You are on page 1of 163

INFORMATION TO USERS

This manuscript has been reproduced from the microfilm m aster. UMI films
the text directly from the original or copy submitted. Thus, som e thesis and
dissertation copies are in typewriter face, while others may be from any type of
com puter printer.

The quality of th is reproduction is dependent upon th e quality of th e


co p y subm itted. Broken or indistinct print, colored or poor quality illustrations
and photographs, print bleedthrough, substandard margins, and improper
alignment can adversely affect reproduction.

In the unlikely event that the author did not send UMI a complete manuscript
and there are missing pages, these will be noted. Also, if unauthorized
copyright material had to be removed, a note will indicate the deletion.

Oversize materials (e.g., maps, drawings, charts) are reproduced by


sectioning the original, beginning at the upper left-hand com er and continuing
from left to right in equal sections with small overlaps.

Photographs included in the original manuscript have been reproduced


xerographically in this copy. Higher quality 6” x 9” black and white
photographic prints are available for any photographs or illustrations appearing
in this copy for an additional charge. Contact UMI directly to order.

Bell & Howell Information and Learning


300 North Zeeb Road, Ann Arbor, Ml 48106-1346 USA
800-521-0600

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
INFORMAL CARE AND ELDERLY HEALTH CARE USE

Courtney Harold Van Houtven, M.Sc.

A dissertation submitted to the faculty of the University of North Carolina at Chapel


Hill in partial fulfillment o f the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy
in the Department of Health Policy and Administration.
School of Public Health.

Chapel Hill
2000

Approved by:

SLnJc.ruti
Edward C. Norton. Ph.D. (Advisor)

Shulamit L. Bernard. Ph.D.

William H. Dow. Ph.D

2
( -
Steven A. Garfinkel. Irn.D

‘Va.%
R. Gary Rafter. Dt

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
UMI Number 9993391

Copyright 2000 by
Van Houtven, Courtney Harold

All rights reserved.

___ <g>

UMI
UMI Microform 9993391
Copyright 2001 by Bell & Howell Information and Learning Company.
All rights reserved. This microform edition is protected against
unauthorized copying under Title 17, United States Code.

Bell & Howell Information and Learning Company


300 North Zeeb Road
P.O. Box 1346
Ann Arbor, Ml 48106-1346

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
©2000
Courtney Harold Van Houtven
ALL RIGHTS RESERVED

ii

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
ABSTRACT
COURTNEY HAROLD VAN HOUTVEN: Informal Care And Elderly Health Care Use
(Under the direction of Edward C. Norton, Ph.D.)

Background: Informal care of the elderly by their adult children is a common form

of long-term care, is often preferred by the elderly to formal care, and can reduce medical

expenditures if it substitutes for formal care. Much work has been done to characterize

informal caregivers. However, there is a dearth of research quantifying informal care’s effect

on subsequent formal care use, beyond knowing that informal care can both replace and

supplement formal care. Objective: This study helps to assess the merit of proposals to

support informal caregivers, such as through tax breaks or respite care programs. I use two

waves of the Asset and Health Dynamics Among the Oldest-Old survey to answer the

following question: Does informal care of elderly parents by their children reduce formal

care use? I examine home health care, nursing home care, hospital care, outpatient surgery,

and doctor’s visits. Methods: I use two-part models to predict the immediate and medium-

term effects of informal care on formal care use of the single elderly. Because informal care

can both precede and follow formal care, I use two-step instrumental variables estimation and

lagged informal care to control for endogeneity. Results: Elderly who received informal

care were 72 percent less likely to use home health care and 89 percent less likely to use

nursing home care in the next three years than those who did not. Doctor’s visits fell slightly

in the short-term for informal care recipients (2 percent), while the risk of outpatient surgery

fell dramatically (by 43 percent) two years later. Caregiving did not significantly affect

hospital use. Specification tests show that simultaneity exists between informal and formal

iii

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
care. Conclusions: Controlling for endogeneity is essential to correctly inform the policy

process that informal care drastically reduces home health care and nursing home use. If

informal care is the type of care that elderly prefer, tax breaks, as well as caregiver training,

respite care, and increased workplace flexibility could all be considered as policies to help the

supply of informal care meet burgeoning demand. Such policies may be more cost-effective

than funneling money into Medicare or Medicaid directly.

iv

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
To my parents:

Timothy Joseph Harold and Judith Ellen Baker Harold

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
ACKNOWLEDGMENTS

I would like to acknowledge the great mentoring and support of my advisor, Edward

Norton. I also benefited from methodological, substantive and practical advice from other

committee members, including Will Dow and Gary Rozier from the Department of Health

Policy and Administration, UNC, and Shula Bernard and Steve Garfinkel from Research

Triangle Institute. Sally Stearns also provided inspiration and mentoring at UNC.

I am grateful to the University of North Carolina Medical School for a Women’s

Health Grant, and the National Institute on Aging, the National Institute of Health for a small

grant (R-03AG16558).

Glen Mays, Jeremy Bray, Mark Holmes and David Guilkey provided myriad

advice on discrete factor analysis and Fortran programming which was helpful. Cheers to the

firm o f Harold, Leahy, and Kieran for providing ample writing space, bad coffee and fine

company. To my fellow graduate students, Sarah Boyce, Jeremy Firestone, Kristin

Komives, Virender Kumar, and Jan Ostermann: What a lonely road it would have been.

While not lofty, it was child care help and devotion from Carla Menius (not to

mention Trisha, Cindy, Frances, Keisha, Michelle, Brian, Sommer, Stuart, Raven, Jenny, and

Lanna) that allowed me to complete this dissertation, as well as the friendship of Jennifer

Gerton, Richard Shrock, Paula Paradis, and Dan Reuland. I cherish the love and support

of the Harold and Van Houtven families, especially Gran, who spoils me still. To George

Louis, Dominic Harold, and Charlotte Elizabeth Van Houtven, you are my everything.

vi

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
TABLE OF CONTENTS

Page

LIST OF TABLES ..................................................................................................xi

Chapter

1. OVERVIEW.......................................................................................................... 1

Introduction........................................................................................................1

What is informal care?..................................................................................... 5

What drives demand for informal care?..........................................................7

What drives supply o f informal care to the elderly?...................................... 11

How does receipt o f informal care affect elderly formal care use?............... 17

Informal care’s effect on formal care...................................................17

Formal care’s effect on subsequent formal care.................................19

How does informal care affect the net cost of formal care?.......................... 22

2. CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK OF INFORMAL AND


FORMAL CARE.................................................................................................. 25

Overview of chapter......................................................................................... 25

Review o f the Grossman model.......................................................................26

Elderly formal care model: the parent’s formal care decision....................... 28

Child informal care model: the informal care decision..................................36

Joint determination o f informal care and utilization.......................................40

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Hypotheses 42

3. METHODS........................................................................................................... 43

Overview of chapter......................................................................................... 43

Two-part models of utilization....................................................................... 44

Endogeneity o f informal care.......................................................................... 48

Correcting for the endogeneity of informal care.............................................52

Not at all: Pseudo-maximum likelihood and generalized


estimating equations (GEE).................................................... 53

Partially: lagged informal care........................................................... 53

Fully: two-stage instrumental variables..............................................54

Obtaining correct standard errors............................................56

Experimentally: full-information maximum likelihood (FIML) 56


\
Overview of discrete factor methods..................................... 57

Specification Tests........................................................................................... 60

Overidentification tests........................................................................61

Endogeneity of informal care.............................................................. 62

Strength of the instruments................................................................. 65

Indirect test of instruments to detect measurement error................... 66

Summary of specification tests........................................................... 68

Performance of discrete factor estimation...................................................... 68

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
4. DATA AND SAMPLE SELECTION.................................................................72

Overview of chapter..........................................................................................72

The Asset and Health Dynamics Among the Oldest Old Survey.................. 72

Sample selection criteria.................................................................................. 74

Description of the dependent variables: Wave 1 and Wave 2 ....................... 78

Description of informal care and other child-level characteristics: Wave 1..83

Description of key parent-level explanatory variables: Wave 1.................... 88

5. RESULTS: EFFECTS OF INFORMAL CARE ON FORMAL HEALTH


CARE UTILIZATION OF THE ELD ERLY .................................................. 94

Overview of chapter........................................................................................ 94

How does informal care affect formal care use of the elderly?....................95

In-depth look at informal care’s effect on home health care........................97

Immediate effect.................................................................................97

Effect two years later..........................................................................101

Simulated risks of home health care..................................................103

In-depth look at informal care’s effect on nursing home u se .......................106

Immediate effect.................................................................................108

Effect two years later......................................................................... 112

Simulated risks o f nursing home care................................................113

Informal care’s effect on other types of formal care..................................... 114

Immediate effects o f informal care on doctor’s visits..................... 114

Effects o f informal care on outpatient surgery two years later 116

ix

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Sensitivity tests of the main results..................................................................117

Sample selection criteria......................................................................117

Home health care definition.................................................................118

Potential endogeneity bias from controlling


for current health status........................................................................120

What determines a child’s provision o f informal care to a parent?............... 121

Child attributes.....................................................................................122

Parent attributes............................................................................................... 127

Discussion............................................................................................ 129

Extensions.........................................................................................................131

Extensions of informal care’s effect on formal care...........................131

Extensions of the prediction o f informal care..................................... 132

6. CONCLUSION AND POLICY IMPLICATIONS........................................... 133

Conclusion........................................................................................................133

Policy conclusions: hypotheses one and tw o...................................... 133

Methodological conclusions: hypothesis three................................... 136

Policy implications.......................................................................................... 137

7. REFERENCES......................................................................................................142

Reproduced with permission o f the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
LIST OF TABLES

Table 1. Tests of exogeneity of informal care and the exclusion restrictions,


Waves 1 and 2, AHEAD.................................................................................... 63

Table 2. Sample Selection Criteria................................................................................... 76

Table 3. Selection o f Wave 1 Sample of the Single Elderly............................................ 76

Table 4. Selection o f Wave 2 Sample of the Single Elderly............................................ 77

Table 5. Formal care patterns of the single elderly in Wave 1 of AHEAD


compared to Wave 2........................................................................................... 80

Table 6. Factors driving supply of informal caregiving by adult children.......................86

Table 7. Factors driving single elderly parent’s demand for informal


caregiving, Wave 1 (A/=2,985)........................................................................... 89

Table 8. Effect o f informal care on utilization patterns o f the single elderly,


by analysis type, Wave 1 and Wave 2................................................................96

Table 9. The effect o f informal care on home health care use......................................... 98

Table 10. Simulated risks of home health care use and nursing home use given
different levels o f informal care, Wave 1 and Wave 2....................................105

Table 11. Simulated risks of having any home health care use in Wave 1.................... 107

Table 12. The effect o f informal care on nursing home use........................................... 109

Table 13. Simulated risks of having any nursing home use in Wave 1..........................115

Table 14. Survey regression of informal care (total ADL’s and LADL’s
helped with) on child and parent characteristics. Wave 1...............................123

xi

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
CHAPTER ONE: OVERVIEW

Introduction

This dissertation examines how informal care of the single elderly by offspring affects

health care utilization of the elderly. Informal care of the elderly by offspring is extremely

common, serves as an important substitute to formal care, and is usually preferred by the

elderly both to formal care and to institutionalization. Elderly who receive care from their

children are more often female than male, and based on projected life expectancies for the

year 2010, 74.1 for males versus 80.6 for females, will continue to be so (U.S. Bureau o f the

Census, 1997). Informal care is typically provided by daughters, who increasingly face

competing demands for their time between caring for elderly parents, working, and child

rearing. These factors make this an important issue in women’s health, because the focus is

largely on women. In addition, demand for informal care in the next three decades will

experience unprecedented growth as baby boomers approach retirement age (the last of the

baby boomers turn 65 in 2030, at which time the number of people in the U.S. over the age of

65 will be double what it is today).

Informal care is also critically important for health and labor policy. Health policies

designed to control costs affect reliance on informal care. For example, restricting Medicaid

eligibility for nursing home care would increase the demand for informal care. Recent

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Medicare expansion o f home health benefits and the trend to Medicare managed care, which

might restrict hospital stays and return the parent home sooner, also affect the demand for

informal care. A more radical policy would allow Medicare and Medicaid to pay lump sum

transfers to family caregivers (Pezzin and Schone, 1997). On a pilot-project level, two states

have offered benefits to informal caregivers in the form of direct payments to family

members and other informal caregivers who provide personal assistance (Pezzin and Schone,

1999a). Finally, the insurer—either the government through Medicare or private insurance

companies—may find that paying informal caregivers is more cost-effective than paying for

home health care providers if they can give informal caregivers a lower rate (Ettner. 1994).

Such a radical insurer-initiated change would certainly affect the supply of informal care.

Even a more minor subsidy provision to informal caregivers, say in the form o f tax

credits or tax exemptions, might affect the provision of care and ultimately utilization

(Fisher, 1998). In fact, marking the first time that caregiving has been a part of the

presidential campaign, both Governor George W. Bush and Vice-president Al Gore proposed

specific compensation plans for caregivers in the form of tax changes. With some variation

in who qualifies, both changes are worth about $3,000 for family caregivers (Gore, 2000;

Bush, 2000). In addition, Al Gore proposed a National Caregiver Initiative to support

informal caregivers through respite care, support services, and information on formal services

(Gore, 2000). Tax breaks would increase the supply of informal care at the margin, even

though most caregivers would maintain they are not motivated by money. Meanwhile, a

national program to support caregivers would increase the supply of informal caregivers if it

helps prevent bumout but it may also replace some informal care because it will increase the

use of respite care.

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
In fact, President Clinton signed into law a program very similar to Gore’s National

Caregiver Initiative on November 13,2000. As a part of the “Older Americans Act

Amendments of 2000” (H.R. 782), this law establishes the National Family Caregiver

Support Program. Currently funded at SI25 million (Goodling, 2000), the support provided

includes “critical information, training, and counseling, as well as much needed quality

respite care for those caregivers who are juggling jobs and other family responsibilities while

meeting the special needs of loved ones in their care.” (Clinton, 2000). This program may

have complicated effects on caregiver supply and demand and will be important to follow as

state and federal policies become increasingly aware that informal caregiving may not be

keeping pace with demand.

Labor policy and labor market dynamics may affect the supply of informal care. For

example, proposed amendments to the Family and Medical Leave Act of 1993, which would

ailow sick leave benefits to be used to care for parents, would increase the supply of informal

care. In contrast, extending employer-provided insurance to allow coverage of elderly

dependents (say through Medigap coverage) would reduce informal care if children decide to

stay on the job to receive the insurance benefits rather than care for parents themselves. In

addition, recent welfare reform legislation, which requires welfare recipients to work after

receiving a set period of benefits, may reduce the provision o f informal care in vulnerable

populations o f the elderly. Prior to this legislation, it was common for AFDC recipients to

care for elderly parents and their own children rather than joining the labor force (Puntenny,

1998). While these elderly parents may be eligible for Medicaid if their children do not care

for them, assuming they have similar socio-economic status to their child, potential tradeoffs

from one public program to another may be occurring. Finally, increased workplace

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
flexibility due to telecommuting and an increased use of home offices may increase employed

children’s ability to provide some care for elderly parents.

Informal care by children is important because it ultimately affects the health status of

the elderly and elderly women in particular, their ability to live independently, and public

expenditures on health care. I address the following research questions:

♦ Does informal care of elderly parents by adult children delay entry into

nursing homes, reduce home health care use, or reduce other health care

utilization of the elderly?

♦ Is informal care endogenous in determining health care utilization of the

elderly?

I apply state-of-the-art statistical techniques and analyze data uniquely suited to address these

questions of elderly persons' health. I use a conceptual framework of utilization and informal

care based on Grossman (1972) and Nocera and Zweifel (1996). The endogeneity of

informal care in predicting health care utilization requires simultaneous equations methods. I

control for endogeneity using a conventional two-step instrumental variables (IV) approach,

using lagged informal care, and I also explore a full-information maximum likelihood

technique called discrete factor analysis. The data are the 1993 and 1995 waves of the Asset

and Health Dynamics Among the Oldest-Old (AHEAD) panel survey, which have detailed

information on informal care and elderly health care utilization.

These research questions have not been addressed to date, providing a unique

opportunity for this dissertation research to uncover how informal care determines elderly

health care utilization, in particular elderly women’s health care utilization.

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
What is informal care?

There are many definitions of informal care in the literature. I view informal care

generally as any care that occurs in a non-market setting, meaning the caregiver is not paid to

provide care. Examples o f informal care include a neighbor assisting with a person’s

shopping, a wife administering medicine to her husband, or a daughter helping her mother

from bed to the bathroom every day. Informal care often occurs in the caregiver or care

receiver’s home. Whether a person who needs care lives independently is dependent on

many factors, but primarily depends on whether a spouse is present, on financial resources

and on health status. Further, informal care can occur on a short or long term basis.

Formal care, by contrast, is care that occurs in the market place, such as nursing home

care, home health care, inpatient hospital care, or ambulatory care. Formal care is paid care,

regardless of whether the care is paid for by private or public insurance, individuals, or is

classified as uncompensated care that is either absorbed by the formal care provider as bad

debt, or cost-shifted to other payers. Throughout this study I use the term “health care

utilization of the elderly” and the term “formal care” synonymously. In other studies formal

care has meant home health care only, but I do not limit the definition to a particular type of

market-provided health care.

Whether informal care is a substitute for formal care or a complement to formal care

is an important notion for this study. Litwak (1985) and Allen (2000) argue for a

complementary relationship between informal and formal care. Pezzin and Schone (1999a)

and Lakdawalla and Philipson (1999) argue that it is a substitute for formal care. Weissert et

al. (1988) support this by finding that informal care tends to decline with the use of formal

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
care. It is plausible that informal care is both a substitute and a complement to formal care,

depending on the particular situation. For example, Ettner (1994) showed that most home

health care users also receive care from family members but that when cost of formal care is

alleviated, formal care is preferred to informal care. In a later article, Ettner pointed out that

the degree to which informal caregivers can substitute formal care for their own care is still

an unresolved empirical question (Ettner 1995 citing Christianson 1988 and Ettner 1994).

This study helps resolve this question.

Informal care is not limited to the frail elderly, as chronically mentally-ill persons and

persons with developmental disabilities have traditionally received informal care.

Furthermore, there is an increased willingness in the medical community to have family

members care for persons with special medical needs. A recent New York Times article

pointed out that parents are increasingly caring for children with special medical attention at

home. Whether this is due to managed care’s influence on cutting inpatient stays or families

demanding to have an ailing child at home rather than in a hospital is a point of debate.

However, the trend towards more informal care is real for persons of all ages in the United

States. According to the New York Times, “Families are performing an unprecedented

amount of technical medical care in their homes, much of which would once have been

provided by doctors or nurses alone.” (Fisher, 1998). Many of these family members are

untrained and unprepared to provide care on top of the comfort that they have traditionally

provided (Fisher, 1998). So it is important to note that family-provided informal care is not

necessarily limited to unskilled care such as assistance with physical functioning tasks.

In this study I focus on informal care of the elderly. Most of these elderly are women

due to differences in mortality rates, but I will look at both male and female elderly. For the

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
elderly, informal care is one of the main forms of long-term care. Quantifying the extent of

informal caregiving for the elderly is extremely difficult because it is not reimbursed in a

market (Norton, 2000). Norton estimates that, while difficult to quantify, about two-thirds of

care for the elderly is informal care. I focus specifically on care provided by offspring, as

informal care by offspring may have unique effects on outcomes compared to care provided

by a spouse, a neighbor, or a friend. In addition, State informal care programs (17 in U.S.

according to the Family Caregiving Alliance, 2000) and informal care policy proposals (Gore,

2000; Bush, 2000) benefit family caregivers, who, in the absence of a spouse, are most

commonly offspring.

What drives demand for informal care?

The primary pre-condition for informal care demand, like formal care demand, is a

parent’s mental or physical health status; whether it is from a long term disability like

Alzheimer's Disease, or a short-term health shock such as the flu or a broken hip. Aside from

measures of self-rated health status, where a person ranks her health as excellent, good, fair

or poor, there are more objective measures of functional status, Instrumental Activities of

Daily Living (IADL’s) and Activities of Daily Living (ADL’s). IADL’s include help with

cognitive or housekeeping tasks such as grocery shopping, preparation of meals, phoning,

administering medicine, or managing money, while ADL’s measure physical independence.

The six ADL’s most commonly measured are needing help with toileting, transferring to and

from bed, walking, dressing, bathing, or eating. Pezzin and Schone (1999b) found that the

number of IADL’s an elderly parent has drives demand for children as caregivers, while the

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
number of ADL’s drives demand for home health care providers as caregivers. In addition,

cognitive impairment drives informal care demand.

Given impaired functional status, for a parent to demand care from a child it is likely

that a spouse is not available to provide care. If a spouse is healthy and living, he or she is

more likely to provide care than a child (Stone and Kemper, 1990; Lakdawalla and Philipson.

1999; Dwyer and Coward, 1991; Pezzin, Kemper and Reschovsky, 1996). Lakdawalla and

Philipson find that the presence of a spouse reduces the probability of nursing home entry by

more than half, and this result holds for all but the severely mentally-ill and those parents

who have children who live less than an hour away (Lakdawalla and Philipson, 1999). This

means that the presence of a spouse as caregiver can delay entry into a nursing home.

Further, living with a spouse, living independently or co-residing with a child can all

affect demand for informal care. B6rsch-Supan (1989) found that sharing accommodation

with adult children will “not only provide housing but some degree of medical care and social

support for the elderly." Living in a rural area also increases the reliance on informal care

because a formal service network is less available (Coward and Cutler. 1989).

Clearly, a parent’s income and wealth may be an important determinant of informal

care demand. The wealthier elderly may prefer to purchase formal care instead of relying on

children. Or, income may be spent to avoid institutionalization by making transfer payments

to children so that the children are more willing to take in their parents (Borsch-Supan et al..

1992b). This can be true despite researchers finding that there is little direct compensation

for children providing informal care, as other financial transfers such as a parent’s deed to the

house or other gifts can be indirect payments for informal care (McGarry and Schoeni, 1995).

Past research has found that lower income people demand much more informal care from

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
family members than formal care. Contradicting this is a finding by Kotlikoff and Morris

(1989) that contact between children and the economically vulnerable elderly appears to be

less than the non-vulnerable elderly. But this could be due to supply-side constraints rather

than demand-side ones. For example, in a study of Medicaid home care subsidies, Ettner

(1994) finds that formal care is used in lieu of informal care by the frail elderly. When cost is

not a consideration, formal care may be preferred.

In addition, resource control was shown by Pezzin and Schone to have a significant

effect on informal care (1997). Resource control means whether or not a parent manages and

makes decisions about spending her own money rather than a child making financial

decisions for her. Switching resource control from a parent to a child decreased the

likelihood o f a child working full-time and of providing informal care (as well as the number

of hours of care provided).

Insurance may also affect tradeoffs between informal and formal care. The presence

of insurance encourages formal care use rather than informal care use, because it reduces the

effective price of formal care. Medical insurance is not a major factor in determining demand

for some types of acute care of the elderly since nearly all elderly over 65 receive Medicare

Part A. However, co-insurance rates, transportation problems, and lack of Medicare

providers may still hinder Medicare recipient access for low-income individuals, rural

individuals, and individuals in under-served regions. This may in turn increase informal care

demand.

Further, Medigap policies, which are optional for the elderly, may influence types of

care not covered by Medicare Part A. And for long-term care. Medicare strictly limits the

number of days o f nursing home care that it will cover, meaning that long-term care

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
insurance or Medicaid, which covers nursing home care comprehensively, become important

when examining tradeoffs between informal care and nursing home utilization. On the other

hand, few elderly purchase long-term care insurance, so its effect on health care utilization

may not be significant in the aggregate. Further, both Medicare and Medigap insurance are

important to consider when examining demand for informal care versus home health care.

While all o f these factors and health status in particular are shown to determine

demand for informal care, it is clear that they also affect demand for formal care. This means

that formal care can be an important factor determining informal care as well. If a parent has

an acute episode which requires surgery or rehabilitation using a skilled nursing facility, it is

likely that such care will be immediately followed by informal care by children, until the

parent is able to function independently again. This close relationship between formal and

informal care, and the potential for two-way causation between the two types of care, must be

incorporated into any model estimating the effect of informal care on formal care.

In fact, Pezzin and Schone (1999a), in a technical study of informal care and

utilization find that use of formal care is the most important predictor of subsequent informal

care. They jointly estimate household membership, labor force participation of the child,

informal care and financial transfers. Theirs is the only study in the literature to consider the

joint determination of formal care and informal care, and they control for this by using

predicted prior formal care in their estimation of informal care and other outcomes. They

find that, in particular, formal care use appears to be an important substitute to informal care

both for those who live independently from each other, and for parents and daughters who co-

reside. In some policy simulations, if all parents received formal care, 35 percent o f parents

would receive informal care from a daughter, whereas they originally predict that 66 percent

10

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
would receive informal care. Such a policy would also cause about a 60 percent reduction in

the number of children co-residing with a parent. This study is limited by two main factors.

First, they are only able to consider one daughter o f the parent, hence limit the caregiving

network by number and gender. Second, they do not have a nationally representative sample

of the elderly, but a random sample of the elderly from Massachusetts. The advantage is that

the methods incorporate the simultaneity of informal and formal care, and that the daughters

of the elderly parents are interviewed directly, limiting measurement error caused by parent

reporting.

In an earlier study, Christianson (1988) studies the changes in informal caregiving

from a home health care program (the channeling experiment). He concluded that “formal

community-based care" led to some withdrawal from informal care, but that the total

consumption of care went up. This also lends credence to formal and informal care having a

substitute relationship, and shows that the demand for formal care can also affect demand for

informal care.

What drives supply of informal care to the elderly?

If care is not available from a healthy spouse, children will typically provide informal

care, followed by other relatives, friends, and neighbors (Stone and Short, 1990). Among

children, research shows that female offspring provide more care than male offspring (Stone

and Short, 1990; Stone and Kemper, 1990; Borsch-Supan et al., 1992a; Kotlikoff and Morris,

1989; Stone, Cafferata, and Sangl, 1987). A study by Stone, Cafferata, and Sangl (1987)

11

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
found that more than three-quarters of children caregivers are daughters, due in part to the

lower average opportunity cost of time in the labor force.

However, even women who work full time are over four times more likely to be

primary caregivers compared to men (Stone and Kemper, 1990). Again, this may be

explained by differences in opportunity costs if these women earn less than men do, but may

also be because some elderly parents prefer receiving care from their daughters.

Alternatively, it may be because daughters are more willing to sacrifice leisure time for

caregiving than are sons. Cultural perceptions of gender roles may certainly influence the

reliance on daughters.

Working constrains the amount of care that offspring can provide. In fact, a

substantial number of women in the labor force quit working when a parent becomes ill. Past

research has found that about 11 percent of daughters and 5 percent of sons who provide

informal care quit a job in order to provide that care (Stone et al., 1987). Regardless of

gender, researchers have found that the higher one’s income, the less likely caregivers are to

quit working (Muurinen, 1986). This finding is consistent with wages or income being good

measures of opportunity costs o f peoples' time. In addition, a 1990 article by Stone and Short

estimated that 29 percent o f caregivers either quit working or accommodated their schedule

to provide care (“work accommodation" was defined as working reduced hours, rearranging

work schedules or taking unpaid leave). By contrast, Wolf and Soldo find a negative but

statistically insignificant effect of caregiving on work hours (1997).

While work certainly can affect the supply of informal care, causality between

caregiving and work decisions is not always easy to discern. While caregiving causes some

people to quit work, in other cases work causes others not to provide care and to provide

12

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
financial assistance instead. Few researchers have considered this in their empirical work.

The exception comes from three studies that consider the simultaneity of informal care and

employment decisions. Ettner (1995) and Wolf and Soldo (1997) examine the effect of

caregiving on the caregiver’s labor supply decisions where caregiving is an endogenous

variable, while Stem (1995) considers the effect of employment (among other things) on the

informal care decision, treating employment as endogenous. The simultaneity between

informal care and work make it difficult to include work behavior in models of informal care

unless good instruments are available.

