. 243–272.
Barber, E. (1991). Prehistoric Textiles: The Development of Cloth in the Neolithic and Bronze Age with
Special Reference to the Aegean, Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ.
Barber, E. (1994). Womens’ Work: The First 20,000 Years, Norton, New York.
Barber, E., and Eicher, J. (eds.) (1992). Dress and Gender: Making and Meaning in Cultural Contexts,
Berg, New York.
Bayman, J. (1999). Craft economies in the North American southwest. Journal of Archaeological
Research 7: 249–299.
Berman, J. (1994). The ceramic evidence for sociopolitical organization in ‘Ubaid southwestern Iran.
In Stein, G., and Rothman, M. (eds.), Chiefdoms and Early States in the Near East: The Organi-
zational Dynamics of Complexity, Prehistory Press, Madison, WI, pp. 23–33.
Bey, G., and Pool, C. (eds.) (1992). Ceramic Production and Distribution, Westview Press, Boulder,
CO.
Bhan, K., Vidale, M., and Kenoyer, J. M. (1994). Harappan technology: Theoretical and methodological
issues. Man and Environment 19: 141–157.
Blackman, M. J., and Vidale, M. (1993). The production and distribution of stoneware bangles a
Mohenjo-daro and Harappa as monitored by chemical characterization studies. In Jarrige, C.
(ed.), South Asian Archaeology 1989, Prehistory Press, Madison, WI, pp. 37–44.
Bray, F. (1997). Technology and Gender, University of California Press, Berkeley.
Brisbane, M. (1981). Incipient markets for early Anglo-Saxon ceramics: Variations in levels and modes
of production. In Howard, H., and Morris, E. (eds.), Production and Distribution: A Ceramic
Viewpoint, BAR International series, No. 120, British Archaeological Reports Oxford, pp. 229–
242.
Bronson, B. (1996). Metals, specialization, and development in early Eastern and Southern Asia. In
Wailes, B. (ed.), Craft Specialization and Social Evolution: In Memory of V. Gordon Childe,
University Museum, University of Pennsylvania, Philadelphia, pp. 177–184.
Brumfiel, E. (1987). Consumption and politics at Aztec Huexotla. American Anthropologist 89: 676–
686.
Brumfiel. E. (1991). Weaving and cooking: Women’s production in Aztec Mexico. In, Gero, J., and
Conkey, M. (eds.), Engendering Archaeology, Basil Blackwell, Oxford, pp. 224–255.
Brumfiel, E. (1994). The economic anthropology of the state: An introduction. In Brumfiel, E. (ed.),
The Economic Anthropology of the State, University Press of America, Lanham, MD, pp. 1–16.
Brumfiel, E. (1996). The quality of tribute cloth: The place of evidence in archaeological argument.
American Antiquity 61: 453–462.
Brumfiel, E., and Earle, T. (eds.) (1987). Specialization, Exchange, and Complex Societies, Cambridge
University Press, Cambridge, UK.
Chapman, R. (1996). Inventiveness and ingenuity? Craft specialization, metallurgy, and the west
Mediterranean Bronze Age. In Wailes, B. (ed.), Craft Specialization and Social Evolution: In
Memory of V. Gordon Childe, University Museum, University of Pennsylvania, Philadelphia,
pp. 73–83.
Charlton, T., Nichols, D., and Charlton, C. O. (1991). Aztec craft production and specialization:
Archaeological evidence from the city-state of Otumba, Mexico. World Archaeology 23: 98–
114.
Childs, J. T. (1998). Social identity and specialization among Toro iron workers in western Uganda. In
Costin, C., and Wright, R. (eds.), Craft and Social Identity, Archeological Papers No. 8, American
Anthropological Association, Washington, DC, pp. 109–122.
Clark, J. E. (1987). Politics, prismatic blades, and Mesoamerican civilization. In Johnson, J., and
Morrow, C. (eds.), The Organization of Core Technology, Westview Press, Boulder, CO, pp. 259–
284.
