You are on page 1of 8

Empire, Law and Economic Growth

Author(s): TIRTHANKAR ROY


Source: Economic and Political Weekly , FEBRUARY 25, 2012, Vol. 47, No. 8 (FEBRUARY
25, 2012), pp. 98-104
Published by: Economic and Political Weekly

Stable URL: https://www.jstor.org/stable/41419909

REFERENCES
Linked references are available on JSTOR for this article:
https://www.jstor.org/stable/41419909?seq=1&cid=pdf-
reference#references_tab_contents
You may need to log in to JSTOR to access the linked references.

JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide
range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and
facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at
https://about.jstor.org/terms

Economic and Political Weekly is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend
access to Economic and Political Weekly

This content downloaded from


14.139.242.231 on Fri, 06 Oct 2023 12:56:48 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Empire, Law and Economic Growth

TIRTHANKAR ROY

This article explores three concepts in global history


- empire, law and economic growth - and their Europeancoming
empires that ruled much of the non-European
In world world
Europeanfor therecentlastfor500 years, the new
years. The empires last interest
scholarship is in part500 that years. ruled has The revived much new of in scholarship the the non-European history is in of part the
closer together to form a new discourse. Two recent
about culture - how empires forged new identities, and how
tendencies contribute to the making of thetheydiscourse.
ruled by means of cultural domination, that is, by mani-
Imperial history moves away from a view of empires
pulating education, ideas about governance, andasthe writing
of
extractive machines towards a view of empires ashistory in the colonies. In this meaning, the phrase "new"
imperial history has established itself as a brand in some
legislating states. Economic history, on the other hand,
schools of history. While accommodating considerable diver-
underscores the role of legislation as a foundation for
sity within itself, the cultural history agenda maintains a dis-
modern economic growth. Law, then, is thetance new bridge
from the economic history of empires.1 There is another
strand in the newthis
between empire and economic growth. Does research, however, idea
that revisits the subject
of the economic origins and effects more explicitly. The
help us understand Indian history?
present essay is interested in this second strand of research,
one that is capable of speaking to the economic historian.
Although the interest in the economic history of empires is
quite old, the new writing on the subject is somewhat novel in
its orientation, as we shall see. The trend was set with the
five volume Oxford History of the British Empire published in
1998-99. This was followed by С A Bayly's Birth of the Modern
World , Niall Ferguson's Empire: How Britain Made the Modern
World , John Darwin's After Tamerlane: The Global History of
Empire , Ronald Findlay and Kevin O'Rourke's Power and
Plenty, shorter treatments, edited anthologies, and numerous
articles and review articles besides.2 These works sometimes

overlap in their arguments, but they do not necessarily follow


a single train of thought. For example, both Bayly's Birth of the
Modern World and Ferguson's Empire share an interest in mar-
ket integration led by empires, but the point of emphasis in the
former is the transformation of states, whereas the latter is
more interested in the role of British private enterprise in forg-
ing empires.
Many of these works are written by historians. Independ-
ently, economists have also developed an interest in empires.
The institutional approach to economic history introduced by
the American economist Douglass North suggests that the ori-
gins of economic growth in the modern world can be traced to
institutions, that is, man-made rules that keep the costs of con-
ducting market exchange within reasonable limits. The usual
examples of institutions are property rights and contract law.
This is the text of the Twelfth Pranab Sen Memorial Lecture, held at
Jadavpur University, Kolkata, on 18 June 2011. 1 wish toThe school
thank theof thought that developed around the idea was
participants, especially Binay Chaudhuri and Lakshmi more at home withfor
Subramanian, the west than the non-western world. In
useful questions, comments and suggestions, and the organisers ofapplication,
North's own the the idea seemed to explain the "rise-
lecture series for giving me a chance to honour the memory of one of the
of-the-west", namely, the economic development of the western
most distinguished philosophers of contemporary India.
Europe from the enlightenment to the industrial revolution.
Tirthankar Roy ( t.roy@lse.ac.uk ) is with the economic history
With such one-sided evidence, the institutionalists claim to
department, London School of Economics and Political Science, London.
having found a theory of economic growth took on a tautological