In addition to work, competing responsibilities for child rearing also complicate the

informal care decision (Soldo and Myllyluoma, 1983). With women delaying their

childbearing age in the United States, many may be caring simultaneously for their own

children and an ailing parent (the so-called sandwich generation). Some researchers,

however, find that there are currently a relatively small number of women with dual care

responsibilities (Stone and Kemper, 1990, Rosenthal et al., 1996, Soldo, 1996). In fact, two-

thirds of daughters o f elderly parents are either middle-aged or elderly themselves, and hence

are grandparents rather than parents of minors (Stone and Kemper, 1990). So it may be more

accurate that adult children make tradeoffs between elderly parent care and grandchild care.

Nevertheless, delayed child bearing and changing demographics in the next three decades

indicate that the sandwich generation will grow, which will cause a greater need to make

tradeoffs between caring for elderly parents and one’s own children or elderly parents and

grandchildren.

Typically tradeoffs between work and caregiving or child-rearing and caregiving are

the competing demands studied, as I already highlighted. Of course, informal care also

13

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
causes a loss of leisure time, so another factor driving the supply of informal care is the

relative value an adult child places on leisure time. For example, even non-working

caregivers age 65 and above complained of problems of “competing demands” in a study by

Soldo and Mllyluoma (1983). Cantor showed that the most severe effect o f informal care

was loss of “free time for oneself and opportunities to socialize with friends, take vacations,

have leisure time pursuits, and run one’s own house,” not a loss of employment which is

typically considered (1983). These studies both speak to caregiver burnout, meaning that the

length of time a child has been providing informal care may reduce the supply of future

informal care.

Because children of the oldest-old are often old themselves, the adult child’s health

status may affect the supply of informal care (Wolinsky, 1986). However, Sloan and

colleagues (1997) and Boaz (1996) found a child’s health status to have an insignificant

effect on the amount of informal care provided. Even in perfect physical health, informal

care can cause emotional or mental stress to the caregiver (Cantor, 1983; Stone and Short,

1990). So even if child’s health and child stress indicators were available, reverse causation

may prohibit their use.

Related to this, in a study o f many kinds of caregivers, children caregivers were

mainly worried about obtaining sufficient help for their parent, and complained of emotional

strain (Cantor, 1983). Hence, the availability of other caregivers may be an important

indicator of whether or not a child will provide informal care. It also may determine the

amount of informal care provided. The number of siblings, and female siblings in particular,

may be an important determinant o f time spent in informal care activities. One study found

that having sisters, holding constant the care efforts of siblings reduces a child’s supply of

14

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
parent-care hours (Wolf et al., 1997). Another study found that the number of caregivers is

inversely related to depression of the caregiver, so children who have other caregivers to

provide relief may be more willing to provide care (Pillemer and Suitor, 1996).

Related to stress is the severity of a parent’s health care needs. If the parent needs

highly specialized care, children may not supply care because they are not qualified to do so.

This is discussed in more detail in the conceptual model (Chapter 2). Interestingly, in a study

of the elderly with senile dementia, it was the availability of social supports, not the

behavioral problems caused by dementia and the ability to manage them that contributed to

the extent of burden felt by primary caregivers (Zarit, 1980).

It is clear that children are motivated to provide care for their parents for many non-

financial reasons. However, they also may be motivated by financial factors besides those

surrounding the work decision already discussed. The income of the child or the parent may

affect the supply of informal care. Several researchers have studied whether children are

motivated to provide care by expected inheritances (Pauly, 1990; Borsch-Supan et al., 1992a;

Sloan et al., 1996; Sloan et al., 1997; Cox and Rank, 1992; McGany and Schoeni. 1995).

Most found other factors to be much more important than bequests in determining the

provision of care. In particular, Sloan and colleagues tested an informal care model of

altruism versus a model o f strategic bequests (1997). In their work the model of strategic

behavior hypothesizes that children of wealthier parents will supply more informal care than

children of the non-wealthy in order to protect their inheritance. They find little evidence of

strategic bequest behavior, but find that a parent’s number of ADL’s and agitation level (as

measured by a binary variable “parent yells when upset”), as well as a child’s wage, a child’s

gender, and a child’s marital status are all significant predictors of informal care (ibid, 1997).

15

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
In tests of altruism versus exchange, the results are mixed. Here it is the parents

behavior that determines altruism versus exchange. An altruistic parent will give those

children money who are less well off, regardless of care behavior. The exchange model

posits that the parent will give more money to those children who care for them, regardless of

how well off they are relative to other children. While Cox and Rank (1992) found that

children who provide informal care receive more financial transfers than their siblings

regardless of income level, McGarry and Schoeni found that financial transfers are directed to

less well-off siblings, and are not provided in exchange for caregiving (1995). Regardless of

the motivation, it appears that there is some evidence that the income of the child or her

parent can influence the decision about informal caregiving or the amount of informal

caregiving.

Related to income but exhibiting a separate effect on the supply of caregiving is the

child’s education level, which may be a proxy for knowledge o f services available to the

parent (Bass and Noelker, 1987). If a child is highly educated, she may be better at finding

formal care services for a parent and use these as a substitute for her own care.

Geographical proximity to a parent can increase the supply of informal care. For

example, children living more than an hour away from their parents had a lower probability

of providing significant help (Lakdawalla and Philipson, 1999). Stem also finds that distance

to a parent reduces informal care supply, but concludes that distance is endogenous to

predicting informal care, and ultimately does not recommend including it as a control without

instrumentation (1995).

16

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Finally, race may be an important determinant of informal care supply. Hanson and

colleagues (1983) find that whites and blacks view their responsibility for caring for their

parents differendy, however, this finding could be due to urban and rural differences as well.

How does receipt of informal care affect elderly formal care use?

Despite the myriad factors shown to affect informal care demand and supply, there is

a dearth of information linking informal care to outcomes such as utilization or expenditures.

The lack of information is due to a lack of data, but fortunately the arrival of AHEAD makes

research on these questions possible.

I expect that informal care and formal care are similar in how they influence

subsequent formal care use. I also expect that formal care will differ between home health

care, nursing home care, inpatient care, and other types of care. In this section I review the

few studies of informal care and utilization, then briefly discuss, in the absence of informal

care's effect on utilization, how other researchers have found home health care and other

formal care to affect subsequent formal care use.

Informal care 5 effect on form al care.

Health care utilization research on older adults shows that as persons age. physician

and hospital contacts increase, with a particular inverse J-curve shape (Wolinsky et al.. 1987),

This means that care increases until a person reaches about age 80, and then tapers off. We

know that this is the pattern for formal care, but we do not know how informal care affects

this pattern specifically. A preferred explanation of this pattern by Wolinsky and colleagues

17

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
is that a substitution from family to physician services occurs as a person approaches age 80,

due to a reduction in the supply of informal care over time. After age 80, as a cohort hospital

use and physician visits may taper off due to mortality (Wolinsky et al., 1987).

This same study also finds that living with others delays utilization as people age.

Clearly, living with someone may be closely associated with informal caregiving, but this

study does not directly consider the effect of informal care on utilization, nor does it establish

causality between living with someone and utilization. The authors themselves point out that

their explanation is based on anecdotal reports, and needs further research (Wolinsky et al..

1987).

The Wolinsky article illustrates that elderly may substitute more costly hospital

services for ambulatory-based services, as the number of social supports fall. So lack of

informal caregiving may cause a substitution effect between one type of formal care and

another. In addition, Soldo found that only ten percent of the functionally disabled elderly

with an informal support network used formal services, compared to 80 percent without an

informal network (Soldo, 1985). However, Soldo’s study also does not establish a causal

relationship between informal care and utilization. Nevertheless, both of these findings

suggest that a close relationship exists between formal health care use and informal care.

In a review of studies assessing institutional care for the elderly, Wingard and

colleagues report that the “evidence predominantly supported the belief that availability of

caregivers is associated with a lower risk of nursing home admissions" (1987). However,

most of the studies they examine are univariate analyses. In addition, Garber (1989) finds

that “living arrangements and family supports appear to have large impacts on long-term care

utilization.” In particular, disabled individuals who live with a spouse or other family

18

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
member consume fewer formal services and are much less likely to enter a nursing home. He

uses a Tobit model and multi-variate analysis, but measures living status rather than informal

care provision specifically, leaving room for improvement.

The next study of informal care is one of the few multivariate analyses in elderly

health care utilization and informal care. Bass and Noelker (1987) tested whether

characteristics of the primary and secondary family caregivers influenced the elderly’s use of

in-home nursing and aide services. This study aimed to better incorporate informal supports

into the Andersen model o f health care utilization (Bass and Noelker, 1987). On average,

this study found that people who received informal care used nearly seven hours of formal

care per week. This is an excellent conceptual article on the enabling and need factors

associated with informal care, and their effects on health care utilization of elderly.

However, several criticisms of this study remain. There is no control group to compare the

results to, the sample was not nationally representative, the authors do not control for the

endogeneity of informal care, they only examine elderly who reside with a caregiver, and they

treat spouse and offspring caregivers the same, despite fundamental differences between

them. Hence, focusing on offspring caregivers regardless of co-residence status, controlling

for the endogeneity o f informal care, and analyzing a nationally representative sample of

elderly over time are some innovations of my work.

Formal care's effect on subsequentformal care.

Looking at formal care use can help describe how informal care affects future formal

care use, since both can occur in response to a need for a particular type o f medical care.

Obviously, by definition formal care affects health care utilization, because they are one in

19

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
the same. However, how a past formal care experience affects future formal care use

depends primarily on a person’s health status, whether the medical care was effective,

whether the person recovered, or whether she had complications. Rabiner (1994) describes it

well by saying that background factors, prior formal care, intensity of prior care, and life

satisfaction all affect subsequent formal care utilization. These background factors include

age, gender, hours of informal support, homeowner status, race, marital status, cognitive

status, incontinence, ADL limitations, patient satisfaction, proxy status, and Medicaid

eligibility (Rabiner et al., 1994). I already mentioned some of these factors, but the notions

that quality of informal care and life satisfaction (perhaps determined by satisfaction with the

caregiving situation?) can determine subsequent formal care use are important and have

received scant empirical attention.

Turning to home health care and nursing home care, the most well-known formal care

intervention for the elderly was the Channeling intervention already mentioned. The

Channeling experiment was a randomized in-home community-based long-term care case

management intervention (Rabiner et al., 1994). Researchers expected there to be significant

substitution of case management and other in-home services for nursing home care. The

effect of Channeling on subsequent nursing home utilization was negative as expected,

however, it was much smaller than expected. Rabiner and colleagues found that this small

effect was due to the direct reductions in nursing home utilization due to case management

and other aspects o f Channeling being substantially offset by the indirect increases in nursing

home utilization associated with additional home care use (1994). Further, while not relevant

to the Channeling intervention, Rabiner and colleagues point out that discerning the effect of

home-care on subsequent nursing home utilization is difficult usually because home-care is

20

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
not precisely defined in the literature. Nevertheless, they report that most studies from 1968

to 1988 found that home and community care generally reduced nursing home care but that

reductions were small (Rabiner et al., 1994). Parallels to informal care can be drawn from

this, especially the possibility that informal caregivers might identify problems and hence

increase the need for more formal care.

Weissert summarizes the other major studies from the Channeling intervention (27 of

them). He states that they all come to remarkably similar conclusions: home care is not a

cost-saving substitute for nursing home care because few patients are at risk of

institutionalization; reductions in institutionalization are small; home care costs exceed the

small reductions in institutional costs; and patient outcome benefits are extremely limited,

and sometimes even negative (Weissert, 1988). He also points out that physical and mental

functioning in the elderly is difficult to maintain or bring back, but that contentment, on the

other hand, may be improved (Weissert, 1988). There is still debate about whether informal

care can alter the trajectory of decline.

Pezzin, Kemper, and Reschovsky (1996) explore the Channeling experiment as well,

but are interested in controlling for the endogeneity of living arrangements. They find that

the Channeling intervention had no significant impact on the hours of formal care, aside from

a small impact seen through changes in living arrangements. This is consistent with

Christianson’s (1988) finding discussed earlier. What Channeling did instead was to increase

the probability o f living independently for unmarried persons in particular, a significant result

in its own right.

21

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Many other studies in the literature echo the same findings. For other studies on

formal care factors driving elderly formal care demand, see Wolinsky (1994), Kemper

(1992), or Ellencweig and Paggliccia (1994).

How does informal care affect the net cost of formal care?

Determining potential costs savings to the private and public sector from informal

care is an important motivating factor of this research, although due to data limitations I am

only able to assess this by examining changes in formal care use. To ascertain costs, one

must recognize that informal caregiving may be able to reduce use and hence expenditures on

some types of care but not on others. For example, because home health and informal

caregiving can be close substitutes for each other, home health care (HHC) costs may go

down with the presence of informal care. However, there are many tiers of home health care

that informal caregivers may not be able to replace, such as physical therapy, occupational

therapy, or RN services. The types of home health care more easily replaced by informal care

are custodial tasks such as assisting a person with bathing, with other ADL’s, or with

IADL’s. Formal home care is heterogeneous, so informal care may not be able to replace the

higher skilled home health care tasks despite an increased reliance on caregivers to perform

complex medical care (Fisher, 1998). This is important to keep in mind as home health care

tends to be lumped into one category of care for data reasons, yet home health care includes

heterogeneous types of care.

Lending credence to this is a finding by Pezzin and Schone that children provide

IADL help while formal care providers provide ADL help (1999b). Further, Christianson

22

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
found that the most common types of care from children were with housekeeping and money

management. The notion that substitution occurs for some types of care but not others is not

new. Ettner finds that Medicaid home health care subsidies replace informal care with home

health care for non-medical services but do not increase the total quantity of care received.

In addition, informal care may have no effect on reducing acute hospital care.

Clearly, having a child caregiver may reduce a parent’s risk of falling and breaking a hip, but

for chronic conditions or other acute illnesses common in old age, such as pneumonia, stroke,

and heart conditions, a child caregiver may have no influence on decreasing hospital care.

Further, an informal caregiver may be able to delay her disabled parent’s entry into a nursing

home to some degree. However, beyond a certain point in the parent’s need for care, such as

becoming bed ridden or having advanced Alzheimer’s, a single caregiver may not be able to

provide sufficient care and hence may not be able to delay nursing home entry. Of a similar

vein, once in a nursing home an adult child may have no influence of the duration of the stay.

In fact, in both of these examples the presence of a caregiver may increase rather than

decrease demand for formal care and hence costs—the close monitoring of a parent may

hasten contact with a hospital in response to an acute illness or injury, or hasten a nursing

home entry due to any deterioration in the health status of a parent. Or, a parent may increase

doctor visits due to a child being available to transport them to and from the doctor. In

addition, a child caregiver may be more cognizant of social services available to an ailing

parent, such as adult day care or respite care, and complement informal care with these

services. This too could increase public expenditures on elderly health care, although it is

difficult to determine whether adult day care might also produce a counter effect such as

reducing depression in a parent and hence alleviating the need for other formal care use.

23

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Recognizing the complexity behind any “cost-savings” calculations from informal care is

vital. Ultimately, while some health care costs may go down due to informal care, in other

instances they may go up.

24

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
CHAPTER TWO:

CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK OF INFORMAL AND FORMAL CARE

Overview of chapter

The basic factors driving demand for elderly medical care are the same as those

driving demand for care for the general population: mental and physical health status, ability

to pay, and access to care. Health status in particular is an important predictor of an elderly

person’s independence, and in turn, of the need for home health care, nursing home care, and

to a lesser extent, acute care. In addition, the use of informal care may be an important

determinant of elderly medical care demand due to its characteristic as both a substitute and a

complement to formal medical care.

In this chapter I review classic work by Grossman (1972) on demand for health, and

incorporate informal caregiving into his model in order to express a theoretical model of

health care utilization for the elderly that is based on utility maximization. Next I review a

model by Nocera and Zweifel (1996) of informal care, and design a model of utility

maximization for adult children who may or may not choose to provide informal care to their

elderly parent. Finally, I describe how these two models are jointly determined and I

conclude the chapter with hypotheses that stem from the conceptual framework.

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Review of the Grossman model

Much work has been done to develop demand models for medical care, ranging from

Grossman’s classic 1972 article which identifies demand for the commodity “good health"

and allows a means to find derived demand for medical care (Grossman, 1972), to Manning

and colleagues classic study of the RAND health insurance experiment, where insurance is

exogenous (Maiming et al., 1987). In addition, researchers have developed demand models

that explicitly account for the endogenous nature of health insurance (Cameron and Triveldi

(1988), Gilleskie and Mroz, (1997), and others). None of this research incorporates informal

care.

An adaptation of Grossman’s model of health demand is most relevant for health care

use by older adults. Such a model needs to reflect differences in the elasticity of demand

between different types of care, allow informal care to enter as either a substitute or a

complement to formal care, and accommodate the unique nature of elderly health insurance.

The presence of universal public insurance for people over 65 in the U.S., Medicare, changes

the elasticity o f demand for care.

In Grossman’s seminal work, he develops a demand model for “good health" rather

than for medical care, as he views the consumption of medical care to be a means towards

achieving good health, not an end in and of itself (1972). Grossman’s basic model assumes

that a person maximizes an inter-temporal utility function, where utility is a function of a

person’s consumption o f health services and another good. Utility can be expressed as:

U = U ( h 0 , h x,..., h T ,Z o ,Z ,,..., Z r ) (2.1)

26

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
where the subscripted index 1,.., T corresponds to the years of a person’s life, and subscript T

is age at death. A novelty of this model is that length of life is determined by a person’s

lifetime investment in health, so it is endogenously determined. The total consumption of

health services is expressed as h, = </>H„ where tf>represents the service flow per unit stock.

Ho is the initial health stock, and Hr is the health stock at death. A person’s health stock

depreciates over time at an exogenous rate, and once H falls below a certain level, what

Grossman calls Hmm, death occurs. However, one’s health stock can be increased by various

investments in health, staving off the arrival of Hmm. All other goods that enter the utility

function are expressed as the composite good, Z, which I describe in the next paragraph.

A person maximizes this utility function subject to four constraints. First, the

production function for health investment is a function of two inputs, medical care and time,

given a person’s stock of human capital. This can be expressed as the function

(2.2)

where M, is the medical care input, TH, is the time input, and E, is the stock of human capital.

Second, the production of the other good, Z„ is a function of a consumption good input and a

time input, given one’s stock o f human capital. The general form is

Z,=Z,{X„TH „\E,) (2.3)

where Z, is a composite good that is a function of a person’s consumption of market goods,

X„ time, THt, and the stock of human capital at time t, Et. The term Zo in equation 2.1 reflects

27

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
goods that a person has inherited at birth. X, and Z, differ in that X, represents market goods

while Z, represents how market goods are transformed into a good that depends on time use

decisions (77/,) and human capital (£,).

Third, there is a health investment constraint, which is equal to gross investment

minus depreciation. The last constraint is a goods budget constraint that stipulates that the

present value of outlays on goods is equal to the present value of earnings income over the

life cycle, plus initial assets.

From the constraints we see that Grossman treats health as a production good.

However, he points out that there is a pure consumption aspect to health as well as a

production aspect—possessing health makes people feel better, which improves their utility.

He also sees a pure investment aspect to health, as investing in health in early years may

increase the number of days an elderly person is able to garden, take walks, or otherwise

enjoy his or her retirement in good health. For working individuals, investing in health

increases the number of days a person can work, which leads to increases in utility. But even

non-workers, like the retired elderly, have an incentive to invest in health because health

affects both market and non-market activities (Grossman, 1972).

Elderly formal care model: the parent’s formal care decision

Modifying Grossman’s framework, it is clear that for the elderly current investment in

health differs greatly from past investment decisions. First o f all, the kinds of decisions that

elderly make are different from those made when they were young. For example, instead of

deciding whether to start smoking or to get a college education, which they did when they

28

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
were young, the elderly are deciding whether to stop smoking, to begin exercising, or to get a

flu shot. In addition, at age 65, a person’s past health behavior and past investment in health,

as well as his or her genetic makeup have already molded one’s health stock. These past

decisions are exogenous when maximizing current utility and future expected utility. For

example, it is well established that both income and education are positively correlated with

health (Rogot, Sorlie and Johnson, 1992, McGinnis and Foege, 1993, Pritchett and Summers,

1993, Ettner, 1996). However, at age 65, most all formal education decisions are sunk in

terms of their ability to improve a person’s future health, and are a part of a person’s stock of

human capital.

Similarly, a 65 year old’s income path is also decided, as he or she is at or nearing

retirement and soon will be living on a fixed income either through private savings or

through Social Security income. Clearly, while income is important in predicting health over

one’s lifetime, income typically will not fluctuate a great deal for the elderly. Nor will

income be a major barrier to obtaining medical care, because nearly all of the elderly have

health insurance through Medicare. In addition, 85 percent o f the elderly have Medigap or

Medicaid, which reduces or eliminates copayments and deductibles. These safety nets mean

that investment in health through medical interventions is less constrained by wealth or

income for the elderly than for those adults under age 65. For these two reasons, the stability

of income and the presence o f insurance, the wealth constraint is not as binding as the health

investment production function (I,) and other goods (Z,) constraint for the elderly. It is still

important, due to the lack o f Medicare providers in some areas, the lack of good prescription

coverage, the need to spend down wealth to cover long-term care, and the differences in

premiums, co-payments and deductibles that go along with insurance and their differential

29

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
effects on different income groups. However, the universal coverage of Medicare serves as

an important safety net for the elderly.

Past investments in health have large effects on current health of the elderly, for

example long term smokers and drinkers may have particular health problems while long

term exercisers and healthy eaters may have particular health protections. However, past

investments in health are sunk, so I am more concerned with seeing how recent investment in

health drives marginal changes in an elderly person’s health stock. Of all of the current

period inputs into an elderly person’s current health investment production function, medical

care, M , has the potential to produce large marginal changes in a person’s health in the event

of a health shock, because it is usually expensive investments in health that have the highest

marginal productivity for elderly health. For example, major acute episodes such as a fall,

stroke or a heart attack, which are common for the elderly, require large and immediate

investments in health to recover one's health status. Diet or a change in exercise regime can

do very little in this case. Another example is expensive prescription drugs that help control

chronic conditions of the elderly such as high blood pressure.

O f course, exceptions to this are that things like daily aspirin doses and flu shots can

be effective and cheap preventive medicine, so the marginal benefit is high at very low cost.

Another important exception to this is the practice of flat of the curve medicine, where large

medical care purchases translate to small gains in health. A relevant example for the elderly

are large medical expenditures in the last months of life, when much medical care is

purchased but a person’s health stock has little to no chance of staying above Hmm.

Nevertheless, the mere aggregate cost of M, justifies focusing on it over other inputs into the

health investment function, regardless o f its marginal medical benefit.

30

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
An elderly person’s choice of M, following an acute illness episode or injury is vital

in predicting recovery and future use of medical care. This choice could include the type of

care sought or the perceived quality of care of a given provider. Sometimes there is little

choice as to the type o f care because a person may need to be treated in a hospital initially.

During the episode of illness following a health shock, however, there are many decision

points. In particular, there will be different rates of return on the health investment based on

whether the person chooses acute care, doctor care, nursing home care, or is able to receive

informal care. Each will have different effects on health. The adjustment in inputs a person

makes in the health investment constraint may or may not prevent their health stock from

falling below Hmm.

Of course, even small investment in health, such as preventive care can have high

returns for the health investment constraint and health of the elderly. For example, annual flu

shots may prevent rapid declines in health for persons with weak immune systems. Likewise,

blood pressure monitoring may be important in preventing stroke in elderly patients. These

are important medical inputs as well, and can also reduce the rate of depreciation of a

person’s health stock. So in addition to a focus on home health care, nursing home care,

hospital care, and outpatient surgery in this project, I also examine doctor’s visits, although I

can not determine whether the doctor’s visit is for preventive care or in response to a specific

problem. A priori, I do not expect to find much of a relationship between informal care and

doctor’s visits because of the low substitutability of the two.

The focus on medical care and informal care is not to belittle the impact of current

time use decisions, THh and consumption o f other goods, X (, on health. To a lesser extent

these are also important components o f the health investment constraint, and important

31

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
determinants of elderly health. For example, choosing to continue working may cause older

individuals to remain healthier longer or to increase feelings of self-worth and hence mental

health. In addition, social supports can be important for elderly mental health, so time spent

with others may have large effects on health, as may choosing to exercise. The same is true

for consumption behavior changes (.Xt) which affects the other good constraint (Z,).

Changing one’s diet or stopping smoking can all have positive effects on health. Similarly,

lifestyle changes, such as remarrying after being widowed, moving to a warmer climate, or

moving closer to children may also have strong effects on health, as may environmental

factors such as pollution exposure, or the safety of one’s home. I control for many of these

important behavioral decisions in the empirical work, despite a focus on medical care use

(A/,) and informal care (A,).

To recap, the focus on informal care {A,) emerges because informal care is the most

common type of long-term care for the elderly and its effect on utilization has not yet been

studied. Meanwhile, the focus on formal medical care (M,) emerges because of the large

marginal effect that medical care can have on the health of elderly individuals, and because of

the sheer magnitude o f the cost o f medical care for the elderly.

Adapting Grossman’s general utility framework, an elderly individual’s inter-temporal

utility function can be expressed as

(2.4)

where t is the age o f the person when I first observe them, and T is the age at death. The four

constraints for the elderly are the same as those described in the previous section, with the

32

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
exception of the health investment production function (2.2). For this constraint, I need to

incorporate informal care, which is exogenous to a parent’s decision making process. This

can be written as

(2.5)

where M, is medical care, T, is the time allocation to health investments, E, is the stock of

human capital, and A, is total hours a parent receives informal care from a child. The

structure of M, must account for the different elasticities of demand for different types of

medical care and the near universal health insurance coverage of the elderly. This can be

accommodated by

M, = M f a ? , M ? , M f , Mf p, M f i B ) (2.6)

where A/,** is home health care, M ? is nursing home care, M f is hospital care, Mfp is

outpatient surgery, and M f is doctor care. The disaggregation of medical care by type

allows for different rates o f return on different types of medical care investments. B in this

equation is insurance status. For the general population, purchases of M, are constrained by

the wealth constraint as well as the presence of insurance. And people choose insurance

partially based on expected medical expenditures, meaning insurance is an endogenous

variable. However, near universal insurance coverage for those age 65 and over allows an

important simplification to be made for an elderly demand model. Insurance can be treated

33

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
as an exogenous variable in the elderly utility maximization problem, because insurance

decisions are less tied to expected use o f medical services than in the general population. This

assumption is not as robust when considering purchases of Medigap or prescription coverage.

Nevertheless, when looking at particular populations of the elderly, such as female elderly,

for cultural reasons associated with this cohort decisions about health insurance may have

been made for them long ago by a husband, hence, insurance decisions may be linked to a

husband’s expected need for care rather than her own. This may help dilute problems with

endogeneity in the cases of Medigap and prescription coverage since so many of my sample

is female. There is more discussion of this assumption in Chapter Three.

I mentioned already that the five types of medical care in M, will have unique

marginal effects on elderly health and elderly utility. It is also important to consider that

purchases o f different types o f medical care inputs, , M "h, M f , M °p, M f ), follow a

sequential process, requiring a dynamic view of utilization to create a complete picture of

utilization. Each choice at each point in time may produce different levels of health. For

example, for a fall resulting in serious injury, a person decides either to see a doctor, go to the

emergency room or seek ambulatory care. Time elapsed until treatment is also important.

Once the patient is in a recovery phase, the patient decides whether to continue rehabilitation

in a nursing home, through home health care visits from a physical therapist, or using

informal family-provided care. Even if it is someone besides the elderly patient making

decisions, such as a doctor, an insurer, or a family member, I assume that they are agents

acting in the patient’s best interest. After the rehabilitation phase the elderly patient may then

need to decide whether to continue a lighter schedule o f home health care, or rely on

available informal care from children, or both.