Clark, J. E. (1995). Craft specialization as an archaeological category. Research in Economic Anthro-
pology 14: 267–294.
Clark, J. E., and Houston, S. (1998). Craft specialization, gender, and personhood among the postcon-
quest Maya of Yucatan, Mexico. In Costin, C., and Wright, R. (eds.), Craft and Social Identity,
Archeological Papers No. 8, American Anthropological Association, Washington, DC, pp. 31–46.
P1: JLS
Journal of Archaeological Research [jar] pp1095-jare-479712 April 12, 2004 10:36 Style file version Nov 28th, 2002

222 Schortman and Urban

Cobb, C. (1996). Specialization, exchange, and power in small-scale societies and chiefdoms. Research
in Economic Anthropology 17: 251–294.
Costin, C. (1993). Textiles, women, and political economy in Late Prehispanic Peru. Research in
Economic Anthropology 14: 3–28.
Costin, C. (1996). Exploring the relation between gender and craft in complex societies: Methodological
and theoretical issues of gender attribution. In Wright, R. (ed.), Gender in Archaeology: Essays
in Research and Practice, University of Pennsylvania Press, Philadelphia, pp. 111–142.
Costin, C. (1998). Housewives, chosen women, and skilled men: Cloth production and social identity
in the late Prehispanic Andes. In Costin, C., and Wright, R. (eds.), Craft and Social Identity,
Archeological Papers No. 8, American Anthropological Association, Washington, DC, pp. 123–
144.
Crabtree, P. J. (1996). The wool trade and the rise of urbanism in Middle Saxon England. In Wailes,
B. (ed.), Craft Specialization and Social Evolution: In Memory of V. Gordon Childe, University
Museum, University of Pennsylvania, Philadelphia, pp. 95–105.
Cross, J. R. (1993). Craft specialization in non-stratified societies. Research in Economic Anthropology
14: 61–84.
Crown, P. L (1994). Ceramics and Ideology: Salado Polychrome Pottery, University of New Mexico
Press, Albuquerque.
Curet, A. (1993). Regional studies and ceramic production areas: An example from La Mixtequilla,
Veracruz. Journal of Field Archaeology 20: 427–440.
D’Altroy, T., and Bishop, R. (1990). The provincial organization of Inka ceramic production. American
Antiquity 55: 120–138.
Ehrenreich, R. (1995). Early metalworking: A heterarchical analysis of industrial organization. In
Ehrenreich, R., Crumley, C., and Levy, J. (eds.), Heterarchy and the Analysis of Complex Society,
Archeological Papers No. 6, American Anthropological Association, Washington, DC, pp. 33–39.
Feinman, G. (1985). Changes in the organization of ceramic production in Pre-Hispanic Oaxaca,
Mexico. In Nelson, B. (ed.), Decoding Prehistoric Ceramics, Southern Illinois University Press,
Carbondale, pp. 195–224.
Feinman, G. (1986). The emergence of specialized ceramic production in Formative Oaxaca. Research
in Economic Anthropology (Suppl. 2): 347–373.
Feinman, G. (1999). Rethinking our assumptions: Economic specialization at the household scale
in ancient Ejutla, Oaxaca, Mexico. In Skibo, J., and Feinman, G. (eds.), Pottery and People,
University of Utah Press, Salt Lake City, pp. 81–98.
Feinman, G., Lightfoot, K., and Upham, S. (2000). Political hierarchies and organizational strategies
in the Puebloan Southwest. American Antiquity 65: 449–470.
Feinman, G., and Nicholas, L. (1993). Shell ornament production in Ejutla: Implications for highland-
coastal interactions in ancient Oaxaca. Ancient Mesoamerica 4: 103–119.
Feinman, G., Upham, S., and Lightfoot, K. (1981). The production step measure: An ordinal index of
labor input in ceramic manufacture. American Antiquity 46: 871–884.
