You are on page 1of 6

Harvard Law School Forum on Corporate Governance

HOMEABOUTARCHIVECATEGORIESCONTRIBUTORSHIRINGBLOGROLL

Why Ownership Concentration Matters

Posted by Alissa Kole Amico, GOVERN, on Monday, February 24, 2020

Comments Offon Why Ownership Concentration Mattersprint this page Printemail this post E-Mail

Capital markets, Common ownership, Controlling shareholders, Dual-class stock, Index funds,
Institutional Investors, Ownership, Private firms, Public firms, Stakeholders

More from: Alissa Kole, Govern

Alissa Kole Amico is the Managing Director of GOVERN. Related research from the Program on
Corporate Governance includes Index Funds and the Future of Corporate Governance: Theory,
Evidence, and Policy (discussed on the forum here); The Specter of the Giant Three (discussed on the
Forum here), both by Lucian Bebchuk and Scott Hirst; and New Evidence, Proofs, and Legal Theories
on Horizontal Shareholding by Einer Elhauge (discussed on the Forum here).

If the global economy was a chess game, few figures would be left standing at the center of the
board, while others would be relegated to the role of by-standers, observing an increasing
concentration of power in the hands of an ever-dwindling number of global players. Now let us
imagine that the figures left standing are corporate entities, at the helm of which sit a shrinking
number of ultimate owners. This analogy fundamentally characterizes the global economy today,
featuring a growing concentration of corporate ownership.

In the 1990s, we watched in awe the rise of the multinational corporation, an entity which operates
cross-border and is able to rapidly crush local competition in smaller markets. With the advent of the
internet economy a decade later, the power of many of these companies was further amplified by
online distribution which also gave birth of behemoths the likes of Amazon, Google and Airbnb.
These new corporate models have solidified corporate concentration and even monopolization of
specific sectors, prompting recent calls for Facebook to be broken up.

Today, corporate ownership concentration is fostered by a new set of parameters and it may pose a
systemic threat to the global economy. One of the new trends encouraging concentration is the
decline of public equity markets across developed economies, whereby the number of companies
accessing them has halved. In most markets apart from Asia, new firms are not listing, on the
contrary, in light of greater compliance and regulatory obligations, some are de-listing.
This is occurring despite policymakers’ attempts over the past 5 years, to revitalize capital markets
and create incentives for fresh listings, especially of technology and state-owned firms. The recently
aborted WeWork public offering highlights the languishing state of public equity markets. The listing
of Saudi Aramco, confirmed yesterday, has galvanized attention not only due to its size, but also
since IPOs have become sparse.

With the decline of IPOs, wealth is becoming further concentrated in private hands, with the result
that the “too large to fail” companies today are not financial institutions, but in many cases privately
held non-financial firms. Ownership concentration is also a reality for listed firms, where the top 3
shareholders have majority control in 50% of the world’s largest companies, according to recent
OECD estimates. This picture will likely be exacerbated in the coming years.

For example, the Snapchat IPO has highlighted a rift of economic ownership rights between
company founders and ordinary investors, which—for the first time in modern history—were given
non-voting shares. The offering, which generated an investor outcry, is however to some extent
representative of the ownership structures of other large public companies such as Tesla, Uber and
Amazon, where founders control with minority ownership due to multiple class shares.

At the same time, with the decline of the privatization momentum globally, governments also
remain significant and, in many cases, controlling owners of large pockets of corporate wealth
through direct ownership and specific mechanisms such as golden shares. The result of this can be
seen in the Nissan-Renault debacle, which highlights governance perils of state-invested
multinationals.

Some investors such as Norges in Norway, which owns 2% of every European listed company, have a
diversified approach, while others such as the Public Investment Fund in Saudi Arabia, has much
more concentrated stakes, including in domestic state-owned enterprises. Indeed, in almost 10% of
the world’s listed companies, the public sector has a controlling stake. As of late, not only sovereign
investors are becoming concentrated players.