34

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
In this example, informal care (A,) may complement the entire episode of care, from

the hospital to the parent’s home. Once the patient returns home, home health care providers

may care for the patient for some hours of the day, while an adult child may care for the

patient for the remainder. On the other hand, the child may only provide care at the end of

the episode, as a substitute for the home health care provider.

It is clear from this example that informal care and formal care can be substituted for

each other over time, so the informal care input is also expected to have a large marginal

effect on health for the elderly. Given a fixed number of inputs and given the amount of

informal care a child is going to provide, an elderly person may adjust the amount of input M,

he or she uses (see equation 2.5), in allocating inputs to health investments. The interplay

between formal care and informal care is of particular importance in this project, but it may

be difficult to capture because I do not have timing o f formal and informal care. For

example, if an elderly person uses more informal care, I want to examine whether formal care

subsequently increases, meaning that informal care is a net complement to formal care, or

whether it decreases, meaning it is a net substitute. Finally, an increase in informal care

could cause utilization both to increase and to decrease over the episode of the parent’s

illness, meaning informal care is both a substitute and complement.

The general utility framework allows me to examine how the interactions between

different types of formal care and informal care produce elderly health. The interactions of

these inputs enter the utility maximization process explicitly through the health investment

constraint (equation 2.5). More importantly, this framework allows empirical testing. A

priori, I expect that the use of informal care will lead to declines in home health care and

nursing home care, but to negligible or small increases in hospital care, due to the acute

35

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
nature o f hospital care. Home health care and informal care can be considered close

substitutes, which means one may fall if the other is provided controlling for changes in

health. For nursing home care, a child’s caregiving efforts can delay the need for a parent to

enter a nursing home, unless the limitations in functional status are too serious for a child to

manage alone. For acute care, if a child is caring for a parent, he or she may detect problems

that the parent is experiencing before they might otherwise be detected, so informal care may

actually increase the use of acute care. On the other hand, a child providing care may

decrease the risk of a parent experiencing a serious fall, which would decrease acute or

physician care. In general, however, preventing acute care through informal care may not be

possible due to a parent’s chronic conditions and the biological aging process. As a result I

expect the effect o f informal care on acute care to be ambiguous, as well as the effect on

outpatient surgery.

Child informal care model: the informal care decision

Just as the parent makes decisions about health care utilization, there is an important

decision facing the adult child if an elderly parent experiences any loss of independence and

needs assistance—whether to provide informal care or not. This process may occur either

before a parent’s formal care episode or in the absence of a formal care episode, due to a

parent’s gradual decline in functional status or other problems, or following a formal care

episode, such as a recovery from a fall, as was described in the example given.

A household production framework is the best way to illustrate the child’s decision

making process. Theoretical models o f supply of informal care involve tradeoffs between

36

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
work, leisure, and the supply of informal care (Chang and White-Means, 1995; Nocera and

Zweifel, 1996; Sloan et al., 1997). The following model was developed based on work by

Nocera and Zweifel (1996), Stem (1995), Becker (1974), and Gronau (1986). For simplicity,

I assume that there is only one child per parent. I also assume that the parent ic single, so that

the child is the most logical care provider for the parent rather than a partner or spouse. A

child will maximize her utility by optimizing her consumption, leisure, and informal care

decisions, as well as considering the health status of the parent. This can be expressed in the

following general intertemporal utility function:

(2.7)

where / indexes the time period, X, is a numeraire of consumption goods, which can be

broken down into the consumption of formal care and all other goods; L, is time spent in

leisure activity; A, is time spent providing informal care; and h' is the health of the parent.

Like Nocera and Zweifel (1996), I assume that the caregiver’s utility depends on

consumption, leisure (labor is all time not spent in pursuit of leisure), and informal care.

Intangible factors such as guilt or cultural beliefs about a child’s responsibility for a parent

are not observed in the theoretical model or empirically, but they can certainly affect utility

by the way they affect all three o f these factors. For example, a child who decides to provide

no informal care initially may feel very guilty when using her leisure time, hence might

experience a drop in utility. The next period she may decide to provide or arrange for care.

Nocera and Zweifel (1996) point out that because informal caregivers are usually not

paid, a child caregiver must derive more utility from caregiving over the alternatives to

37

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
caregiving (arranging formal care or no care), or she would provide no care. If a child

derives more utility from leisure than from caregiving but still feels she should help her

parent, she may optimize utility by choosing to pay for formal care and give up some of her

own consumption.

The optimization process is subject to two constraints, an income constraint and the

parent’s health production function. The income constraint, a function of time spent in labor

activities, wages, and other income, is as follows:

Y , = { T - L - A t )wt +C, (2.8a)

Here, T, is the total time endowment available per period, for example 7=24 if the

optimization process is made daily, so that T , - L , ~ A, = W„ where W, is labor time per

period. In addition, wt is the wage rate, and C, can be thought of as lump sum compensation

for caregiving. Few children caregivers are actually compensated for care through wages, so

another interpretation of C, could be that it includes future expected income coming from

parental bequests or indirect transfers from the parent. Alternatively, C, could include any

other non-wage income earned by the child. This constraint also can be expressed as

(2.8b)

which assumes that there is no savings. A child depletes all of her income, Yh by the end of

each period through the purchase of different types of market goods. Consumption goods are

disaggregated into X/c, which is any purchases o f formal care that the child may make for the

38

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
parent and X og is purchases of all other consumption goods. P/c is the price o f formal care

while Pog is the price of other goods.

The second constraint is the parent’s optimal health production constraint, which

emerges from the parent’s utility maximization process, and is a function of all of the health

investment decisions that an elderly parent makes. The optimal health production constraint

can be expressed as

(2.9)

where Z* is the optimal other good a parent consumes and /,’ is the optimal level of health

investment a parent makes. Arriving at the optimal levels of health investment and other

good consumption depends on market goods consumption, time use decisions, and medical

care consumption, as well as exogenous factors such as human capital and the optimal

amount of informal care available. The child takes h' as given (see equation 2.7).

I try to incorporate a parent’s health status in the child’s utility maximization

framework through h ’ , based on an important notion pointed out by Becker (1992). Becker

points out that if a child operates partly from altruism, she will incorporate the parent’s health

status into her own utility function. Other researchers have not allowed the child to

incorporate the parent’s utility into his or her utility function (e.g. Sloan et al.. 1997). In the

utility framework, a parent’s health status enters the child’s utility function through the health

production constraint h ' .

39

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Joint determination of informal care and utilization

The theoretical models of utilization and informal care are helpful in illustrating how

the two decisions by two different generations interact. The parent chooses her optimal level

of medical care use based in part on how much informal care her child will provide (see 2.5).

Likewise, the child maximizes utility and decides how much informal care to provide based

on the parent’s health production function h’ which is a function of medical care use (see

2.6). From this it is clear that the parent’s utilization decision and the child’s caregiving

decision are jointly determined. The decisions of one affect the other, so they are in no way

independent.

In other words, a child's informal care decision depends on whether her elderly parent

can receive home health care, or if there is an affordable nursing home nearby. Alternatively,

a parent may not invest in home health care if the child is willing to care for her. Therefore. 1

cannot consider informal care to be exogenous in predicting health care utilization of the

parent. Just as informal care may cause utilization to increase, so might utilization cause

informal care to increase.

In terms of the conceptual framework, a child will optimize her utility function and

decide on an optimal level o f informal care A '. Using that information, a parent will decide

on utilization, (A/*), once he or she knows how much informal care is available. But this

optimal level of informal care depends also on how much utilization, or M, a parent will

consume, so will adjust over time. This interdependence means that I must control for the

endogeneity of informal care in the empirical work, in order to get unbiased estimates of

40

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
informal care's effect on formal medical care. I will carefully account for this in the

empirical model.

41

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Hypotheses

The conceptual framework leads to three testable hypotheses:

Testable hypotheses:

H I: Informal care reduces total formal health care utilization of elderly.

H2: The effect of informal care on health care utilization will vary by type

o f utilization. Informal care will cause a net drop in home health care

and nursing home use, but will have little or no affect on hospital use

due to its acute nature. It is not clear what effect informal care will

have on outpatient surgery and doctor’s visits.

H3: Informal care by children is endogenous to health care utilization of

their elderly parent.

42

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
CHAPTER THREE

METHODS

Overview of chapter

The methodology is based on a quasi-experimental design. The experimental group is

those who receive informal care from their children, while the control group is those who do

not. I test the null hypothesis that informal care has no effect on health care utilization. I

measure five types of health care utilization: home health care, nursing home care, acute

hospital care, outpatient surgery, and doctor’s visits. I expect the effect of informal care on

utilization to differ across types o f care. Because of the large percentage of the sample

expected not to have any utilization, I estimate two-part utilization models. Because informal

care is endogenous, I control for endogeneity.

In this section I describe the empirical models of elderly health care utilization and

informal caregiving. I suggest three approaches to deal with the endogeneity of informal

care: use of lagged informal care, two-step instrumental variable estimation, and discrete

factor analysis. Then I describe the numerous specification tests employed to check

robustness of the model specification and the conclusions drawn from these tests. I end the

chapter by describing the performance of discrete factor analysis compared to two-step IV

estimation.

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Two-part models of utilization

Because health care utilization is zero for many individuals, I use two-part models

with controls for selection, as has been developed in the health economics literature (Duan et

al., 1984; Jones, 2000). The first part is a probit or logit model that predicts the probability of

having any formal care. The second part uses ordinary least squares (OLS) to predict the

continuous amount of care, conditional on having any care. The dependent variable in the

second part is the logarithm o f utilization, so as to diminish the influence of outliers.

The general form is: E i M ) = E § 4 \M >0)Pr (V/ >0)

Where M is formal care. The two-part model is appropriate because it restricts

outcomes from being negative. Further, the two-part model assumes that decisions are made

sequentially. In this case, an elderly parent first decides whether or not to use care, and then

decides how much care to use. It is important for two-part models to include all relevant

controls in order to minimize omitted variable bias. This ensures that the assumption about

sequential decision-making holds.

Because the same explanatory variables are included in both parts of the model, any

omitted variables that belong in both parts will be correlated with explanatory variables in

both parts. If this is the case, the error terms are correlated across equations and decisions are

then considered to be made simultaneously. I include an exhaustive list of controls besides

caregiving, the variable o f interest, in order to m in im iz e omitted variable bias. Because

omitted variable bias still may persist, I also use discrete factor analysis which allows us to

relax the assumption of sequential decision making across the two parts by explicitly

estimating the error correlation between the two parts.

44

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
The unit o f analysis is the elderly parent. In the model, however, there are both parent

characteristics and child-level informal care characteristics, as both are hypothesized to affect

the types of utilization in question. Following the notation from the theoretical framework,

formal medical care is a function of informal care, A , , health, H t , demographic and income

characteristics, Z, ,and, other consumption goods, C,, such as insurance:

M , Jt = g j , , / / , , , Z „,C (1 .e,„ ) (3.1)

The dependent variable, M IJt, is formal medical care use, either any home health care,

any nursing home care, nights in a nursing home, any hospital care, any outpatient surgery,

any doctor’s visits or number of doctor's visits. The / index represents an individual, and is

either i=l,...,2985 for the Wave 1 sample, or z-l,...2444 for the Wave 2 sample, depending

on the value o f w. The index t shows whether the equation is estimated for the Wave 1 or

Wave 2 sample, and ranges from i= 1,2. The index j represents the eight continuous and

discrete types of formal care, so ranges from j = l . . . 8 . The model is estimated using a logit

model or a log-linear model, depending on the value of j. I use a log-linear model on

continuous measures o f utilization because the distribution is skewed. Finally, the index /

shows whether the dependent variable is medical care utilization in Wave 1 or Wave 2.

The main explanatory variable of interest, informal caregiving, Atl, is hypothesized

to be endogenous, hence I will need to control for the endogeneity of informal caregiving.

Informal care is only measured in the first wave, hence the t subscript is constant at f=l.

Informal caregiving is defined two different ways: whether any child provided care, and as

45

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
total number of ADL’s and IADL’s (also referred to as I/ADL’s) a parent receives help with

from all children.

Measures of the parent's health from Wave 1, HlX, include controls for both recent

and past health indicators. I control for self-assessed health status and self-assessed eyesight,

chronic conditions such as diabetes, arthritis, poor eyesight, incontinence and hypertension,

diseases such as cancer and lung disease, acute episodes such as falls, hip fractures, stroke,

angina and heart attacks, and health behavior, such as smoking and drinking too much

alcohol.

Many of these health status measures ask the respondent to look back over the past 5

years or look back over a lifetime. However, including current health status could introduce

endogeneity bias if it is correlated with past health status or some other unobserved

characteristic that is a part o f the error term. I am not interested in the parameter estimates on

health status per se, but it would be of concern if informal care is also correlated with health

status and hence with these unobservable characteristics. I check this by examining the

correlation between informal care and the most recent health status measures, and the

correlation between predicted informal care and the health status measures. I also run the

models with and without the most recent health status indicators and compare the results.

In addition I control for the usual demographic controls such as age, gender, rural

residence, race and ethnicity, as well as some socio-economic variables such as household

income, net worth, whether the respondent works or not, education, and importance of

religion, all values from the first time period. These are closely related to consumption, and

are represented by Z(I.

46

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
I also control for insurance status (Medicaid, other private insurance, and long-term

care). Much work on demand for health care services has established that insurance status is

endogenous in models o f health care utilization (e.g. Arrow, 1963; Pauly 1983, 1988;

Manning et al., 1987; Gilleskie and Mroz, 1998; Cameron et al., 1988). Despite this, I

assume that insurance is exogenous. Most elderly make decisions about Medigap about the

time they turn 65, and at this time they are usually healthy. Considering the youngest

respondent in my sample is 70, there is a long lag time between choosing Medigap or

prescription coverage options, and needing care. Uncertainty surrounding future need and the

lag time between purchase and use help to break the path of endogeneity. Decisions about

long-term care insurance are also typically made long before the age of 70, when premiums

are lower. Finally, my sample is primarily women (80 percent), and for women of this cohort

it is very likely that husbands made the insurance decision for the family, which further

breaks the endogeneity path between insurance and individual health care use.

Regarding Medicaid, it is true that utilization can affect Medicaid status due to spend-

down to Medicaid from nursing home use. Since the AHEAD sample originally interviewed

only the non-institutionalized, spend down should not be a problem in the first wave. Any

nursing home use had to be relatively short-term use since a person had to be living in a

private residence to be included in the sample. Therefore, I think it is valid to consider

Medicaid coverage to be exogenous as well. Even if a person entered a nursing home after

being interviewed in 1992-93, the spend-down to Medicaid typically takes more than 2 years.

Medicaid nursing home residents are more likely to be chronically poor individuals than

spend-down individuals based on the sample selection criteria in Wave 1 that people not be

in an institution. Furthermore, I am mainly interested in controlling for insurance status, and

47

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
not the point estimates, in discerning the impact of informal care on utilization, so I will not

try to correct for the endogeneity of insurance, due to the lack o f instruments.

Besides informal care, one other child-level variable is included in the utilization

model. I include education of the informal caregiver to incorporate Bass and Noelker’s

(1987) notion o f a caregiver’s education serving as a proxy for “knowledge about services."

This variable and the insurance variables are represented by the C(, vector.

I also hoped to control for caregiver stress, as the sociology literature finds that

caregiver stress is likely to directly or indirectly influence the elderly’s use of community

services in order to relieve the caregiver from the burdens of caregiving (Hess and Soldo.

1985, Bass and Noelker, 1987). Unfortunately, because the information in my data set is

reported by the parent and not the adult child, there is no information about caregiver stress.

If available, this variable would have belonged in the utilization equation as well.

Endogeneity of informal care

Looking at supply o f and demand for informal care together, it is important to

consider the chance for reverse causation, the particular kind o f endogeneity I am concerned

with, to come into play. Clearly, just as informal care will affect formal care use, so will

formal care affect informal care (for more detail on the latter case, see Pezzin and Schone,

1999b). For example, as I mentioned in Chapter One, if a parent breaks her hip, first she will

seek inpatient care, then perhaps home health care for rehabilitation, and then she may need

one of her adult children to help her complete certain tasks of daily living until she is fully

48

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
recovered. There are also unobserved care preferences that could affect both formal and

informal care, which could be another source of endogeneity.

For example, consider the simplified three period model (t = 0,1,2) below which

shows medical care in the second period, M ljX, as a function o f contemporaneous informal

care. A,,, health status in the previous period, Hl0, and time invariant preferences for care.

P,-

M,j \ = b] A, , + b2Hl0 + b3Pt + e, y,

In reality, Hl0 and Pt are part of the error term but I include them explicitly here to

illustrate the two types o f endogeneity which may occur. Using contemporaneous informal

care means that there is a potential for both reverse causation and unobserved care

preferences to cause endogeneity bias. Any health shock from the previous period, which is

an omitted variable, may be correlated with informal care in the current period since informal

care occurs in response to a health need of the parent. This causes endogeneity bias since the

health shock is captured in the error term. Further, unobserved preferences, which are time

invariant, could also be correlated with informal care in the current period.

Using informal care from the first period to predict medical care use in the second

period can break one but not both sources of endogeneity as illustrated below:

A/,yl = b1/fl0 + b-j/f,, + b 3f^ + e <yi

Since Al0 precedes Htl there is no correlation between the two. However, there

could still be endogeneity from unobserved care preferences if lagged informal care, A,0, is

correlated with P,.

49

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Unobserved care preferences and reverse causation indicate that not controlling for

the endogeneity of informal caregiving would lead to biased and inconsistent parameter

estimates in any model that includes informal care to predict formal care utilization.

Accounting for endogeneity will produce consistent parameter estimates of informal

caregiving. One method I propose to correct for endogeneity is to use lagged caregiving to

predict utilization. As shown in the first simplified model above, this eliminates endogeneity

from Hl0 from the error term. A better way, however, is to estimate a model that predicts

whether or not an adult child will provide informal care for the parent, and then to use

simultaneous equations methods. This accounts for both Hl0 and Pt in the example above.

The informal care model consists o f parent and child-level characteristics. I central for both

child characteristics and parent characteristics in this model, as both are hypothesized to

predict the caregiving decision in distinct ways. The parent-level characteristics are the same

as in equation (3.1), the model of utilization. The identifying instruments proposed are child-

level characteristics, and are described below. The caregiving model is as follows:

(3.2)

The superscript index w indicates whether informal care is estimated using the Wave

1 sample or the Wave 2 sample. As in the medical care use equation (3.1), the i subscript

indicates whether the number o f individuals is /=!,. ..,2985 or i=l,...2444 depending on

which sample is being used (indicated by vv=l or 2). Including a parent’s health status, Hlt.

follows directly from the conceptual model. I expect demographic and socio-economic

characteristics, Zn , as well as insurance and the child’s education, C(I, to affect an adult

50

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
child’s decision to provide informal care. Besides a child’s level of education, I expect all of

the other child characteristics to affect the parent’s formal care utilization only through their

effect on the likelihood of providing informal care. These are represented by I , ,, and are as

follows: child’s gender, child’s marital status, number of siblings a child has, and number of

offspring a child has.

Other models have found that a child’s gender, marital status, and number of children

affect caregiving behavior. In addition, a control for step child status is included due to

recent work by Pezzin and Schone (1999c) which shows that marital disruption affects

informal caregiving, and that transfers from parents are different for biological versus step

children.

Number of siblings is added to proxy for caregiver stress and more likely to proxy for

the caregiving network, as this variable loosely measures whether there are other caregivers

available to give respite to the primary caregiver (Stone and Short, 1990; Ettner. 1995).

I measure the adult child’s income, and also measure financial and property transfers

between parent and adult child. This is to control for the possibility of a bequest motive

discussed in the literature review.

Missing from the model are two obvious controls mentioned in Chapter One, namely

work status and distance o f an adult child to an elderly parent. In a 1995 article, Stem

hypothesized and found that a daughter’s care decision may affect her work status and

distance characteristics, meaning that these two variables are endogenous. While I think

these are important determinants in predicting informal caregiving behavior, I do not have

good instruments on a child’s work status or distance from the parent so do not include them.

Related to distance to a parent, another variable that is missing is co-residence with a parent.

51

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
While it is an important predictor o f caregiving, Pezzin, Kemper and Reschovsky (1999)

have found living arrangements too to be endogenous.

Some innovations of my caregiving model compared to Stem’s or others in the

economics and sociology literature, are that I have better measures o f income for both the

adult child and the parent, as well as a good measure of net worth for the parent. In addition.

I control for the importance o f religion to the parent in predicting whether the child provides

care or not. I wanted to explore whether the importance of religion could uncover the child’s

value system for providing informal care. Variables on “values” are typically unobserved by

the econometrician. My expectation is that families who view religion to be a very important

part of their lives may have different preferences for providing informal care. Ideally I would

measure the importance of religion to the child but I do not have this information.

Besides the absence of a child’s work status, distance to a parent and co-residence

status, a child’s own health status, and direct measures of caregiver stress are all omitted from

equation 3.2. These and other unobserved characteristics that may affect informal care

become part of the error term and are not estimated separately.

Correcting for the endogeneity of informal care

In the analysis I first estimate informal care’s effect on utilization in a simple two-part

model, assuming all right hand side variables are exogenous. Then I explore three methods

to correct for the endogeneity o f informal care. The first method is to use caregiving in the

first wave to predict utilization in the second wave. The second method is standard to use

when there is a right hand side endogenous variable, two-step IV estimation (better known as

52

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
two-stage least squares if both outcomes are continuous). The third method is to use discrete

factor analysis to account for endogeneity of informal care and health care utilization (Mroz

andGuilkey, 1995).

Not at all: Pseudo-maximum likelihood and generalized estimating equations (GEE).

To treat informal care exogenously, I use estimation methods for the two-part

utilization models which stem from either logit or OLS estimation. They differ because of a

need to control for the stratified cluster sample of the survey data. For the discrete measure

of any care, I use the ‘'svylogit” command. Stata uses a weighted maximum likelihood

estimator to obtain robust standard errors, called a “pseudo-maximum likelihood estimator’',

or pseudo-MLE. With this approach, the weighted “likelihood” is not the distribution

function for the sample, and the traditional likelihood ratio tests are not appropriate (Stata.

1999; Skinner, 1989). For the continuous outcome of quantity of care, I use the "svyreg”

command. Here, Stata uses weighted ordinary least squares to produce consistent standard

errors due to the clustering of the data. This is also known as generalized estimating

equations, or GEE. The more generic term that I use, one-step estimation, refers to both of

these types of models. The model estimated is equation 3.1 above:

—gj (-<4,1 ,Z M,C (, , e , yf ) (3.1)

Partially: lagged informal care.

By using informal care in the first wave (1992-1993) to predict utilization in the

second wave (1994-1995), temporal endogeneity can be interrupted. The basic model in this

approach is: M,jZ =g] (i4M,Hn ,Z tl ,C,, , e (y2 ). By definition, informal care takes place

53

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
before the formal care event. Similarly, I control for the stratified cluster sample of the

survey data using survey commands in Stata. While controlling for reverse causation, this

method does not correct for unobserved individual heterogeneity, which can be another

source of endogeneity bias (recall example of P, above).

Fully: two-stage instrumental variables.

The second approach is to use two-step instrumental variables estimation (IV

estimation) in order to estimate asymptotically unbiased parameter estimates and to reduce

measurement error. This approach corrects for reverse causation and unobserved individual

heterogeneity, but does not account for omitted variable bias, which in a two-part model can

cause the sequential decision-making assumption to be violated. If omitted variable bias

exists, then the decisions are simultaneous, and a Heckman selection model or some other

model would be more appropriate. I control for endogeneity from clustering using survey

commands in Stata. I refer to these methods generically as two-step estimation.

This approach hinges on finding good instruments, that is, variables highly correlated

with informal care, but not correlated with the error term in the utilization model. Good

instruments are usually difficult to find in practice. However, in this research, excellent

instruments exist. All of the identifying instruments that I explore are the adult child-level

characteristics in equation 3.2. I surmise that child characteristics generally affect a child’s

decision about caregiving, and through that decision, a parent’s consumption of formal care.

I consider a child’s gender to be the strongest instrument, based on other findings in the

literature. The system is over-identified, so I am able to perform a test of the over­

identifying restrictions, and eliminate empirically rejected instruments if necessary.

54

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
A child will provide a positive number of caregiving activities if the value he or she

gets from this choice is greater than the value associated with other care choices. I explore a

discrete measure of informal care and a continuous measure. The following framework

assumes a discrete measure of caregiving, but could be adjusted to accommodate a

continuous measure of caregiving.

Let y ’j, be the value that a child gets from providing informal care and y'^ be the

value of not providing informal care (modified based on Stem, 1995), where / is the child, j is

informal care and k is formal care or no care, and t is the time period. The value of

caregiving is unobserved, therefore, from the data I have only an indicator of which

alternative is chosen:

In general, the caregiving model will be a function of the explanatory variables

described in equation (3.2). The system for my two-part model of utilization with an

endogenous right hand side variable, is summarized as follows. The right hand side variables

are the same as in equations (3.1) and (3.2):

Main equation: (3.1) E ( M tJl )=

First-stage:

55

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Obtaining correct standard errors. For the continuous portion of the two-part utilization

model, 3.1b, it is straight forward to use canned two-stage least squares estimation of

equations 3.1b and 3.2, and the standard errors will be correct. However, estimating the

discrete portion of the two-part model, which asks, “Did an elderly parent consume any

formal care?" requires an iterative process. First, I estimate the caregiving equation (3.2).

then estimate the predicted probability of providing any care for each observation.

Depending on whether informal care is measured discretely, this is a linear or non-linear

prediction. Next I insert the predicted values for each elderly parent into the logit equation

(3.1a).

Using this mechanical approach, the estimated standard errors of the coefficients in

the logit model (3.1.a) are not correct. To be correct they would have to be adjusted for using

the predicted value o f caregiving in place of the actual value (Bollen, Guilkey, and Mroz,

1995). It is complex to calculate asymptotically correct standard errors, as seen in Maddala

(1983). However, evidence from Guilkey, Mroz and Taylor (1992) shows that “the

asymptotically correct standard errors are no more effective in large finite samples than the

conditional standard errors." Hence, I do not estimate the asymptotically correct standard

errors when estimating the discrete part of the two- part models. I do estimate correct

standard errors using linear probability models and compare the standard errors to those in

the svylogit model.

Experimentally: full-information maximum likelihood (FIML).

Using instrumental variables to correct for endogeneity generally does not impose any

structure on the error term. But because I am estimating a two-part model of utilization with

56

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
a logit model as the first part, I assume that the error term has a logistic distribution. This

may be too restrictive, because the error term may follow some other distribution.

If this is the case, using two-step estimation will not be consistent Further, less

directed at my project since I have between 2,000 and 3,000 observations, there is a concern

emerging in the econometrics literature that instrumented variables do not have desirable

properties in small samples (Staiger and Stock (1997), Bound and colleagues (1995) and

Goldman (1995)).

To address such concerns, researchers have developed ways to estimate simultaneous

equations semi-parametrically in an approach called discrete factor analysis. This is an

approach that deals with endogeneity from reverse causation, from unobserved individual

heterogeneity, and from clustering (Angeles, Guilkey, and Mroz 1996). It does not place

strict assumptions on the error distribution, and may be more efficient in small samples. This

method allows for explicit estimation of the correlation between the error terms so is able to

model unobserved heterogeneity directly. Discrete factor analysis is also known as full-

information maximum likelihood (FIML) or discrete factor methods (DFM).

Overview o f discretefactor methods.