Foias, A., and Bishop, R. L. (1997). Changing ceramic production and exchange in the Petexbatun
region, Guatemala: Reconsidering the Classic Maya collapse. Ancient Mesoamerica 8: 275–291.
Ford, A., and Olson, K. (1989). Aspects of ancient Maya household economy: Variation in chipped
stone production and consumption. Research in Economic Anthropology (Suppl. 4): 185–211.
Freter, A. C. (1996). Rural utilitarian ceramic production in the Late period Copan Maya state. In
Mastache, A. G., Parsons, J. F., Santley, R. S., and Serra Puche, M. C. (eds.), Arqueologı́a
mesoamericana: homenaje a William T. Sanders, Vol. II, Instituto Nacional de Antropologı́a e
Historia, Mexico City, pp. 209–229.
Geselowitz, M. N. (1993). Labor specialization in late Iron Age temperate Europe: The evidence from
the Kelheim Iron. In Wells, P. (ed.), Settlement, Economy, and Cultural Change at the End of the
European Iron Age: Excavations at Kelheimin Barvaria, International Monographs in Prehistory,
Ann Arbor, MI, pp. 77–82.
Gilman, A. (1996). Craft specialization in late Prehistoric Mediterranean Europe. In Wailes, B. (ed.),
Craft Specialization and Social Evolution: In Memory of V. Gordon Childe, University Museum,
University of Pennsylvania, Philadelphia, pp. 67–71.
Gilman, P. A., Canouts, V., and Bishop, R. L. (1994). The production and distribution of Classic
Mimbres Black-on-White Pottery. American Antiquity 59: 695–709.
P1: JLS
Journal of Archaeological Research [jar] pp1095-jare-479712 April 12, 2004 10:36 Style file version Nov 28th, 2002

Modeling the Roles of Craft Production in Ancient Political Economies 223

Gosselain, O. (1998). Social and technical identity in a clay crystal ball. In Stark, M. T. (ed.), The
Archaeology of Social Boundaries, Smithsonian Institution Press, Washington, DC, pp. 78–106.
Grave, P., Barbetti, M., Hotchkis, M., and Bird, R. (2000). The stoneware kilns of Sisatchanali and
Early Modern Thailand. Journal of Field Archaeology 27: 169–182.
Hastorf, C. (1990). The effect of the Inka state on Sausa agricultural production and crop consumption.
American Antiquity 55: 262–290.
Hegmon, M. (1998). Technology, style, and social practices: Archaeological approaches. In Stark, M.
T. (ed.), The Archaeology of Social Boundaries, Smithsonian Institution Press, Washington, DC,
pp. 264–280.
Hegmon, M., Hurst, W., and Allison, J. (1995) Production for local consumption and exchange: Com-
parisons of early red and white ware ceramics in the San Juan Region. In Mills, B., and Crown,
P. L. (eds.), Ceramic Production in the American Southwest, University of Arizona Press, Tucson,
pp.30–62.
Helms, M. (1988). Ulyssey’s Sail: An Ethnographic Odyssey of Power, Knowledge, and Social Distance,
Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ.
Helms, M. (1992). Long-Distance contacts, elite aspirations, and the Age of Discovery in cosmological
context. In Urban, P., and Schortman, E. (eds.), Resources, Power, and Interregional Interaction,
Plenum, New York, pp. 157–174.
Helms, M. (1993). Craft and the Kingly Ideal, University of Texas Press, Austin.
Hicks, F. (1987). First steps towards a market-integrated economy in Aztec Mexico. In Claessen, H. J.
M. (ed.), Early State Dynamics, E. J. Brill, Amsterdam, pp. 91–107.
Hirth, K. G. (1995). The investigation of obsidian craft production at Xochicalco, Morelos. Ancient
Mesoamerica 6: 251–258.
Hirth, K. G. (1996). Political economy and archaeology: Perspectives on exchange and production.
Journal of Archaeological Research 4: 203–239.
