You are on page 1of 31

1122428

research-article2022
SOQ0010.1177/14761270221122428Strategic OrganizationLu et al.

Article

Strategic Organization

Doing safe while doing good:


1­–31
© The Author(s) 2022

Slack, risk management Article reuse guidelines:


capabilities, and the reliability of sagepub.com/journals-permissions
DOI: 10.1177/14761270221122428
https://doi.org/10.1177/14761270221122428

value creation through CSR journals.sagepub.com/home/soq

Hao Lu
Xiaoyu Liu
Saint Mary’s University, Canada

Oleksiy Osiyevskyy
University of Calgary, Canada

Abstract
When can corporate social responsibility become a reliable strategic asset? There is a scarcity of both
theoretical arguments and empirical evidence investigating the trade-off between the risk and return of
corporate social responsibility. We intend to fill this gap by (1) investigating corporate social responsibility’s
simultaneous impact on firm value and the reliability of this impact and (2) exploring the conditions under
which corporate social responsibility’s impact on firm value becomes more or less reliable. The presented
findings suggest that corporate social responsibility by itself is an unreliable value enhancer, in that it not only
increases firm value but also increases the variance of expected value distribution. Yet, the impact of corporate
social responsibility on firm value becomes more reliable when a firm has immediately redeployable slack
or when a firm has stronger risk management capabilities. This research provides practical implications to
managers and investors regarding the riskiness of corporate social responsibility investments and strategies
for mitigating such risks.

Keywords
corporate social responsibility, organizational slack, reliability of value creation, resource-based view, risk
management capability

Introduction
The relationship between corporate social responsibility (CSR) and firm value is one of the most
important yet controversial topics in the management field. Over the past few decades, scholars
have made countless attempts to shed light on the fundamental proposition about whether firms

Corresponding author:
Xiaoyu Liu, Sobey School of Business, Saint Mary’s University, 923 Robie Street, Halifax, NS B3H 3C3, Canada.
Email: Xiaoyu.liu@smu.ca
2 Strategic Organization 00(0)

can do well financially by doing good socially (e.g. Barnett et al., 2020; Gras and Krause, 2020;
Hillman and Keim, 2001; Jayachandran et al., 2013; Lu et al., 2021; Orlitzky et al., 2003). Along
these lines, the instrumental approach to CSR treats CSR engagement as a deliberate investment
for long-term financial gain (Jones, 1995). By considering stakeholders’ interests in a firm’s
resources allocation, a firm accumulates moral capital (Godfrey et al., 2009) or builds stakeholder
trust (Mishra and Modi, 2013), thereby buffering itself from negative shocks (e.g. Muller and
Kräussl, 2011; Shiu and Yang, 2017) and increasing efficiencies of business operations (e.g.
Flammer, 2018; Flammer and Luo, 2017).
Although a majority of researchers point out that firms can do well by doing good from an
instrumental point of view (Flammer, 2013, 2015; Godfrey et al., 2009; Orlitzky et al., 2003), this
proposition has also been doubted by many others (e.g. List and Momeni, 2017; Masulis and Reza,
2015). On one hand, scholars argue that the proposition of “doing well by doing good” is contin-
gent on contextual factors, such as economic development (e.g. Wang et al., 2016), organizational
attributes (e.g. Sun et al., 2019), institutionalization stage of CSR (Brower and Dacin, 2020),
industry characteristics and dynamics (e.g. Gras and Krause, 2020), and stakeholders’ characteris-
tics (Wiengarten et al., 2017). On the other hand, the opponents of the “doing well by doing good”
proposition stress that it is not uncommon to observe a non-significant, in many cases even nega-
tive, relationship between CSR and firm value. This negative relationship between CSR and value
may be caused by a high opportunity cost (Friedman, 1970) or agency problem (Masulis and Reza,
2015). A negative relationship might also occur when the costs of CSR are higher than the benefits
accrued from it. For example, through an experiment, List and Momeni (2017) found that CSR
performance increases employee misbehavior and shirking through the cognition effect of moral
licensing: When employees feel that they have done “good” in one dimension, they later feel less
morally constrained and hence misbehave in other dimensions (Bénabou and Tirole, 2010).
The abundant current research regarding the possible negative impact of CSR for certain firms
questions the monotonicity of the efficacy of CSR. In other words, even though CSR has shown to
increase value for some firms, it may make many other firms worse off. If CSR does not always
lead to better performance, diverting valuable and scarce resources to CSR activities is fundamen-
tally a risky investment decision to make. This uncertainty of achieving the expected outcome from
CSR constitutes the risky nature of CSR. However, when assessing CSR’s impact on firm value,
the current literature generally overlooked the riskiness of CSR investments. In other words, it
mainly focuses on the change in the level of firm value (statistically: the change in the mean of the
resulting distribution) (e.g. Flammer, 2018; Hillman and Keim, 2001; Hull and Rothenberg, 2008;
Jayachandran et al., 2013), neglecting the possible simultaneous impact on the reliability of the
effect (statistically: the change in the variability of the distribution).
Scholars have shown the danger of understanding an investment’s impact on firm value without
considering the risk associated with it (e.g. Duffee, 1995; Figenbaum and Thomas, 1986; Parida
et al., 2016). High volatility of the expected outcome of an investment is usually unacceptable for
firms because of the danger of falling into tail risk, which can often bring about severe financial
distress (Osiyevskyy et al., 2020; Stulz, 1996). Therefore, for managers, it is just as important to
understand the variability of the potential return of an investment as it is to measure the expected
(average) return (Osiyevskyy et al., 2020; Parida et al., 2016). Measuring return without consider-
ing the risk associated with the investment is problematic because the risk nature of investment
reflects the likelihood of it reaching the expected return. With an emphasis on only the expected
return, the abundant current research only reveals one side of the coin, and thus provides limited
guidance to managers and investors. Without understanding the risk associated with CSR, manag-
ers are practically taking a gamble when they invest in CSR activities: it may look good, but there
is no guarantee that they can achieve it.
Lu et al. 3

This article intends to fill these research gaps by answering two research questions: (1) What is
CSR’s impact on the variability of firm value distribution? (2) Are there contingencies that make
CSR’s impact on firm value more reliable (less volatile)? Empirically, we investigate CSR’s simul-
taneous impact on both the mean and the variance of the resulting value distribution, with the latter
representing the risk nature of CSR. Moreover, anchored in the resource-based view (RBV), we
aim at understanding how this CSR–variance relationship is affected by two main types of resources
that may affect the riskiness of CSR: slack (tangible resources) and risk management capability
(intangible resources).
With the primary objective of understanding how firms can realize “doing safe while doing
good,” this article aims to add a second layer to the proposition of “doing well by doing good,” and,
therefore, makes two important theoretical contributions. First, the study enhances our understand-
ing of the uncertainties and riskiness of CSR and develops a holistic view of CSR’s effects in real
business situations. By investigating CSR’s simultaneous impact on both the level and the variabil-
ity of value distribution, we aim to provide insightful theoretical contributions in understanding the
risk-reward trade-off of CSR. Second, this research supplements current knowledge of the instru-
mental value of CSR by exploring the contingencies under which CSR may be more successful in
producing expected instrumental value. We propose that understanding how to make CSR’s impact
on firm value more reliable is just as important as understanding how to increase such impact.
This research provides practical guidance to managers and investors and answers the call to
contribute to practical implications of CSR research (Wang et al., 2020). First, we help managers
determine when investing valuable resources in CSR will be more likely to succeed and when hav-
ing high CSR performance is likely to be a risky gamble given certain contexts. We show managers
that although having a high CSR performance may lead to possible abnormal returns, they should
not make decisions to invest in CSR without considering the risk-return trade-off of CSR. Second,
it provides managers with guidance on building appropriate channels to improve the efficacy of
CSR and ensures that managers realize a reliable value increase from CSR. To improve the reliabil-
ity of CSR’s impact on value, managers may need to explore avenues to develop relevant resources
and capabilities to mitigate the risk of CSR.

Theory background and hypotheses development


CSR and reliability of firm value creation
From the RBV perspective, whether a corporate strategy or action leads to competitive advantage
depends on the ability of the strategy or action to accumulate a stock of valuable resources or capa-
bilities (Dierickx and Cool, 1989). The traditional proposition of “doing well by doing good” sug-
gests that CSR engagement has a positive impact on firm value through building social recognition
(e.g. Godfrey, 2005; Hillman and Keim, 2001), developing corporate reputation (e.g. Brammer and
Pavelin, 2006; Fombrun and Shanley, 1990; Turban and Greening, 1997), fostering efficient tech-
nologies (e.g. Porter and Kramer, 2006), reducing firm risks (Boutin-Dufresne and Savaria, 2004;
Godfrey et al., 2009; Lu et al., 2022; Luo and Bhattacharya, 2009; Shiu and Yang, 2017), and
attracting responsible investors (e.g. Chava, 2014; Cheng et al., 2014; Graves and Waddock, 1994;
Kim et al., 2019). From the perspective of asset stock accumulation (Dierickx and Cool, 1989), the
flow of investment of organizational resources toward CSR activities leads to the accumulation of
a stock of “moral capital” (Godfrey, 2005), which can underpin the set of value-creating mecha-
nisms listed above. Importantly, the accumulated stock of moral capital is firm-specific and not
tradable on the strategic factors market (Dierickx and Cool, 1989). As such, following the RBV
framework, CSR performance can lead to the emergence of valuable, rare, inimitable, and
4 Strategic Organization 00(0)

non-substitutable resources of a given firm (e.g. corporate reputation and social recognition devel-
oped from CSR performance), which ultimately underpin the firm’s sustained competitive advan-
tage to outperform its rivals (Barney, 1991).
To achieve the desired financial outcome from CSR, it is necessary to translate a firm’s CSR
activities into its stock of moral capital and utilize this stock to gain rent. Yet, a positive outcome
from this process is not guaranteed. The pay-off from CSR performance is highly unreliable con-
sidering the complex and multi-stage mechanisms of translating CSR investments into shareholder
value. That is, while CSR can lead to an increase in firm value for many firms, it can also make
many others worse off. For example, Danone CEO Emmanuel Faber’s ambition in CSR changed
the firm into an “enterprise à mission,” a company with a purpose, and made it one of the only 10
companies worldwide to receive the “AAA” rating in global environmental rating (Van Gansbeke,
2021). But the company’s success in CSR did not help it thrive financially. Compared to its rivals,
the company fell far short in profitability and shareholder returns, leading to the forced resignation
of its CEO in 2021 (Kostov, 2021).
Many current studies have identified the possible non-significant or even negative impact of
CSR on firm value. For example, Masulis and Reza (2015) found that shareholders react nega-
tively to increases in corporate philanthropic activities. Wang et al.’s (2015) results show that only
the economic pillar of CSR positively impacts firm performance in Taiwan, whereas the environ-
mental and social pillars of CSR generally have no impact on performance. Servaes and Tamayo
(2013) argue that CSR is detrimental to firms with low consumer awareness.
Such unpredictability of achieving a desired financial outcome by having a good CSR perfor-
mance represents the risky nature of CSR investment. In practice, the riskiness of an investment is
measured using the variance of its expected outcome (Tobin, 1958). The understanding and estima-
tion of variance are important to practitioners since variance reflects how likely it is that the invest-
ment will achieve its expected outcome. A high-risk investment, one that has a high probability of
generating high reward but also of suffering high loss, is usually unacceptable for firms, because
the tail risk may exceed the firms’ risk tolerance level, and a high volatility in expected cash flow
creates a high cost of financial distress for both the shareholders and the stakeholders (Cornell and
Shapiro, 1987). Therefore, estimating and managing the volatility of expected returns is essentially
important for a corporation’s strategic actions (Engle, 2004). Discussing the expected return of
CSR without considering the volatility of such expected return provides limited guidance to prac-
titioners in terms of the fate of their investment in this activity and the subsequent formation of
moral capital. In other words, although we may observe a general financial reward of achieving
high CSR performance on average, the fate of any particular participant in its adventure in CSR
remains uncertain ex-ante, making CSR investment a gamble for any given firm: you either win
big or lose big.
In essence, the riskiness of CSR lies in a firms’ ability, or inability, to transfer CSR performance
into its stock of moral capital and exploit rent from the stock that outweighs the direct cost and
opportunity cost of CSR. Given that the mechanisms that lead to a positive impact of CSR on firm
value have been extensively discussed in the current literature (e.g. Godfrey, 2005; Godfrey et al.,
2009; Lu et al., 2022; Porter and Kramer, 2006), this study focuses on the unpredictability of such
impact from a reversed perspective. That is, to explain the risk nature of CSR, we focus on estab-
lishing the reasons why CSR can be detrimental to some firms while acknowledging that it will
lead to financial benefit for many other firms. As is the case with all accumulated stock assets
(Dierickx and Cool, 1989), the development of CSR-based moral capital is always a context-
dependent, sometimes even stochastic, process, with causal ambiguity preventing not only com-
petitive imitation but also the firm’s own ability to scale up CSR programs by repeating what
worked or modifying what did not work in the past.
Lu et al. 5