In particular, Mroz suggests an approach for dealing with an endogenous dummy

variable that is asymptotically efficient both when the disturbances s , and e 2 are normally

distributed and when they follow a non-normal distribution (Mroz, 1997). (He also shows

that the approach can be applied to continuous endogenous variables as well). The appeal of

discrete factor methods is that one can guard against biases caused by imposing incorrect

57

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
distributional assumptions on the error terms. This approach assumes that unobserved

variables can be approximated by a discrete distribution (Mroz, 1999).

In general, the discrete factor representation of a bivariate distribution function (Mroz.

1997) is:

£ , = tt, -I- V,

and the joint distribution of the disturbances is given by (Mroz, 1997):

where

P k = Pr(v, = 7 l i n v ', = 7 7 , i )

Here, the dependence of the disturbances s t and s 2 is captured through the implicit

dependence o f the factors v, and v 2. If <x, and <x, approach zero and the number of points

of support, K, grows large, then it is the same as the bivariate kernel for arbitrarily dependent

bivariate random variables (Mroz, 1997). Unlike the multivariate kernel estimator, the

discrete factor approach does not set the number of points of support equal to the sample size.

Instead, researchers usually experiment to find the number of supports which cause the

estimates to be well behaved (Mroz, 1997).

Identification is achieved by setting one of the supports to zero, but if the errors are

normally distributed, there can be problems with identification when there are a large number

of supports. However, underidentification typically has little substantive importance, since it

only affects the estimators of the components of the error distribution ( , e 2). In practice

researchers have successfully used three points of support (Mroz and Guilkey, 1995,

58

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Goldman, 1995). I use specification tests suggested by Mroz (1997) to determine the

appropriate number o f supports for my sample size and model.

A more important issue is that it is not clear how one should interpret the parameter

estimates obtained from discrete factor approximations (Mroz, 1997). The parameter

estimates converge to a particular value in large samples, but the convergence is based on the

limiting values, the imposed distributional assumptions, variables assumed to be exogenous,

and the underlying joint distribution of the disturbances. Through Monte Carlo experiments.

Mroz finds that approximation estimators through discrete factor analysis can be interpreted

in the conventional manner, and “can help researchers avoid false inferences due to the

imposition of incorrect joint distribution assumptions while providing relatively precise point

estimates” (Mroz, 1997).

Mays (1999) points out that using discrete factor methods for a two-part model

controls for error correlation between the discrete and continuous parts of the utilization

process by including parameters for common unobserved characteristics at the individual and

cluster-level. This offers an advantage over two-step estimation, because of the high

likelihood of omitted variables in my model (caregiver stress is just one example of a missing

variable).

Dampening this advantage, however, is that under certain conditions Mroz (1999)

finds that two-step IV estimation performs nearly as well as discrete factor analysis. In

Monte Carlo simulations, Mroz performs exhaustive tests comparing OLS estimation,

maximum likelihood estimation (MLE), two-step estimation, and discrete factor estimation.

He assumes different sample sizes ranging between 1,000 and 5,000 observations. He

assumes 0.8 correlation between the first- and second-stage variables. He also assumes an

59

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
adjusted-R2 of .2 for both stages. Further, he assumes a mean value of .5 or .75 for his

endogenous variable.

Mroz shows that two-step estimators work well if the concern is to obtain an unbiased

estimator, however, he illustrates that the point estimates from DFM can be more precise than

this and other methods, especially with smaller sample sizes. With weak instruments, the

discrete factor models easily outperform two-step estimators, but with strong instruments,

two-step estimators perform reasonably well.

Further, compared to all other types o f estimation, Mroz finds that DFM estimation,

with a liberal criteria for adding points o f support (a=.25) performs remarkably well in terms

of mean squared error (MSE). He also shows that there is little bias from DFM when

disturbance terms are not normally distributed, and that DFM performs better than maximum

likelihood methods in this case.

Specification tests

Before running DFM, I use the Stata two-step instrumental variable results to conduct

five different specification tests of the instruments. I test for the validity of the exclusion

restrictions, for endogeneity of informal care, the strength of the instruments, for sufficient

explanatory power in the first stage, and a less standard test of the instruments to examine

whether measurement error invalidates their use. These tests are performed on all five

utilization types, and control for clustering in the data.

After initial investigation of the child-level instruments listed in (3.2), I pare down the

list considerably. The initial reason for doing this is the suspicion that financial transfers and

60

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
consultation between a parent and child could be endogenous to the child’s informal care

decision. If a child provides care, this could cause financial transfers as indirect payment for

informal care. The secondary reason for paring down the list o f instruments is because

correlation between child-level variables and parent-level variables is high for age. income,

and education. Hence, they cause spurious correlation when used as instruments. Finally, I

do not use step child as an instrument due to the lack of statistical power to explain behavior

of step child caregivers (2.5 percent are step children only).

As a result, I use four identifying instruments that are highly correlated with informal

care but not a parent's utilization: a child’s gender, a child’s marital status, a child’s number

of siblings, and the number of offspring the child has (Ettner, 1995 used number of siblings

as an instrument in her study of caregiving’s effect on female labor supply). I feel that a

child's gender is the strongest identifying instrument based on other findings in the literature,

so I begin testing the instruments with child's gender as the exactly identifying instrument.

Overidentification tests.

First, I test the overidentifying restrictions. Three variables, a child’s marital status, a

child’s number of siblings, and the number of offspring the child has are overidentifying

instruments in Wave I. A child's gender, a child’s marital status, and the number of

offspring the child has are overidentifying instruments in Wave 2. To perform tests of

overidentification, I use the predicted value o f informal care from the exactly identified first

stage regression, and plug it, along with the overidentifying instruments, into the utilization

model. The null hypothesis is that these three variables are valid instruments, and so should

have no explanatory power in the utilization models. If a joint F-test on the coefficients of

61

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
the three overidentifying instruments is rejected, meaning they are significantly different from

zero, then they are not valid instruments.

Columns two and five o f Table 1 show the test results for Waves 1 and 2 of the data.

In Wave I, the exclusion restrictions are valid for all utilization types but home health care

and nursing home care. In Wave 2, the exclusion restrictions are valid for all but nursing

home care and outpatient surgery.

Endogeneity of informal care.

Second, I test for the exogeneity o f informal care in predicting the five different types

of utilization. This entails estimating reduced form models of the informal care model (3.2)

and forming predicted values for informal care. I use the exactly-identified or over-identified

instruments based on the overidentification tests (columns three and six of Table 1). Then. I

plug in the predicted value o f informal care, as well as actual formal care, into the health care

utilization equation. If informal care is exogenous then the additional predicted value should

have no explanatory power. This is a variant of the Wu-Hausman test, sometimes called the

omitted variables version (Kennedy, 1992). In the discrete models of utilization, standard

errors are not corrected after using the predicted value. However, comparisons to linear

probability models which use survey regression commands and produce correct standard

errors showed little change in standard errors.

Columns four and seven of Table 1 show the results from the Wu-Hausman tests.

There is great variation in whether informal care is endogenous or exogenous. In Wave 1,

shown in column two, I detect endogeneity of informal care in any home health care

62

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.

Table I. Tests o f the exclusion restrictions and exogeneity o f informal care, waves I and 2, AHEAD.

WAVE 1 UTILIZATION (N=2.985'> WAVE 2 UTILIZATION 0M=2.4441

Test o f DWH test o f Test o f DWH test o f


Dependent Exclusion System endogeneity o f Exclusion System Endogeneity o f
Variable Restrictions Identity informal care Restrictions Identity informal care

Any home health care F(3, 2930) = 4.87** Exact F( 1,2932) = 6.35** F(3, 2 5 9 8 )= 1.74 Over F(l,2391)=.93

Any nursing home care F(3, 2930) = 2.55* Exact F (l, 2932) = 5.27** F(2, 2391) = 2.62* Exact F(l,2391)=5.3**

Nights in nursing home F( 3,29) = 7.39*** Exact F( 1, 31) = . 19 F(3, 165)= .31 Over F (!,I67)=.37

Any hospital care F(3, 2931) =.63 Over F (l, 2931) = .63 F(3,2383) =1.62 Over F( 1,2385)= .89

Times in hospital F(3, 653) = 1.91 Over F (l, 655) = .81 F(3, 848) = 029 Over F (l, 890) = 1 2

Any outpatient surgery F (3 ,2926) = .24 Over F( 1,2982) = .00 F(3,2389) =4.19*** Exact F( 1,2391 )=.26

Any doctor’s visits F(3, 2 9 2 5 )= 1.13 Over F( 1,2927) = .98 F(3, 2282)=.68 Over F (l,2284)=2.04

Times to the doctor F(3,2564) = .94 Over F( 1,2566) = .24 F(3, 2163)= 1.33 Over F(l,2165)=2.50

NOTES: I. * significant at the 10 percent level ** significant at the 5 percent level *** significant at the I percent level.
2. All estimations use probability weights and account for the design effect.
3. In wave I, child’s gender is the exactly identifying instrument while in wave 2, number o f siblings is.
utilization and any nursing home use. This makes sense in practical terms, especially for

nursing home use. By the nature of the sample selection in AHEAD, a person had to be non­

institutionalized to be interviewed. Hence, if a person had any nursing home use, it is likely

that it occurred prior to the receipt of informal care. Turning to Wave 2 utilization. I detect

endogeneity in any nursing home care only.

Endogeneity detected in Wave 1 can be from reverse causation or unobserved

individual heterogeneity. In Wave 2, however, since I use informal care in Wave 1 to predict

utilization in Wave 2, the sources for endogeneity come only from unobserved individual

heterogeneity causing correlation of the error terms.

While not used commonly in the literature, Mroz recommends more liberal criterion

for detecting endogeneity. He points out that a 25-50% exogeneity test would eliminate most

of the bias in the two-step procedure when the disturbances are actually joint normal (Mroz.

1999). Applying this criterion I find that informal care is endogenous for more types of care.

For p < . 25, informal care is endogenous in predicting the number of doctor's visits in wave 2.

For/K.5, however, endogeneity is detected in the prediction of outpatient surgery, doctor’s

visits, times to the doctor, and Wave 2 hospital care. This is a useful criteria, because it

allows researchers to consider endogeneity that is imprecisely measured through the use of

instruments. I suspected a priori that endogeneity existed between informal care and all of

the types of formal care under examination, but I was unable to detect it for all types at

conventional levels.

64

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Strength o f the instruments.

Second, I test the general strength of the instruments to see whether they are

significantly correlated with the potentially endogenous variable, informal care. A significant

correlation is required for the system to be identified. According to Bound, Jaeger and Baker

(1995), weak instruments can bias two-step least squares estimates towards OLS and can also

invalidate the distributions commonly used to evaluate statistics on Hausman and other tests

(Staiger and Stock, 1997).

A joint F-test o f the four instruments rejects the null hypothesis that they are zero

(F(4,2929)= 6.95 for Wave 1; F(4,2388)=3.66 for Wave 2 ). Tests on the exactly

identifying instrument, a child’s gender, also show high explanatory power, but only in the

first wave (joint F (l, 2391) = 13.05 in Wave 1, and joint-Ftest of F (l, 2932)=4.04 for

Wave 2). Hence, I begin exploring some of the other instruments as exactly identifying the

system in Wave 2. I find that number of siblings is the best predictor of informal care in

Wave 2 (F(l, 2391)=12.94, p-value=0.0003).

Third, the explanatory power of the first-stage regression should be large so that the

measure of informal care is not replaced with a noisy measure. I test the explanatory power

by measuring the adjusted-R2 in the first-stage survey regression. Bollen, Guilkey and Mroz

maintain that the adjusted-R2 in the first stage should be higher than 0.1. and that when a

large number of the variables are in both stages of the equations (75 percent or more), the

adjusted-R? be higher than 0.3 (1995). I have a high amount of overlap, so I use .3 as the

benchmark.. In the overidentified system the adjusted-R2 values are .40 and .395 in waves 1

and 2 respectively. In the exactly identified system, the adjusted-R2 value is .393 in both

waves. So the explanatory power o f the first-stage regression is sufficiently high.

65

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
In summary, a child’s gender is the exactly identifying instrument in Wave 1, and the

number o f siblings is in Wave 2.

Indirect test of instruments to detect measurement error.

Finally, I check for identification of the system using a less direct approach. I run

two-stage least squares of health outcomes on informal care, accounting for the complex

survey design. I expect, controlling for all other factors, that informal care should have no

effect on the two measures of health outcomes—the number of diseases a parent has and

number of ADL’s or IADL’s a parent reports needing help with. If informal care

significantly affects a parent’s health outcomes, I expect the sign to be positive. Expecting a

positive sign is counterintuitive at first, because we may think of an informal caregiver’s role

as nursing a parent back to health. But for this age group, receipt of informal care is likely a

signal that a person’s health is in decline. This notion is supported by Weissert (1988).

Referring to informal care of the elderly, he points out that “physical and mental functioning

in the elderly is very difficult to maintain or bring back, but that contentment, on the other

hand, may be improved.”

If I do not find informal care to be insignificant in this model, I would be concerned

that measurement error—from the fact that the parent reports informal care from the child, or

from other sources—invalidates the instruments. The model is as follows:

ln( IC ) = a + b parent + d child + g instruments+ e (3.5)

\n(health outcome) = 1/C + k paren t + h (3.6)

66

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
where IC is informal care and parent, child, and instruments are the variables already

described. The first health outcome measured in equation 3.6 is the total number of ADL’s

and IADL’s that a parent reported needing help with. The mean number of activities is 1.25

but the distribution is skewed, so I take the natural log of it in the estimation. This variable is

highly correlated with informal caregiving, however (.71 for Wave 1 sample, .68 for Wave

1), which means that I could find a spurious relationship between the two variables even if

there is none. Hence, I measure a second, more objective health outcome, a composite of

disease indicators. I sum up all the following diseases that a parent experienced in the last

year: heart attack, angina, stroke, hip fracture, fall, diabetes, lung disease, arthritis, and

incontinence. (Note that I omit them from the right hand side parent variable vector) The

mean number of diseases in the sample is 1.5. A priori I expect informal caregiving to have

no effect on a parent’s disease state. There is little reason to expect a child could affect a

parent’s disease state unless it is simply that the child suspects a parent has a certain disease

and makes the parent go in and get diagnosed. I take the log of the health outcomes because

the distributions are skewed. I also add 1 to the health outcome variables for zero cases.

I ran two-stage least squares of health outcomes on informal care, controlling for

endogeneity of informal care. I ran this on both the Wave 1 and Wave 2 samples. Informal

care had no effect on ADL’s or IADL’s that a parent needed help with in either wave (more

detailed results available upon request). This is particularly reassuring since the measure for

caregiving is close to the health outcome, and that is "number of ADL’s and IADL's that all

children help with.”

For the preferred health outcome measure, number of diseases, I also find that

informal care has no statistically significant effect on the number o f diseases a parent has in

67

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
either wave. This finding helps to bolster the use of the identifying instruments in the

informal care equation. While these instruments do a good job of predicting caregiving, they

do not help at all in predicting other health outcomes. Hence, measurement error does not

appear to be a major problem.

Summary of specification tests.

I conclude from these tests that my instruments are strong based on their explanatory

power and the first-stage adjusted-R 2, that informal care is endogenous to elderly health care

utilization in some cases, both due to reverse causation and due to unobserved individual

heterogeneity, that in many cases the exclusion restrictions are valid, and that measurement

error on the instruments is not a large concern.

While I do not find informal care to be endogenous in all cases. I feel that there are

theoretical reasons which warrant use of simultaneous equation methods for all of the

utilization types. I feel I was unable to detect endogeneity in many cases because of the lack

of a statistical relationship between informal care and formal care. Mroz's recommendation

that a more liberal criteria of a = 25-50 percent be used in endogeneity tests allows for the

detection of more endogeneity across the board (Mroz. 1999).

Performance of discrete factor estimation

Given that I have a relatively simple system of equations, the main penalty of using

two-step estimation compared to DFM is a loss in precision of the estimates (Mroz, 1999). If

the two-step estimators are precise, then DFM holds little advantage over two-step estimation

68

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
because two-step estimation is unbiased if the error distribution assumptions are correct. I

have a relatively large sample size, between 2,500 and 3,000; strong instruments but a large

level o f overlap in the first and second stage variables because the system is exactly identified

(97 percent o f the variables in the first stage appear in the second stage for the exactly

identified model while 89 percent do for the over-identified model); and, an adjusted-R2 of .4

for the first stage and a pseudo-R2 o f about .2 for the second discrete stages. Hence, under

these conditions I should not experience a great loss of precision using two-step estimation.

In fact, according to David Guilkey, a leading expert in discrete factor methods, if I saw

significant changes in my results using discrete factor analysis, it would be extremely

worrying (conversation with David Guilkey, September, 2000). In addition, despite

identifying endogeneity for select types of formal care, I find that the correlation between the

error terms in the first and second stages is low, at around .0142. When error correlation is

high, Mroz (1999) found DFM to work particularly well.

Nevertheless, I wanted to measure empirically whether there was a loss in precision

from two-step estimation, so I estimated the Wave 1 home health care model using discrete

factor methods. I used LEO, a FORTRAN discrete factor analysis program written by a

graduate student at UNC. Based on Monte Carlo evidence (Mroz, 1999), I expected to need

about 4 points o f support to see improvements in the precision of the estimates in DFM

versus two-step estimation.

First, I replicated the two-step estimation results obtained in Stata using one

individual-level and one cluster-level heterogeneity parameter in LEO (hereafter called p;

and p c). After altering the starting values, holding certain coefficients constant and

69

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
estimating the system iteratively, I also obtained consistent results using one pc parameter

and two p; parameters. Consistent means results which showed a large improvement in the

value of the likelihood function over the previous one (based on a pseudo-likelihood ratio

test), and where the norm of the first partial derivative was zero (.000087). These conditions

indicate that the likelihood function has arrived at a local maximum.

Adding an additional pj, however, does not lead to a consistent answer to the

maximization problem, despite using all of the different estimation tools common to this

method of estimation. The pj and constant term on the continuous equation (of informal

care) mirrored each other, at -4.36 and 4.36 respectively, and the norm of the first partial

derivative never fell below four. Holding the discrete equation constant and estimating the

continuous equation led to coefficients of -26.53 and 26.55, respectively, an indication that it

was truly the continuous equation which was causing the problems. I also tried holding pj at

one point of support and adding cluster-level points o f support only, but the same problem

occurred. With this approach the constant and the pc term mirrored each other. Nothing that

I tried bumped the constant and heterogeneity term away from each other to allow for a local

maximum to be found. Because I could not reach a local maximum, the likelihood value was

approximately equal to the model with one less point of support and one less probability

weight. While not instructive because I knew that I was not even at a local optimum, a

likelihood ratio test (d.f.=2) indicated I stop adding points of support.

Professor David Guilkey suggested that I use a different optimization program.

OMEGA, in order to estimate non-linear heterogeneity parameters because the linear ones

70

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
were not working (meeting with Professor Guilkey, September 30,2000). Based on the

relatively precise estimates that I obtain using traditional two-step estimation, and based on

the high time costs of estimating my model using OMEGA, I deal with endogeneity using

traditional, two-step procedures in this work.

71

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
CHAPTER FOUR

DATA AND SAMPLE SELECTION

Overview of chapter

Only one nationally representative sample exists to date with extensive information

on the elderly who are most apt to need informal care, the oldest old, and their children, who

are most apt to provide informal care after a spouse. In this chapter I describe the data set,

explain the sample selection criteria, and provide definitions and descriptive statistics of

important parent and child-level variables.

The Asset and Health Dynamics Among the Oldest Old (AHEAD) Survey

I use the 1993 and 1995 waves of the Asset and Health Dynamics Among the Oldest-

Old Survey (AHEAD), conducted by the University of Michigan for the National Institute on

Aging, National Institute of Health (AHEAD; 1998,1999). AHEAD is a nationally

representative sample of the oldest-old, defined as persons over age 70 in the United States.

The data set includes respondent-level and household-level weights to adjust for complex

survey design. I use the respondent-level weights to account for differences in the probability

of respondents being selected. For example, African-Americans, Mexican-Hispanics, and

residents o f the state of Florida were sampled at about 1.8 times the probability of the general

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
population (AHEAD, 1998). In addition, AHEAD over-samples persons over 80 years of

age. AHEAD staff has already made post-stratification adjustments to match sample

demographic distributions with known 1990 Census totals (AHEAD, 1998). I use

information on the strata to account for clustering o f the data.

AHEAD contains extensive information about health care utilization of the oldest-old.

In addition, there is information about a parent’s health status, functional status, housing,

employment, income, net worth, trusts, asset transfers among family members, and health

and other types o f insurance.

The AHEAD survey is conducted every two years. It included 8,222 elderly

respondents in 1993 and 7,027 respondents in 1995. None of the respondents were

institutionalized in 1993, but subsequent waves follow respondents into nursing homes if

necessary. Since the 1993 wave was only of the non-institutionalized, it is important to note

that the surveyed population is somewhat biased towards healthier elderly individuals

(McGarry and Schoeni, 1995).

Besides extensive information on the elderly, AHEAD has extensive information on

caregiving behavior of children—by task, by hours of care provided, and by whether the

caregiver was paid or not. This is reported by the parent or by proxy respondents for the

elderly respondent. Besides child informal care information, there is information about a

child’s marital status, number of offspring, a child’s employment status, income, transfers to a

parent, distance from a parent, and other variables. There is also information about the

child’s spouse, which I am unable to use due to prevalence of missing values. Not

surprisingly, missing data on children is a problem for portions of the sample, especially

when there is a proxy respondent.

73

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
There have been criticisms in the literature of AHEAD’s informal care measure. In

particular, Pezzin and Schone (1999c) report that the AHEAD survey underestimates the

incidence of both formal and informal care due to the way caregiving questions are asked for

ADL’s versus IADL’s. In the case of IADL’s the respondent may list up to two persons who

help the respondent the most, whereas in the case of ADL’s only the one person who helps

the most is listed. Since these helpers could be home health care providers (hence formal

care) or children (hence informal care) they claim both are underestimated in the survey.

In addition. Wolf and colleagues (1997) point out that while the AHEAD baseline

survey does not capture all child caregivers consistently, such as those who provide few hours

of care, the data yield a more comprehensive picture of family caregiving than heretofore

available (Wolf et al., 1997).

Sample selection criteria

Because married and single elderly differ in many respects (Stone and Short, 1990

citing Horowitz 1985), I limit the analysis to single elderly with living offspring, the majority

of whom are women. The single elderly may be widowed, divorced, separated, or never

married. Further, I classify as single those individuals who are married but whose spouses do

not live in the household, since they resemble the single elderly closely in their potential for

needing informal care from offspring.

While I use two waves from AHEAD, I do not create a panel of data in the traditional

sense. I first draw a sample of the single elderly from Wave 1 of AHEAD based on specific

selection criteria. Using this sample I estimate informal care’s effect on utilization in Wave

74

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
1. Then, using all of the same people who were interviewed a second time in Wave 2 ,1 look

at the effect of informal caregiving on utilization in Wave 2. In other words, I base my

analysis on informal care and parent characteristics in Wave 1 to predict separately utilization

in wave one and two. This design was dictated by delays in the release of child-level

variables in Wave 2, which I use both for the informal care measure and for the instrumental

variables, but there are some advantages to my approach. Using informal care in Wave 1 to

predict formal care in Wave 2 controls for temporal endogeneity. In addition, the unbalanced

recall periods on utilization in the two waves makes it difficult to combine the two periods.

The sample of single elderly was reduced due to missing values on important

variables. For missing values on dependent variables, the observations were dropped.

Typically, for those with missing values, there were missing values on some utilization types

but not others. Instead of dropping the respondent if any of the five utilization types was

missing, I only omitted them for the specific utilization type that was missing. So the sample

actually differs slightly by utilization type in the analysis, but not by more than 5 or 10

observations from the one reported here in most cases. The exception is doctor’s use in Wave

2, where missing values are prevalent.

For missing explanatory variables, I was able to resolve some by checking Wave 1

values against Wave 2 values in order to assign values to time invariant variables. For values

which could not be assigned (mainly child-level variables), I either created a missing variable

or I dropped the observation. For example, for individuals with long-term care insurance

status missing, I replaced the missing value with a zero, and changed the long-term care

insurance missing variable to a 1. This allowed a check for whether missingness was random

or not rather than simply throwing out observations with missing explanatory variables.

75

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
The following table shows the different attributes that a respondent had to have in

order to be selected into the Wave 1 and Wave 2 samples.

Table 2. Sample Selection Criteria

Respondent attributes Wave 1 Wave 2

Single in Wave 1 x x
Living adult offspring in Wave 1 x x
Seventy or above in Wave 1 x x
Interviewed in Wave 1 and 2_________________________ x_
Total number o f single elderly 2,985 2,444

To qualify to be in the sample for Wave 1, a respondent had to be single in Wave 1.

70 years or older, and have living offspring above age 18. The table below. Table 3. shows

the reduction of the sample from the original number, 8,222 to the final one used in Wave 1.

Table 3. Selection of Wave 1 Sample of the Single Elderly______ Obs.

1. Total number of respondents in Wave 1 8,222


2. Drop Wave 1 respondents who are married with spouse
present or are living with a partner 3,728
3. Drop Wave 1 respondents under age 70 in 1993 3,704
4. Drop Wave I respondents with no children alive in Wave 1
or with other dependents reported who are not children 3,013
5. Drop Wave 1 respondents with children only under age 18 3,012
6. Drop Wave 1 respondents with missing information on
key child-level explanatory variables. 2,985

A little less than half o f the respondents were single in Wave 1. A handful of

respondents were not age-eligible (24) and a little under 700 had no children or no age-

eligible children. Finally, 27 respondents were dropped due to missing values on key child-

76

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
level variables: child’s gender, marital status, number of siblings, and number of offspring.

This represents under one percent of the sample, so dropping these due to missing values

should not bias the sample. The final number of single elderly analyzed in Wave 1 was

2,985.

Similar qualifications apply to the Wave 2 sample. To be included, a respondent had

to be single in Wave 2,70 years or older in Wave 1, interviewed in both waves, and have

living offspring in Wave 1 (see Table 2). The respondents had to be interviewed in both

waves because the informal care and child information comes from Wave 1 while the

utilization information is from Wave 2.

Table 4. Selection o f Wave 2 Sample of the Single Elderly_____________Obs.

1.Total number o f respondents in Wave 2 7.027


2.Drop Wave 2 respondents who were married with spouse
present or living with a partner in Wave 1 3.120
3.Drop Wave 2 respondents under age 70 in 1993 3.100
4.Drop Wave 2 respondent who were new in Wave 2 2.590
5.Drop Wave 2 respondents with missing information on all
utilization types 2.585
6. Drop Wave 2 respondents with no children alive in Wave 1
or with other dependents who are not children 2.477
7. Drop Wave 2 respondents with children only under age 18 2.476
8. Drop Wave 2 respondents with missing information on
child-level explanatory variables which could not be resolved. 2,444

From the 8,222 original respondents in Wave 2, only 7,027 were interviewed two

years later. Assuming that the majority of those missing in Wave 2 died, my sample in Wave

2 is biased towards healthier individuals, and I may be underestimating the amount of

informal care by children and the amount of utilization occurring for the second wave.

Comparisons of descriptive statistics (not reported here) confirm that the individuals who

77

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
were absent from Wave 2 had more functional limitations and received more informal

caregiving than those who were alive in both waves. So my estimation o f informal care’s

effect on utilization in Wave 2 is conservative, and may be an underestimation of total

informal care activity in the U.S.. This is potentially exacerbated by only being able to use

informal care measures from the first wave.

From the original number of 7,027, more than half of the Wave 2 respondents were

disqualified because they were married in Wave 1. About 20 were dropped because they

were not age-eligible in Wave 1. I use Wave 1 as the criteria so that we do not have younger

individuals entering the Wave 2 sample (new widows of age-eligible males from Wave 1)

which could further bias the sample towards the healthy. About 510 respondents were

dropped because they were not interviewed in Wave 1. This was overwhelmingly due to

being a long term nursing home respondent during Wave I interviews. I dropped five

individuals who had missing information on all of the dependent variables for utilization.