Hodge, M. G., Neff, H., Blackman, M. J., and Minc, L. D. (1993). Black-on-Orange ceramic production
in the Aztec empire’s heartland. Latin American Antiquity 4: 130–157.
Hosler, D. (1988). Ancient west Mexican metallurgy: South and Central American origins and west
Mexican transformations. American Anthropologist 90: 832–855.
Hosler, D. (1996). Technical choices, social categories, and meaning among the Andean potters of Las
Animas. Journal of Material Culture 1: 63–92.
Janusek, J. W. (1999). Craft and local power: Embedded specialization in Tiawanaku cities. Latin
American Antiquity 10: 107–131.
Kolb, C. C., and Lackey, L. M. (eds.) (1988). A Pot for All Reasons: Ceramic Ecology Revisited Papers
Dedicated to Fredrick R. Matson, A Special Edition of Cerámica de Cultura Maya, Laboratory of
Anthropology, Temple University, Philadelphia.
Kowalewski, S. A., and Finsten, L. (1983). The economic system of ancient Oaxaca: A regional
perspective. Current Anthropology 24: 413–441.
Kramer, C. (1997). Pottery in Rajasthan: Ethnoarchaeology in Two Indian Cities, Smithsonian Insti-
tution Press, Washington, DC.
Kristiansen, K. (1987). Center and periphery in Bronze Age Scandanavia. In Rowlands, M., Kristiansen,
K., and Larsen, M. (eds.), Centre and Periphery in the Ancient World, Cambridge University Press,
Cambridge, UK, pp. 74–86.
Kristiansen, K. (1987) From stone to bronze: The evolution of social complexity in northern Europe,
2300–1200 BC. In Brumfiel, E., and Earle, T. (eds.), Specialization, Exchange, and Complex
Societies, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, pp. 30–51.
Lechtman, H. (1984). Andean value systems and the development of prehistoric metallurgy. Technology
and Culture 25: 1–36.
McCafferty, S., and McCafferty, G. (1991). Spinning and weaving as female gender identity in
Post-Classic central Mexico. In Schevill, M., Berlo, J. C., and Dwyer, E. (eds.), Textile Tra-
ditions of Mesoamerica and the Andes: An Anthology, Garland Press, New York, pp. 19–
45.
McCafferty, S., and McCafferty, G. (2000). Textile production in Postclassic Cholula, Mexico. Ancient
Mesoamerica 11: 39–54.
McCorriston, J. (1997). The fiber revolution: Textile extensification, alienation, and social stratification
in ancient Mesopotamia. Current Anthropology 38: 517–550.
P1: JLS
Journal of Archaeological Research [jar] pp1095-jare-479712 April 12, 2004 10:36 Style file version Nov 28th, 2002

224 Schortman and Urban

Michaels, G. H., (1989). Craft specialization in the Early Postclassic of Colha. Research in Economic
Anthropology, Supplement 4: 139–183.
Mills, B. J. (1995). The organization of Protohistoric Zuni ceramic production. In Mills, B. J., and
Crown, P. L. (eds.), Ceramic Production in the American Southwest, University of Arizona Press,
Tucson, pp. 200–230.
Mills, B. J. (2000). Gender, craft production, and inequality. In Crown, P. L. (ed.), Women and Men
in the Prehispanic Southwest: Labor, Power, and Prestige, School of American Research Press,
Santa Fe, NM, pp. 301–343.
Mills, B. J., and Crown, P. L. (eds.) (1995). Ceramic Production in the American Southwest, University
of Arizona Press, Tucson.
Morris, C. (1993). The wealth of a Native American state: Value, investment, and mobilization in
the Inka economy. In Henderson, J., and Netherly, P. (eds.), Configurations of Power Holistic
Anthropology in Theory and Practice, Cornell University Press, Ithaca, NY, pp. 36–50.
Morris, C. (1995). Symbols to power: Styles and media in the Inka state. In Carr, C., and Neitzel, J.
(eds.), Style, Society, and Person, Plenum, New York, pp. 419–433.