Many reasons contribute to the risk nature of CSR. Such reasons may either prevent a firm from
accumulating a stock of moral capital or increase the direct cost and opportunity cost of such accu-
mulation, leading to a higher deviation from the expected outcome. First, from the classic Friedman
perspective, CSR diverts valuable resources from business operations (Friedman, 1970), which
may force a firm to forego other potentially profitable projects. The opportunity costs may offset
the benefits of CSR for many firms; furthermore, opportunity costs have their own dynamics and
hence add to the lack of reliability in CSR’s outcomes. For example, for a firm experiencing finan-
cial hardship, CSR may be detrimental to its economic performance and may lead to negative value
implications if it cannot transfer high CSR performance into its stock of moral capital. As another
example, an employee-oriented CSR program may involve paying for employees’ continuing edu-
cation or providing service for their schoolchildren (Mirvis, 2012). Although these CSR programs
may improve employee efficiency and build their loyalty (Edmans, 2011), such investment may
also limit a firm’s ability to provide competitive compensation, especially when the firm’s budget
is tight, leading to an increase in opportunity cost.
Second, the riskiness of CSR in value creation can be manifested in the diverse opinions of
shareholders about high CSR performance. On one hand, high CSR performance is often wel-
comed by many investors (Graves and Waddock, 1994; Hawn et al., 2018), especially those port-
folio investors with a social goal (Arjaliès, 2010). For such social responsibility investors (SRI),
social screening helps build a stronger portfolio and leads to higher expected returns (Auer, 2016).
Therefore, increasing CSR performance can lead to a positive stock market reaction. On the other
hand, achieving high CSR performance can also be viewed by shareholders as a sign of an agency
problem and thus lead to shareholder sanctions (Masulis and Reza, 2015). CSR may be employed
by CEOs to pursue self-interests and satisfy personal needs for attention and image reinforcement,
and consequently is perceived by the public as not being genuine (Petrenko et al., 2016). The pur-
suit of managerial self-interest through CSR might cause shareholders to penalize high levels of
CSR if the motivation for CSR is not well justified (Masulis and Reza, 2015). Essentially, the
unpredictability of shareholder perception about high CSR performance contributes to the riski-
ness of CSR.
Finally, an established view suggests that CSR’s impact on corporate financial performance
(CFP) is not monotonic in nature, that is, that high CSR performance only leads to high financial
performance under certain conditions (e.g. Du et al., 2011; Hull and Rothenberg, 2008; Jo and Na,
2012; Liu et al., 2020; Servaes and Tamayo, 2013; Wang and Bansal, 2012). For example, Hull and
Rothenberg (2008) argue that CSR is only value-enhancing for less innovative firms and in indus-
tries with less differentiation. Servaes and Tamayo (2013) found that the CSR–CFP relationship is
positive only when customer awareness is high, whereas CSR may impact performance negatively
for firms with low customer awareness. Du et al. (2011) show that a CSR strategy is effective only
when customers actively participate in the CSR initiative; otherwise, it becomes detrimental to
performance. CSR is also found to increase value only for firms in an informationally opaque
industry (Ramchander et al., 2012), firms with a long-term orientation (Wang and Bansal, 2012),
and firms in industries with high institutionalization of CSR (Brower and Dacin, 2020).
As such, we argue that although CSR has the potential to lead to value creation, as shown by the
general consensus in the current literature (Barnett et al., 2020; Orlitzky and Benjamin, 2001), this
effect is unreliable, since CSR also increases the volatility of value distribution across firms. This
increase in the volatility of value distribution represents the risk nature of CSR. In other words, we
hypothesize that CSR is a strategic asset, but it has a risky nature. That is, whereas, ceteris paribus,
firms with low CSR performance are likely to achieve similar value outcomes, the firms with high
CSR performance are likely to obtain a broad range of value outcomes.
6 Strategic Organization 00(0)

Hypothesis 1. CSR has a negative impact on the reliability of firm value (i.e. a positive impact
on the variability of value distribution). That is, firms with higher CSR performance have higher
variability in value distribution compared to firms with lower CSR performance.

RBV and the moderating effect on the reliability of value creation


When CSR does not reliably lead to expected value creation, it becomes a risky choice for managers
and raises concerns for investors and stakeholders (Barnea and Rubin, 2010; Cheng et al., 2016).
The risky nature of CSR requires managers to exercise discretion when diverting valuable resources
to it and be able to justify their actions. Thus, understanding the factors that increase the reliability
of the efficacy of CSR is important because it guides managers to make more robust CSR decisions
and helps them solicit support for their actions. The RBV framework provides insight into the
resources that possibly influence a firm’s performance and risk (Aragón-Correa and Sharma, 2003;
Barney, 1991; Barney et al., 2001; Helfat and Peteraf, 2003). Of the full spectrum of possible
resources that may influence the riskiness of CSR investment, we limit our exposition to two salient
factors that might be the most relevant, both stemming directly from the argument presented above
for the baseline hypothesis. We propose that the reliability of the CSR–value relationship, that is, the
risk nature of CSR, is moderated by the availability of two fundamental types of resources that are
important for managing such risk: organizational slack (tangible resources) and risk management
capability (intangible resources) (Helfat and Peteraf, 2003; Henderson and Cockburn, 1994).

Organizational slack. The first focal moderator, organizational slack, occupies a prominent role in
the RBV framework, determining the availability of the resources that influence a firm’s allocation
decisions, risk, and asset stock accumulation (Aragón-Correa and Sharma, 2003; Barney, 1991;
Barney et al., 2001; Helfat and Peteraf, 2003). Organizational slack is defined as the additional
resources, especially financial assets, held by a firm in excess of the minimum required amount
given the current output level (Cyert and March, 1963; Nohria and Gulati, 1996). Considering that
the source of CSR investments, as well as their direct and opportunity costs, could to a large extent
be determined by organizational slack, prior studies stress the non-trivial role of this internal factor
in shaping the performance outcomes of CSR engagement (e.g. Arora and Dharwadkar, 2011;
Bhandari and Javakhadze, 2017; Mattingly and Olsen, 2018; Zhang et al., 2018).
The argument about the slack–CSR interaction stems from the “slack resources theory” as sum-
marized by Orlitzky et al. (2003: 406). The theory finds its deep roots in RBV, treating organiza-
tional slack as available resources for discretionary investments such as CSR (Orlitzky et al., 2003;
Shahzad et al., 2016). Organizational slack helps a firm reconcile its internal conflicts of resource
requirements among different functions of operations, increases internal operation flexibility
(Miller and Leiblein, 1996), and buffers a firm from external environmental turbulence (Cooper
et al., 1994; Cyert and March, 1963). It influences the enactment of organizational activities when
a firm reconfigures its resource endowments by shifting resources into different operations and
markets (George, 2005). Organizational slack is thus regarded by organization theory as a valuable
asset for firm growth and organizational performance (e.g. Barney, 1991; Daniel et al., 2004;
George, 2005; Penrose, 1959).
Given the availability of resources, firms often need to make decisions to allocate valuable
resources to a broad range of functional areas, such as CSR development, diversification, and other
value-added projects. The resource allocation process becomes more challenging when different
functional areas compete for a scarce resource (Noda and Bower, 1996). In contrast, substantial
slack relaxes a firm’s decision-making and allows it to take on multiple competitive projects
(Dolmans et al., 2014). Therefore, firms with more slack are less likely to experience difficulties in
Lu et al. 7

allocating resources to CSR, thus reducing the opportunity cost of CSR investment. For example,
energy firms sometimes need to invest in clean energy and carbon reduction technologies to reduce
their carbon footprint under institutional pressures (Petersen and Vredenburg, 2009). Such an
investment may drain resources from other value-added operations for firms with less slack, but
not for firms with excess slack (Evans, 1991; Miller and Leiblein, 1996).
Moreover, managers with more available slack have more flexibility in choosing the most suit-
able CSR strategy. Taking CSR related to employee engagement as an example, firms may have
choices among paid leave, lunch programs, and education rebates as superior employee benefit
programs to increase employee productivity and employee retention (Mirvis, 2012). The required
investment varies among these different benefit programs. Managers with limited slack may be
stuck with non-cash incentives regardless of the employees’ preferences. Consequently, inflexibil-
ity caused by limited slack increases the uncertainty of the CSR outcome, leading to an increased
variance in firm performance. In contrast, managers with more slack can choose the best combina-
tion of cash incentives and non-cash incentives, leading to decreasing firm performance variance.
As suggested by Waddock and Graves (1997), firms with a higher level of slack are more flexible
to participate in CSR which could lead to a reliable outcome but may require more resources,
whereas firms with a lower level of slack have limited options, if any, in their choice of CSR strat-
egy. Also, the flexibility of choosing among different options improves the speed of response to
external changes (Evans, 1991). As such, organizational slack provides a cushion for firms to
maintain a lower performance variance because of the flexibility and the quick response speed
(Cyert and March, 1963).
However, it should not be ignored that slack represents inefficiency in business operations
(Antle and Eppen, 1985; Jensen and Meckling, 1976), which stems from the holding cost of excess
organizational slack (Galbraith, 1973; Tan and Peng, 2003). Scholars also believe that holding
excess slack can be a sign of an agency problem where managers are overly risk-averse in making
investment decisions (Jensen and Meckling, 1976; Leibenstein, 1969; Nohria and Gulati, 1996).
Therefore, to consider whether organizational slack reduces the riskiness of CSR, we need to
understand and evaluate the relationship between the value addition of using slack to create a stock
of moral capital through CSR and the value disruption represented by the inefficiency in holding
slack. When a firm has an aggressive CSR strategy and maintains high slack, it reduces the chance
of falling into an unsuccessful CSR strategy but increases its cost of operations. In other words, the
firm trades off efficiency for certainty. A low-slack firm, in contrast, may benefit more from its
CSR performance because its CSR effort may be considered as more sincere. For example, during
the 2021 Henan rainstorm disaster, both ANTA, the industry leader in sports equipment in China,
and ERKE, a market follower who was thought to be “broke” at the time, donated 50 million Yuan
to the Red Cross for the province’s recovery. After the donation gained social attention, ERKE
received much higher recognition from society and had a 52 times short-term increase and a 280%
annual increase in sales, a much better outcome compared to ANTA (Faithfull, 2021; Lv et al.,
2021). The risk, however, is that the financial outcome due to CSR is not guaranteed. If a low-slack
firm cannot convert its high CSR performance into high rewards, the overconsumption of resources
may lead to financial distress. In other words, when a firm has an aggressive CSR strategy but
maintains a low level of slack, it gambles between higher performance and higher losses. Thus,
Hypothesis 2 is developed:

Hypothesis 2. Organizational slack positively moderates CSR’s impact on the reliability of


value creation, such that CSR’s impact on firm value is more (less) reliable for firms with higher
(lower) slack.
8 Strategic Organization 00(0)

Although slack should have a significant impact on the riskiness of CSR in creating firm value,
this effect may not be universal for all types of organizational slacks. Not all slack is created equal.
Each type of slack differs from others in terms of availability, cost, and redeployability (e.g.
Bourgeois and Singh, 1983). Therefore, to further understand the impact of slack on the risk nature
of CSR, we need to compare such impact between different types of slacks.
Bourgeois and Singh (1983) defined three types of organizational slack: available, recoverable,
and potential slack. Available slack refers to the type of slack that is readily available for out-of-
pocket expenses, such as cash and cash equivalents. Recoverable slack refers to uncommitted
resources that are not immediately available but can be changed into available slack with some
effort, that is, accounts receivable, prepaid expenses, and inventory (Bourgeois and Singh, 1983;
Tyler and Caner, 2016; Vanacker et al., 2017). Finally, potential slack refers to a firm’s capability
to generate future slack (Bourgeois, 1981; Bourgeois and Singh, 1983; Tyler and Caner, 2016). The
availability and redeployability of different types of slacks are different (Bourgeois and Singh,
1983). Available slack, which consists of mostly cash and cash equivalents, represents the highest
redeployability, whereas potential slack, which represents the expectation of a firm’s future financ-
ing capability, has the lowest redeployability (Bourgeois and Singh, 1983).
As discussed previously, organizational slack reduces the riskiness of CSR performance by
reducing the opportunity cost of CSR and increasing the flexibility of CSR strategies, at the cost of
the reduced efficiency that is associated with holding slack. The key argument about the risk-
reduction effect of slack is that it helps firms balance between non-market strategies such as CSR
and the core business operations. As a result of this, redeployable slack is more likely to create such
a risk-reduction effect. First, when a firm faces discretionary expenses, highly redeployable slack
has higher priority in consumption due to its high flexibility and availability for discretionary use
by managers (Sharfman, 1985; Sharfman et al., 1988). As CSR often requires immediate out-of-
pocket expenses that lead to a reduction in a firm’s current and future cash flow (Sprinkle and
Maines, 2010), highly redeployable slack is more likely to create a flexible CSR strategy than slack
with low redeployability. Second, liquidating recoverable slack and financing through potential
slack increases operation costs and creates uncertainty (Sharfman et al., 1988), making their effect
in reducing the riskiness of CSR unpredictable.
We predict that available slack, being the most redeployable slack, should have the strongest
effect in reducing the volatility of value creation through CSR. Although recoverable slack is less
flexible and less redeployable compared with available slack, it can be changed into immediately
available resources with some effort and at a cost. A firm may have a certain level of choices and
flexibility in developing its CSR with recoverable slack, which can lead to a decrease in the vari-
ance of firm performance. Moreover, a firm may directly use its inventory to support its CSR by
donating the inventory as goodwill or using it to create social benefit. For example, Amazon imple-
mented a donation program in August 2019 for third-party sellers that store their inventory in
Amazon’s warehouses. In this program, called “Fulfillment by Amazon Donations,” sellers could
choose to donate their unsold or unwanted products through a network of US non-profits instead
of destroying them (Eugene, 2019). In contrast, since potential slack does not reflect a firm’s capa-
bility to meet short-term obligations, it should not have a significant impact on the reliability of
value creation through CSR. In sum, we hypothesize that more redeployable slack is more effective
at reducing the risk associated with CSR than less redeployable slack.