About 108 of those remaining had no living offspring in Wave 1 and had to be dropped.

Finally, I dropped respondents who only had children under the age o f 18, and children with

missing values on important child-level variables. The final sample for Wave 2 totals 2.444

respondents.

Description of the dependent variables: Wave 1 and Wave 2

As mentioned in the Methods section (Chapter 3), I use five different elderly health

care utilization measures as the dependent variables in five statistical models: home health

78

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
care utilization, nursing home utilization, in-patient hospital utilization, outpatient surgery,

and doctor’s visits. I look at utilization in two different time periods, in 1992-93 and 1993-

1995. Table 5 reports summary statistics on the formal care variables for Waves I and 2.

These descriptive statistics are weighted by the probability of being selected into the sample.

It is important to note that the recall period for Waves 1 and 2 were not uniform. In

Wave 1 respondents were asked about utilization in the past 12 months, while in Wave 2 they

were asked about utilization since the interviewer’s last visit (giving a date to anchor the

recall period), which is a two year recall period in general. In repeating the questions here I

report from Wave 1, but Wave 2 has identical questions except for the recall period.

For home health care, I use a discrete measure, which is comprised of information

from several questions in the helper file of AHEAD about assistance with ADL's and

IADL’s. For example, respondents were asked, “Who most often helps you move across the

room?” or “Who most often helps you make phone calls?” One of the response options is

“organization or agency," and another is “other individual (non-relative)”. If the response was

“organization,” home health care is coded one for yes. If it was “other individual,” then only

if that individual was paid (either by insurance, the respondent, or on behalf of the respondent

by some other party) do I consider the help to be home health care. The home health care

measure is restrictive in that I only capture assistance with ADL’s and IADL’s, and do not

include highly skilled care. The advantage of this is that this type of home health care is the

type that informal caregivers are most likely to replace. The disadvantage is that I am not

encompassing all types o f formal home health care, such as physical therapy, RN-visits, and

so forth.

79

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.

T ab le 5. Form al care p attern s o f the single elderly in W ave 1 o f A H E A D com pared to W ave 2

Form al care in past y e ar ( 1992-199 3 ) Form al care in past 2 years (1 9 9 3 -199 5 )

N u m b er Std. N u m ber Std.


F orm al care d escription o fO b s M ean Dev. M in__ M ax______ o f O b s M ean D ev. M in M ax

H om e H ealth C are
A ny hom e health care v isits 2,985 .10 .30 0 I 2,444 .08 .28 0 I

N u rsin g H om e C are
A ny n u rsin g hom e stay s 2,985 .02 .14 0 1 2,444 .09 .29 0 1
N ig h ts in a n ursing hom e 53 4 5 .5 0 53.97 I 30 0 211 408.28 438.21
00
o
H osp ital C are
A ny in patient hosp ital care 2,984 .24 .43 0 1 2,418 .38 .48 0 1
T im es in hospital 707 1.59 1.25 1 20 903 1.95 2.53 I 75

O u tp atien t C are
A ny o u tp atien t su rg ery 2981 .14 .35 0 I 2,444 .20 .40 0 I

P hysician care
A ny v isits to th e d o c to r 2 ,9 8 0 .89 .31 0 I 2,337 .95 .22 0 1
N u m b er o f visits to th e d o c to r_______________________2 ,6 1 9 5.65 5.79 I_____50_________ 2,218 10.90 12.90_____ 1 250
_

S O U R C E : A sset and H ealth D y nam ics o f the O ldest O ld Survey, W aves I and 2.
There are questions on frequency of visits by a helper and the usual number of hours

of help on those days, allowing for an average hours per month o f home health care measure

to be calculated. However, I am not able to use this measure in my analysis. First of all,

missing values on hours o f help are prevalent. Second, hours were recorded only for

individuals receiving help more than once a week. In Wave 1.10 percent of the sample had

home health care use while in Wave 2, 8 percent did (see Table 5).

For nursing home care there are more straightforward discrete and continuous

measure of use. A respondent was asked, “During the last 12 months, have you been a

patient overnight in a nursing home, convalescent home, or other long-term health care

facility?" In addition respondents were asked about number of nights and number of times

they had such use in the last 12 months. I use number of nights as the continuous measure,

since it is more reflective of severity of disability than number of times in a nursing home.

Nursing home care is likely to be homogenous, although it is unclear what other types of

“long-term health care facilities” were included, for example, assisted living facilities or

board-and-care homes. Since the definition is limited to “health care" facility, retirement

homes and group homes are unlikely to be included. In Wave 2, there are new questions on

many different types o f long-term care facilities, including assisted living facilities, so

nursing home use may truly be limited to nursing home and assisted living facilities in Wave

2.

Recalling that Wave 1 respondents had to be non-institutionalized to qualify- it is not

surprising that about 2 percent o f the sample used nursing homes in Wave 1, while a much

higher proportion, 9 percent, did in Wave 2 (Table 5). The stays were also much longer in

Wave 2 than in Wave 1, at 408 nights and 45 nights respectively. The mean number of

81

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
nights is extremely high in Wave 2 because of the large number of persons who were in the

nursing home for the entire two year recall period. Depending on the date of the interviews

from Wave 1 to Wave 2, a respondent could have been in a nursing home for a maximum of

1,098 days in Wave 2. In Wave 1 the respondent had to be at home to be interviewed, hence

the nursing home use was for short-stays primarily.

Regarding inpatient hospital utilization, AHEAD asked, “In the past 12 months, have

you been a patient in a hospital overnight?", as well as, “How many different times were you

a patient in a hospital overnight in the last 12 months?" I also could have used a continuous

measure on nights of hospital use, but chose number of times because there were fewer

missing values and because nights in the hospital were not broken down by stay (AHEAD,

1998 ).

In Wave 1,24 percent o f the single elderly had any hospital visits, while in Wave 2. a

much higher 38 percent did (recall the unequal recall periods for the two waves). Number of

visits to the hospital averaged 1.59 in Wave 1, and 1.95 in Wave 2 (Table 5).

The measure of outpatient surgery is a discrete measure. The survey asked, “(Not

counting overnight hospital stays), during the last 12 months have you had outpatient

surgery?" In Wave 1 ,14 percent received outpatient surgery, while 20 percent did in Wave 2.

Finally, I analyze doctor’s visits in the past year and past two years for Wave 1 and

Wave 2 respondents. In Wave 1, respondents were asked “During the last 12 months, have

you seen a medical doctor about your health?" If so, the next question was, “How many

times have you talked to a medical doctor (about your own health)?” Unfortunately, in Wave

2 the respondents were only asked, “How many times have you seen or talked to a medical

doctor about your health, including emergency room or clinic visits?" Because there is not a

82

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
discrete lead-in question, the prevalence of missing values is high. The recall period of 2

years is simply too long for people to estimate how many visits they may have had since

going to the doctor can be a common event for the oldest-old. In Wave 2,4.2 percent had

missing values on doctor’s visits compared to only 0.2 percent in Wave 1, an increase of

2,000 percent. Overall, 89 percent of respondents had doctor’s visits in Wave I, while 95

percent did in Wave 2. The average number of visits was 5.65 and 10.90 respectively (See

Table 5).

Description of informal care and other child-level characteristics: Wave 1

I explore both a discrete and continuous measure of informal care in the utilization

models to see which form adds the most predictive power. The discrete measure shows

whether any child provided any informal care. The continuous measure is the total number of

1/ADL’s that all children in the family assisted with. I also explored using total hours of care,

but there were too many missing values and it was not as robust a measure as number of

1/ADL’s. I decided after preliminary analysis to use the measure of total number of I/ADL's

that a parent received from all offspring rather than the discrete measure, because it best

reflected the total quantity of informal care a parent received.

Some evidence exists that primary informal caregivers provide all but 11.5 percent of

all informal care, with this being provided by secondary or third caregivers (Christianson,

1988). This is even more extreme in my data set, as all but 3.5 percent of all informal care by

children came from one child (part o f this was due to the way the measure of caregivers was

limited). The remainder came from two children (3.32 percent) or three children (0.2

83

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
percent). Nonetheless, I define the quantity o f informal care from all child sources in the

analysis. By aggregating across all children instead of measuring care from only one child, I

do not lose the 3.5 percent of care provided by secondary and tertiary caregivers.

Even though I am able to aggregate informal care from all children, because the unit

of observation for the utilization models is the parent, I needed to have only one informal

caregiving equation with one set of child-level instruments per parent. This is a problem

when there is more than one offspring per parent. It is not possible to include all of the child

caregivers as separate observations in the model due to the endogenous nature o f informal

care, and the lack of unique identifying instruments for more than one first-stage informal

care equation. I could not identify the system if I included two informal caregiving variables

in the utilization models, say “primary caregiver" and “secondary caregiver" because the same

instruments would be relevant for both. I explore achieving this two different ways, first by

selecting a primary caregiver from all of the children, and second by averaging the child-level

characteristics.

In the first approach, I develop a model from the sample of all children o f the single

elderly to select the child most likely to provide care to the parent. This model uses many of

the same variables in the informal care equation (equation 3.2) except that it is a logit model

predicting the probability of providing any care to a parent. Using the coefficient estimates

from the selection model, I created predicted probabilities of the likelihood of providing any

informal care. The child in a family who had the highest predicted probability o f providing

care was selected as the primary caregiver and included in the main samples. I did this

separately for Wave 1 and Wave 2. If the child selected based on the predicted probability

84

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
provided no care but another child provided care, then the predicted probability score was

overridden and the child providing care was selected instead.

In the second approach, I aggregated children by family and calculated averages of

their attributes to use as instruments. This is done in the intra-household decision making

literature when parent-level data and child-level data must be matched to examine parent-

level outcomes. Hence, whereas one of the child-level variables in the primary caregiver

approach is “age of the child," in the aggregated caregiver approach it is measured as

“average age of all of the children." To give an example of the difference in dichotomous

child-level variables in the two approaches, in the primary caregiving model there is a

variable “live more than ten miles from the parent." whereas in the aggregate caregiver

analysis this variable is measured as “percent of children living more than ten miles away

from the parent.” I chose the primary caregiver approach over this one because so much of

the care was provided by only one caregiver, because it was easier to interpret the

coefficients, and because it had higher explanatory power.

A comparison of the characteristics of all children of the single elderly in the sample

(tV=9,136), and the children selected as primary caregivers (iV=2,985 in Wave 1 and W=2,444

in Wave 2) appears in Table 6. While 9 percent of all children provided any irformal care to

a parent, 23 percent o f parents received informal care from at least one child in Wave 1. In

Wave 2,22 percent of parents received some informal care. Those with positive informal

care received help with 2 1/ADL’s on average in Wave 1, and 1.86 in Wave 2.

Looking at the child-level instruments used (in bold in Table 6), it is clear that

daughters are more likely than sons to provide informal care. Seventy-two to seventy-three

percent o f the primary caregivers selected were daughters. Informal caregivers were also less

85

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.

Table 6. Factors driving supply o f informal caregiving by adult children

All children (N = 9.136) Wave 1 careeivers (/V=2.985) Wave 2 careeivers (N=7


Child characteristics Mean Std. Dev. Mean Std. Dev. Mean Std. Dev

Caregiving activity
Gave any help with l/ADL’s .09 .44 .23 .42 .22 .41
Number o f I/ADL’s helped with if any 2.14 .28 2.00 1.57 1.86 1.40
Identifying instruments
Daughter .50 .50 .72 .45 .73 .44
Married .68 .47 .58 .49 .58 .49
Number of children 2.23 1.76 2.00 1.59 1.99 1.57
Missing value on number o f children .03 .16 0 0 0 0
Number of siblings n.a. n.a 2.25 2.40 2.26 2.31
Annual Household Income
Income between $0-20,000 .16 .37 ..25 ..43 .23 .42
Income between $20,001-30,000 .11 .31 .12 .33 .12 .32
Income between 30,001-50,000 .19 .39 .18 .38 .19 .40
. Income over $50,000 .18 .38 .15 .36 .16 .37
Income between $0-30,000 .03 .16 .04 .19 .04 .19
Income over $30,000 .05 .22 .03 .16 .02 .15
Income between $0-50,000 .04 .20 .03 .16 .03 .17
Income is missing .25 .43 .21 .41 .21 .40
Other demographic characteristics
Step child .05 .22 .025 .15 .02 .15
Age 49.34 9.12 49.41 9.47 48.86 9.45
Age missing .04 .19 .02 .13 .01 .11
Child works .73 .44 .69 .46 .71 .46
Missing value on work .05 .21 .02 .14 .01 .12
Child lives at least 10 miles away .68 .47 .67 .47 .66 .47
Transfer behavior
Received $5,000+ fr. parent in last 10 yrs. .09 .29 .13 .34 .13 .34
Received $500 or more from parent in last year .10 .30 .16 .37 .16 .37
Owns deed to parent’s house .03 .17 .04 .19 .04 .20
Gives parent financial assistance .02 .14 .03 .16 .03 .16
Parent asks child for advice .23 .42 .31 .46 .30 .46
NOTES; Probability weights used to calculate means. Bold variable descriptions indicate identifying instruments used.
SOURCE: Asset and Health Dynamics of the Oldest Old, 1993, 1995.
likely to be married than the sample of all children, at about 58 percent versus 68 percent.

Primary caregivers also tended to have slightly fewer children (1.99-2.00) than the sample of

all children (2.23). The last instrument used, number of siblings, was a parent-level variable,

and averaged about 2.25-2.26 for primary caregivers.

There are other child-level variables in AHEAD that help characterize informal

caregivers. Primary caregivers averaged 49 years of age, about 69-71 percent of them

worked, and about 66-67 percent o f them lived more than ten miles away from their parents.

Surprisingly, this last statistic does not differ much at all from non-caregivers. Looking at

other distance thresholds may be more indicative (1 hour driving time or longer). Not

surprisingly, step children are much less likely to be the primary caregiver, at 2.5 percent

versus 5 percent in the sample of all children.

The income measure is total household income for the child and a spouse, as reported

by the parent. Because continuous income values were not reported for a significant

proportion of the children, I was only able to explore using categorical controls for the child’s

income. There are many missing values for income, which is not surprising since the elderly

parent reported income of the child. In both waves 21 percent o f the primary caregivers had

missing income values, while income was missing for 25 percent o f all children. McGarry

and Schoeni surmised that a missing income value may indicate that the parent and child do

not have a close relationship, hence the parent is unable to report a value for the child (1995).

There may be other reasons as well, however, such as a proxy respondent not knowing, or a

parent not wanting to give out sensitive information.

Primary caregivers are more likely to be in the $0-520,000 income range than all of

the children (23-25 percent). However, they are about equally likely as their siblings to have

87

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
income over $50,000 a year (19 percent). Note that some categories are upper and lower

bounded while other ones cover a wider range. It is difficult to know where in the distribution

the children are when the parent reports $0-50,000, making the income measures somewhat

imprecise in all.

Looking at transfer behavior between children and parents, we see that while 9

percent of children received $5,000 from their parent in the past 10 years, 13 percent of

primary caregivers did. A similar pattern exists for smaller transfers. About 10 percent of all

children received $500 from a parent in the past year, while 16 percent of caregivers did.

Sometimes parent’s may transfer property instead of cash to their children. However,

here we see that few children own the deed to their parent’s house, at 3-4 percent. Looking at

transfers from children to parents, a similar pattern exists. Few parents reported receiving

financial assistance from their children in the past year, at about 2 percent for all children and

only 3 percent for caregivers. Finally, it is not surprising that about 30 percent of parents

report asking primary caregivers for advice on important decisions while only 23 percent of

all children are asked.

Description of key parent-level explanatory variables: Wave 1

The formal and informal care models control for parent-level variables that

sociologists, demographers, aging experts, and economists have determined affect health care

utilization of the elderly. The parent-level summary statistics are listed in Table 7.

88

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
T able 7. Factors driving single elderly p aren t’s dem and for inform al caregiving, w ave 1 (A/=2,985)

Standard
V ariable description M ean D eviation M in M ax

(N = 2,985)

H ealth Status Indicators


N eed help w ith ADLs .36 .48 0 1
N eed h elp w ith IADLs .33 .47 0 t

N u m b er o f A D L s need help with 2.31 1.54 0 6


N u m b er o f IA D L s need help w ith 2.01 1.31 0 5
N u m b er o f d ays in bed in past m onth 1.24 4.64 0 31
Self-rated health (l= excellent, 5=poor) 3.10 1.18 1 5
Self-rated eyesight (l= ex c. 6=leg. blind) 2.98 1.14 1 6

A cute illnesses/C hronic health conditions


H eart attack last 5 years (M I included) .07 .25 0 1
A n g in a o r ch est pains recently .10 .30 0 1
Stroke (inclu d es TTA’s) ever .11 .32 0 1
Fractured hip ever .06 .24 0 I
M ajo r fall past 12 months .28 .45 0 1
D iabetic now .13 .34 0 1
C an cer ever .14 .35 0 1
L ung disease ever .12 .33 0 1
A rthritis p a st 12 months .29 .46 0 1
Incontinence past 12 m onths .24 .43 0 1
H igh blood pressure ever .53 .50 0 I

H ealth B eh av io r
C u rren t cigarette smoker .10 .30 0 1
Form er cigarette smoker .34 .47 0 1
F eels sho u ld drin k less alcohol .11 .31 0 1

D em ographic inform ation


A ge 79.00 6.34 70 103
M ale .18 .39 0 10
W hite .86 .35 0 1
B lack .12 .33 0 1
A n o th er race .02 .14 0 1
C onsid ers s e lf Hispanic .05 .21 0 1
R esid es in rural area .28 .45 0 1

Im portance o f R eligion in life


V ery im portant .70 .46 0 1

S o m ew h at im portant .2 1 .40 0 1

N o t at all im portant .09 .29 0 1

Y ears o f E d ucation Com pleted 10.47 3.65 0 17

89

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
T able 7. Factors d riving single elderly parent's dem and for inform al caregiving, wave I, continued.

Standard
V ariable description M ean Deviation Min Ma

(V=2,985)

R espondent w orks .07 .25 0 1


H ousehold incom e 20,484 25,527 0 700,00(
N et w orth (all assets m inus all debts) 115,162 271,372 139,898 6,104.050

Insurance status
M edicare P art A .97 .16 0 1
M edicare P art B .93 .26 0 1
M edicaid .14 .35 0 1
M issing M edicaid inform ation .005 .068 0 1
O th e r private insurance .70 .46 0 1
M issing o th er insurance inform ation .010 .097 0 1
L ong-term care (L T C ) insurance .13 .34 0 1
M issing LTC insurance inform ation .09 .28 0 1

Proxy respondent .10 .30 0 1

C are
R eceive any inform al care .25 .43 0 1
N u m b er o f I/A D L ’s caregiver(s) help w ith 2.00 1.57 1 9

N O TES: Probability w eights used in calculation o f m eans.


SOURCE: A sset and Health D ynam ics A m ong the O ldest O ld, 1993.

90

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
First, to give an idea of the general health status of the elderly in the sample, we see

that about 36 percent reported needing help with physical functioning tasks, or ADL’s, while

33 percent need help with cognitive tasks, or IADL’s. For those who needed help, on average

they needed help with 2.3 ADL’s and 2 IADL’s. These variables are highly correlated with

the measure of caregiving, “total number of ADL’s and IADL’s a parent receives help with

from all children,” and are not included in the model.

Instead, the health of the single elderly is controlled for using several indicators.

First, I control for self-assessed health status. On average the single elderly in my sample

rated their health status as “good” (3.1). A score of “5” means poor health and a “ 1” means

excellent. I also control for self-rated corrected eyesight, where the mean respondent

considers her eyesight to be “good” (2.98 score)

Health shock controls include: heart attack (7 percent), stroke (11 percent), hip

fracture (6 percent), and falls (28 percent), all o f which had to occur in the last year. I also

control for health conditions such as diabetes (13 percent), arthritis (29 percent), incontinence

(24 percent), high blood pressure (53 percent), lung disease (12 percent), and cancer (14

percent). For these, the recall period is generally vague. For example, for cancer the wording

is “Has a medical provider ever told you that you have cancer?” Others ask about the last

five years.

There are a limited number of health behaviors in AHEAD that I use. About 10

percent o f the single elderly were current smokers, while a much larger 34 percent were

former smokers. About 11 percent of respondents felt they drink too much alcohol.

91

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
In terms of the demographic profile, the average respondent was a white, urban-

dwelling woman who was 79 years old in 1992-93, had less than a high school education (10

years completed), and viewed religion to be very important in her life.

AHEAD respondents are weighted to reflect the ethnic and racial make-up of the

elderly population in the U.S., and using the probability weights my sample reflects this

diversity. About 12 percent o f the respondents were African-American, 2 percent were

another non-white race, and 5 percent were Hispanic. Only about 7 percent of the

respondents reported working at the time of the interview, which is not surprising given the

mean age and the gender composition of this cohort. The mean income was $20,000 and the

mean wealth (as measured by net worth) was $115.162.

Health insurance characteristics show the near universal coverage of Medicare, with

97 percent of the respondents receiving Medicare Part A, and 93 percent receiving Medicare

Part B. About 14 percent had Medicaid. Nearly 70 percent purchased some other form of

private insurance (could be Medigap), while about 13 percent had long-term care insurance.

Long-term care insurance information was missing for a significant number of respondents (9

percent), so I create a missing variable to control for this being non-random.

Proxy respondents were used for about 10 percent of the single elderly. Missing from

the model are depression or cognition indicators, which have been found to be important in

other informal care studies. Because cognitive scores and depression scores were compiled

differently for those with proxy respondents and those without, I could not compute a

cohesive measure for these characteristics that was not too highly (less than 0.7) correlated

with proxy. Leaving these out, it is up to the proxy variable to explain imperfectly depression

or impaired cognition.

92

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Finally, we see at the bottom of Table 7 that 25 percent of all parents received

informal care, while in the table of child caregivers, (Table 6) it shows that 23 percent of all

children provided care. The discrepancy is explained by the fact that I attribute care from

grandchildren and other dependents who are “like” children to be the same as “child-

provided” informal care. This contributed to 2 percent of all informal care.

93

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
CHAPTER FIVE

RESULTS: EFFECTS OF INFORMAL CARE ON FORMAL HEALTH

CARE UTILIZATION OF THE SINGLE ELDERLY

Overview of chapter

In this section I present the main results on how informal caregiving of the single

elderly by their children affects formal care utilization. My econometric models confirm that

informal care of the elderly can significantly reduce many types of formal care use. First I

provide a detailed profile o f the home health care and nursing home models, along with some

realistic simulation scenarios on how changes in informal care provision would affect home

health care use and nursing home use in the immediate and longer-term. I also present

simulation results for other key variables. Next I summarize the findings for hospital use.

outpatient procedures, and doctor’s visits, for which informal care has a less consistent causal

relationship. Then I discuss some sensitivity tests on the robustness of the utilization model

results.

I end the chapter by discussing the results of the first-stage estimation, “What

determines a child’s provision of informal care to a parent?”

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
How does informal care affect formal care of the single elderly?

Informal care has a great ability to replace home health care and nursing home care.

Informal care had less of an effect on acute or routine care, which is what I expected, since

this care is much less like informal care. Table 8 shows the informal care coefficients for all

five different utilization types, differentiated by method (one-step or two-step estimation) and

by timing of utilization (Wave 1 or Wave 2). The other parent-level controls are suppressed

in order to focus on informal care.

There are major differences in the results across the three primary domains of the

analysis—differences (1) between one-step and two-step estimation methods, (2) between

Wave 1 and Wave 2, and (3) between the discrete and continuous measures of formal care.

First, for all utilization types there are stark differences in the results between one-step

estimation and two-step estimation, which controls for endogeneity of informal care— signs

switched from positive to negative or the reverse, and p-values switched from insignificant to

significant or the reverse. Standard errors also increased when controlling for endogeneity, as

expected.

Recalling the specification test results from Chapter 3 ,1 detect endogeneity between

informal care and other long-term care, namely, home health and nursing home care, but not

between informal care and acute and routine care. There was positive endogeneity bias in all

o f the models for which endogeneity was detected. For example, if endogeneity had not

been controlled for any nursing home use, we would have concluded that informal care

served as a net complement

95

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.

T ab le 8. E ffect o f inform al care on utilization patterns o f the single elderly, by an aly sis type, W ave I and W ave 2

F orm al care in past y ear ( 19 9 2 -1 9 9 3 ) Form al care in past 2 years ( 1 9 9 3 -1 9 9 5 )

N u m b er O ne-step T w o -ste p N um ber O n e-step T w o -S te p


D epen d en t variab le______________________________ o f O bs.________ E stim ation E stim ation___________ o f O bs. E stim ation E stim ation

H om e H ealth C are
A n y h o m e health care visits 2,985 .043 —5.17**§ 2,444 .153** -.79
(.057) (2.09) (.076) (1.20)
N u rsin g H om e C are

*
*
00
cn
coo
A n y n u rsin g hom e stays 2,985 .267** 2,444 .147* -2.87**§

1
(.104) (4.13) (.076) (1.46)

N atu ral log o f nig h ts in a n u rsing hom e 53 .092** -.04 211 .124 1.64
(.045) (3 8 ) (.077) (5.5)
H ospital C are
A ny inpatient hospital care 2,984 .082 .44 2,418 .061 -.66
(.052) (.47) (.062) (.73)

N atu ral log o f tim es in hospital 707 .000 .05 903 .031 -.06
(.017) (10 ) (.024) (.22)
O u tp atien t C are
A n y o u tp atien t surgery 2,981 .066 -.02 2,444 -.25*** .42
(.065) (58) (08) (98)
P hysician C are
A n y visits to th e d o cto r 2,980 -.048 .47 2,337 -.14 2.44
(.102) (.65) (.18) (1.87)

N atu ral log o f visits to th e d o cto r 2,619 -.029* -.08 2,218 .024 -.41
(017) (.15) (.025) (31 )
O th e r p a re n t-le v e l co n tro ls used? Y es Y es Yes Y es
C o n tro ls fo r en d o g en eity ? No Y es Partially Y es
N O TES: * S ignificant at th e 10 percent level. ** S ignificant at the 5 percent level *** S ignificant at the I percent level.
§ Indicates that en d o g eneity w as detected. A ll estim atio n s use probability w eights and account for th e design effect.
(P = .267) to nursing home care, rather than a net substitute (P = -8.3).

Second, informal care has a generally weaker effect on formal care by Wave 2, which

is expected because we do not know whether informal care persisted into the second wave.

Also, using informal care in Wave 1 to predict utilization in Wave 2 eliminates endogeneity

bias in the case of home health care but not nursing home care.

Third, in all but one case, informal care has no effect on any of the continuous

measures of formal care. In general, once a particular type of care is sought, informal care

can not increase or decrease the amount.

In-depth look at informal care’s effect on home health care

Im m ediate effect

Informal care significantly reduced the likelihood of any home health care in Wave 1

(column 2 of Table 9) after controlling for endogeneity. Only having a proxy respondent had

a stronger (and counter-balancing) effect. Because I detected endogeneity, here I discuss the

findings from the two-step estimation.