Muller, J. (1987). Salt, chert, and shell: Mississippian exchange and economy. In Brumfiel, E., and
Earle, T. (eds.), Specialization, Exchange, and Complex Society, Cambridge University Press,
Cambridge, UK, pp. 10–21.
Newport, M. A. (2000). Clays of contention: An ethnoarchaeological study of factionalism and clay
composition. Journal of Archaeological Method and Theory 7: 249–272.
Nichols, D. (1994). The organization of provincial craft production in the Aztec city-state of Otumba.
In Hodge, M., and Smith, M. (eds.), Economics and Politics in the Aztec Realm, Institute for
Mesoamerican Studies, State University of New York, Albany, and University of Texas Press,
Austin, pp. 175–193.
Parry, W. (2001). Production and exchange of obsidian tools in Late Aztec city states. Ancient
Mesoamerica 12: 101–111.
Peacock, D. (1982). Pottery in the Roman World: An Ethnoarchaeological Approach, Longham,
London.
Peregrine, P. (ed.) (1991). Craft Production and Specialization. World Archaeology 23.
Petersen, J., Mitchell, D., and Shackley, M. S. (1997). The social and economic contexts of lithic
procurement: Obsidian from Classic period Hohokam sites. American Antiquity 62: 231–259.
Pool, C., and Santley, R. S. (1992). Middle Classic pottery economics in the Tuxtla Mountains, southern
Veracruz. In Bey, G., III, and Pool, C. (eds.), Ceramic Production and Distribution: An Integrated
Approach, Westview Press, Boulder, CO, pp. 205–234.
Raber, P. (1987). Early copper production in the Polis region, western Cyprus. Journal of Field Ar-
chaeology 14: 297–312.
Reents-Budet, D. (1998). Elite Maya pottery and artisans as social indicators. In Costin, C., and Wright,
R. (eds.), Craft and Social Identity, Archeological Papers No. 8, American Anthropological As-
sociation, Washington, DC, pp. 71–92.
Reents-Budet, D., Bishop, R., Taschek, J., and Ball, J. (2000). Out of palace dumps: Ceramic production
and use at Buenavista del Cayo. Ancient Mesoamerica 11: 99–121.
Renfrew, C. (2001). Production and consumption in a sacred economy: The material correlates of high
devotional expression at Chaco Canyon. American Antiquity 66: 14–25.
Rice, P. (1991). Women and prehistoric pottery production. In Walde, D., and Willows, N. (eds.), The
Archaeology of Gender, Archaeological Association, University of Calgary, Calgary, Canada,
pp. 436–443.
Sabloff, J. (1996). Postscript: The continuing interest in V. Gordon Childe. In Wailes, B. (ed.), Craft
Specialization and Social Evolution: In Memory of V. Gordon Childe, University Museum, Uni-
versity of Pennsylvania, Philadelphia, pp. 229–231.
Santley, R. (1994). Specialized commodity production in and around Matacapan: Testing the goodness
of fit of the regal-ritual and administrative models. In Schwartz, G. M., and Falconer, S. E. (eds.),
Archaeological Views from the Countryside: Village Communities in Early Complex Societies,
Smithsonian Institution Press, Washington, DC, pp. 91–108.
Santley, R. (1994). The economy of ancient Matacapan. Ancient Mesoamerica 5: 243–266.
Santley, R., Arnold, P., and Pool, C. (1989). The ceramic production system at Matacapan. Journal of
Field Archaeology 16: 107–132.
P1: JLS
Journal of Archaeological Research [jar] pp1095-jare-479712 April 12, 2004 10:36 Style file version Nov 28th, 2002

Modeling the Roles of Craft Production in Ancient Political Economies 225

Santley, R., and Kneebone, R. (1993). Craft specialization, refuse disposal, and the creation of spatial
archaeological records in Prehispanic Mesoamerica. In Santley, R., and Hirth, K. (eds.), Prehis-
panic Domestic Units in Western Mexico, CRC Press, Boca Raton, FL, pp. 37–63.