Hypothesis 3. The moderating effect of slack on CSR’s impact on the reliability of value crea-
tion is contingent on the redeployability of the type of slack, such that highly redeployable slack
has a higher effect than less redeployable slack.
Lu et al. 9

Risk management capabilities. The second moderator of our study emphasizes the possible organi-
zational capabilities embedded in enterprise risk management (ERM) practices that might mitigate
the riskiness of CSR. RBV stresses the importance of organizational capabilities as a valuable
source of competitive advantage and provides insight into the possible moderating effect of organi-
zational capabilities on CSR’s effect on firm performance reliability (Aragón-Correa and Sharma,
2003; Barney, 1991; Barney et al., 2001; Helfat and Peteraf, 2003). Organizational capabilities are
embedded in firm routines and involve the transformation of physical inputs into outputs (Collis,
1994). Broadly speaking, organizational capabilities can be classified into three categories (Collis,
1994): (1) capability to perform the basic functional activities of the firm (e.g. risk management);
(2) capability to learn, adapt, change, and renew over time (e.g. innovation); and (3) capability to
recognize the intrinsic value of other resources or to develop novel strategies that transform into
profitability (e.g. CSR). The riskiness of CSR is reflected by the heterogeneous capability in trans-
forming CSR performance into financial benefit, which should intuitively be impacted by a firm’s
capabilities in performing basic functional activities such as risk management (Kuo et al., 2021).
In other words, we believe that a superior risk management practice, that is, the ERM practice,
should function as a costly risk mitigation mechanism that reduces the uncertainty of CSR
performance.
ERM is defined by the Committee of Sponsoring Organizations (COSO) as “a process ...
designed to identify potential events that may affect the entity, and manage risk to be within its risk
appetite, to provide reasonable assurance regarding the achievement of entity objectives” (COSO,
2004: 16). Firms with ERM have sophisticated risk management capabilities to manage corporate
risks at the head office level and support two-way communication between the head office and
each business unit.
As stated previously, the three main mechanisms that lead to the riskiness of CSR are the oppor-
tunity cost of financial hardship, diverse investor perceptions of CSR, and non-monotonic impact
of CSR on value. We propose that firms’ risk management capabilities developed through ERM
can help mitigate these mechanisms. First, scholars have argued that ERM helps firms reduce the
cost of financing (Berry-Stölzle and Xu, 2018) and reduce the marginal cost of risk-bearing (Eckles
et al., 2014). This means that when a firm requires additional funding from the capital market due
to its aggressive CSR strategy, ERM firms will experience lower direct and opportunity costs of
financing. Moreover, the residual risk caused by CSR strategies can also be better managed since
ERM help reduce the cost of risk-bearing by considering corporate risk as a holistic portfolio. This
reduces the possibility of financial hardship when a firm pursues an aggressive CSR strategy.
Second, a firm’s CSR strategy is often considered as a sign of an agency problem between the
shareholders and the firm (Masulis and Reza, 2015). Moreover, if a firm increases its external
financing for CSR, it also inevitably incurs additional financial risk, which is often triggered by the
agency cost (between the debt holders and the firm) of excessive leverage (Jensen, 1986; Kim and
Sorensen, 1986). In contrast, investors usually consider ERM as a sign of good managerial capa-
bilities (Nair et al., 2014). It reduces information asymmetry between a firm and its stakeholders
since it requires a firm to build sound relationships with a variety of stakeholders and incorporate
their concerns into its risk management process (Dickinson, 2001; Lu et al., 2022; Nocco and
Stulz, 2006). Therefore, a firm can achieve alignment by having complementary CSR strategy and
ERM practices. This alignment enables the firm’s investors to achieve a better understanding of the
risks associated with CSR and incorporate their risk management considerations into CSR
decision-making.
Finally, since the ERM program facilitates two-way communication between business units and
the head office, and between stakeholders and the firm (Lee and Kleffner, 2003), it enables a firm
to adapt its CSR strategy to the changing external environment. The two-way communication
10 Strategic Organization 00(0)

channel also helps a firm develop idiosyncratic CSR strategies to accommodate the different envi-
ronments its business units experience. This makes the financial outcome of CSR performance
more monotonic. In other words, firms with ERM programs may experience a more reliable out-
come of their CSR engagement. For example, scholars have argued that CSR creates more value
when customer awareness is high (Servaes and Tamayo, 2013) and when customers actively par-
ticipate in making the CSR strategies (Du et al., 2011). One significant difference between ERM
and traditional risk management practice is that ERM considers stakeholder concerns when assess-
ing the risk portfolio and incorporates stakeholder interests in risk treatment, including that of the
customers (COSO, 2004, 2017). Therefore, customer preferences are inherently an important com-
ponent of a firm’s risk assessment, analysis, and treatment process for ERM firms (D’Arcy and
Brogan, 2001). This allows ERM firms to pursue an aggressive CSR strategy while effectively
incorporating customer interests in the decision-making process, thus reducing the probability of
backfire due to a lack of trust from customers.
However, similar to the discussion about organizational slack, the buffer provided by ERM on
the reliability of value creation through CSR is not without cost. ERM itself is a costly process that
requires a significant input of both financial and human resources (Harner, 2013; Lin et al., 2012).
Therefore, firms that use ERM to reduce the risk of CSR need to consider the trade-off between the
risk borne by having an aggressive CSR strategy and the cost to mitigate such risk through ERM.
Considering this trade-off leads to a decreased probability that high CSR firms fall under the tails
on both sides of the value distribution. In other words, the outcome of CSR is more predictable
when a firm has an ERM program. Hypothesis 4 is thus developed:

Hypothesis 4. Risk management capability positively moderates CSR’s impact on the reliability
of value creation, such that CSR’s impact on firm value is more (less) reliable for firms that
adopted (did not adopt) ERM.

Research method
Sample and data
We constructed our sample by combining the Compustat, MSCI ESG (formally the KLD data-
base), Standard and Poor’s (S&P) Capital IQ, and Rating Specific databases. The number of rating
criteria in each dimension and the definitions of some remaining rating criteria of ESG were
changed significantly after 2011. Therefore, we chose 2011 as the cut-off year and obtained data
between 2002 and 2011. Our final data consist of 4713 firm-year observations (down to 3914
observations after considering Dynamic Panel Structures).

Dependent variables
Following previous literature (e.g. Albuquerque et al., 2019; Hawn and Ioannou, 2016; Jayachandran
et al., 2013; Servaes and Tamayo, 2013; Surroca et al., 2010), we used Tobin’s Q to measure firm
market value because of its forward-looking nature (Jayachandran et al., 2013), its long-term ori-
entation (Surroca et al., 2010), its independence of managerial manipulation (Jayachandran et al.,
2013), and its comparability among firms from different industries (Nekhili et al., 2017). Tobin’s
Q is measured as the sum of the market value of equity, the liquidation value of preferred shares,
and the book value of debt, divided by the book value of assets (Chung and Pruitt, 1994;
Jayachandran et al., 2013).
Lu et al. 11

The variance of firm value represents the predictive power of the line of best fit. It is measured
as the level of deviation of the actual value from the predicted value (Fleming and Sorenson, 2001;
Sørensen, 2002; Sorenson and Sørensen, 2001). A high level of variance represents a low level of
reliability of the mean prediction, that is, a high risk of not being able to achieve the predicted
mean. Following previous literature (e.g. Fleming, 2001; Fleming and Sorenson, 2001; Harvey,
1976; Sørensen, 2002; Sorenson and Sørensen, 2001), we measure the variance of market value as
the log-squared residuals of Tobin’s Q in the mean regressions.

Independent variables
We measure CSR using the commonly adopted MSCI ESG database. MSCI measures CSR using
a well-developed matrix of strengths and weaknesses. Each of the three dimensions (environmen-
tal, social, and governance) is assessed using a series of strengths and weaknesses criteria, with
each criterion given a value of “0” or “1.” The value of “1” in a strength criterion means that the
firm met or exceeded the minimum requirement of the criterion, whereas the value of “1” in a
weakness means that the firm did not meet the minimum requirement (MSCI ESG Research,
2015). Many scholars have criticized the combination of strength and weakness criteria for creat-
ing an indexed CSR because they measure different concepts of CSR and corporate social irrespon-
sibility, respectively (e.g. Godfrey et al., 2009; Mattingly and Berman, 2006). Therefore, we used
CSR strengths to measure our CSR variable.
The rating criteria of the MSCI ESG database constantly change over time. In order to enhance
the comparability of the criteria over time, we followed the current literature and used the CSR
strength percentage score (rate) instead of the raw number of CSR strengths (e.g. Albuquerque
et al., 2019; Deng et al., 2013; Servaes and Tamayo, 2013). The CSR rate in each dimension was
calculated as the sum of the strength scores of each dimension divided by the number of strength
criteria of the dimension. The final CSR was calculated as the sum of strength rates of all dimen-
sions in MSCI.

Moderators
The first moderator is organizational slack. In this article, we focus on three types of organizational
slack: (1) available slack, (2) recoverable slack, and (3) potential slack. Following previous
research (e.g. Bourgeois and Singh, 1983; Kim et al., 2008; Singh, 1986; Tyler and Caner, 2016;
Vanacker et al., 2017), we use financial ratios to measure different types of slacks. As available
slack represents the availability of immediate cash resources as a percentage of total assets
(Vanacker et al., 2017), it is operationalized as cash and short-term assets as a percentage of total
assets. A high level of available slack means that the company has extra cash and short-term assets
to pay for immediate obligations or make prompt investments. As recoverable slack measures the
availability of resources that have not been absorbed by current operations, such as accounts
receivable, inventory, and prepaid expenses, we measure it using the current ratio (Bourgeois and
Singh, 1983; Iyer and Miller, 2008; Tyler and Caner, 2016). A higher current ratio means that a
larger portion of current assets has not yet been committed to paying current liabilities and hence
represents higher available slack. Potential slack measures a firm’s ability to obtain further debt
financing (Daniel et al., 2004; Iyer and Miller, 2008; Tyler and Caner, 2016). We use the debt-to-
equity ratio to measure potential slack (Iyer and Miller, 2008; Tyler and Caner, 2016). A high debt-
to-equity ratio represents a low ability to obtain further debt financing, hence a low level of
potential slack; whereas a low debt-to-equity ratio represents a high ability to borrow more
(Bourgeois and Singh, 1983; Iyer and Miller, 2008; Tyler and Caner, 2016).
12 Strategic Organization 00(0)

The second moderator measures a firm’s risk management capability. As stated above, based on
the current literature in risk management, it is generally believed that a holistic risk management
practice, for example, ERM, imparts superior capability to identify, analyze, and treat risk in a
strategic manner, and thus represents better risk management capability. Therefore, we measure
risk management capability using a binary variable that identifies the existence of an integrated
risk management practice (i.e. ERM). Extensive literature in the risk management and insurance
discipline has established a standard method to measure the existence of ERM (e.g. Berry-Stölzle
and Xu, 2018; Eckles et al., 2014; Hoyt and Liebenberg, 2011; Lu et al., 2022; Pagach and Warr,
2011). Following this standard method, we first conducted a thorough company-by-company
search in Factiva, company annual reports, and social media using keywords of “ERM, chief risk
officer, risk committee, integrated risk management, consolidated risk management, strategic risk
management, and holistic risk management” (Berry-Stölzle and Xu, 2018; Eckles et al., 2014;
Hoyt and Liebenberg, 2011; Lu et al., 2022). We then carefully read each hit and identified whether
and when a firm established its ERM program. The dummy variable, ERM, takes the value of “1”
starting in the first year that a firm established an ERM program and thereafter “0” if it does not
have an ERM program in a given year.