Having poorer health led to significantly more home health care use for many of the

dimensions of health measured in the model. Having lower self-rated health status and

poorer eyesight increased the probability of home health care use significantly, as did the

number of days a person spent in bed in the past month. In addition, many acute illness

episodes increased the chance of home health care use, whether they occurred in the last year

(major fall, incontinence, diabetes) or ever (stroke or TIA, fractured hip). Of these, stroke,

incontinence and hip fracture led to the largest increases in the likelihood of home health care

97

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
T ab le 9. O ne an d tw o -ste p estim ation o f inform al care and other characteristics’ effect on any hom e
health care, both im m ediately and two years later (W ave 1 and W ave 2 o f A H E A D )

Im m ediate formal care S u b sequent form al care


T w o-step estim ation O ne-step estim ation
V a ria b le D e sc rip tio n C o eff. / (SE ) C o e f f / (S E )

In fo r m a l c a r e /P r e d ic te d In fo rm a l ca re -5 .1 7 * * 0.1534**
(2.09) (0 .0762)
H e a lth S ta tu s In d ic a to rs
Self-rated health( ^ e x c e lle n t, 5=poor) 0.531*** 0.3364***
(0.157) (0 .0 9 0 3 )

Self-rated eyesight (l= ex cellen t, 6= blind) 0.2686*** 0.0256*


(0.0992) (0 .0154)

N u m b er o f days in bed in past m onth 0.573*** -0 .0 1 1 3


(0.178) (0 .0 9 0 6 )
A c u te illn e sse s a n d c h r o n ic h ea lth c o n d itio n s
H eart attack last 5 years (M I included) 0.395 -0 .3 7 9
(0.253) (0 .364)

A n g in a o r ch est pains recently -0 .3 8 5 -0 .6 1 3 *


(0.250) (0 .342)

Stroke (includes T IA 's) ever 2.274*** 0.553**


(0.643) (0 .2 2 3 )

M ajo r fall past 12 m onths 0.729*** 0.558***


(0.261) (0 .1 7 9 )

F ractured hip ever 1.575*** 0.144


(0.530) (0 .3 0 8 )

D iabetic now 0.656*** 0.149


(0.212) (0.244)

C an cer ever 0.035 0.284


(0.213) (0 .220)

L ung disease ever -0 .3 5 7 0.160


(0.305) (0 .2 7 2 )

A rthritis p a st 12 m onths 0.230 0.344**


(0.157) (0 .1 7 6 )

Incontinence p ast 12 m onths 1.737*** 0.098


(0.524) (0 .1 8 9 )

98

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
T able 9. O ne an d tw o -ste p estim atio n o f inform al care and o ther characteristics’ effect on any hom e
health care, bo th im m ediately a n d tw o -y e a rs later (W ave 1 and W ave 2 o f A H E A D )

Im m ediate form al care S ubsequent form al care


T w o-step estim ation O ne-step estim ation

V a ria b le D e sc rip tio n ________________________ C o e ff. / (S E ) _____________ C o e f f / (SE ) __________

H igh blood pressure ev er -0 .2 1 3 -0 .1 7 7


(0.156) (0.175)
H ea lth b e h a v io r
C u rren t cigarette sm oker -0 .0 5 9 -0 .0 8 0
(0.289) (0.330)

F orm er cigarette sm oker 0.400* 0.137


(0.206) (0.202)

Feels sho u ld drink less alco h o l 0.690*** -0 .0 9 1


(0.232) (0.314)
D e m o g r a p h ic c h a ra c te ristic s
A ge 0.2581*** 0.0667***
(0.0648) (0.0138)

M ale -0 .8 1 2 * * * -0 .7 6 4 * *
(0.238) (0.294)
R ace (w hite is reference)
B lack 0.180 0.440*
(0.247) (0.244)

O th e r race 0.063 -0 .2 3 2
(0.387) (0.734)

C onsiders s e lf H ispanic 0.247 -0 .1 6 7


(0.296) (0.379)

R esides in rural area -0 .5 6 4 * * 0.327*


(0.277) (0.190)
Im p o r ta n c e o f re lig io n (v e r y is refere n ce J
S om ew hat im portant 0.422** 0.331
(0.199) (0.212)

N o t at all im portant -0 .4 2 3 0.413


(0.404) (0.293)

Y e a rs o f e d u c a tio n c o m p le te d -0 .0 1 2 9 0.0257
(0.0299) (0.0316)

R esp o n d en t w orks -0 .5 7 4 -1 .6 7 3 * *
(0.572) (0.783)

99

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Table 9. O n e and tw o -s te p estim ation o f informal care and o th e r characteristics’ effect o n any home
health care, b o th im m ediately a n d tw o -y ears later (W ave 1 and W ave 2 o f A H E A D )

Im m ediate form al care S ubsequent form al care


Tw o-step estim ation O ne-step estim ation

V ariable D e sc rip tio n ________________________ C oeff. / (SE ) _____________ C oeff. / (SE ) ______________

In c o m e a n d w e a lth
H ousehold incom e (divided by $10,000) 0.1061 0.0325
(0.0769) (0 .0322)

N e t w orth (divided by $1 0 ,0 0 0 ) -0 .0 0 8 5 9 * 0.00401


(0.00504) (0.0 0 2 6 4 )
In su ra n c e c h a r a c te ristic s
M edicaid 0.858*** 0.264
(0.282) (0.273)

O th er private insurance -0 .8 3 0 * * * -0 .1 8 2
(0.274) (0.229)

L ong-term care insurance -0 .3 6 1 0.148


(0.282) (0 .2 6 2 )

M issing LTC insurance value 0.253 0.415


(0.276) (0.263)

P roxy resp o n d en t 7.30** -0 .2 6 5


(2.78) (0 .3 2 5 )

P r o x y f o r k n o w le d g e o f s e rv ic e s -0 .0 3 7 6 0.0572
(c h ild 's e d u c a tio n in y e a rs) (0.0472) (0.0335)

In te rc e p t -2 4 .8 8 * * * -1 0 .5 0 * * *
(4.89) (1.28)

C o n tro ls f o r e n d o g e n e ity o f in fo r m a l c a re ? Y es Partially1

* significant at th e 10 p ercen t level


** significant at th e 5 percent level
*** significant at th e 1 p ercen t level
1. C ontrols fo r rev erse cau satio n b u t not unobserved individual heterogeneity.
N OTES: N u m b e r o f observ atio n s is 2,985 for W ave 1 sam ple, 2,444 for W ave 2.
A ll estim ations u se probability w eights an d acco u n t fo r the design effect.
SO U R C E : A sse t a n d H ealth D ynam ics A m ong the O ldest O ld, W aves 1 and 2.

100

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
use. Looking at health behavior, being a former smoker increased the chance of using any

home health care (p<.10), as did a person feeling that they should drink less alcohol (/?< 01).

Being older and being somewhat religious increased the probability of any home

health care use, while being male and residing in a rural area significantly decreased the

chance. Race and ethnicity (ethnicity limited to being Hispanic) did not change home health

care use behavior, nor did a parent’s education or her work status.

People with a higher net worth were slightly less likely to consume home health care,

but this result was only statistically significance at the 10 percent level. Even so, this

provides little evidence of a bequest motive because elderly with higher net worth also

received less informal care from children (Table 14). It may be that wealthier elderly

consume less of both types o f care due to wealth-specific differences in health status that I

was not able to capture.

Among the health insurance characteristics, having Medicaid increased the chance of

home health care use significantly, while having other private insurance (Medigap or other

types) reduced the chance by about the same magnitude. Long-term care insurance did not

influence home health care use.

Finally, having a proxy respondent increased the likelihood of home health care use

more than any other variable (p<.01).

Effect two years later.

I did not detect endogeneity between informal care and home health care use two

years later. Since unobserved individual heterogeneity does not appear to cause endogeneity

bias in this case, I present the one-step results here (column 3, Table 9).

101

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
The main difference two years later is that having received informal care in Wave 1

significantly increased the likelihood o f home health care use in Wave 2. This finding is

difficult to interpret. My initial interpretation was that parents who received informal care in

the first wave simply needed more absolute care in the second wave due to declines in health

that I did not control for (by only using health characteristics in the first wave). That is,

receiving informal care in Wave 1 acts as a signal that a parent’s health is beginning to

decline. I attribute this decline to receipt of informal care when it is more likely due to

declines in health status. However, looking at mean levels of home health care across the

two periods, the chance of having any home health care use fell from Wave 1 to Wave 2 (fell

from .10 to .08), so functional status may not be declining for those who were still living in

Wave 2.

Due to data limitations we do not know what happened to informal care when W'ave 2

utilization occurred. Informal care in the first period is used first as a way to break the

temporal endogeneity between informal care and utilization, and second, to serve as a proxy

for Wave 2 informal care. However, we do not know whether parents who received

informal care in Wave 1 also received it in Wave 2. Because of this it is not easy to discern

why informal care increases the chance for home health care consumption. It could be

because caregivers were burning out and no longer providing care. On the other hand,

regardless of whether informal care decreased or increased by Wave 2, it could have been

because parental health was declining in a significant way that I did not capture, hence

parents needed more absolute care in the second wave. Recognizing that informal care from

the first wave is an inexact measure of informal care two years later, it seems likely that the

102

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
latter explanation is valid, but it is not possible to draw strong conclusions about why this

result occurred.

With a few exceptions, the other controls displayed a weaker influence on the

likelihood of home health care use two years later. A few exceptions are worth noting. First

recently experiencing angina and arthritis become significant in predicting Wave 2 home

health care use: angina decreased, while arthritis increased the chance of any home health

care use. Having a major fall in the past 12 months or a stroke ever still increased the chance

of home health care use, but to a lesser extent. This shows that there are long lasting health

care ramifications from these types of health shocks.

Residing in a rural area now (p<.10) increased the likelihood of any home health care

use, while working significantly reduced the chance for home health care, which was

insignificant before. Having a proxy respondent no longer mattered.

Simulated risks of home health care.

Using the parameter estimates from the home health care model. I simulated what

would happen if all persons in the sample received set decreases and increases in informal

care. Receiving even small increases in informal care can reduce home health care use

considerably in the short-term. Further, the modest increases in home health care in Wave 2

caused by informal care are overwhelmed by the reductions in Wave 1 so that the cumulative

effect is still negative. Hence, informal care is a net substitute for home health care over the

entire study period.

It is not reasonable to simulate all persons receiving help with 4 ADL’s or 5 ADL’s,

since the mean level o f assistance was around 2 for the 22-23 percent o f the sample who

103

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
received any informal care. Therefore, I set the quantity of informal care provided at the 25th

percentile to the 90th percentile of informal care found in the sample. This translates to a

range of assistance o f about 0.3 I/ADL's to about 2 1/ADL’s for all persons in the sample

rather than just those who received any care.

These modest changes in informal care supply may correspond loosely to two

possible scenarios in the future. First, we may see a reduction in informal care supply

relative to demand due to smaller numbers of potential caregivers. This could result from

lower fertility rates and a smaller number of potential child caregivers per elderly parent,

delayed child bearing in the U.S. which creates conflict between child care and elder care

responsibilities, or increasing work constraints of potential caregivers (usually daughters).

On the other hand, we may see an increase in informal care if any of the current public policy

proposals to support caregiving are enacted, such as tax credits or tax exemptions for

caregivers, or programs aimed to prevent caregiver burnout such as through occasional

respite care (Gore, 2000; Bush, 2000). While not based on actual projections of informal

care supply and demand, which are not readily available, each scenario has direct

implications for the use of home health care, and corresponding implications for the cost of

elderly health care in the United States.

In Wave 1, mean home health care use was 10 percent. If all persons received the 90th

percentile of informal care, home health care use would be 5 percent (Table 10). Receiving

the 75th percentile quantity increases the likelihood of any home health care use by 262

percent, to 18 percent. Finally, receiving only the 25th percentile level care leads to a 38

percent likelihood of any home health care use (an increase of 108 percent over the 75th

percentile).

104

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.

T a b le 10. S im ulated risk o f ho m e health care use and nu rsin g hom e use given different levels o f inform al care, W ave I and W ave 2

ANY H O M E HEALTH CARE A N Y N U R S IN G H O M E U SE

P redicted R elative Predicted R elative


Probability A bsolute D ifference Probability A b so lu te D ifference
Inform al care sim ulation scen ario ______________ o f A ny C are D ifference (% )____________ o f A ny C are D ifference (% )______

Wave 1

A ll receiv e 90th percen tile o f inform al care 0.0501 0.0360


0.1311 262% 0.0995 276%
A ll receive 75th p ercentile o f inform al care 0.1812 0.1355
0.0950 52% 0.0691 51%
A ll receive m edian level o f inform al care 0.2762 0.2046
0.1024 37% 0.0 9 2 0 45%
A ll receiv e 25th p ercentile o f inform al care 0.3787 0.2966

Wave 2

A ll receiv e 90th p ercentile o f inform al care 0.0959 0.0283


-0 .0 1 6 0 -1 7 % 0.0869 307%
A ll receive 75th percentile o f inform al care 0.0799 0.1152
-0 .0 0 3 3 -4 % 0.0601 52%
A ll receiv e m edian level o f inform al care 0.0766 0.1754
-0 .0 0 2 5 -3 % 0.0629 36%
A ll receiv e 25th p ercen tile o f inform al care 0.0741 0.2382

N o te: C alcu latio n o f risk s are from sim ulations based on th e full estim ation o f the m odel. O th er param eter e stim ate s w ere held
constan t. F or hom e health care in W ave 1 tw o-step IV estim ates are used, for W ave 2, the Pseudo-M L E resu lts. For nursing
hom e care, tw o -step IV resu lts are used for both W aves. A ccounts for com plex su rvey design o f A H E A D .

\
In Wave 2, mean home health care use was 8 percent. There are smaller relative changes in

Wave 2, with informal care now increasing the likelihood of any home health care use (Table

10). Receiving the 25th percentile of informal care translates to a 7.4 percent predicted

probability o f home health care use, while receiving the 90th percentile level of care leads to a

9.6 percent predicted probability of home health care use. This represents an increase of

about 29 percent from the highest to lowest percentile simulated, and is dwarfed by the

decrease we see in Wave 1 for the same care levels simulated, of over 600 percent.

Taking the weighted average over the entire study period (1992-1995), people who

received informal care at the mean level of 2 VADL’s had an overall reduction in the

likelihood of any home health care use in Waves I and 2 of 72 percent (overall predicted

probability for Waves 1 and 2 is .07 versus .25) despite the increase in Wave 2.

Simulations also show that having poor health, being female, having a proxy

respondent, and being older increased the likelihood of home health care (Table 11). The

Wave 2 simulations were similar but had slightly smaller relative changes, and some

variables were no longer significant.

In-depth look at informal care’s effect on nursing home use

Informal care is a net substitute for nursing home use, both immediately and two years

later. Informal care is a net complement for the number of nights spent in a nursing home in

Wave 1 when not controlling for endogeneity (Table 8). Even though I did not detect

endogeneity between informal care and nights in a nursing home use, from the questionnaire

design we know that nursing home care preceded informal care in most cases. Only non-

106

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Table 11. Simulated risks of having any home health care use in Wave 1

More likely to have any HHC_______ By percent_______ Less likely to have any HHC

Poor self-rated health 220% Excellent self-rated health

Fair self-rated health 79% Very good self-rated health

Stroke (TLA) ever 58% No stroke

Major fall past year 60% No major falls

Hip fracture ever 13% No hip fractures

Diabetic 13% Non-diabetic

Arthritis past year 33% No arthritis

Incontinent past year 9% No incontinence

Former smoker 12% Never smoked

Should not drink less 7% Should drink less

Age 90 72% Age 80

Age 80 80% Age 70

Female 93% Male

Urban resident 24% Rural resident

25th quartile of wealth 1% Median level of wealth

Median level o f wealth 3% 75th quartile of wealth

75th quartile of wealth 4% 90th percentile of wealth

Proxy respondent 20% No proxy respondent


Note: Calculation o f risks are from simulations based on the full estimation
of the models. Other parameter estimates were held constant. For home
health care, two-step IV results are used. Estimation accounts for complex
survey design o f AHEAD.

107

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
institutionalized individuals were interviewed, so if nursing home care occurred it was

before the interview. Hence, I suspect that one step estimation is positively biased for nights

in the nursing home, and that these results are not valid. Instead, I highlight the results from

two-step IV estimation of the discrete measure of nursing home care (columns 3 and 5 of

Table 12).

Immediate effect

Informal care reduces the chance of any nursing home use when controlling for the

endogeneity of informal care (p<. 05). Receiving more informal care is the largest deterrent

from having any nursing home care over any other variable (column 3. Table 12). The

statistical power is low for nursing home use in Wave 1 (53 individuals out of 2,985 had any

use), so it was surprising to find any relationship.

Similar to home health care utilization, health factors are important predictors of

nursing home use, with poorer health leading to an increased likelihood of any care. Having

poor self-rated health or poor eyesight both increase the chance of nursing home use. Among

health conditions, ever having a stroke or a hip fracture, and having a major fall or arthritis in

the past 12 months increased the chance of any nursing home use. In addition, being diabetic

increased the likelihood of use. Of the health behaviors measured, being a current cigarette

smoker reduced the likelihood of nursing home use significantly (p<.05).

Being older increased the chance of nursing home use, but other demographic

characteristics did not matter. A parent viewing religion to be somewhat important in her life

increased the chance of nursing home use relative to people who viewed religion to be very

important.

108

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Table 12. E stim atio n o f inform al care and o th er characteristics’ effect on any nursing hom e use, both
im m ediately an d tw o years later (W ave 1 an d W ave 2 o f A H EA D )

Im m ediate formal care S u b sequent form al care


O ne-step T w o-step O ne-step T w o-step
V ariable D e s c r ip tio n __________________________ C o e ffJ (S E ) C o e ffJ (S E ) C o e ff./(S E ) C o e ffJ (S E )

In fo rm a l c a r e /P r e d ic te d I n fo r m a l ca re 0.267** -8 .3 1 * * 0.1471* -2 .8 7 * *
(0.104) (4.12) (0.0764) (1.46)
H e a lth S ta tu s I n d ic a to r s
S elf-rated h e a lth (l= e x c e l!e n t, 5=poor) 0.086 0.630** 0.2497*** 0.456***
(0.142) (0.294) (0 .0873) (0.132)

S elf-rated e y esig h t (l= e x c e lle n t, 6= blind) 0.0333 0.444** -0 .0 1 9 5 0.1321*


(0.0198) (0.198) (0 .0193) (0.0734)

N um ber o f days in bed in past m onth -0 .1 7 2 * 0.507 -0 .0 0 2 9 0.225


(0.155) (0.340) (0.0854) (0.139)
A c u te e p iso d e s a n d c h r o n ic c o n d itio n s
H eart attack last 5 years (M I included) -0 .1 9 7 -0 .4 0 8 -0 .1 8 5 -0 .3 4 7
(0.519) (0.616) (0.303) (0.315)

A ngina o r ch e st pains recently -0 .5 4 3 -0 .7 3 3 0.482* 0.620**


(0.559) (0.568) (0.256) (0.266)

Stroke (in clu d es T IA 's) ev er 0.748* 3.39** 0.227 0.946**


(0.391) (1.28) (0.233) (0.409)

M ajor fall p ast 12 m onths 2.184*** 3.000*** 0.533*** 0.712***


(0.371) (0.610) (0.177) (0.195)

Fractured h ip e v e r 0.984** 2.93*** 0.213 0.810**


(0.453) (1.07) (0 .3 0 5 ) (0.413)

D iabetic now 0.854** 1.187** 0.323 0.500**


(0.382) (0.454) (0.237) (0.248)

C ancer ever 0.402 0.024 0.099 -0 .0 0 1


(0.369) (0.439) (0.235) (0.245)

Lung disease e v e r -0 .1 7 4 -1 .0 5 6 -0 .0 0 2 -0 .3 4 3
(0.542) (0.649) (0 .2 7 7 ) (0.308)

A rthritis past 12 m onths 0.527* 0.507* 0 .2 5 7 0.237


(0.308) (0.298) (0 .1 8 7 ) (0.187)

Incontinence p a st 12 m onths -0 .4 8 1 1.69 0.1 6 9 0.787**


(0.352) (1.08) (0 .1 8 7 ) (0.336)

109

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
T able 12. Estim ation o f inform al care and o ther characteristics’ effect on any nursing hom e use, both
im m ediately and tw o years later (W ave I and W ave 2 o f A H EA D )

Im m ediate formal care Subsequent formal care


O ne-step Tw o-step O ne-step Two-step
V ariable D esc rip tio n __________________________C o e jfJ (S E ) C o e ffJ (S E ) C o e ffJ (S E ) C o e ffJ (S E )
H igh blood pressure ev e r -0 .2 9 4 -0 .0 8 0 -0 .1 5 7 -0 .1 8 6
(0.328) (0.350) (0.182) (0.181)

H e a lth b eh a v io r
C urrent cigarette sm oker -2 .1 9 * * -2.54** 0.438 0.206
(1.04) (1.06) (0.299) (0.319)

Form er cigarette sm oker -0 .0 7 6 0.264 0.240 0.349*


(0.369) (0.425) (0.195) (0.204)

Feels should drink less alcohol 0.393 0.341 0.330 0.295


(0.601) (0.586) (0.300) (0.303)
D e m o g ra p h ic c h a ra c te ristic s
Age 0.0522** 0.314** 0.0993*** 0.1842***
(0.0257) (0.127) (0.0145) (0.0433)

M ale -0 .2 9 7 -0.691 -0 .1 3 2 -0 .0 7 6
(0.509) (0.546) (0 .257) (0.252)
Race (w hite is reference)
Black -0 .0 8 0 0.438 -0 .2 5 5 -0 .4 3 3
(0.468) (0.467) (0.262) (0.276)

O ther race -0 .7 3 -0.61 -0 .6 0 5 -0 .4 3 6


(1.58) (1.44) (0.879) (0.819)

C onsiders s e lf H ispanic -0 .3 0 3 -0 .7 1 6 -1 .5 2 1 * * -1.844**


(0.705) (0.755) (0 .693) (0.714)

R esides in rural area 0.180 -0 .7 8 5 0.018 -0 .3 3 5


(0.373) (0.567) (0.203) (0.269)
Im p o r ta n c e o f re lig io n (v e ry is re fe re n c e )
Som ew hat im portant 0.786** 1.055** 0.218 0.302
(0.359) (0.420) (0.203) (0.206)

N o t at all im portant 0.293 -0 .9 5 7 0.713** 0.217


(0.619) (0.862) (0 .280) (0.374)

Y ea rs o f e d u c a tio n c o m p le te d 0.0651 -0.0011 0.0534* 0.0276


(0.0500) (0.0547) (0.0287) (0.0301)

R e sp o n d e n t w o rk s 0.227 0.403 -0 .5 2 4 -0 .5 0 2
(0 .667) (0.679) (0 .561) (0.565)

110

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
T ab le 12. E stim ation o f in fo rm a l care and other ch aracteristics’ effect on any nursing hom e use, both
im m ediately and tw o y ears la te r (W ave 1 and W ave 2 o f A H E A D )

Im m ediate form al care S ubseauent formal care


O ne-step T w o-step O ne-step Tw o-step
V a ria b le D esc rip tio n C o e ffJ (S E ) C o e ffJ (S E ) C o e ffJ (S F ) C o e ffJ (S E )
In c o m e a n d w e a lth
H ousehold incom e (d iv id e d b y $10,000) -0.173 0.089 -0.0099 0.0864
(0.107) (0.147) (0.0437) (0.0584)

N e t worth (divided by $ 1 0 ,0 0 0 ) 0.00096 -0.0176 -0.01045 -0.01848*


(0.00701) (0.0115) (0.00816) (0.00951)
In su ra n c e c h a ra c te ristic s
M edicaid -0.311 0.406 -0.601** -0.326
(0.472) (0.640) (0.273) (0.312)

O ther private insurance -0.026 -0.813* -0.360* -0.587**


(0.365) (0.488) (0.219) (0.235)

Long-term care in surance 0.967** 0.435 0.079 -0.039


(0.388) (0.476) (0.258) (0.265)

M issing LTC in surance v a lu e -0.048 -0.376 0.436 0.478


(0.548) (0.546) (0.285) (0.293)

P r o x y re sp o n d en t 0.759* 12.18** 0.828*** 4.58**


(0.446) (5.54) (0.268) (1.85)

P r o x y f o r k n o w le d g e o f s e r v i c e s 0.0599 -0.1125 -0.0116 -0.0834*


(child's education in y e a rs) (0.0639) (0.0995) (0.0327) (0.0484)

In te rc e p t -11.29*** -30.74*** -11.82*** -17.88***


(2.40) (9.61) (1.32) (3.19)

C o n tro ls f o r e n d o g e n e ity o f in fo r m a l care? No Y es Partially Yes

*significant a t th e 10 p e rc e n t level
** significant a t th e 5 p e rc e n t level
*** significant a t th e 1 p e rc e n t level

NOTES: N u m b e r o f o b serv atio n s is 2,985 for W ave 1 sam ple, 2,444 for W ave 2.
A ll e stim a tio n s u se probability w eights and a c co u n t fo r the design effect.
SOURCE: A sset a n d H e a lth D ynam ics A m ong the O ld e st O ld, W aves 1 and 2 .

Ill

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Having other private insurance significantly reduced the chance of nursing home use,

while having long-term insurance had no influence. Finally, as in the case of home health

care, having a proxy respondent produced the largest increase in the likelihood of any nursing

home use (p<.05).

Effect two years later.

When using two-step IV estimation in Wave 2, informal care still reduces the chance

of any nursing home use, but less than in the shorter-term (Table 12, column 5). Again,

because I used informal care in Wave 1, it is difficult to discern whether informal care

persisted in Wave 2. However, even if we assume that none of the informal care persisted, it

is clear that having informal care two years earlier acted a strong deterrent from having any

later nursing home use.

The other coefficients that affected nursing home care mirrored those in the first

Wave, although at lower magnitudes. Some notable exceptions were that arthritis no longer

affected use, but having incontinence increased the chance of nursing home use. Since

incontinence can be a chronic condition, the onset o f incontinence becomes as important as

having a major fall in predicting nursing home use two years later. This reflects what

geriatric nurses have said about incontinence. Besides major accidents, it is the condition

which best foreshadows nursing home entry for the single elderly (UNC Aging seminar

series, 1999).

Looking at heath behaviors, being a former cigarette smoker now increases the chance

o f nursing home care, while being a current smoker no longer matters. Religious convictions

112

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
cease to be important but net worth becomes important. The higher one’s net worth, the

lower the probability of any nursing home use two years later (p<. 10).

Simulated risks o f nursing home care.

I performed the same simulations for nursing home care as I did for home health care

to see how set changes in informal care affect nursing home use (right hand side of Table 10).

In Wave 1 the mean level of any nursing home care was a mere 2 percent, while in Wave 2 it

was 9 percent.

In Wave 1, persons receiving the 90th percentile of informal care had a 3.6 percent

chance of any nursing home use, while person’s receiving very small quantities of informal

care (as measured by the 25th percentile) had nearly a 30 percent chance. Moving from the

90th percentile to the 75th percentile had the biggest effect, increasing the relative chance of

any care by 276 percent (predicted probability of .13), while moving from the 75th percentile

to the median level o f care created a smaller relative increase (51 percent) in the predicted

probability to .20.

In Wave 2, informal care had a smaller coefficient but more people had nursing home

use, so we saw a simulation pattern similar to Wave 1. People receiving high quantities of

informal care (at the 90th percentile) had a 2.8 percent chance of any nursing home care,

while 75th percentile recipients had about 11.5 percent chance. Moving to median levels of

care, recipients had about a 18 percent likelihood, while those with the smallest quantity

simulated, 25th percentile, recipients, had about a 24 percent likelihood o f care.

Looking at changes over the entire study period, informal care reduced the likelihood

of nursing home care by 88.7 percent for people who received mean levels of care (weighted

113

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
predicted probability for both waves of .05 versus .48).

Besides caregiving, having a proxy respondent, poor health, and being older all

increased the risk of nursing home use in Wave 1 based on other simulation results (Table

13). Having no other health insurance besides Medicare increases the chance of nursing

home care by 58 percent over those who have other insurance, which is surprising since

Medicaid has more comprehensive coverage of nursing home care than Medicare.

Informal care’s effect on other types of formal care

Informal care displays less o f a link with acute or routine health care use. Informal

care reduces the number of doctor's visits in the short-term and the risk of outpatient surgery

two years later, but as no influence over hospital use or quantities of acute and routine care.

Immediate effects of informal care on doctor’s visits.

Endogeneity was not detected between informal care and number of doctor’s visits in

Wave 1. Informal care slightly reduced the number of doctor visits (p<.05) in the one-step

estimation. Elderly persons who received help with 1 I/ADL had 2.9 percent fewer visits to

the doctor in a year than those who did not (Table 8), while people who received help with 2

I/ADL’s had 5.8 percent fewer visits.