Schortman, E., and Urban, P. (1996). Actions at a distance, impacts at home: Prestige good theory and
a Pre-Columbian polity in southeastern Mesoamerica. In Peregrine, P., and Feinman, G. (eds.),
Precolumbian World Systems, Prehistory Press, Madison, WI, pp. 97–114.
Shafer, H., and Hester, T. (1991). Lithic and craft specialization and production at the Maya site of
Colha, Belize. World Archaeology 23: 79–97.
Sheets, P. (2000). Provisioning the Ceren household: The vertical economy, village economy, and
household economy in the southeast Maya periphery. Ancient Mesoamerica 11: 217–230.
Shimada, I., and Merkel, J. F. (1991). Copper-alloy metallurgy in ancient Peru. Scientific American
265: 80–86.
Sievert, A. K. (1992). Maya Ceremonial Specialization: Little Tools from the Sacred Cenote at Chichén
Itzá, Yucatan, Prehistory Press, Madison, WI.
Sinopoli, C. (1989). Standardization and specialization: Ceramic production at Vijayanagara, South
India. In Kenoyer, J. M. (ed.), Old Problems and New Perspectives in the Archaeology of South
Asia, Wisconsin Archaeological Reports, No. 2, University of Wisconsin, Madison, pp. 263–
272.
Skibo, J. M., and Feinman, G. (eds.) (1999). Pottery and People: A Dynamic Interaction, University
of Utah Press, Salt Lake City.
Smith, M., and Heath-Smith, C. (1994). Rural economy in Late Postclassic Morelos: An archaeological
study. In Hodge, M., and Smith, M. (eds.), Economies and Polities in the Aztec Realm, Institute
of Mesoamerican Studies, State University of New York, Albany, and University of Texas Press,
Austin, pp. 349–376.
Spence, M. (1984). Craft production and polity in early Teotihuacan. In Hirth, J. K. (ed.), Trade and
Exchange in Early Mesoamerica, University of New Mexico Press, Albuquerque, pp. 87–114.
Spence, M. (1985). Specialized production in rural Aztec society: Obsidian workshops of the Teoti-
huacan valley. In Folan, W. J. (ed.), Contributions to the Archaeology and Ethnohistory of Greater
Mesoamerica, Southern Illinois University Press, Carbondale, pp. 76–125.
Stark, B. (1985). Archaeological identification of pottery production locations: Ethnoarchaeological
and archaeological data in Mesoamerica. In Nelson, B. (ed.), Decoding Prehistoric Ceramics,
Southern Illinois University Press, Carbondale, pp. 155–194.
Stark, B. (1992). Ceramic production in prehistoric La Mixtequilla, south-central Veracruz, Mexico. In
III, Bey, G., and Pool, C. (eds.), Ceramic Production and Distribution: An Integrated Approach,
Westview Press, Boulder, CO, pp. 175–204.
Stein, G., and Blackman, J. M. (1993). The organizational context of specialized craft production in
early Mesopotamian states. Research in Economic Anthropology 14: 29–60.
Strazicich, V. (1998). Clay sources, pottery production, and regional economy in Chalchihuites, Mexico,
A. D. 200–900. Latin American Antiquity 9: 259–274.
Underhill, A. P. (1991). Pottery production in chiefdoms: The Longshan period in northern China.
World Archaeology 23: 12–17.
Underhill, A. P. (1996). Craft production and social evolution during the Longshan period of northern
China. In Wailes, B. (ed.), Craft Specialization and Social Evolution: In Memory of V. Gordon
Childe, University Museum, University of Pennsylvania, Philadelphia, pp. 133–150.
Vidale, M. (1989). Specialized producers and urban elites: On the role of craft industries in Mature
Harappan urban contexts. In Kenoyer, J. M. (ed.), Old Problems and New Perspectives in the
Archaeology of South Asia, Wisconsin Archaeological Reports No. 2, University of Wisconsin,
Madison, pp. 171–181.