Control variables
We include control variables that are commonly used in CSR value literature. We control for firm
size, operationalized as the logarithm of total assets because larger firms have more resources and
are under higher external pressure regarding social obligations. We control for the market-to-book
ratio because it has a positive correlation with Tobin’s Q (Villalonga, 2004) and CSR (Cheung
et al., 2010). We control for firm sales growth, measured as the change in sales in the current year
divided by sales in the previous year, because it impacts firm performance (McGuire et al., 1988)
and CSR (Cai et al., 2012). We control for systematic risk, operationalized as S&P 1-year beta,
because CSR interacts with systematic risk in determining firm performance (Albuquerque et al.,
2019). Previous literature shows that innovation influences both a firm’s CSR strategy (Candi
et al., 2019) and value creation. Therefore, we also control for R&D intensity, which is operational-
ized as R&D investment divided by total sales (e.g. Hull and Rothenberg, 2008; Kelm et al., 1995).
We also control for dividend, operationalized as dividend per share, as dividend reflects future
earning capability (e.g. Arnott and Asness, 2003; Nissim and Ziv, 2001; Zhou and Ruland, 2006),
which influences both CSR and firm expected value. We include year-fixed effects in all regres-
sions to eliminate the confounding effects of the time trend. The possible time-invariant covariates
(most notably, fixed effects of the firm’s industry) are not included in the regressions because we
employ a within-firm specification that accounts for all time-invariant factors. All independent and
control variables are lagged by 1 year.

Model specification and identification strategy


In order to assess CSR’s impact on the level (statistically: mean) and the reliability (statistically:
variance) of firm value simultaneously, we apply the multiplicative heteroscedasticity estimation
(MHE) model (Davidian and Carroll, 1987; Harvey, 1976). This method has been widely used to
investigate the simultaneous effect of the independent variable on the mean and variance of the
dependent variable in various disciplines (e.g. Davidian and Carroll, 1987; Fleming and Sorenson,
2001; Harvey, 1976; Kim and Seltzer, 2011; Shirokova et al., 2020; Sørensen, 2002; Sorenson and
Sørensen, 2001). The MHE model has two sets of regressions (mean and variability equations) in
Lu et al. 13

each estimation to test the associations between the dependent variables and the independent vari-
ables simultaneously, as shown below

Qi ,t +1 = X i ,t B + ε i ,t +1 (1)
Z i ,t Γ
ε i2, t +1 = e ui ,t +1 (2)

where Qi ,t +1 represents the value (Tobin’s Q) of a firm i in period t + 1, X i ,t and Z i ,t are vectors of
predictors, including the independent variable, the moderators, the interaction terms, and the con-
trol variables, in period t, B and Γ are the vectors of regression weights, ε i ,t +1 and ui ,t +1 are the error
terms, in the first and second regressions, respectively. A positive value of a parameter β in B
means that the independent variable has a positive impact on the mean of the dependent variable
distribution (equation (1)), whereas a positive value of a parameter γ in Γ means that the independ-
ent variable has a simultaneous positive impact on the dispersion (variance) of the dependent vari-
able distribution (equation (2)). Following previous literature (e.g. Sorenson and Sørensen, 2001),
we used the same predictors for the two regressions ( X i ,t = Z i ,t ).
A problem with the estimation is that CSR is endogenously determined, leading to a possible
overestimation of the significance and effect size of the parameter. To address this issue, we apply
the Arellano–Bond dynamic panel data (DPD) estimator (Arellano and Bond, 1991; Arellano and
Bover, 1995; Blundell and Bond, 1998). The DPD model treats the focal predictor (CSR) and the
interaction terms derived from it as endogenous. It controls for unobserved time-variant and time-
invariant trends by applying the lagged independent variables at (t – 1) and further lags, as well as
lagged dependent variable at (t) and further lags as instruments (Arellano and Bond, 1991; Arellano
and Bover, 1995). It also provides an unbiased estimation regardless of whether reverse causality
exists by treating the independent variables with both the lagged self and the lagged dependent
variable (Leszczensky and Wolbring, 2022; Wintoki et al., 2012). In sum, for the mean regressions,
we apply the dynamic panel structure to mitigate endogeneity, and for the variance regressions, we
use ordinary least squares (OLS) regression.

Results
The descriptive statistics and Pearson correlations of all variables are shown in Table 1. The results
show no collinearity issues as no correlation is greater than 0.5 or less than –0.5 (except for the
correlation between size and CSR: 0.58).

CSR and market value distribution


We report the test results for Hypothesis 1 in Model 1 of Table 2. The results show that CSR has a
significant positive impact on both the mean (β = 0.24, p ⩽ 0.01) and the variance of Tobin’s Q
(γ = 0.24, p ⩽ 0.01). The coefficients also have a strong economic size: a 1 standard deviation
increase in CSR (0.51) leads to an increase in Tobin’s Q by 0.122 or an 8.7% increase in the mean
of Tobin’s Q (|mean| = 1.40). More importantly, a 1 standard deviation increase in CSR increases
the variance of Tobin’s Q by 0.122 or a 3.9% increase in the variance of Tobin’s Q (|mean| = 3.13).
Therefore, Hypothesis 1 is supported. As shown in Model 1, CSR is a strategic asset in that it sig-
nificantly increases firm value, with the cost of increased dispersion of Tobin’s Q distribution. In
other words, CSR’s positive impact on Tobin’s Q is not reliable.
14

Table 1. Descriptive statistics.

Mean SD 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11
1. Tobin’s Q 1.40 0.83
2. CSR 0.35 0.51 0.11
3. Available slack 0.11 0.12 0.33 0.11
4. Recoverable slack 1.84 1.02 0.07 –0.11 0.48
5. Potential slack 0.50 20.30 –0.02 0.01 0.00 –0.01
6. RM capability 0.22 0.42 –0.09 0.30 0.03 –0.14 0.00
7. Size 8.40 1.32 –0.04 0.58 –0.03 –0.26 0.02 0.32
8. Market-to-book ratio 3.52 9.30 0.17 0.05 0.04 –0.06 –0.01 0.02 0.00
9. Sales growth 0.09 0.21 0.12 –0.07 0.08 –0.01 0.00 –0.06 –0.03 0.01
10. Systematic risk 1.32 1.11 –0.12 –0.11 0.06 0.09 0.00 –0.02 –0.15 –0.04 –0.02
11. R&D intensity 0.02 0.05 0.25 0.21 0.38 0.26 0.00 0.03 0.13 0.02 0.05 –0.01
12. Dividend 0.07 0.67 0.02 0.03 –0.02 –0.04 0.00 0.01 0.02 0.49 –0.02 –0.04 –0.01

SD: standard deviation; CSR: corporate social responsibility; RM: risk management.
N = 4713 firm-year observations. All Pearson correlations with absolute values above |r| > 0.03 are significant at the p < 0.05 level; all |r| > 0.04 are significant at the p < 0.01
level; all |r| > 0.05 are significant at the p < 0.001 level.
Strategic Organization 00(0)
Table 2. Multiplicative heteroscedasticity regression models for firm value and variance.
Mean regression: Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 Model 5 Model 6
Lu et al.

DV = Qt+1 CSR rate baseline Moderator = Moderator = Moderator = All slack Moderator = ERM
Variance regression: available slack recoverable slack potential slack
DV = ln(et+1)2
Mean (βj) Variance Mean (βj) Variance Mean (βj) Variance Mean (βj) Variance Mean (βj) Variance Mean (βj) Variance
(γj) (γj) (γj) (γj) (γj) (γj)

CSR 0.24** 0.24** 0.24** 0.53*** 0.30** 0.60*** 0.22** 0.14 0.22* 0.58*** 0.26*** 0.52***
(0.08) (0.09) (0.09) (0.12) (0.11) (0.17) (0.08) (0.09) (0.09) (0.18) (0.08) (0.11)
[0.00] [0.01] [0.01] [0.00] [0.01] [0.00] [0.00] [0.11] [0.02] [0.00] [0.00] [0.00]
Available slack 0.96* 3.86*** 1.01† 3.88*** 1.42* 3.70*** 0.98* 4.74***
(0.48) (0.39) (0.58) (0.36) (0.72) (0.37) (0.43) (0.43)
[0.05] [0.00] [0.08] [0.00] [0.05] [0.00] [0.02] [0.00]
Recoverable slack –0.01 –0.04 0.00 –0.05 0.01 0.00 –0.02 –0.14**
(0.07) (0.04) (0.07) (0.04) (0.08) (0.04) (0.06) (0.05)
[0.89] [0.33] [0.99] [0.28] [0.91] [0.93] [0.66] [0.01]
Potential slack 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00*
(0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00)
[0.18] [0.16] [0.29] [0.23] [0.30] [0.31] [0.19] [0.04]
CSR × available slack –0.48 –1.59** –0.47 –1.80*
(0.34) (0.60) (0.43) (0.84)
[0.16] [0.01] [0.27] [0.03]
CSR × recoverable –0.08† –0.22** 0.00 0.03
slack (0.05) (0.08) (0.06) (0.12)
[0.08] [0.01] [0.95] [0.83]
CSR × potential 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00
slack (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00)
[0.27] [0.45] [0.14] [0.87]
RM capability 0.09 –0.05
(0.09) (0.11)
[0.33] [0.67]
CSR × RM capability –0.11† –0.32*
(0.06) (0.14)
[0.09] [0.03]
Firm size –0.18** –0.13*** –0.13* –0.23*** –0.12* –0.21*** –0.17*** –0.06† –0.11** –0.30*** –0.15** –0.20***
(0.06) (0.03) (0.05) (0.03) (0.05) (0.04) (0.05) (0.03) (0.04) (0.04) (0.05) (0.03)
[0.00] [0.00] [0.01] [0.00] [0.02] [0.00] [0.00] [0.06] [0.00] [0.00] [0.01] [0.00]
(Continued)
15
Table 2. (Continued)
16

Mean regression: Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 Model 5 Model 6


DV = Qt+1 CSR rate baseline Moderator = Moderator = Moderator = All slack Moderator = ERM
Variance regression: available slack recoverable slack potential slack
DV = ln(et+1)2
Mean (βj) Variance Mean (βj) Variance Mean (βj) Variance Mean (βj) Variance Mean (βj) Variance Mean (βj) Variance
(γj) (γj) (γj) (γj) (γj) (γj)

Market-to-book ratio 0.00 0.02*** 0.00 0.02*** 0.00 0.01** 0.00 0.01* 0.00 0.01** 0.00 0.01*
(0.01) (0.00) (0.01) (0.00) (0.01) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.01) (0.01)
[0.61] [0.00] [0.46] [0.00] [0.98] [0.00] [0.18] [0.02] [0.19] [0.00] [0.68] [0.02]
Sales growth –0.70* 0.70*** –0.54** 0.38† –0.54** 0.47* –0.67** 0.51* –0.21 0.39* –0.70** 0.65***
(0.32) (0.19) (0.20) (0.22) (0.21) (0.22) (0.24) (0.20) (0.15) (0.18) (0.26) (0.20)
[0.03] [0.00] [0.01] [0.09] [0.01] [0.03] [0.01] [0.01] [0.17] [0.03] [0.01] [0.00]
Systematic risk 0.07 0.08* 0.03 0.00 0.02 –0.01 –0.01 –0.07* 0.01 –0.04 0.07 0.12***
(0.07) (0.04) (0.05) (0.03) (0.05) (0.03) (0.03) (0.03) (0.03) (0.03) (0.06) (0.03)
[0.32] [0.03] [0.58] [0.97] [0.71] [0.72] [0.75] [0.04] [0.78] [0.28] [0.21] [0.00]
R&D intensity 3.45† 6.33*** 1.60 1.77† 1.48 2.54*** 2.07 2.78*** 1.26 2.10* 1.81 3.14***
(1.89) (0.63) (1.32) (1.07) (1.07) (0.75) (1.44) (0.70) (0.99) (0.87) (1.12) (0.72)
[0.07] [0.00] [0.23] [0.10] [0.17] [0.00] [0.15] [0.00] [0.20] [0.02] [0.11] [0.00]
Dividend –0.07 0.08 0.04 0.01 –0.04 0.07 0.01 –0.08 0.00 –0.05 –0.03 0.05
(0.17) (0.05) (0.12) (0.05) (0.10) (0.04) (0.01) (0.06) (0.01) (0.06) (0.11) (0.05)
[0.67] [0.12] [0.73] [0.91] [0.69] [0.13] [0.44] [0.18] [0.73] [0.40] [0.80] [0.26]
Lagged DV 0.76*** 0.73*** 0.73*** 0.70*** 0.71*** 0.76***
(0.05) (0.05) (0.05) (0.06) (0.05) (0.04)
[0.00] [0.00] [0.00] [0.00] [0.00] [0.00]
Constant 1.59*** –2.36*** 1.38*** –1.88*** 1.32** –2.09*** 1.74*** –3.06*** 1.27*** –1.34*** 1.40*** –2.24***
(0.45) (0.30) (0.41) (0.31) (0.42) (0.32) (0.46) (0.32) (0.32) (0.33) (0.39) (0.28)
[0.00] [0.00] [0.00] [0.00] [0.00] [0.00] [0.00] [0.00] [0.00] [0.00] [0.00] [0.00]
Wald χ2 (df) 14,126.90 20,595.52 21,383.18 13,109.38 24,673.16 19,357.86
*** *** *** *** *** ***
AR1 –6.10*** –7.47*** –7.45*** –8.00*** –7.77*** –6.97***
AR2 1.20 1.37 1.47 1.61 1.65 1.20
R2 0.04 0.07 0.07 0.07 0.08 0.04
N 3914 3914 3914 3914 3914 3914 3914 3914 3914 3914 3914 3914

AR1: Arellano-Bond tests for first order autocorrelation; AR2: Arellano-Bond tests for second order autocorrelation; CSR: corporate social responsibility; DV: dependent variable; ERM: enterprise risk
management.
Robust standard errors are reported in parentheses and exact p-values are reported in square brackets.

p ⩽ 0.1; *p ⩽ 0.05; **p ⩽ 0.01; ***p ⩽ 0.001.
Strategic Organization 00(0)
Lu et al. 17

0
Low CSR High CSR

Variance of Tobin's Q -0.5 Low Available


Slack

-1 High Available
Slack

-1.5

-2

-2.5

Figure 1. The moderating effect of available slack.