While the reduction in visits is small, it is still not easy to interpret. A parent who

receives assistance with I/ADL’s would be expected to need more doctor’s care because they

are generally more infirm than parents not receiving care. Similarly, with a child monitoring

a parent closely, we might expect problems to be detected faster (such as repeatedly high or

114

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Table 13. Simulated risks of having any nursing home use in Wave 1

More likely to have By Less likely to have


any home health care Percent any home health care

Poor self-rated health 341% Excellent self-rated health

Fair self-rated health 111% Very good self-rated health

Stroke (TIA) ever 104% No stroke

Major fall past year 76% No major falls

Hip fracture ever 84% No hip fractures

Diabetic 47% Non-diabetic

Arthritis past year 20% No arthritis

Incontinent past year 84% No incontinence

Does not smoke 15% Current smoker

Should drink less alcohol 26% Should not drink less

Age 90 263% Age 80

Age 80 427% Age 70

Has no other health insurance 58% Has other health insurance

Proxy respondent 989% No proxy respondent

Note: Calculation o f risks are from simulations based on the full estimation
of the models. Other parameter estimates were held constant. For nursing home
care, two-step IV results are used for both Waves. Estimation accounts for
complex survey design of AHEAD.

115

Reproduced with permission o f the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
low glucose levels for a diabetic for example) or more visits for preventive care since the

child can help with the scheduling of appointments and /or provide transportation. This

result does not match these scenarios.

Perhaps having an informal caregiver reduces the number of visits to the doctor by

helping to reduce the parent’s risks o f accidents or by helping to manage better a parent’s

medications or other daily medical care. On the other hand, this finding may have nothing to

do with physical health. An informal caregiver may simply help reduce a feeling of social

isolation common to the single elderly, which may alleviate the need to visit the doctor to

increase social interactions.

Two years later, I detected that unobserved individual heterogeneity is a source of

endogeneity for doctor’s visits, but that instrumenting for informal care led to imprecise

estimation of the standard errors. Hence, informal care had no effect on doctor's visits in

Wave 2. It is possible that problems of recall could bias the findings towards zero. Doctor’s

visits are fairly common for the elderly, so it is difficult to recall with accuracy a common

event over a two year period.

Effects o f informal care on outpatient surgery two years later.

Informal care had no influence on outpatient surgery in the short-term, but

significantly reduced the chance of outpatient surgery two years later (p<.01). For example,

if a person received informal care in Wave 1, they had a 14 percent likelihood of any

outpatient surgery two years later. For those with no informal care, they had a 20 chance, a

43 percent increase in the predicted probability. Unfortunately we do not know what kinds of

procedures these were in order to further assess this finding. It would be interesting to know

116

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
whether these were surgeries due to accidents, chronic conditions, or new diagnoses. If they

were primarily surgeries from accidents or chronic conditions, it may mean that having an

informal caregiver both reduces the risk o f accidents and allows for better management of

daily medical care for chronic conditions. An indication of the types of outpatient surgeries

performed comes from a sub-sample o f the National Survey of Ambulatory Surgery (1994)

conducted by the Center for Disease Control (CDC, 1994).

Sensitivity tests of the main results

I ran sensitivity tests on the sample selection criteria, the home health care measure,

and the health status measures in order to check the robustness of my results.

Sam ple selection criteria.

The utilization analysis covers two waves of data, with informal care measured only

in the first wave. An elderly respondent had to be single in Wave 1, the period in which they

received informal care, to be included in the sample. This criteria could have introduced a

different dynamic in the Wave 2 analysis if getting remarried in Wave 2 created substitution

from children informal caregivers to spousal ones. I did not control for being remarried in

the main analysis. I test for potential bias by examining the first stage regression on the

Wave 2 sample both with and without a control for ‘'married in Wave 2.” I found that being

married in Wave 2 did not affect informal care behavior of children (p < 0.310 in the over­

identified model and p < .294 in the exactly-identified model). The effect of being married in

the second wave on utilization in the second wave was marginally significant in only two

117

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
cases, the two-step IV estimation of doctor’s visits, and the one-step estimate of nights in a

nursing home. Newly married persons had slightly fewer doctor’s visits (p<. 098) and spent

more nights in a nursing home (/t<.079). Because informal care did not significantly

influence times to the doctor in Wave 2 ,1 am not overly concerned with this finding.

Informal care also had no influence on the nights in a nursing home in Wave 2

(r=l .61). When I added a control for being newly married, informal care was still not

significant at the 10 percent level (t = 1.62). Still, this does not address the concern that

spousal caregivers may be replacing and hence diluting the effect of child caregivers. In fact,

when newly married individuals were removed from the sample, informal care had a stronger

effect on nights in the nursing home (r= 1.643), but just shy o f significance at the 10 percent

level. This result reflects some bias by including married individuals in Wave 2, but also

ensures that the bias is insignificant because it does not affect the main results in Wave 2. I

conclude from these tests that the selection criteria is valid.

Home health care definition.

The home health care measure is a derived variable from AHEAD’s helper file, and is

limited to paid assistance with I/ADL’s. While the same home health care provider who

helped with I/ADL’s may also have helped with skilled caregiving tasks, limiting the

definition in this way means that some skilled home health care is missed. Including skilled

care would have provided a more complete measure of all of the home health care provided

to the elderly, but it also would have changed informal care’s ability to substitute for home

health care.

118

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
There is a question in AHEAD which states, “During the last 12 months did a

medically-trained person come to your home to help you?” This would have imperfectly

captured skilled home health care if incorporated into the home health care measure. I did

not incorporate data from this question into my home health care measure for two reasons:

1.) The question is vague. It is not clear whether such a visit was by a home health care

professional, a medical doctor, or a medically-trained relative. More importantly, we do not

know whether this person was paid or not, which is the only indicator I had to determine

whether individual assistance was home health care or another source of informal care. 2.)

Even if I assume that all of the people who answered yes to this question were referring to

paid home health care visits, I would not expect informal care to affect this type of home

health care in the same way. I do not even know from the data whether they are two different

types o f home health care, or simply I/ADL assistance from a medically trained individual.

Looking at cross-tabulations, I find that some people who had a visit from a

medically-trained individual also received help from an agency, organization or paid

individual with I/ADL’s (what I call home health care), but that the correlation was not very

high, at 0.35 for Wave 1 and 0.37 for Wave 2. From this I assume that at least for a large

proportion of people, these are two heterogeneous types of home health care.

Hence, I would expect informal care to replace unskilled home health care (which I

found) and to complement skilled home health care. I test this empirically by running a logit

model of skilled home health care on informal care. I find that, not controlling for

endogeneity, informal care significantly increases the use of skilled home health care. I do

not find evidence of endogeneity. Controlling for endogeneity, informal care does not affect

skilled home health care significantly. Turning to Wave 2 utilization, I find that, like

119

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
unskilled home health care, informal care increased skilled home health care use by about the

same magnitude.

I also explore combining the two measures, so that receiving either unskilled or

skilled home health care is coded as "1.” I find that informal care no longer significant

changes Wave 1 home health care use after controlling for endogeneity. In Wave 2, informal

care increases home health care by slightly more than the unskilled measure does in the one-

step estimation.

These findings confirm that combining the two measures into one would incorporate

two heterogeneous types o f care, leading to offsetting effects of informal care in the short­

term. For this reason, and the fact that the question on medically-trained visits was vague, I

do not include skilled home health care in my measure.

Potential endogeneity bias from controllingfor current health status.

There is a debate in the health economics literature that including health status in

outcomes models introduces endogeneity bias, which I discussed in the methods chapter

(Chapter 3). In the case o f informal and formal care, if current health status is correlated with

an unobserved preference for care, and this unobserved preference for care is correlated with

informal care as well, the policy variable could be biased. I check for this indirectly in two

ways. First, I check the correlation between the health status measures and informal care. I

find that there is between .004 and .34 correlation between the most recent health status

measures and informal care. This does not ring any alarms that health status and informal

care are too closely associated. Second, I re-ran the models without the health status

measures that occurred in the last year or less (self-rated health, self-rated eyesight, number

120

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
of days in bed in the past month, major fall in past year, angina recently, arthritis past 12

months, and incontinence past 12 months). Essentially, the coefficient estimates on informal

care or instrumented informal care show stronger effects on formal care use without these

measures included. For example, for the two-step estimate of informal care, it moves from -

5.17 to -5.33. Most of the significance stays the same, although informal care has a positive

effect on hospital use when we do not control for current health status. This means that

hospital use that was originally attributed to a recent health shock such as a major fall, now

gets attributed to having had informal care. Instead of controlling for endogeneity bias by

excluding the most current health status measures, it appears that I am instead introducing

omitted variable bias. Omitting these variables leads the models to overstate the effect of

informal care on subsequent home health care use, when in fact it is these health status

measures that are driving some of the formal care use. For this reason and because of the low

level of correlation between informal care and recent health status measures, it is valid to

include recent health status measures as well as past health status measures.

What determines a child’s provision of informal care to a parent?

To control for the endogeneity o f informal care, I used two-step estimation procedures

which required that the informal caregiving model contain only those child-level variables

which passed tests of over-identification in the larger system. In addition to examining these

models, it is interesting to examine less restrictive models of informal care to see whether

they better predict informal care behavior of children. In this section I present two such

models, the first o f which contains all variables listed in equation 3.2. The second model

121

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
removes potentially endogenous variables from the estimation. In the third and fourth, I

present results from the models used in the main analysis, both the over-identified and the

exactly-identified specifications.

Both child and parent attributes determine a child’s informal care behavior, as

hypothesized. The same parent-level attributes were significant in all four of the models in

Table 14, and were of similar magnitude. The differences came from child-level variables,

which varied across equations.

Child attributes.

In the first model (see Column 1, Table 14) only two child characteristics affected

informal care behavior significantly, the number of siblings that a child had, and an indicator

of whether or not a parent asked the child for advice on major decisions. Each additional

sibling increased the number of I/ADL’s that a child helped with by .042 {p<.01). Given that

the mean number was 2 for those receiving informal care, this represents a relatively minor

increase, only 2 percent. Nevertheless, it echoes what Pillemer and Suitor (1996) found,

which is that having more siblings increases the willingness of a child to provide care.

Asking a child for advice increased the provision of informal care by much more, at .32

(/K.01). This represents a 15 percent increase in I/ADL’s. I suspect that this variable is

endogenous, so I do not use it or other transfer variables in the next model (see Column 2). I

also exclude a child’s work status and distance from a parent because Stem found them to be

endogenous (Stem, 1995).

122

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Table 14. Survey regression o f informal care (total ADLs and IADLs helped with) on child and parent
characteristics, Wave 1, (page 1 o f 4)

Column 1 Column 2 Column 3 Column 4

All Exogenous Over-id. Exact-id.


Child var’s Child Var’s Child Var’s Child Var’s
Variable Description Coeff. / (S.E.) Coeff. / (S.E.) Coeff. / (S.E.) Coeff. / (S.E.)

Child-level identifying instruments

Daughter .042 .039 .034 .075**


(.039) (.039) (.038) (.037)
Married -.020 -.002 -.027
(.040) (.040) (.037)
Number o f children -.004 -.005 -.006
(.013) (.013) (.012)
Number o f siblings .042*** .041*** .043***
(.010) (.010) (.010)
Step child (0,1) -.027 -.076
(.069) (.069)
Age -.0011 -.0006
(.0025) (.0025)
Age missing .04 .03
(.20) (JO)

Child’s income (S0-$20k is reference)


Income b.t. $20,001-30,000 -.059 -.071
(.064) (.065)
Income b.t. 30,001-50,000 -.028 -.031
(.059) (.061)
Income over $50,000 -.1 0 -.112*
(.067) (.067)
Income b.t. $0-30,000 -.125 -.133
(.080) (.084)
Income over $30,000 -.046 -.060
(.12) (.12)
Income b.t. $0-50,000 -.141 -.132
(.090) (.088)
Income is missing -.066 -.071
(.060) (.061)
Works -.034
(.040)
Missing value on work -.0 4
(.13)
Lives at least 10 miles away from parent -.017
(.035)
Receive $500 + from parent past year -.062
(.039)
Child owns deed to parent's house .091
(.11)
Child gives parent financial assist. -.084
(.133)
Parent asks child for advice .308***
(-041)

123

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Table 14. Survey regression o f informal care (total ADLs and IADLs helped with) on child and parent
characteristics, wave 1 (page 2 o f 4)

Column 1 Column 2 Column 3 Column 4

All Exogenous Over-id. Exact-id.


Child var’s Child Var’s Child Var’s Child Var’s
Variable Description Coeff. / (S.E.) Coeff. / (S.E.) Coeff. / (S.E.) Coeff. / (S.E.)

Parent-level variables

Health Status Indicators

Self-rated health.(l=exc., 5=poor) .061*** .064*** .064*** .061***


(.018) (.018) (.018) (.018)
Self-rated eyesight (l=exc. 6=blind) .073*** .077*** .077*** .077***
(.018) (.019) (.019) (.019)
Number o f days in bed in past mo. .0457*** .0468*** .0472*** .0474***
(.0076) (.0077) (.0077) (.0077)

A cute episodes a nd chronic conditions

Heart attack last 5 yrs (MI included) -.047 -.042 -.039 -.042
(.090) (.092) (.092) (.093)
Angina or chest pains recently -.012 -.014 -.012 -.011
(.072) (.073) (.073) (.073)
Stroke (includes TIA's) ever .270*** .30*** .30*** .29***
(.080) (.082) (.082) (.083)
M ajor fall past 12 months .098** .108** .108** .103**
(.042) (.043) (.043) (.043)
Fractured hip ever 212** 22** 22** 222**
(.10) (.10) (.10) (.101)
Diabetic now .044 .047 .047 .057
(.055) (.056) (.056) (.056)
Cancer ever -.029 -.038 -.038 -.042
(.051) (.052) (.052) (.052)
Lung disease ever -.088 -.098 -.095 -.092*
(.054) (.055) (.055) (.055)
Arthritis past 12 months 0.004 .006 .008 .008
(.040) (.041) (.041) (.041)
Incontinence past 12 months 212*** 232*** .232*** 238***
(.050) (.050) (.050) (.050)
High blood pressure ever .024 .017 .017 .020
(.034) (.035) (.034) (.035)

H ealth behavior

Current cigarette smoker -.016 -.019 -.018 -.035


(.049) (.050) (.049) (.050)
Former cigarette smoker .061 .059 .057 .045
(.037) (.038) (.038) (.038)
Feels should drink less alcohol -.0 1 4 -.012 -.012 -.008
(.049) (.050) (.050) (.050)

124

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Table 14. Survey regression o f informal care (total ADLs and IADLs helped with) on child and parent
characteristics, wave 1 (page 3 o f 4)

Column 1 Column 2 Column 3 Column 4

All Exogenous Over-id. Exact-id.


Child var’s Child Var’s Child Var’s Child Var’s
Variable Description Coeff. / (S.E.) Coeff. / (S.E.) Coeff. / (S.E.) Coeff. / (S.E.)

Parent-level variables, cont.

D em ographic characteristics

Age .0294*** .0329*** .0323*** .0312***


(.0045) (.0046) (.0040) (.0040)
Male -.029 -.0615 -.056 -.050

Race (white is reference)


(.047) (.048) (.047) (.046)
Black .023 .019 .021 .050
(.064) (.065) (.065) (.064)
Other race -.025 -.04 -.04 .01
(.123) (.13) (.12) (.13)

Considers self Hispanic -.092 -.098 -.095 -.055


(.084) (.086) (.086) (.086)

Resides in rural area -.11*** -.12*** -.12*** -.11***


(.037) (.037) (.037) (.037)

Importance o f religion (very is reference)

Somewhat important .053 .045 .049 .038


(.043) (.044) (.044) (.044)
Not at all important -.128** -.139** -.138** -.136**
(.063) (.065) (-065) (.066)
Years o f education completed .001 -.0026 -.003 -.007
(.006) (.0062) (.006) (.006)
Respondent works .029 -.0002 .000 .017
(.037) (.038) (-037) (.037)

Incom e a n d -wealth

Household income (div. by $10,000) .0267*** .0282*** .0282*** .0304***


(.0074) (.0073) (.0074) (.0075)
N et worth (div. by S10,000) -.002*** -.0019*** -.00187*** -.00203***
(.00058) (.00059) (.00060) (.00062)

125

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Table 14. Survey regression o f informal care (total ADLs and IADLs helped with) on child and parent
characteristics. Wave I, (page 4 o f 4)

Column 1 Column 2 Column 3 Column 4

All Exogenous O ver-id. Exact-id.


Child var’s Child Var’s Child V ar’s Child Var’s
Variable Description Coeff. / (S.E.) Coeff. / (S.E.) Coeff. / (S.E.) Coeff. / (S.E.)

Insurance characteristics

Medicaid .046 .068 .068 .098


(.067) (.067) (.067) (.067)
Other private insurance -.075 -.069 -.071 -.086*
(.049) (.050) (-050) (.049)
Long-term care (LTC) insurance -.059 -.055 -.055 -.055
(.040) (.040) (.040) (.040)
Missing LTC insurance value -.023 -.025 -.029 -.026
(.054) (.054) (.056) (.056)
Proxy respondent 1.209*** 1.30*** 1.31*** 1.32***
(.12) (.24) (.12) (.12)
Proxy for knowledge o f services -.0160** -.0148** -.017** -.019***
(child’s education in years) (.0075) (.0076) (.007) (.007)

Intercept -2.35*** -2.59*** -2.60*** -2.39***


(.33) (.33) (.33) (.33)

A djusted-R3 .410 .396 .397 .391

* significant at the 10 percent level


** significant at the 5 percent level
*** significant at the 1 percent level.

NOTES: Number o f observations is 2,985.


All estimations use probability weights and account for the design effect.
SOURCE: Asset and Health Dynamics Among the Oldest Old. 1993

126

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
The model in Column 2 includes all exogenous child-level variables expected to

affect a child’s informal care behavior. Again, number of siblings affects informal care

behavior by about the same amount as just described. None of the income measures were

significant, which was unexpected, because income is a good measure of the opportunity cost

o f a child’s time. Measurement error on a child’s income may be prohibitively high since

income is reported by parents.

The over-identified model has only one significant child-level variable (see column 3

of Table 14), number of siblings (/?<.00l). A child’s gender in the exactly identified model

absorbs the explanatory power that number of siblings provided in the over-identified model,

becoming significant when it appears alone. The increase, while significant at the 5 percent

level, is small, as daughters help with .075 more I/ADL’s than sons (Column 4, Table 14).

Parent attributes.

Because the effects o f the parent-level attributes on informal care behavior were

nearly uniform across the four specifications, I discuss the results from the exactly-identified

model here (shown in Column 4 o f Table 14). Looking at the health measures, both self­

assessed health and eyesight have small but statistically significant increases on amount of

informal care. The poorer the person views his or her health or eyesight, the more I/ADL’s a

parent will receive help with. The magnitudes are small, however, at .061 and .077,

respectively. Moving from excellent health (score o f 1) to very poor health (score of 6)

would lead to help with only a third more I/ADL’s (5x.077=.39). The number of days a

parent spent in bed in the past month also increased the quantity of informal care provided.

A person who spent all 31 days in bed received help with 1.5 more I/ADL’s than a person

127

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
who spent zero days in bed (3 lx.0474), which is more than a 75 percent increase from the

mean level of care.

The more objective disease measures, stroke, a fall, fractured hip, and incontinence all

increased informal care provision. If a parent ever had a stroke they received help with .29

more I/ADL’s from children than persons who did not. People experiencing incontinence

recently, or a hip fracture ever received help with between .22 and .29 more I/ADL’s than

those who did not, about a 10 percent increase from the mean. People who had a major fall

in the past year received less of an increase in informal care, at .10 I/ADL's.

Turning to demographic attributes of the parents, only age showed a small increase in

informal care provision (p<.01). Each additional year of age (from 70 on) leads to help with

.03 more I/ADL’s. This means that 85 year olds receive help with .45 more I/ADL's than 70

year olds.

Single elderly in rural areas received help with .11 fewer I/ADL’s than their urban

counterparts (p<.01), which is contrary to what I expected. I had hypothesized that living in a

rural area would increase reliance on informal care compared to urban people since access to

formal care in rural areas can be limited. Out-migration of children may explain this finding.

Parents who viewed religion to be not at all important to them received help with .14 fewer

I/ADL’s than those who viewed it to be very important (p<.05).

Income and net worth had miniscule offsetting effects on informal care behavior. One

additional thousand dollars o f income led to a 0. 00267 increase in I/ADL’s. On the contrary,

a $10,000 dollar increase in net worth led to a -0.0002 decrease in I/ADL assistance.

Increasing both by income and net worth by one standard deviation led to a net change in

128

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
I/ADL assistance of 0.014 ($25,527x0.00000267+ $271,372x-0.0000002). This provides

scant evidence for a bequest motive.

Possessing private health insurance besides long-term care insurance reduced the

quantity of informal care provided (/K.10). No other insurance attributes were significant.

The proxy for knowledge of services, a child’s education in years, slightly reduced the

quantity of informal care. This means that children with more education were more efficient

at finding formal care services for their parents. Still, the resulting decrease is miniscule,

with one more year o f education leading to a .019 fall in number of I/ADL’s assisted with.

The most overwhelming of all of the parent-level variables is whether or not there

was a proxy respondent. A parent received help with 1.32 more I/ADL’s than a parent who

had no proxy, a 66 percent increase over the mean number of I/ADL*s.

Discussion.

It was surprising that so few child-level variables were significant, especially a child

working and a child living at least 10 miles away, which Stem found to be significant when

treated exogenously (Stem, 1995). In my sample, the percentage of children living 10 miles

away and the percentage o f primary caregivers living 10 miles away did not differ, hence, this

distance threshold was not a prohibitive factor in being able to provide care. However,

endogeneity may bias the work coefficient towards zero. That is, if a child has already

adjusted her work situation to adapt to a parent’s caregiving needs, this coefficient would

show a less negative effect than with no endogeneity. It is also likely that the child-level

instruments such as income and age are highly correlated with the same variables at the

parent-level, so the parent measures absorb the explanatory power.

129

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
It is also interesting that, while I was limited in my choice of child-level instruments

because of the larger system of analysis in this dissertation, the more restrictive informal care

models perform equally well as those with many more child-level controls. The adjusted-R2

values hover around .40 for all models (see bottom of Table 14). This is likely due to the

exhaustive number o f parent-level controls included, which may have overwhelmed any

unique child attributes. In fact, when parent-level variables that are likely highly correlated

with child variables were omitted from the model, I find only one more unique child variable,

a child’s age.

It is reassuring that direct (days in bed, stroke, falls, incontinence) and indirect

(proxy) measures o f a parent’s health and functional status are the most important factors in

determining informal care behavior. It lends credence to my theoretical framework in which

children incorporate a parent’s health status directly into their utility maximization

framework. A child’s optimizing behavior between leisure, labor and informal care provision

is affected by a parent’s health.

With the exception of the extreme case which compares a parent who spent zero days

in bed in the last month to a person who spent the entire month in bed, all of the direct

measures of health status are overwhelmed by having a proxy respondent. Proxy is a

surrogate for cognition and depression, as I discussed in Chapter 3.

We cannot infer from these results that parent-level attributes are more important

than child-level attributes in determining informal care behavior of children, because the

model is based on parent-level data, but it is interesting that a model which controls for many

child-level characteristics is not superior to one controlling for gender only.

130

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Extensions

There are several extensions o f this dissertation work that I will pursue, both on child

informal care behavior and the effects o f informal care on formal care.

Extensions o f informal care's effect on formal care.

I plan to estimate the model using discrete factor analysis and non-linear

heterogeneity parameters. This will be useful to confirm that the loss in precision from two-

step TV estimation is low. When informal care data from Wave 2 of AHEAD becomes

available, I would like to revisit the research question using informal care in Wave 2 to

predict utilization in Wave 2. This will allow for a panel data approach using time fixed

effects, and will eliminate the uncertainty surrounding informal care in Wave 2.

In addition, I would like to explore further the finding that informal care affects

outpatient surgery drastically two years after the receipt o f informal care. I will do this using

CDC data on outpatient procedures and will determine what types of outpatient surgeries

these are. I also plan to work with Dr. Edward Norton in examining how informal care

affects public health care expenditures using Medicare claims. This will clarify whether the

cost savings from informal care are public or private.

I also have a nascent research idea to explore. There are three main factors that cause

adult children to cease providing informal care to a frail parent: increasing frailty o f the

parent, caregiver burnout, and the adult child being no longer able to manage competing

demands. Looking at this in a qualitative study would help to analyze current policy

proposals to support informal caregivers such as tax breaks and the newly adopted National

131

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Caregiver Support Program as a part of H.R. 782 (Clinton, 2000). The main focus will be to

find out what types of interventions would be useful to allow caregivers to keep caring for a

parent, and when in the care path these interventions should occur. Also, if a child stops

caring for a parent I want to assess the main reasons for stopping.

Extensions o f the prediction of informal care.

In future work I will examine the decision to provide care and the quantity of care

provided in a two-step model. I will also try to develop a conceptual framework of the intra­

family child caregiving decision, and empirically examine all children rather than just the

primary caregivers, controlling for clustering at the family level. In addition, I will analyze

this question measuring informal care as IADL assistance only, since researchers have found

that children help more with LADL’s than ADL’s (Pezzin and Schone, 1999a).

In addition, I will use forecasts from the literature on future informal care demand and

supply, and design some policy simulations based on these, to analyze what current proposals

by the presidential candidates on support for caregivers would do to informal care demand

and supply.

I would also like to examine issues surrounding the quality o f informal care,

especially in light o f the trend for family caregivers to provide highly skilled care that they

may not be qualified to perform. This is particularly relevant for the informal care of young

dependents. Quality o f informal care has not even begun to be addressed in the literature.

Less difficult to test but equally important is that I would like to explore the common

assumption made that elderly prefer informal care to formal care.

132

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
CHAPTER SEX:

CONCLUSION AND POLICY IMPLICATIONS

Conclusion

I have carefully controlled for reverse causation and other sources of endogeneity in

assessing how informal care affects the health care utilization of the single elderly. I

analyzed a comprehensive list of formal care types, including home health care, nursing home

care, hospital care, outpatient surgery, and doctor's visits.

Policy conclusions: hypotheses one and two.

Informal care by children reduces home health care use in the short-term and

increases it two years later. Elderly persons who received informal care were 87 percent less

likely to have any home health care use in Wave 1 than people who did not (predicted

probability of is .05 versus .40). Two years later, people who had received informal care in

Wave 1 were 30 percent more likely to use any home health care than those who did not

(predicted probability is .10 versus .07). Despite the increase in Wave 2, informal care is a

net substitute for home health care over the entire study period (1992-1995). Weighting by

the sample sizes, people who received informal care had an overall reduction in the

likelihood o f any home health care use in Waves 1 and 2 of 72 percent (overall predicted

probability for Waves 1 and 2 is .07 versus .25).

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Informal care by children can also delay entry into nursing homes by reducing the

probability of any nursing home use. This is true both immediately following the receipt of

informal care and two years later. People who received informal care at conventional levels

(2 I/ADL’s) in Wave 1 were 88.7 percent less likely to have any nursing home use in Wave 1

than people who did not (predicted probability of .028 versus .252). Two years later,

informal care recipients were also 88.8 percent less likely to have nursing home use than

people with no informal care (predicted probability of .036 versus .318). Looking at changes

over the entire study period, informal care reduced the likelihood of nursing home care by

88.7 percent (weighted predicted probability for both waves of .05 versus .48). Once in a

nursing home, informal care had no influence on the duration of the stay after controlling for

endogeneity.

Informal care played a less definitive role in determining other types of formal care.