With the ongoing shift of capital from actively to passively managed funds, asset managers’
portfolios are becoming more concentrated as well. A recent study by two Harvard researchers,
Lucian Bebchuk and Scott Hurst, has highlighted that 80% of the capital allocated to investment
funds today is going to Vanguard, Blackrock and State Street. In two decades, they are predicted to
cast as much as 40% of the votes in S&P 500 companies, at the same time as their resources to
behave as effective stewards remain insufficient.
Their growing concentration raises a spectrum of new concerns, not least competition-related, since
asset managers vote on strategic matters in companies which could be competitors. In the airlines
industry for example, the largest 10 institutional investors own 20% of the global market
capitalization. Indeed, concentration-related conflicts of interest faced by institutional investors and
asset managers are already subject to raised eyebrows in policy circles.

This picture is further complicated by the concentration of other financial intermediaries. Stock
exchanges are now longer mutualized or state-owned, most are now organized in a few large, self-
listed exchange groups. As a result, competition for new listings is not occurring between national
stock exchanges but between an oligopoly of exchange groups whose ultimate objective is
increasingly less the rights of shareholders or listed companies, but more of their own shareholders.

Ultimately, these recent trends translate into a dwindling number of large enterprises and financial
intermediaries whose underlying ownership is increasingly concentrated. This is equally true for the
industrial and financial companies, privately and state-owned, resulting in a death of a “dispersed
ownership company”, on which modern economic theory is premised.

While a degree of ownership concentration can create value, it can create macro-level negative
externalities on competition, wealth distribution and fiscal transparency. On the micro-level, it can
have adverse externalities on corporate sustainability and minority shareholder rights. The current
level of economic concentration facilitates neither fair rents to minority shareholders, nor the
respect of consumer rights affected by oligopolies, nor overall citizen welfare affected by aggressive
corporate tax planning.

A novel concoction of economic and corporate governance approaches is needed in the corporate
ownership and financial system configuration facing us. Broadening the purpose of the corporation
and board responsibilities towards stakeholders and focusing on the stewardship responsibilities of
institutional investors and asset managers—both policy remedies currently in vogue among
policymakers—will prove insufficient as they are challenging to monitor and enforce.

Instead, a focus on duties of controlling shareholders towards minorities and specific prerogatives
for minority investors and directors representing them are needed. At the same time, stronger
checks and balances, and maybe even Chinese walls already in place in the proxy advisory industry,
need to be introduced for large asset managers. These are other remedies to address concentration
are needed not only in the name of better corporate governance, but ultimately to address a wave
of unprecedented protests in New York, Paris, Beirut, and Santiago against unjust systems of wealth
distribution.
Capital markets, Common ownership, Controlling shareholders, Dual-class stock, Index funds,
Institutional Investors, Ownership, Private firms, Public firms, Stakeholders

More from: Alissa Kole, Govern

Both comments and trackbacks are currently closed.

Subscribe or Follow

Supported By:

Program on Corporate Governance Advisory Board

William Ackman

Peter Atkins

David Bell

Kerry E. Berchem

Richard Brand

Daniel Burch

Paul Choi

Jesse Cohn

Creighton Condon

Arthur B. Crozier

Michael Delikat

John Finley

Bruce H. Goldfarb

Joseph Hall

Jason M. Halper

Paul Hilal

Carl Icahn

Jack B. Jacobs

David Millstone

Theodore Mirvis

Maria Moats
Erika Moore

Carey Oven

Morton Pierce

Philip Richter

Paul K. Rowe

Marc Trevino

Steven J. Williams

Daniel Wolf

HLS Faculty & Senior Fellows

Lucian Bebchuk

Robert Clark

John Coates

Alma Cohen

Stephen M. Davis

Allen Ferrell

Jesse Fried

Oliver Hart

Howell Jackson

Kobi Kastiel

Reinier Kraakman

Mark Ramseyer

Mark Roe

Robert Sitkoff

Holger Spamann

Leo E. Strine, Jr.

Guhan Subramanian

Harvard Law School Forum on Corporate Governance


All copyright and trademarks in content on this site are owned by their respective owners. Other
content © 2022 The President and Fellows of Harvard College.

You might also like