The moderating effect of organizational slack


The moderating effects of organizational slack on the CSR and firm value variance relationship are
reported in Table 2. We tested the moderating effect of each type of organizational slack separately
in Models 2–4 and the combined effects in Model 5. The results show that the interaction of CSR
and available slack significantly reduces the variance of Tobin’s Q in both the separate model
(γ = –1.59, p ⩽ 0.01) and the combined model (γ = –1.80, p ⩽ 0.05). We plotted the interaction effect
of available slack at ±1 standard deviation based on the coefficients in Model 2 (as shown in
Figure 1) to help visually interpret the results. The figure indicates that when a firm processes high
available slack, higher CSR leads to a much lower increase in the variance of Tobin’s Q compared
to low-slack firms. Moreover, recoverable slack also has a negative and significant moderating
effect (γ = –0.22, p ⩽ 0.01) on the CSR–variance relationship, as shown in Model 3 of Table 2.
Therefore, CSR’s impact on the mean of Tobin’s Q (positive from the first stage regression) is more
reliable for firms with high available (recoverable) slack than low-slack firms. Therefore,
Hypothesis 2 is supported.
Hypothesis 3 states that highly redeployable slack should have more impact on the CSR–
variance relationship than less redeployable slack. We can see some evidence of this in Table 2.
First, more redeployable slack, such as available and recoverable slack, has a significant modera-
tion effect in the separate models (Models 2 and 3). In contrast, the interaction of CSR and poten-
tial slack does not have a significant impact on the variance of Tobin’s Q in either the separated
model or the combined model, as shown in Models 4 and 5. Second, in the full model considering
all interaction effects of different types of slacks, only available slack, being the slack with the
highest redeployability, has a significant moderation effect on the CSR–variance relationship.
Therefore, Hypothesis 3 is supported.

The moderating effect of risk management capabilities


We reported the moderating effect of risk management capabilities in Model 6 of Table 2. Model 6
shows that the interaction of CSR and ERM has a negative correlation with the variance of Tobin’s
Q (γ = –0.32, p ⩽ 0.05), indicating that ERM firms have a lower impact of CSR on the variance of
Tobin’s Q. We plotted the change in variance of Tobin’s Q at ±1 standard deviation of CSR in
18 Strategic Organization 00(0)

0.9

0.7
Variance of Tobin's Q

0.5 No ERM

0.3
ERM
0.1

-0.1 Low CSR High CSR

-0.3

-0.5

Figure 2. The moderating effect of risk management capability.

Figure 2, separating the impact of ERM firms from that of non-ERM firms. Figure 2 reveals that
the positive impact of CSR on the variance of Tobin’s Q is significantly weaker when a firm imple-
ments ERM. Therefore, Hypothesis 4 is supported.

Endogeneity control
As stated before, one of the major concerns with the data is that CSR is endogenously determined,
leading to possible omitted variable bias (OVB). Although the dynamic panel method can reduce
OVB by controlling for biases from the possible time-fixed or path-dependent omitted variables,
there could still be residual biases from unobserved time-variant variables that may impact both
CSR and firm value. To further control for endogeneity, we applied the two-stage instrumental
variable (IV) regression method combined with the dynamic panel structure as a robustness check.
In the first stage, we used non-profit organization (NPO) density as the instrumental variable to
purge out possible endogenous variance from CSR (Lu et al., 2022). NPO density is measured as
the number of NPOs, in 1000, in the state where the firm resides divided by the population density
of the state. The number of NPOs in each state is obtained from the National Center for Charitable
Statistics, a third-party agency that works closely with the Internal Revenue Agency to provide
data for the non-profit sector (NCCS, 2017). The population density data is collected from the US
Census Bureau. Because NPOs usually exercise their power against firms through their monitoring
functions (Lu et al., 2022; Rivera-Santos and Rufín, 2010), areas with high NPO density should
have a higher demand for high CSR performance. However, it is hard to argue that a firm should
have higher (or lower) value just because it is headquartered in an area with more NPOs. Therefore,
since the number of NPOs can be considered as exogenous to firm value (except for its influence
on CSR performance), it is a good instrumental variable for our analysis.
Table 3 reports the results from combining the IV regression and DPD estimation. In Model 1,
we report the first stage IV regression using CSR as the dependent variable and NPO intensity as
the independent variable. The results show that NPO density significantly predicts CSR perfor-
mance. As expected, firms in states with a higher NPO density have higher CSR performance
(β = 0.08, p ⩽ 0.001). In the second stage, we calculated the fitted value of CSR (predicted CSR)
Lu et al. 19

Table 3. Instrumental variable regressions.


Mean Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4
regression: First Baseline regression Moderator = available Moderator = RM capability
DV = Qt+1 stage IV slack
Variance regression
regression:
DV = ln(et+1)2 Mean (βj) Variance (γj) Mean (βj) Variance (γj) Mean (βj) Variance (γj)

NPO density 0.08***


(0.02)
[0.00]
Predicted CSR 1.67*** 1.40*** 0.83*** 1.41*** 0.70** 1.55***
(0.49) (0.18) (0.24) (0.21) (0.23) (0.19)
[0.00] [0.00] [0.00] [0.00] [0.00] [0.00]
Available slack 1.13* 4.18***
(0.55) (0.41)
[0.04] [0.00]
CSR × –1.23† –2.97***
available slack (0.63) (0.84)
[0.05] [0.00]
RM capability 0.05 0.26†
(0.07) (0.14)
[0.49] [0.07]
CSR × RM –0.10 –0.57**
capability (0.10) (0.23)
[0.33] [0.01]
Firm size 0.23*** –0.42*** –0.27*** –0.20** –0.44*** –0.20*** –0.46***
(0.01) (0.12) (0.05) (0.07) (0.05) (0.06) (0.05)
[0.00] [0.00] [0.00] [0.01] [0.00] [0.00] [0.00]
Market-to- 0.00 0.00 0.01 –0.01 0.01* 0.00 0.02***
book ratio (0.00) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.00)
[0.16] [0.65] [0.36] [0.18] [0.02] [0.57] [0.00]
Sales growth –0.08*** 0.24 0.75*** 0.11 0.65*** 0.02 0.33
(0.02) (0.30) (0.17) (0.19) (0.16) (0.19) (0.28)
[0.00] [0.43] [0.00] [0.57] [0.00] [0.92] [0.24]
Systematic risk –0.01 0.03 –0.05 –0.01 –0.06† 0.02 –0.02
(0.00) (0.04) (0.04) (0.03) (0.03) (0.03) (0.04)
[0.15] [0.49] [0.20] [0.83] [0.06] [0.52] [0.64]
R&D intensity 0.51* 1.71 4.40*** 0.53 1.29† 0.92 2.93***
(0.21) (1.70) (0.61) (0.99) (0.75) (1.07) (0.73)
[0.02] [0.31] [0.00] [0.59] [0.08] [0.39] [0.00]
Dividend 0.00 0.02 –0.25* 0.17 0.09 0.07 0.02
(0.01) (0.15) (0.11) (0.12) (0.07) (0.10) (0.08)
[0.93] [0.91] [0.03] [0.17] [0.16] [0.49] [0.80]
Lagged DV 0.75*** 0.70*** 0.74***
(0.05) (0.05) (0.04)
[0.00] [0.00] [0.00]
Constant –2.03*** 3.41*** –1.06** 1.87*** –0.82* 1.87*** –0.33
(0.29) (0.89) (0.38) (0.57) (0.40) (0.46) (0.40)
[0.00] [0.00] [0.01] [0.00] [0.04] [0.00] [0.41]
Wald χ2 (df) 7523.27 18,436.45 21,630.28
*** *** ***
AR1 –6.64*** –6.17*** –6.59***
AR2 1.71† 1.95† 1.68†
R2 0.55 0.05 0.08 0.05
N 4713 3914 3914 3914 3914 3914 3914

AR1: Arellano-Bond tests for first order autocorrelation; AR2: Arellano-Bond tests for second order autocorrelation; DV: dependent
variable; IV: instrumental variable; RM: risk management; NPO: non-profit organization; CSR: corporate social responsibility.
Robust standard errors are reported in parentheses and exact p-values are reported in square brackets. For the first stage IV regression,
the dependent variable is CSR. Year fixed effects are controlled in all regressions. Industry fixed effects are controlled for in Model 1.

p ⩽ 0.1; *p ⩽ 0.05; **p ⩽ 0.01; ***p ⩽ 0.001.
20 Strategic Organization 00(0)

and used it in the Arellano–Bond DPD regressions as the independent variable. Model 2 shows the
baseline regression of CSR’s impact on the level and variability of Tobin’s Q using predicted CSR.
The results show that CSR significantly increases both the mean and the variance of Tobin’s Q,
providing further support for Hypothesis 1. Models 3 and 4 showed that the moderation effects of
both available slack (γ = –2.97, p ⩽ 0.001) and risk management capability (γ = –0.57, p ⩽ 0.01) are
still significant, even when we control for endogeneity using IV regressions. Therefore, we con-
clude that it is unlikely the results are caused by OVB.

Robustness check: ES score


Many scholars argue that the CSR score should focus on the environmental and social aspect rather
than the governance component in the MSCI rating (e.g. Albuquerque et al., 2019; Greening and
Turban, 2000) because, unlike the other two components, the governance component is an impor-
tant aspect of the core operations. To address this possible concern, we ran the main regressions
using the environmental and social (ES) rate scores instead of the CSR rate. The ES rate is calcu-
lated as the average score rate for the six dimensions in the MSCI database: environment, com-
munity, product, human rights, employee, and diversity. We included the governance rate as a
control variable in all models in Table 4 to control for possible confounding effects caused by
agency aspects.
Table 4 shows the results of the regressions using the ES score as the independent variable. The
results in Model 1 show that the ES score has a positive and significant relationship with both
Tobin’s Q and the variance of Tobin’s Q, which provides further support for Hypothesis 1. More
importantly, the interaction effects of both available slack and risk management capability on the
variance of Tobin’s Q are still significant at the p ⩽ 0.01 level. Therefore, we confirm that our
results are robust even if we only consider the environmental and social aspects of CSR.

Discussion and conclusion


For decades, CSR has been treated as a non-market strategy that helps firms build moral capital and
enhance performance (Godfrey et al., 2009; Goldstein and Pauzner, 2005). From this instrumental
approach, CSR is considered a social investment that should lead to long-term benefits for share-
holders. Scholars have shown that CSR can create value through various channels, including the
“insurance-like effect” hypothesis (Godfrey et al., 2009; Shiu and Yang, 2017), stakeholder man-
agement hypothesis (Jones, 1995; Wood, 1991), and efficiency enhancement hypothesis (Flammer
and Kacperczyk, 2019; Flammer and Luo, 2017). However, the current instrumental approach to
CSR has an emphasis on the return of CSR but neglects the risk associated with an investment in
CSR. For decades, we as academic scholars have been trying to promote the idea of “doing well by
doing good” to practitioners, as if CSR’s impact on firm value is monotonic. The problem with this
idea, obviously, is that such impact is never monotonic, as shown by many current studies (e.g. Du
et al., 2011; Gras and Krause, 2020; Servaes and Tamayo, 2013). The non-monotonicity leaves
managers and investors in a baffling position: without knowing the conditions under which CSR
can lead to more reliable value creation, their investment in CSR is at best a risky gamble. The
recent discharge of Danone’s CEO Emmanuel Faber—due to his inability to transfer an aggressive
CSR strategy into profitability of the company—is a good example of this problem (Kostov, 2021;
Van Gansbeke, 2021). Therefore, to provide meaningful guidance to managers regarding the CSR–
value relationship, we need to show the uncertain nature of CSR investment and determine the
conditions under which such uncertainty can be reduced.
Lu et al. 21

Table 4. Multiplicative heteroscedasticity regression models with ES score.