Informal care reduced the chance of doctor’s visits in the short-term and reduced the chance

of outpatient surgery two years after the receipt of informal care, but had no effect on hospital

use or the continuous measures of care after controlling for endogeneity. Elderly persons

who received informal care at mean levels had 5.8 percent fewer doctor visits in a year than

those who did not. Furthermore, elderly persons who had informal care in Wave 1 were 43

percent less likely to have an outpatient procedure two to three years later (predicted

probability of .14 versus .20). Informal care played no role in the use of acute hospital care.

In addition, when controlling for both child and parent-level characteristics, it is a

parent’s health that is the most important determinant of a child’s provision of informal care.

While being a daughter and having a large number of siblings both increased informal care

provision, these factors were overwhelmed by the multi-faceted measure of a parent’s health.

134

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
This is different from other studies, which found many child-level characteristics to be

important predictors of a child’s behavior (Pezzin and Schone, 1999a; Boaz, 1999). The

importance of a parent’s health lends credence to the conceptual model, which assumed that a

parent’s health status enters the child’s utility maximization function directly.

Further, a parent’s wealth plays a very small role in a child’s decision to provide

informal care, which debunks the bequest motive, and provides support that children are

altruistic. The utility gained from providing informal care does not come from expected

monetary compensation, at least as measured by a parent’s wealth, income and other

monetary and non-monetary transfers.

It is interesting that the number of siblings a child has increases the likelihood of

providing care. If there are other siblings available to help with informal care duties, a child

provides more informal care. It could easily have been the reverse, that is. with more siblings

a child may provide less care because other siblings take up some slack. But we know that it

is rare to have more than one child caring for a parent. Therefore, having more siblings may

affect a primary caregiver’s behavior purely through the option value that more siblings

provide.

Lastly, confirming what has already been found in the literature, I find that most

primary caregivers of the single elderly are daughters, but that daughters provide only slightly

more informal care than sons on average.

135

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Methodological conclusions: hypothesis three.

Controlling for endogeneity is essential in order to correctly measure how informal

care affects elderly health care utilization. Endogeneity of informal care was most persistent

in the home health care and nursing home care models, although it was also detected in the

Wave 2 measure o f doctor’s visits. In these cases endogeneity bias made coefficients more

positive than they otherwise would have been. Even though I did not detect endogeneity for

all types of formal care, there are theoretical reasons to control for undetected endogeneity,

ranging from the peculiarities of the survey instrument to the reverse causation inherent in

informal and formal care. In fact, relaxing the significance criteria on the Durbin-Watson Hu

endogeneity tests from 5 percent to 25 percent, as suggested by Mroz (1999), allows more

endogeneity to be detected. This looser criteria encompasses any doctor’s visits and times to

the doctor, while relaxing the criteria to 50 percent encompasses all formal care types but

outpatient surgery.

I explored controlling for endogeneity using lagged caregiving, two-step instrumental

variables estimation and discrete factor analysis. I was unable to estimate the model using

linear heterogeneity parameters in discrete factor analysis. However, I find that using two-

step IV estimation with child-level identifying instruments is a fairly precise way to address

endogeneity given the characteristics o f my sample and models. I have a large number of

observations, strong instruments, and high explanatory power in the first-stage regression.

Using lagged informal care to predict utilization in Wave 2 is also an effective way to

break the temporal endogeneity that was detected. This approach, however, does not control

for the endogeneity from unobserved individual heterogeneity, which was persistent in the

136

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Wave 2 nursing home model. Not correcting for endogeneity would lead to biased inference

about the relationship between informal care and health care use of the elderly.

Finally, in this work I have run careful specification and sensitivity tests to ensure that

the main findings are valid. Along with standard endogeneity and exclusion restriction tests,

I test for measurement error in the informal care measure, for any bias in Wave 2 stemming

from the sample selection criteria, and the appropriateness of the home health care definition.

Based on all of these I conclude that the results are robust.

Policy implications

The policy significance of this study is clear. It is commonly recognized that family

caregivers provide a vast quantity of long-term care to the elderly in the United States. The

National Family Caregiver’s Alliance (2000) estimates there are about 25 million family

caregivers in the U.S. today (only about 24 percent of those care for parents). The demand

for informal care over the next 30-50 years is projected to increase exponentially, as the last

of the baby boomers turns 65 in 2030. This will coincide with fewer caregivers available due

to Americans having smaller families, as well as increased competition for a daughter’s time

as she juggles work, child rearing, leisure, and parent care responsibilities. Many other

studies along with this one have examined the tradeoffs adult children make between work,

child rearing, and/or caring for an elderly parent. This study, however, goes beyond targeting

factors that affect a child’s decision to provide informal care to an elderly parent.

This study is the first to use a nationally representative sample of the oldest-old and

appropriate statistical methods to quantify precisely how informal care affects formal care

137

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
use. Receiving informal care can save Medicare money by reducing home health care use

and can save federal and state Medicaid dollars by delaying entry into nursing homes. On a

much smaller scale, informal care replaces some doctor’s visits in the short-term and reduces

the risk of outpatient surgery two years after receiving informal care, which can also save

both public and private health care expenditures.

This finding can help policy analysts, policymakers, employers, caregiving

proponents, and other stake holders analyze current policy proposals to support caregivers.

For the first time ever the presidential candidates outlined specific proposals to support

informal caregivers. Vice-President Gore proposes to give family caregivers a $3,000 tax

credit to help defray the costs of long-term care (Gore, 2000). Governor Bush proposes to

offer a tax exemption, currently valued at $2,750 per care recipient, for family caregivers who

care for elderly parents in their home (Bush. 2000). In addition. Gore proposes to launch a

National Caregiving and Family Support Initiative. This would support adult day care, home

care coordination and other respite services for family caregivers.

These proposals differ sharply in their scope and cost. Bush’s tax exemption plan is

more modest because it benefits only caregivers and parents who co-reside, and caregivers

who already claim a parent as a dependent would not benefit. Gore’s tax credit plan would

cost more and affect more people because a caregiver need not live with her parent. Finally,

Gore’s Caregiver Initiative would be the most costly and far reaching program. It is

estimated to cost $30 billion over 10 years, and would encompass all family caregivers who

desire occasional respite care and help with the coordination of long-term care services

(Gore, 2000).

Consequently, these proposals also differ in how they would affect the supply of

138

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
informal care. The monetary benefits of the tax relief programs target the children who

provide care. Yet from a child’s perspective, which I confirm in my econometric model,

money is not a large motivator behind providing care. Children who provide care for a parent

gain utility from intangible factors. These could range from relief that a parent can remain in

her own home as she desires, to satisfaction at being able to repay a parent for all of the effort

it took to raise the child, to happiness associated with a closer relationship with a parent.

Less idealistically, these intangible benefits may arise from alleviating a child’s feelings of

guilt or the knowledge that an obligation has been fulfilled. Despite the importance of

intangible benefits to children, however, economic constraints truly may be preventing some

daughters who work from providing care, so at the margin providing monetary compensation

may increase informal care.

A much more poignant issue to child caregivers, however, is that they often

experience high levels of stress and feelings of isolation. This can lead to depression,

potentially lower quality informal care, and ultimately, a cessation of care and a substitution

o f formal care. By allowing caregivers to use occasional respite care. Gore’s Caregiver

Initiative may prevent burnout and/or improve a caregiver’s own health so may increase

informal care over time. In addition, this initiative may reduce caregivers’ feelings of

isolation by officially recognizing the role of the family caregiver in the larger health care

system, helping to increase supply of informal care. On the other hand, because Gore’s

initiative includes incentives for formal care as well, such as the respite care mentioned and

other types o f long-term care, the net effect on informal care supply is unclear. Informal

caregivers could simply provide less informal care over a longer period of time, leading to no

net change in the total care provided.

139

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
From a parent’s perspective, programs providing monetary benefits to caregivers may

help a parent feel like less o f a burden to a child. To assess how elderly parents might view a

program increasing the availability of respite care and other formal care such as the one

proposed by Gore (2000), some assumptions have to be made: a parent’s first choice is to be

fully independent. If full independence is not possible, then a parent prefers to stay in her

own home and have a child care for her. If that is not possible, a parent would prefer having

a paid caregiver in her home to moving into an assisted living facility or a nursing home. If

these assumptions are correct, a parent may be resistant to participating in a respite care

program. However, if participating ultimately means that a child will continue caring for her

and she can remain in her own home, it may be much better perceived. Similarly, occasional

respite care may improve a parent’s overall quality of care by allowing a child to re-energize

or by increasing a parent’s contact with her peers.

If informal care truly does provide the type of care that the elderly prefer, ensuring

that informal care supply from children meets demand can improve the utility of the elderly

parent. While I confirm in this dissertation that informal caregivers do not affect the physical

health outcomes o f parents, there may be large mental health gains from having informal care

versus formal or nursing home care. This, in turn, can improve the quality of life of the frail

elderly.

With all o f the intangible benefits of informal care to both child and parent that I have

described, focusing on the tangible outcome of subsequent formal care use may appear to be

limiting. It is imminently clear that caring for an elderly parent and/or arranging for formal

long-term care are inherently emotional tasks, and that there exist many emotional and moral

arguments to support caregivers. In fact, proponents of caregiving say that caregivers should

140

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
be supported because of the valuable role they play in our society (NFCA, 2000). It is nearly

impossible to measure the societal value of caregiving, however, never mind objectively, and

is not something I attempt in this dissertation.

However, proponents o f caregiving also say that informal caregivers save the

government money (NFCA, 2000; FCA, 2000) and many researchers have echoed this claim,

although direct measures o f these savings have been heretofore unavailable. By showing that

a concrete reduction in formal care occurs from informal care, I can begin to assert that

informal care does indeed save the government money. Further, depending on the cost and

the scope o f the program, initiatives which support informal caregivers may be more cost-

effective to the government than funneling money directly to Medicare and Medicaid, if they

ensure that informal care supply meets burgeoning demand. The next step is to look beyond

formal care use and assess carefully how informal care affects public versus private health

care expenditures.

141

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
REFERENCES

Allen, S. M. Receiving Help at Home: The Interplay o f Human and Technological


Assistance , Poster Presentation, American Health Services Association Annual
Meeting, June 2000.

Asset and Health Dynamics Among the Oldest-Old, AHEAD Documentation. Wave /.
University of Michigan, 1998.

Asset and Health Dynamics Among the Oldest-Old, AHEAD Documentation, Wave 2,
University of Michigan, 1999.

Arrow, K. J. “Uncertainty and the Welfare Economics of Medical Care.” The American
Economic Review , December 1963, 53 (5), pp. 941-973.

Bass, D. M. and L. S. Noelker. “The Influence of Family Caregivers on Elder’s Use of In-
Home Services: An Expanded Conceptual Framework.” Journal o f Health and Social
Behavior, June 1987, 28, pp. 184-196.

Becker, G .S. “A Theory of Social Interactions," Journal o f Political Economy , 1974, 82 (6).
pp. 1063-1093.

Becker, G. S. “Habits, Addictions, and Traditions,” Kyklos, 45(3), pp. 327-346.

Boaz, R. F. “Full-time Employment and Informal Caregiving in the 1980s," M edical Care ,
1996,34 (6), pp. 524-536

Bollen, K. A., D. K. Guilkey, T. A. Mroz. “Binary Outcomes and Endogenous Explanatory


Variables: Tests and Solutions with an Application to the Demand for Contraceptive
Use in Tunisia,” Demography , 1995,32(1), pp. 111-131.

Borsch-Supan, A. Household Dissolution and the Choice of Alternative Living


Arrangements among Elderly Americans,” The Economics of Aging, ed. David A.
Wise, University of Chicago Press, 1989, pp. 119-146.

Borsch-Supan, A., J. Gokhale, L. J. Kotlikoff. and J.N. Morris. “The Provision o f Time to
the Elderly by their Children,” in Tonics in the Economics of Aging, ed. David A.
Wise, University of Chicago Press, 1992a, pp. 109-134.

Borsch-Supan, A., V. Hajivassiliou, L. J. Kotlikoff, and J. N. Morris. “Health, Children, and


Elderly Living Arrangements: A Multiperiod-Multinomial Probit Model with
Unobserved Heterogeneity and Autocorrelated Errors” in Topics in the Economics of
Aging, ed. David A. Wise, University of Chicago Press, 1992b, pp. 109-134.

142

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Bound, J., D. A. Jaeger, and R. M. Baker, “Problems with Instrumental Variables Estimation
When the Correlation Between the Instruments and the Endogenous Explanatory
Variable is Weak," Journal o f the American Statistical Association , 1995,90 (430),
pp. 443-450.

Bush, G.W. “Healthcare Issues,” www.georgewbush.com/ issues/domestic/healthcare/


points.asp, 2000.

Cafferata, G.L. “Marital Status, Living Arrangements, and the Use of Health Services by
Elderly Persons,” Journal o f Gerontology , 1987,42(6), pp. 613-8.

Cameron, A., P. Trivedi, F. Milne, and J. Piggott. “A Microeconomic Model of the Demand
for Health Care and Health Insurance in Australia,” Review o f Economic Studies, 1988.
55, pp. 85-106.

Cantor, M. H. “Strain Among Caregivers: A Study of Experience in the United States.” The
Gerontologist, 1983,23 (6), pp. 597-604.

Center for Disease Control, National Survey o f Ambulatory Surgery, 1994: Data set and
Documentation , National Center for Health Statistics.:
http://www.cdc.gOv/nchs/datawh/ftpserv/ftpdata/ftpdata.htm#nsas

Chang, C. F., and White-Means, S. I. “Labour Supply of Informal Caregivers." International


Review o f A pplied Economics , 1995, 9(2), pp. 192-205.

Christianson, J. B. “The Evaluation of the National Long-term Care Demonstration: The


Effect of Channeling on Informal Caregiving.” Health Services Research. 1988,
23(1), pp. 99-117.

Clinton, W. J. “President Signs National Family Caregiver Support Program,” White House
Release, The White House, Office of the Press Secretary, November 13,2000.

Cook, T. D. and D. T. Campbell. Quasi-Experimentation: Design and Analysis Issues in Field


Settings. Rand McNally, 1979.

Coward, Raymond T., and S. J. Cutler, “Informal and Formal Health Care Systems for the
Rural Elderly," Health Services Research , February 1989,23 (6), pp. 785-806.

Cutler, D. M. “The Incidence o f Adverse Medical Outcomes Under Prospective Payment,”


Econometrica, 1995,63 (1), pp. 29-50.

Duan, N., W. G. Manning, C. N. Morris, and J. P. Newhouse. “Choosing Between the


Sample-Selection and Multi-Part model,” Journal o f Business and Economic
Statistics, 1984, pp. 283-289.

143

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Dunlop, B. D. “Expanded Home-Based Care for the Impaired Elderly: Solution of Pipe
Dream?" American Journal o f Public Health, 1980, 70, pp. 514-519.

Ellencweig, A. Y. and Pagliccia, N. “Utilization Patterns of Cohorts of Elderly Clients: A


Structural Equation Model," Health Services Research , 1994, 29(2), pp. 225-245.

Ettner, S. L. “The Effect of the Medicaid Home Care Benefit on Long-Term Care Choices of
the Elderly.” Economic Inquiry, 32(1): pp. 103-127.

Ettner, S. L. “The Impact o f “Parent Care” on Female Labor Supply Decisions."


Demography, 1995, 32(1), pp. 63-80.

Ettner, S. L. “New Evidence on the Relationship Between Income and Health *Journal o f
Health Economics, 1996, 15, pp. 67-85.

Family Caregiver Alliance web site, http://www.careaiver.org. 2000.

Fisher, I. “Families Provide Medical Care, Tubes and All,” The New York Times, June 7,
1998, Vol. CXLVH (51,180).

Garber, Alan. “Long-Term Care, Wealth, and Health of the Disabled Elderly Living in the
Community." The Economics of Aging, ed. David A. Wise, University of Chicago
Press, 1989, pp. 255-277.

Gilleskie, D. B. “A Dynamic Stochastic Model of Medical Care Use and Work Absence,”
Econometrica, January, 1998,66 (1), pp. 1-45.

Gilleskie, D. B., and T. Mroz. “A Dynamic Model of Medical Care Consumption During the
Health Insurance Year,” Working Paper, University of North Carolina, 1997.

Goldman, D. P. “Managed Care as a Public Cost-Containment Mechanism." RAND Journal


o f Economics, Summer 1995,26 (2), pp. 277-295.

Goodling, B. Summary: The O lder Americans Act Amendments o f 2000,


http://www.house.gov/ed workforce/hottopics/oaa/oaasiimmarv-htm.

Gore, A. “National Caregiving Initiative," Press Release, June 7,2000.

Gronau, R. “Home Production: A Survey,” Handbook of Labor Economics. Volume I. Edited


by O. Ashenfelter and R. Layard, Elsevier Science Publishers BV, 1986, Chapter 4.
pp. 273-304.

Grossman, M. “On the Concept of Health Capital and the Demand for Health,” The Journal
o f Political Economy, 1972, 80 (2), pp. 223-255.

144

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Hanson, S. L., W. J. Sauer, and W. C. Seelbach. “Racial and Cohort Variations in Filial
Responsibility Norms.” The Gerontologist, 1983,23 (6), pp. 626-631.

Harold, C. “A Child’s Decision to Provide Informal Care to an Elderly Parent: a Dynamic


Approach to the Optimization Problem and Approximation of the Child’s Value
Function,” unpublished paper submitted to Professor Donna Gilleskie, May 7,1998.

Hess, B. B. and B. J. Soldo. “Husband and Wife Networks," In Social Support Networks
and the Care o f the Elderly: Theory. Research and Practice, edited by W. J. Sauer and
R.T. Coward. New York, Springer, 1985.

Jones, A. M. 1998. In review. “Health Econometrics.” Draft chapter for the forthcoming
Handbook of Flealth Economics.

Kemper, P., “The Use o f Formal and Informal Home Care by the Disabled Elderly,” Health
Services Research , 1992.27 (4), pp. 421-451.

Kennedy, P. A. A Guide to Econometrics , 3rd edition, Cambridge, MA, MIT Press, 1992.

Kotlikoff, L. J. and J. N. Morris. “How Much Care do the Aged Receive from Their
Children? A Bimodal Picture of Contact and Assistance,” The Economics of Aging.
ed. David A. Wise, University of Chicago Press, 1989, pp. 151-175.

Lakadawalla, Darius and Tomas Philipson. Aging and the Growth o f Long-Term Care.
NBER Working paper, w6980. National Bureau of Economic Research. 1999.

Litwak, E. Helping the Elderly; The Complementary Roles o f Informal Networks and Formal
System. New York: Guilford Press, 1985.

Manning, W., J. Newhouse, N. Duan, E. Keeler, A. Leibowitz, and M. Marquis. “Health


Insurance and the Demand for Medical Care: Evidence from a Randomized
Experiment,” American Economic Review, 1987,77, pp. 251-277.

Mays, Glen P. “Managed Care Contracting and Community Health Center Performance,"
Unpublished Doctoral Dissertation, Department of Health Policy and Administration,
School o f Public Health, University of North Carolina, 1999.

McGarry, K. and R. F. Schoeni. “Transfer Behavior within the Family: Results from the
Asset and Health Dynamics Survey, Working Paper No. 5099, April 1995, NBER,
Cambridge, Massachusetts.

McGinnis, J. M. and W. H. Foege. “Actual Causes of Death in the United States,” Journal o f
the American M edical Association, 1993,270 (18).

145

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Mroz, T. A. “Discrete Factor Approximations in Simultaneous Equation Models: Estimating
the Impact of a Dummy Endogenous Variable on a Continuous Outcome," Journal o f
Econometrics, 1999, 92, pp. 233-274.

Mroz, T. A. and D. K. Guilkey. “Discrete Factor Approximations for Use in Simultaneous


Equation Models with Both Continuous and Discrete Endogenous Variables,"
Working Paper Series , University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill, 1995,95-02,.

Muurinen, J-M. “The Economics o f Informal Care: Labor Market Effects in the National
Hospice Study." M edical Care, 1986, 24, pp. 1007-1017.

National Family Caregiver’s Alliance (NFCA) web site, http://www.nfcacares.org. 2000.

Nocera, S., and Zweifel, P. “Women’s Role in the Provision o f Long-Term Care, Financial
Incentives, and the Future Financing o f Long-Term Care”, In Long-Term Care:
Economic Issues and Policy Solutions, R. Eisen and F. A. Sloan, eds., Boston:
Kluwer Academic Publishers, 1996, pp. 79-102.

Norton, E. C. “Long-Term Care,” Handbook of Health Economics. Volume IB. A. J. Culyer


and J.P. Newhouse, eds. New York: North-Holland, 2000. pp. 956-991.

Norton, E. C., S. A. Garfinkel, L. J. McQuay, D. A. Heck, J. Wright, R. Dittus, and R.


Lubitz. “The Effect o f Hospital Volume on Complication Rates in Knee Replacement
Patients.” Health Services Research. 33(5), 1998, pp. 1191-1210.

Pauly, M. V. “Is Medical Care Different?" In Issues in Health Economics. W. Greenberg


(ed.), Washington: Bureau of Economics. FTC, 1983.

Pauly, M. V. “Is Medical Care Different? Old Questions, New Answers,” Health Politics.
Policy and Law, 13, pp. 227-238.

Pauly, M. V. “The Rational Nonpurchase of Long-Term-Care Insurance.” The Journal fo r


Political Economy , 1990,98(1), pp. 153-168.

Pezzin, L. E. and B. Steinberg Schone. “The Allocation o f Resources in Intergenerational


Households: Adult Children and Their Elderly Parents,” American Economic Review,
AEA Proceedings and Papers, 1997,87(2), pp. 460-464.

Pezzin, L. E. and B. Steinberg Schone. “Intergenerational Household Formation, Female


Labor Supply and Informal Caregiving: A Bargaining Approach,” Journal o f Human
Resources, 1999a, 34(3), pp. 475-503.

Pezzin, L. E. and B. Steinberg Schone. “Intergenerational Transfers of Time and Elderly


Living Arrangements: A Bargaining Model o f Family Resource Allocation
Decisions,” forthcoming, Journal o f Public Economics, 1999b.

146

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Pezzin, L. E. and B. Steinberg Schone. “Parental Marital Disruption and Intergenerational
Transfers: An Analysis o f Lone Elderly Parents and Their Children." Forthcoming,
Demography, 1999c.

Pezzin, L. E., P. Kemper and J. Reschovsky. “Does Publicly Provided Home Care Substitute
for Family Care? Experimental Evidence with Endogenous Living Arrangements.”
The Journal o f Human Resources, 1996,31(3), pp. 650-676.

Pillemer, K.and J. J. Suitor. “ ‘It Takes One to Help O n e': Effects of Similar Others on the
Well-being of Caregivers,” Journal o f Gerontology, 1996, 51B(5), pp. S250-S257.

Pritchett, L., and L. H. Summers. “Wealthier is Healthier," Policy Research Working Paper,
Background paper f o r W orld Development Report 1993, June 1993, WPS 1150,
World Bank, Washington, District of Columbia.

Puntenny, D. Poor Mothers a t Work: Balancing Family and Labor Market Responsibilities
in an Inner City Community, unpublished doctoral dissertation, 1998, Northwestern
University, Institute for Policy Research.

Rabiner, D. J., S. C. Steams, and E. Mutran, “The Effect of Channeling on In-Home


Utilization and Subsequent Nursing Home Care: A Simultaneous Equation
Perspective," Health Services Research, December 1994,29 (5), pp. 6C5-622.

Rogot. E., P. D. Sorlie, and N. J. Johnson. “Life Expectancy by Employment Status. Income,
and Education in the National Longitudinal Mortality Study," Public Health Reports,
July-August 1992, 107 (4).

Rosenthal, C. J., A. Martin-Matthews, and S. H. Matthews. “Caught in the Middle?


Occupancy in Multiple Roles and Help to Parents in a National Probability Sample of
Canadian Adults," Journal o f Gerontology, 1996,5 IB (6), pp. S274-S283.

Skinner, C. J. Analysis o f Complex Surveys, ed. C. J. Skinner, C. Holt, and T. M. F. Smith,


pp. 23-58, 1998, New York, John Wiley and Sons.

Sloan, F. A., T. J. Hoerger, and G. Picone. “Effects of Strategic Behavior and Public
Subsidies on Families’ Savings and Long-Term Care Decisions,” in R. Eisen and F.
Sloan, eds., Long-Term Care: Economic Issues and Policy Solutions.
Boston/Dordrect/London: Kluwer Academic Publishers, 1996. pp. 45-78.

Sloan, F. A., G. Picone, and T. J. Hoerger. “The Supply of Children’s Time to Disabled
Elderly Parents,” Economic Inquiry, April 1997,34, pp. 295-308.

Sloan, F. A., and E. C. Norton. “Adverse Selection, Bequests, Crowding Out, and Private
Demand for Insurance: Evidence from the Long-term Care Insurance Market,"
Journal o f Risk and Uncertainty, 1997, 15(3), pp. 201_219.

147

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Soldo, B. J. and J. Myllyluoma. “Caregivers Who Live with Dependent Elderly.” The
Gerontologist, 1983,23 (6), pp. 605-611.

Soldo. B. J. “In-Home Services for the Dependent Elderly,” Research on Aging, 1985,7, pp.
281-304.

Soldo, B. J. “Cross Pressures on Middle Aged Adults," Journal o f Gerontology, 1996, 51B
(6), pp. S271-S273.

Staiger, D. and J. H. Stock. “Instrumental Variables Regression with Weak Instruments,”


Econometrica, 1997, 65 (3), pp. 557-586.

StataCorp. Stata Statistical Software: Release 6.0. Reference Manual. College Station. TX:
Stata Corporation, Volumes I-IV. 1999.

Stem, S. “Estimating Family Long-Term Care Decisions in the Presence of Endogenous


Child Characteristics,” Journal o f Human Resources , 1995, 30 (3), pp. 551-580.

Stone, R., Cafferata, G. L., and Sangl, J. “Caregivers of the Frail Elderly: A National
Profile," The Gerontologist, 1987,27 (5), pp. 616-626.

Stone, R. I., and P. Kemper. “Spouses and Children of Disabled Elders: How Large a
Constituency for Long-term Care Reform?" The Milbank Quarterly, 1990, 67 (3-4),
pp. 485-505.

Stone, R. I., and P. F. Short. “The Competing Demands of Employment and Informal
Caregiving to Disabled Elders,” Medical Care, 1990,28 (6), pp. 513-526.

United States Bureau o f the Census. Statistical Abstract of the United States. 1997. U.S.
Government Printing Office, Washington, D. C., 1997.

University of Michigan, Institute for Survey Research, Institute for Social Research, Health
and Retirement Survey and Asset o f Health Dynamics o f the Oldest O ld Homepage,
www.umich.edu/~hrswww/, 1998.

Weissert, W. G., “The National Channeling Demonstration: What We Knew, Know Now,
and Still Need to Know,” Health Services Research, April 1988, 23(1), pp. 175-187.

Wingard, D. L., D. W. Jones and R. M. Kaplan. “Institutional Care Utilization by the


Elderly: A Critical Review.” The Gerontologist, 1987,27 (2), pp. 156-163.

Wolf, D. A., V. Freedman, and B. J. Soldo. “The Division of Family Labor: Care for Elderly
Parents,” The Journals o f Gerontology, Series B, 1997,52B (Special Issue), pp. 102-
109.

148

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Wolinsky, F. D. “Health Services Utilization Among Older Adults: Conceptual,
Measurement, and Modeling Issues in Secondary Analysis," The Gerontologist, 1994,
34(4), pp. 470-475.

Wolinsky, F. D., R. R. Mosely n, R. M. Coe. “A Cohort Analysis of the Use o f Health


Services by Elderly Americans,” Journal o f Health and Social Behavior, September
1986,27, pp. 209-219.

Zarit, S. H., K. E. Reever, J. Bach-Peterson. “Relatives of the Impaired Elderly: Correlates


ofFeelings of Burden." The Gerontologist, 1980, 20 (6), pp. 649-655.

149

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.

You might also like