Vidale, M. (1990). Stoneware industries of the Indus civilization. In Kingery, D. (ed.), Ceramics and
Civilization, American Ceramic Society, Westerville, OH, pp. 231–256.
Wailes, B. (ed.) (1996). Craft Specialization and Social Evolution: In Memory of V. Gordon Childe,
University Museum, University of Pennsylvania, Philadelphia.
Wattenmaker, P. (1994). Household economy in early state society: Material value, productive con-
text, and spheres of exchange. In Brumfiel, E. (ed.), The Economic Anthropology of the State,
Monographs in Economic Anthropology No. 11, University Press of America, Lanham, MD,
pp. 93–118.
P1: JLS
Journal of Archaeological Research [jar] pp1095-jare-479712 April 12, 2004 10:36 Style file version Nov 28th, 2002

226 Schortman and Urban

Wattenmaker, P. (1998). Craft production and social identity in northwest Mesopotamia. In Costin, C.,
and Wright, P. (eds.), Craft and Social Identity, Archeological Papers No. 8, American Anthro-
pological Association, Washington, DC, pp. 47–56.
Wells, P. (1987). Industry, commerce, and Temperate Europe’s first cities: Preliminary report on 1987
excavations at Kelheim, Bavaria. Journal of Field Archaeology 14: 399–412.
West, G. (2002). Ceramic exchange in the Late Classic and Postclassic Maya lowlands: A diachronic
approach. In Masson, M., and Freidel, D. (eds.), Ancient Maya Political Economies, Altamira
Press, Walnut Creek, CA, pp. 140–196.
Widmer, R. (1991). Lapidary craft specialization at Teotihuacan: Implications for community structure
at 33:S3W1 and economic organization in the city. Ancient Mesoamerica 2: 131–147.
Widmer, R. (1996). Procurement, exchange, and production of foreign commodities at Teotihuacan:
State monopoly or local control? In Mastache, A. G., Parsons, J. F., Santley, R. S., and Serra
Puche, M. C. (eds.), Arqueologı́a mesoamericana: homenaje a William T. Sanders, Vol. II, Instituto
Nacional de Antropologı́a e Historia, Mexico City, pp. 271–279.
Wright, R. (1991). Patterns of technology and organization of production at Harappa. In Meadow, R.
(ed.), Harappa Excavations 1986–1990: A Multidisciplinary Approach to 3rd Millennium B. C.
Urbanism, Prehistory Press, Madison, WI, pp. 71–88.
Wright, R. (1991). Women’s labor and pottery production in prehistory. In Gero, J., and Conkey, M.
(eds.), Engendering Archaeology: Women and Prehistory, Blackwell, Oxford, pp. 194–223.
Wright, R. (1996). Technology, gender, and class: Worlds of difference in Ur III Mesopotamia. In
Wright, R. (ed.), Gender and Archaeology: Essays in Research and Practice, University of
Pennsylvania Press, Philadelphia, pp. 79–110.
Wright, R. (1998). Crafting social identity in Ur III southern Mesopotamia. In Costin, C., and Wright,
R. (eds.), Craft and Social Identity, Archeological Papers No. 8, American Anthropological As-
sociation, Washington, DC, pp. 57–70.
Yerkes, R. W. (1991). Specialization in shell artifact production at Cahokia. In Stoltman, J. B. (ed.), New
Perspectives on Cahokia: Views from the Periphery, Prehistory Press, Madison, WI, pp. 49–64.
Yoffee, N. (1995). Political economy in early Mesopotamian states. Annual Review of Anthropology
24: 281–311.
Zettler, R. (1996). Gordon Childe and the socioeconomic position of craft specialists in early
Mesopotamia. In Wailes, B. (ed.), Craft Specialization and Social Evolution: In Memory of V.
Gordon Childe, University Museum, University of Pennsylvania, Philadelphia, pp. 17–23.

You might also like