Mean regression: Model 1 Model 2 Model 3
DV = Qt+1 ES rate baseline Moderator = available slack Moderator = ERM
Variance regression:
DV = ln(et+1)2 Mean (βj) Variance (γj) Mean (βj) Variance (γj) Mean (βj) Variance (γj)

ES score 1.51** 1.33* 2.12** 3.18*** 1.91*** 3.93***


(0.58) (0.67) (0.68) (0.79) (0.55) (0.70)
[0.01] [0.05] [0.00] [0.00] [0.00] [0.00]
Available slack 0.99* 3.35***
(0.44) (0.37)
[0.02] [0.00]
ES × available slack –3.71 –9.67**
(2.44) (3.28)
[0.13] [0.00]
RM capability 0.11 –0.02
(0.09) (0.12)
[0.20] [0.85]
ES × RM capability –0.76† –2.76**
(0.40) (0.89)
[0.06] [0.00]
Governance score 0.16 –0.41 –0.66 –0.07 –0.34 0.27
(0.97) (0.79) (0.71) (0.79) (0.58) (0.72)
[0.87] [0.61] [0.35] [0.93] [0.56] [0.71]
Firm size –0.20*** –0.10** –0.16** –0.17*** –0.15** –0.22***
(0.06) (0.03) (0.05) (0.03) (0.05) (0.03)
[0.00] [0.00] [0.00] [0.00] [0.00] [0.00]
Market-to-book 0.00 0.01** 0.00 0.01* 0.00 0.01**
ratio (0.01) (0.00) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.00)
[0.85] [0.01] [0.62] [0.04] [0.90] [0.00]
Sales growth –0.70* 0.63** –0.57** 0.25 –0.66** 0.59**
(0.31) (0.21) (0.22) (0.27) (0.25) (0.21)
[0.02] [0.00] [0.01] [0.36] [0.01] [0.01]
Systematic risk 0.06 0.04 0.01 –0.02 0.07 0.13***
(0.07) (0.03) (0.05) (0.04) (0.06) (0.03)
[0.40] [0.30] [0.81] [0.65] [0.22] [0.00]
R&D intensity 3.67† 6.19*** 2.03 3.35*** 1.78 3.21***
(1.94) (0.66) (1.45) (0.72) (1.17) (0.69)
[0.06] [0.00] [0.16] [0.00] [0.13] [0.00]
Dividend –0.07 0.08† 0.02 –0.06 –0.05 0.08†
(0.15) (0.04) (0.11) (0.05) (0.10) (0.05)
[0.64] [0.06] [0.85] [0.24] [0.61] [0.09]
Lagged DV 0.75*** 0.72*** 0.76***
(0.05) (0.05) (0.04)
[0.00] [0.00] [0.00]
Constant 1.83*** –2.45*** 1.59*** –2.37*** 1.36*** –1.95***
(0.48) (0.30) (0.44) (0.30) (0.38) (0.30)
[0.00] [0.00] [0.00] [0.00] [0.00] [0.00]
Wald χ2 (df) 13,337.30 17,096.30 18,925.20
*** *** ***
AR1 –6.24*** –7.79*** –6.72***
AR2 1.26 1.55 1.22
R2 0.04 0.05 0.04
N 3914 3914 3914 3914 3914 3914

AR1: Arellano-Bond tests for first order autocorrelation; AR2: Arellano-Bond tests for second order autocorrelation; DV: dependent
variable; ES: environmental and social; ERM: enterprise risk management.
Robust standard errors are reported in parentheses and exact p-values are reported in square brackets.

p ⩽ 0.1; *p ⩽ 0.05; **p ⩽ 0.01; ***p ⩽ 0.001.
22 Strategic Organization 00(0)

This article tries to fill this gap by investigating the reliability of the value creation effect through
CSR and exploring the conditions under which CSR can create value more reliably (i.e. contingent
factors that reduce CSR’s positive impact on the volatility of value distribution). By exploring how
firms realize “doing safe (financially) while doing good (socially),” this article adds a second
important layer to the proposition of “doing well by doing good,” thus incorporating the uncer-
tainty of CSR investment into considerations of the efficacy of CSR. Using the MHE model and
dynamic panel regression structure, we find that CSR by itself is an unreliable value enhancer and
a risky choice (not only increases value but also increases the volatility of value distribution)
(Barnea and Rubin, 2010; Cheng et al., 2016). With further investigation based on the RBV of
firms (Barney, 1991; Barney et al., 2001; Helfat and Peteraf, 2003), we find that the reliability of
the efficacy of CSR is moderated by two fundamental resources: organizational slack and risk
management capability. Specifically, the impact of CSR on firm value is more reliable when a firm
has more slack on hand or when a firm has stronger capability in risk management.
In addition, we found that the moderating effect of slack is more significant for highly redeploy-
able slack than slack with low redeployability. This means that the flexibility and immediate avail-
ability of organizational slack play a critical role in determining its impact on the riskiness of CSR
investment. A possible reason is that unlike highly redeployable slack (measured by the availability
of cash and cash equivalents), recoverable slack is measured by the availability of short-term assets
that are, at least to a certain extent, tied up in business operations. Although liquid, most current
assets, such as accounts receivable, stock inventories, supplies, and prepaid liabilities (Wharton
Research Data Services, 2020), are not as readily available as cash and cash equivalents. However,
CSR investment usually requires the input of highly liquid assets that are immediately turned into
out-of-pocket expenses. For example, if a firm’s liquid assets are heavily tied to accounts receiva-
ble, investing in CSR may still cause the firm to experience financial hardship. Similarly, potential
slack is not a measurement of resources on hand, but rather a measurement of a firm’s ability to
borrow from external sources. In other words, a firm with high potential slack may still experience
difficulties paying immediate out-of-pocket CSR expenses if it cannot transform potential slack
into resources. Moreover, raising debt to invest in CSR increases not only the transaction costs of
CSR (in terms of interest) but also the opportunity costs (in terms of reduced debt capacity). Third,
increasing debt to invest in CSR is likely a hard story to sell to investors and could be regarded as
a sign of an agency problem (Masulis and Reza, 2015). Therefore, the risk-reduction effect of less
redeployable slack, such as recoverable and potential slack, may not be as strong as that of avail-
able slack.
Gras and Krause (2020) argue that CSR’s impact on financial performance is more prominent
when a firm is in a munificent industry. Firms in the munificent industries have more slack to
invest in discretionary strategies such as CSR; therefore, they experience more pressure due to
imitation by rival firms and a higher industry standard for CSR. As a result, the efficacy of CSR as
a differentiation tool is marginally less significant compared with firms in less munificent indus-
tries. The assumption for this argument, as stated by Gras and Krause (2020), is that pursuing CSR
in resource-scarce industries is riskier due to the lack of organizational slack. In other words, slack
provides a risk-reduction effect for CSR investment. We show that slack does have a positive risk-
reduction effect on CSR, providing evidence for this important assumption for Gras and Krause
(2020). Therefore, our research not only complements Gras and Krause (2020) by providing
important support for their arguments but also extends their argument to the perspective of firm-
level volatility.
Slack is an important component of the behavior theory of the firm (BTOF) (Argote and Greve,
2007; Cyert and March, 1963). According to the BTOF, slack provides a buffer for unexpected
Lu et al. 23

expenses to deal with internal or external disruptions (Bourgeois, 1981; Cyert and March, 1963).
This leads to two types of possible functions of slack: increase innovation and resolve conflict
(Argote and Greve, 2007). The former has been substantially discussed while the latter draws less
attention in previous literature (Argote and Greve, 2007). This article provides some evidence for
the role of slack in resolving conflicts in operations. When CSR needs to compete for valuable
resources with the core operations, conflicts occur between the economic and social/environmental
goals of the firm (Symeou et al., 2019). Our findings suggest that this conflict may be reflected as
the risk nature of CSR: without a proper level of slack resources, investing in CSR activities is
fundamentally a risky choice. Moreover, our findings regarding the moderating effect of slack on
the CSR–variance relationship provide evidence for the stabilizing function of slack (Cyert and
March, 1963).
Aiming to fill current research gaps in understanding the reliability of the impact of CSR on
value, and the factors that influence this reliability, this research provides both significant theoreti-
cal contributions in the field of CSR and managerial implications. Theoretically, by considering
uncertainty as well as the effect of the relationship between CSR and firm value, this research
enhances the field’s understanding of the role of CSR as a value enhancer. The investigation of the
risk-return trade-off of CSR sheds light on the situation, moving research on CSR into theoretically
fruitful areas compared to the investigation of a single aspect.
Previous organization theorists have argued that organizational slack buffers a firm’s technical
core strategies from environmental turbulence and thus enhances its financial performance (Bowen,
2002; Tan and Peng, 2003). Building on these arguments, we link the “risk buffering” effect of
slack to the uncertainty of CSR. We supplement the current understanding of the instrumental
value of CSR by exploring when CSR may fail to reliably produce the expected instrumental value,
and when it may succeed. We further identify that the nature of organizational slack, in terms of its
flexibility and immediate availability, determines its buffering effect on firm value in this article.
In addition, by showing that the uncertainty of CSR investment can be reduced by having superior
risk management practice, we bring theories from the risk management discipline into the under-
standing of the riskiness of CSR. These findings provide a valuable avenue to advance CSR
research and answer the call for the further theorization of CSR investigations (Wang et al., 2020).
Our research provides a strong tie to link current CSR theoretical development to CSR prac-
tices, thus answering the call to increase the practical implications of CSR research (Wang et al.,
2020). From a practical point of view, shareholders and managers are concerned about the varia-
bility of firm performance (Orlitzky and Benjamin, 2001) because it plays a key role in perfor-
mance-driven organizational change (Donaldson et al., 2012). Managing the variability of firm
value can make a difference between “future bankruptcy and organizational health” because
organizational activities that increase firm risks may be penalized over the long term (Orlitzky
and Benjamin, 2001).
This study helps find an optimal balance between CSR investment, firm growth, and reliability
of corporate performance. We propose that managers should be cautious about the timing of CSR
investment to avoid unexpected negative impacts on firm value. We show that CSR’s impact on
value is more reliably positive when a firm has sufficient highly redeployable slack or organiza-
tional capabilities in risk management, as shown in Figure 3. That is, allocating resources to CSR
will be more likely to succeed when a firm possesses a high level of slack and when a firm exhibits
superior capabilities in mitigating risk associated with CSR. Otherwise, investing in CSR is like a
risky gamble, and the outcome of CSR is not reliable. Therefore, an important question a manager
may need to ask before investing in CSR activities is: Do we have the resources and capabilities to
ensure the success of our CSR strategy?
24 Strategic Organization 00(0)

Firms with High Slack or High Capability


Frequency

Low CSR High CSR

Firm Value

Firms with Low Slack or Low Capability


Frequency

Low CSR

High CSR

Firm Value

Figure 3. Illustration of the empirical results.

Our research may have several limitations that justify future research on this topic. We used the
MSCI database to measure CSR. Although the MSCI database is frequently used in CSR research,
it has certain issues. First, its rating criteria constantly change over time, raising data reliability
issues. Second, MSCI’s sample universe relies heavily on the United States, which confines our
sample to US companies only. Future research should explore CSR’s impact on firm value, and the
reliability of this impact, using other CSR databases and firms from other countries.

Declaration of conflicting interests


The author(s) declared no potential conflicts of interest with respect to the research, authorship, and/or publi-
cation of this article.

Funding
The author(s) received no financial support for the research, authorship, and/or publication of this article.

Informed consent
This study does not involve human participants, their data or biological material.

ORCID iD
Xiaoyu Liu https://orcid.org/0000-0002-6527-7882
Lu et al. 25

References
Albuquerque R, Koskinen Y and Zhang C (2019) Corporate social responsibility and firm risk: Theory and
empirical evidence. Management Science 65(10): 4451–4469.
Antle R and Eppen GD (1985) Capital rationing and organizational slack in capital budgeting. Management
Science 31(2): 163–174.
Aragón-Correa JA and Sharma S (2003) A contingent resource-based view of proactive corporate environ-
mental strategy. Academy of Management Review 28(1): 71–88.
Arellano M and Bond S (1991) Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte Carlo evidence and an appli-
cation to employment equations. The Review of Economic Studies 58(2): 277–297.
Arellano M and Bover O (1995) Another look at the instrumental variable estimation of error-components
models. Journal of Econometrics 68(1): 29–51.
Argote L and Greve HR (2007) A behavioral theory of the firm – 40 years and counting: Introduction and
impact. Organization Science 18(3): 337–349.
Arjaliès DL (2010) A social movement perspective on finance: How socially responsible investment mat-
tered. Journal of Business Ethics 92(1): 57–78.
Arnott RD and Asness CS (2003) Surprise! Higher dividends = higher earnings growth. Financial Analysts
Journal 59(1): 70–87.
Arora P and Dharwadkar R (2011) Corporate governance and corporate social responsibility (CSR): The mod-
erating roles of attainment discrepancy and organization slack. Corporate Governance: An International
Review 19(2): 136–152.
Auer BR (2016) Do socially responsible investment policies add or destroy European stock portfolio value?
Journal of Business Ethics 97(1): 71–86.
Barnea A and Rubin A (2010) Corporate social responsibility as a conflict between shareholders. Journal of
Business Ethics 97(1): 71–86.
Barnett ML, Henriques I and Husted BW (2020) Beyond good intentions: Designing CSR initiatives for
greater social impact. Journal of Management 46(6): 937–964.
Barney J (1991) Firm resources and sustained competitive advantage. Journal of Management 17(1): 99–120.
Barney J, Wright M and Ketchen DJ Jr (2001) The resource-based view of the firm: Ten years after 1991.
Journal of Management 27(6): 625–641.
Bénabou R and Tirole J (2010) Individual and corporate social responsibility. Economica 77(305): 1–19.
Berry-Stölzle TR and Xu J (2018) Enterprise risk management and the cost of capital. Journal of Risk and
Insurance 85(1): 159–201.
Bhandari A and Javakhadze D (2017) Corporate social responsibility and capital allocation efficiency. Journal
of Corporate Finance 43: 354–377.
Blundell R and Bond S (1998) Initial conditions and moment restrictions in dynamic panel data models.
Journal of Econometrics 87(1): 115–143.
Bourgeois LJ III (1981) On the measurement of organizational slack. Academy of Management Review 6(1):
29–39.
Bourgeois LJ III and Singh JV (1983) Organizational slack and political behavior among top management
teams. Academy of Management Proceedings 1983: 43–47.
Boutin-Dufresne F and Savaria P (2004) Corporate social responsibility and financial risk. The Journal of
Investing 13(1): 57–66.
Bowen FE (2002) Organizational slack and corporate greening: Broadening the debate. British Journal of
Management 13(4): 305–316.
Brammer SJ and Pavelin S (2006) Corporate reputation and social performance: The importance of fit.
Journal of Management Studies 43(3): 435–455.
Brower J and Dacin PA (2020) An institutional theory approach to the evolution of the corporate social perfor-
mance–corporate financial performance relationship. Journal of Management Studies 57(4): 805–836.
Cai Y, Jo H and Pan C (2012) Doing well while doing bad? CSR in controversial industry sectors. Journal of
Business Ethics 108(4): 467–480.
Candi M, Melia M and Colurcio M (2019) Two birds with one stone: The quest for addressing both business
goals and social needs with innovation. Journal of Business Ethics 160: 1019–1033.
26 Strategic Organization 00(0)

Chava S (2014) Environmental externalities and cost of capital. Management Science 60(9): 2223–2247.
Cheng B, Ioannou I and Serafeim G (2014) Corporate social responsibility and access to finance. Strategic
Management Journal 35(1): 1–23.
Cheng IH, Hong HG and Shue K (2016) Do managers do good with other peoples’ money? AFA 2013 San
Diego Meetings Paper, Chicago Booth Research Paper No. 12-47. Available at: https://papers.ssrn.com/
sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1962120
Cheung YL, Tan W, Ahn HJ, et al. (2010) Does corporate social responsibility matter in Asian emerging
markets? Journal of Business Ethics 92(3): 401–413.
Chung KH and Pruitt SW (1994) A simple approximation of Tobin’s q. Financial Management 23(3): 70–74.
Collis DJ (1994) Research note: How valuable are organizational capabilities? Strategic Management Journal
15(S1): 143–152.
Cooper AC, Gimeno-Gascon FJ and Woo CY (1994) Initial human and financial capital as predictors of new
venture performance. Journal of Business Venturing 9(5): 371–395.
Cornell B and Shapiro AC (1987) Corporate stakeholders and corporate finance. Financial Management
16(1): 5–14.
COSO (2004) Enterprise risk management: Integrated framework. Available at: http://drcia.nau.edu.cn/old/
UploadFiles/UploadFiles_1882/200804/20080415101610532.pdf (accessed 7 November 2015).
COSO (2017) Enterprise risk management: Integrating with strategy and performance. Available at: https://
www.coso.org/Documents/2017-COSO-ERM-Integrating-with-Strategy-and-Performance-Executive-
Summary.pdf (accessed 29 January 2020).
Cyert RM and March JG (1963) A Behavioral Theory of the Firm. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.
Daniel F, Lohrke FT, Fornaciari CJ, et al. (2004) Slack resources and firm performance: A meta-analysis.
Journal of Business Research 57(6): 565–574.
D’Arcy SP and Brogan JC (2001) Enterprise risk management. Journal of Risk Management of Korea 12(1):
207–228.
Davidian M and Carroll RJ (1987) Variance function estimation. Journal of the American Statistical
Association 82(400): 1079–1091.
Deng X, Kang JK and Low BS (2013) Corporate social responsibility and stakeholder value maximization:
Evidence from mergers. Journal of Financial Economics 110(1): 87–109.
Dickinson G (2001) Enterprise risk management: Its origins and conceptual foundation. Geneva Papers on
Risk and Insurance. Issues and Practice 26: 360–366.
Dierickx I and Cool K (1989) Asset stock accumulation and sustainability of competitive advantage.
Management Science 35(12): 1504–1511.
Dolmans SA, Van Burg E, Reymen IM, et al. (2014) Dynamics of resource slack and constraints: Resource
positions in action. Organization Studies 35(4): 511–549.
Donaldson L, Charlier SD and Qiu JX (2012) Organizational portfolio analysis: Focusing on risk inside the
corporation. Long Range Planning 45(4): 235–257.
Du S, Bhattacharya CB and Sen S (2011) Corporate social responsibility and competitive advantage:
Overcoming the trust barrier. Management Science 57(9): 1528–1545.
Duffee GR (1995) Stock returns and volatility a firm-level analysis. Journal of Financial Economics 37(3):
399–420.
Eckles DL, Hoyt RE and Miller SM (2014) The impact of enterprise risk management on the marginal cost of
reducing risk: Evidence from the insurance industry. Journal of Banking & Finance 43: 247.
Edmans A (2011) Does the stock market fully value intangibles? Employee satisfaction and equity prices.
Journal of Financial Economics 101(3): 621–640.
Engle R (2004) Risk and volatility: Econometric models and financial practice. American Economic Review
94(3): 405–420.
Eugene K (2019) Amazon is launching a new program to donate unsold products, after reports that millions
were being destroyed. Available at: https://www.cnbc.com/2019/08/14/amazon-launches-fba-donations-
program-for-unsold-inventory.html (accessed 13 February 2020).
Evans JS (1991) Strategic flexibility for high technology manoeuvres: A conceptual framework. Journal of
Management Studies 28(1): 69–89.
Lu et al. 27

Faithfull M (2021) Sales soar at ailing Chinese brand Erke after good deed goes viral. Available at: https://
www.forbes.com/sites/markfaithfull/2021/08/05/sales-soar-at-ailing-chinese-brand-erke-after-good-
deed-goes-viral/?sh=382f80b3b136 (accessed 15 December 2021).
Figenbaum A and Thomas H (1986) Dynamic and risk measurement perspectives on Bowman’s risk-return
paradox for strategic management: An empirical study. Strategic Management Journal 7(5): 395–407.
Flammer C (2013) Corporate social responsibility and shareholder reaction: The environmental awareness of
investors. Academy of Management Journal 56(3): 758–781.
Flammer C (2015) Does corporate social responsibility lead to superior financial performance? A regression
discontinuity approach. Management Science 61(11): 2549–2568.
Flammer C (2018) Competing for government procurement contracts: The role of corporate social responsi-
bility. Strategic Management Journal 39(5): 1299–1324.
Flammer C and Kacperczyk A (2019) Corporate social responsibility as a defense against knowledge
spillovers: Evidence from the inevitable disclosure doctrine. Strategic Management Journal 40(8):
1243–1267.
Flammer C and Luo J (2017) Corporate social responsibility as an employee governance tool: Evidence from
a quasi-experiment. Strategic Management Journal 38(2): 163–183.
Fleming L (2001) Recombinant uncertainty in technological search. Management Science 47(1): 117–132.
Fleming L and Sorenson O (2001) Technology as a complex adaptive system: Evidence from patent data.
Research Policy 30(7): 1019–1039.
Fombrun CJ and Shanley M (1990) What’s in a name? Reputation building and corporate strategy. Academy
of Management Journal 33(2): 233–258.
Friedman M (1970) The social responsibility of business is to increase its profits. New York Times Magazine
13: 32–33.
Galbraith J (1973) Designing Complex Organizations. Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley.
George G (2005) Slack resources and the performance of privately held firms. Academy of Management
Journal 48(4): 661–676.
Godfrey PC (2005) The relationship between corporate philanthropy and shareholder wealth: A risk manage-
ment perspective. Academy of Management Review 30(4): 777–798.
Godfrey PC, Merrill CB and Hansen JM (2009) The relationship between corporate social responsibility and
shareholder value: An empirical test of the risk management hypothesis. Strategic Management Journal
30(4): 425–445.
Goldstein I and Pauzner A (2005) Demand–deposit contracts and the probability of bank runs. The Journal
of Finance 60(3): 1293–1327.
Gras D and Krause R (2020) When does it pay to stand out as stand-up? Competitive contingencies in the cor-
porate social performance–corporate financial performance relationship. Strategic Organization 18(3):
448–471.
Graves SB and Waddock SA (1994) Institutional owners and corporate social performance. Academy of
Management Journal 37(4): 1034–1046.
Greening DW and Turban DB (2000) Corporate social performance as a competitive advantage in attracting
a quality workforce. Business & Society 39(3): 254–280.
Harner MM (2013) The potential cost and value of ERM. Available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2239161
(accessed 13 February 2017).
Harvey AC (1976) Estimating regression models with multiplicative heteroscedasticity. Econometrica 44(3):
461–465.
Hawn O and Ioannou I (2016) Mind the gap: The interplay between external and internal actions in the case
of corporate social responsibility. Strategic Management Journal 37(13): 2569–2588.
Hawn O, Chatterji AK and Mitchell W (2018) Do investors actually value sustainability? New evidence from
investor reactions to the Dow Jones Sustainability Index (DJSI). Strategic Management Journal 39(4):
949–976.
Helfat CE and Peteraf MA (2003) The dynamic resource-based view: Capability lifecycles. Strategic
Management Journal 24(10): 997–1010.
Henderson R and Cockburn I (1994) Measuring competence? Exploring firm effects in pharmaceutical
research. Strategic Management Journal 15(S1): 63–84.
28 Strategic Organization 00(0)

Hillman AJ and Keim GD (2001) Shareholder value, stakeholder management, and social issues: What’s the
bottom line? Strategic Management Journal 22(2): 125–139.
Hoyt RE and Liebenberg AP (2011) The value of enterprise risk management. Journal of Risk and Insurance
78(4): 795–822.
Hull CE and Rothenberg S (2008) Firm performance: The interactions of corporate social performance with
innovation and industry differentiation. Strategic Management Journal 29(7): 781–789.
Iyer DN and Miller KD (2008) Performance feedback, slack, and the timing of acquisitions. Academy of
Management Journal 51(4): 808–822.
Jayachandran S, Kalaignanam K and Eilert M (2013) Product and environmental social performance: Varying
effect on firm performance. Strategic Management Journal 34(10): 1255–1264.
Jensen MC (1986) Agency costs of free cash flow, corporate finance, and takeovers. The American Economic
Review 76(2): 323–329.
Jensen MC and Meckling WH (1976) Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership
structure. Journal of Financial Economics 3(4): 305–360.
Jo H and Na H (2012) Does CSR reduce firm risk? Evidence from controversial industry sectors. Journal of
Business Ethics 110(4): 441–456.
Jones TM (1995) Instrumental stakeholder theory: A synthesis of ethics and economics. Academy of
Management Review 20(2): 404–437.
Kelm KM, Narayanan V and Pinches GE (1995) Shareholder value creation during R&D innovation and com-
mercialization stages. Academy of Management Journal 38(3): 770–786.
Kim H, Kim H and Lee PM (2008) Ownership structure and the relationship between financial slack and
R&D investments: Evidence from Korean firms. Organization Science 19(3): 404–418.
Kim I, Wan H, Wang B, et al. (2019) Institutional investors and corporate environmental, social, and govern-
ance policies: Evidence from toxics release data. Management Science 65(10): 4901–4926.
Kim J and Seltzer M (2011) Examining heterogeneity in residual variance to detect differential response to
treatments. Psychological Methods 16(2): 192–208.
Kim WS and Sorensen EH (1986) Evidence on the impact of the agency costs of debt on corporate debt
policy. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 21(2): 131–144.
Kostov N (2021) CEO of yogurt giant Danone steps aside after clash with activists. Available at: https://
www.wsj.com/articles/ceo-of-yogurt-giant-danone-steps-aside-after-clash-with-activists-11615807316
(accessed 16 August 2021).
Kuo YF, Lin YM and Chien HF (2021) Corporate social responsibility, enterprise risk management, and real
earnings management: Evidence from managerial confidence. Finance Research Letters 41: 101805.
Lee RB and Kleffner AE (2003) A Framework for the Third Generation of Risk Management. Haskayne School of
Business, University of Calgary. Available at: https://www.researchgate.net/publication/228832370_A_
Framework_for_the_Third_Generation_of_Risk_Management (accessed 15 January 2018).
Leibenstein H (1969) Organizational or frictional equilibria, X-efficiency, and the rate of innovation. The
Quarterly Journal of Economics 83(4): 600–623.
Leszczensky L and Wolbring T (2022) How to deal with reverse causality using panel data? Recommendations
for researchers based on a simulation study. Sociological Methods & Research 51: 837–865.
Lin Y, Wen MM and Yu J (2012) Enterprise risk management: Strategic antecedents, risk integration, and
performance. North American Actuarial Journal 16(1): 1–28.
List JA and Momeni F (2017) When corporate social responsibility backfires: Theory and evidence from a
natural field experiment. NBER working paper. Available at: https://www.nber.org/papers/w24169.pdf
Liu AZ, Liu AX, Wang R, et al. (2020) Too much of a good thing? The boomerang effect of firms’ invest-
ments on corporate social responsibility during product recalls. Journal of Management Studies 57(8):
1437–1472.
Lu H, Liu X and Falkenberg L (2022) Investigating the impact of corporate social responsibility (CSR) on risk
management practices. Business & Society 6(2): 496–534.
Lu H, Oh WY, Kleffner A, et al. (2021) How do investors value corporate social responsibility? Market valu-
ation and the firm specific contexts. Journal of Business Research 125: 14–25.
Lu et al. 29

Luo X and Bhattacharya CB (2009) The debate over doing good: Corporate social performance, strategic
marketing levers, and firm-idiosyncratic risk. Journal of Marketing 73(6): 198–213.
Lv P, Liu J, Xiang Y, et al. (2021) Research on e-commerce enterprise’s network public opinion handling
mechanism and crisis public relations strategy. Financial Engineering and Risk Management 4(4):
70–86.
McGuire JB, Sundgren A and Schneeweis T (1988) Corporate social responsibility and firm financial perfor-
mance. Academy of Management Journal 31(4): 854–872.
Masulis RW and Reza SW (2015) Agency problems of corporate philanthropy. The Review of Financial
Studies 28(2): 592–636.
Mattingly JE and Berman SL (2006) Measurement of corporate social action: Discovering taxonomy in the
Kinder Lydenburg Domini ratings data. Business & Society 45(1): 20–46.
Mattingly JE and Olsen L (2018) Performance outcomes of investing slack resources in corporate social
responsibility. Journal of Leadership & Organizational Studies 25(4): 481–498.
Miller KD and Leiblein MJ (1996) Corporate risk-return relations: Returns variability versus downside risk.
Academy of Management Journal 39(1): 91–122.
Mirvis P (2012) Employee engagement and CSR: Transactional, relational, and developmental approaches.
California Management Review 54(4): 93–117.
Mishra S and Modi SB (2013) Positive and negative corporate social responsibility, financial leverage, and
idiosyncratic risk. Journal of Business Ethics 117(2): 431–448.
MSCI ESG Research (2015) MSCI ESG KLD STATS: 1991–2014 data sets methodology. Available at:
https://wrds-web.wharton.upenn.edu/wrds/ (accessed 08 November 2016).
Muller A and Kräussl R (2011) Doing good deeds in times of need: A strategic perspective on corporate dis-
aster donations. Strategic Management Journal 32(9): 911–929.
Nair A, Rustambekov E, McShane M, et al. (2014) Enterprise risk management as a dynamic capability: A
test of its effectiveness during a crisis. Managerial and Decision Economics 35(8): 555–566.
NCCS (2017) Guide to using NCCS data. Available at: http://nccs-data.urban.org/NCCS-data-guide.pdf
(accessed 10 March 2017).
Nekhili M, Nagati H, Chtioui T, et al. (2017) Corporate social responsibility disclosure and market value:
Family versus nonfamily firms. Journal of Business Research 77: 41–52.
Nissim D and Ziv A (2001) Dividend changes and future profitability. The Journal of Finance 56(6):
2111–2133.
Nocco BW and Stulz RM (2006) Enterprise risk management: Theory and practice. Journal of Applied
Corporate Finance 18(4): 8–20.
Noda T and Bower JL (1996) Strategy making as iterated processes of resource allocation. Strategic
Management Journal 17(S1): 159–192.
Nohria N and Gulati R (1996) Is slack good or bad for innovation? Academy of Management Journal 39(5):
1245–1264.
Orlitzky M and Benjamin JD (2001) Corporate social performance and firm risk: A meta-analytic review.
Business & Society 40(4): 369–396.
Orlitzky M, Schmidt FL and Rynes SL (2003) Corporate social and financial performance: A meta-analysis.
Organization Studies 24(3): 403.
Osiyevskyy O, Shirokova G and Ritala P (2020) Exploration and exploitation in crisis environment:
Implications for level and variability of firm performance. Journal of Business Research 114: 227–239.
Pagach D and Warr R (2011) The characteristics of firms that hire chief risk officers. Journal of Risk and
Insurance 78(1): 185–211.
Parida V, Lahti T and Wincent J (2016) Exploration and exploitation and firm performance variability:
A study of ambidexterity in entrepreneurial firms. International Entrepreneurship and Management
Journal 12(4): 1147–1164.
Penrose ET (1959) The Theory of the Growth of the Firm. New York: John Wiley.
Petersen HL and Vredenburg H (2009) Morals or economics? Institutional investor preferences for corporate
social responsibility. Journal of Business Ethics 90(1): 1–14.
30 Strategic Organization 00(0)

Petrenko OV, Aime F, Ridge J, et al. (2016) Corporate social responsibility or CEO narcissism? CSR motiva-
tions and organizational performance. Strategic Management Journal 37(2): 262–279.
Porter ME and Kramer MR (2006) The link between competitive advantage and corporate social responsibil-
ity. Harvard Business Review 84(12): 78–92.
Ramchander S, Schwebach RG and Staking K (2012) The informational relevance of corporate social respon-
sibility: Evidence from DS400 index reconstitutions. Strategic Management Journal 33(3): 303–314.
Rivera-Santos M and Rufín C (2010) Odd couples: Understanding the governance of firm-NGO alliances.
Journal of Business Ethics 94(1): 55–70.
Servaes H and Tamayo A (2013) The impact of corporate social responsibility on firm value: The role of
customer awareness. Management Science 59(5): 1045–1061.
Shahzad AM, Mousa FT and Sharfman MP (2016) The implications of slack heterogeneity for the slack-
resources and corporate social performance relationship. Journal of Business Research 69(12):
5964–5971.
Sharfman MP (1985) Environmental pressure, organizational buffers and organizational performance: A
structural equations model (slack). PhD Thesis, University of Arizona, Tucson, AZ.
Sharfman MP, Wolf G, Chase RB, et al. (1988) Antecedents of organizational slack. Academy of Management
Review 13(4): 601–614.
Shirokova G, Osiyevskyy O, Laskovaia A, et al. (2020) Navigating the emerging market context: Performance
implications of effectuation and causation for SMEs during adverse economic conditions in Russia.
Strategic Entrepreneurship Journal 14(3): 470–500.
Shiu YM and Yang SL (2017) Does engagement in corporate social responsibility provide strategic insur-
ance-like effects? Strategic Management Journal 38(2): 455–470.
Singh JV (1986) Performance, slack, and risk taking in organizational decision making. Academy of
Management Journal 29(3): 562–585.
Sørensen JB (2002) The strength of corporate culture and the reliability of firm performance. Administrative
Science Quarterly 47(1): 70–91.
Sorenson O and Sørensen JB (2001) Finding the right mix: Franchising, organizational learning, and chain
performance. Strategic Management Journal 22: 713–724.
Sprinkle GB and Maines LA (2010) The benefits and costs of corporate social responsibility. Business
Horizons 53(5): 445–453.
Stulz RM (1996) Rethinking risk management. Journal of Applied Corporate Finance 9(3): 8–25.
Sun W, Yao S and Govind R (2019) Reexamining corporate social responsibility and shareholder value: The
inverted-U-shaped relationship and the moderation of marketing capability. Journal of Business Ethics
160(4): 1001–1017.
Surroca J, Tribó JA and Waddock S (2010) Corporate responsibility and financial performance: The role of
intangible resources. Strategic Management Journal 31(5): 463–490.
Symeou PC, Zyglidopoulos S and Gardberg NA (2019) Corporate environmental performance: Revisiting the
role of organizational slack. Journal of Business Research 96: 169–182.
Tan J and Peng MW (2003) Organizational slack and firm performance during economic transitions: Two
studies from an emerging economy. Strategic Management Journal 24(13): 1249–1263.
Tobin J (1958) Estimation of relationships for limited dependent variables. Econometrica: Journal of
Econometric Society 26(1): 24–36.
Turban DB and Greening DW (1997) Corporate social performance and organizational attractiveness to pro-
spective employees. Academy of Management Journal 40(3): 658–672.
Tyler BB and Caner T (2016) New product introductions below aspirations, slack and R&D alliances: A
behavioral perspective. Strategic Management Journal 37(5): 896–910.
Van Gansbeke F (2021) Sustainability and the downfall of Danone CEO Faber. Available at: https://www.
forbes.com/sites/frankvangansbeke/2021/03/20/sustainability-and-the-downfall-of-danone-ceo-faber-
12/?sh=34f5c6fc5b16 (accessed 16 August 2021).
Vanacker T, Collewaert V and Zahra SA (2017) Slack resources, firm performance, and the institutional con-
text: Evidence from privately held European firms. Strategic Management Journal 38(6): 1305–1326.
Villalonga B (2004) Intangible resources, Tobin’s q, and sustainability of performance differences. Journal
of Economic Behavior & Organization 54(2): 205–230.
Lu et al. 31

Waddock SA and Graves SB (1997) The corporate social performance-financial performance link. Strategic
Management Journal 18(4): 303–319.
Wang D, Chen P, Yu T, et al. (2015) The effects of corporate social responsibility on brand equity and firm
performance. Journal of Business Research 68(11): 2232–2236.
Wang H, Gibson C and Zander U (2020) Editors’ comments: Is research on corporate social responsibility
undertheorized? Academy of Management Review 45(1): 1–6.
Wang Q, Dou J and Jia S (2016) A meta-analytic review of corporate social responsibility and corpo-
rate financial performance: The moderating effect of contextual factors. Business & Society 55(8):
1083–1121.
Wang T and Bansal P (2012) Social responsibility in new ventures: Profiting from a long-term orientation.
Strategic Management Journal 33(10): 1135–1153.
Wharton Research Data Services (2020) Compustat daily updates—Variable reference. Available at: https://
wrds-www.wharton.upenn.edu/ (accessed 11 January 2020).
Wiengarten F, Lo CK and Lam JY (2017) How does sustainability leadership affect firm performance? The
choices associated with appointing a chief officer of corporate social responsibility. Journal of Business
Ethics 140(3): 477–493.
Wintoki MB, Linck JS and Netter JM (2012) Endogeneity and the dynamics of internal corporate governance.
Journal of Financial Economics 105(3): 581–606.
Wood DJ (1991) Corporate social performance revisited. Academy of Management Review 16(4): 691–718.
Zhang Y, Li J, Jiang W, et al. (2018) Organizational structure, slack resources and sustainable corporate
socially responsible performance. Corporate Social Responsibility and Environmental Management
25(6): 1099–1107.
Zhou P and Ruland W (2006) Dividend payout and future earnings growth. Financial Analysts Journal 62(3):
58–69.

Author biographies
Hao Lu is an assistant professor at the Sobey School of Business, Saint Mary’s University and a visiting
scholar at the Haskayne School of Business, University of Calgary. His research is interdisciplinary, focusing
on creating a niche theoretical angle by integrating corporate risk management into strategic management. His
research interests involve corporate social responsibility (CSR), social entrepreneurship, business ethics,
enterprise risk management, and risk management practice. His research is published in journals including
Business & Society and Journal of Business Research. He had over 10 years of working experience in various
industries, mostly in insurance and related industries. He holds the Charted Insurance Professional (CIP)
designation and the Canadian Risk Management (CRM) designation.
Xiaoyu Liu is an associate professor of management at the Sobey School of Business, Saint Mary’s University.
She holds a doctoral degree from the University of Calgary. Her research interests lie at the intersection of
corporate social responsibility and international business, with a focus on issues in energy industries and
developing countries. She has published research in journals such as Business & Society, Energy Policy, and
Journal of International Management.
Oleksiy Osiyevskyy is an associate professor of Entrepreneurship & Innovation at the Haskayne School of
Business, University of Calgary, where he also serves as an associate dean, Professional Graduate Programs.
He leads the Global Business Futures Initiative, an emerging thought leadership center aimed at preparing
established businesses to thrive on disruption in the global marketplace. In his scholarship, he concentrates on
the problem of achieving and sustaining firm growth and prosperous longevity through successful engage-
ment in entrepreneurial strategies. He has published over 50 papers, including the articles appearing in
Strategic Entrepreneurship Journal, Journal of Product Innovation Management, and Journal of World
Business.

You might also like