98 February 25, 2012 vol XLVii no 8 ЕВВД Economic & Political WEEKLY

This content downloaded from


14.139.242.231 on Fri, 06 Oct 2023 12:56:48 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
character. After all, a theory of success cannot be validated The beginning of factory industrialisation in India serves as an
with reference to examples of success alone. It should explain example of Warren's point. Putting the burden of under-
the failures of growth as well. In the last ю years, a group of development upon empire raises the question, what about
economists have been making amends to this deficiency.3 A China, which was not colonised; and what about the New
part of the enterprise involves rethinking the concept of em- World territories in Australia, New Zealand and North America,
pire. Economists contributing to the scholarship read the Euro- which were colonised but still developed?
pean empires as agents in institutional change in the non- A second universal tendency is a renewed interest in the his-
western world. They recognise that the modern empires recast tory of globalisation. After a 60-year gap, dating from the
property rights and contract laws in the non-western world, Great Depression in 1930 to the collapse of socialism in eastern
and investigate the quality of the property and contract law Europe, end of cold war, and economic reforms in the third
that emerged from the imperial project in order to explain the world in the 1980s, restrictions on trade in the world have
relatively poor growth record in the tropics. fallen away. The world today trades more than it did in the re-
It should be clear that the new imperial history (in the sense cent past, and in that respect, the world today resembles the
in which I use the label) cannot be defined as a single move- 19th century more than the world of the 1960s or the 1970s.
ment because these writings on the subject do not adhere to a This apparent resemblance induces historians to look at the
common set of ideas and assumptions. Historians rewriting empires of the last two centuries in a different light, rather less
the empire and economists rethinking the empire are doing so as an extractive machine, and rather more as an agent in "glo-
for different reasons, and there are differences also in the balisation", or a worldwide market integration. In the ancient
points of emphasis of individual writers. Why, then, is there an and medieval times, the aim of empires was to maintain the
outburst of interest in the same subject? flow of taxes and tributes between regions. Protecting private
enterprise and integration of markets were at best by-products
Why a Rethinking? of the enterprise. In the 19th century, the empires were capi-
There are, in fact, three underlying intellectual currents talistic in aim. They wanted to create and maintain a cross-
behind the rethinking. First, there has been a move away from border market for goods, capital, labour and technologies, and
what we may call the old imperial history, namely, the neo- cemented these markets with a compatible, if not a common,
Marxist paradigms that ruled the historiography of the empire institutional framework between the colonist and the colonies.
until the 1980s. Marxist theories of underdevelopment read A third change in global history motivating a fresh look at
the European expansion eventually leading to colonial rule as empires is a revised understanding of states, especially the
a process that involved extraction of resources from the tropi- emergence of large fiscal states in Europe through the process
cal world, leaving the tropics poorer, and in possession of a of sustained military conflict. That the empires were causally
distorted-exploitative class structure. The scholarship explor- linked to the transformation of European politics has long
ing the relationship between empires, dependency, "back- been known, but the transformation itself and its repercus-
wardness" and underdevelopment from a Marxist perspective sions upon the extension of military power became major
is very large. Formative writings by Paul Baran, Walter Rod- fields of study only recently. The European literature on the
ney, and especially, André Gunder Frank considered imperial- emergence of fiscal states is very large - associated with the
ism to be the main cause of poverty and underdevelopment in works of, among others, Charles Tilly, Martin Wolfe, Patrick
the 20th century world.4 Interpretations of the mechanism, O'Brien, Michael Mann and С A Bayly.6
however, emphasised either trade (i e, exchange relations) or Taken together, then, the new imperial history can be defined
class (i e, production relations). Much of the analysis had little by two characteristics: an interest in economic globalisation,
in common with classical Marxism except a shared interest in and an interest in a new kind of state trying to sustain the
surplus appropriation. Karl Marx himself, as we know, was up- process. But how did the new kind of state sustain the process
beat about the British Empire in India, and expressed the hope of capitalistic globalisation? Attempts to answer that question
that the entrepreneurial Britons of his time would eventually take us closer to the economists' interest in empire as an agent,
beat the "vegetative" Indians into useful shape. an imperfect one no doubt, in institutional modernisation.
Examples of extractive and exploitative empires can be Capitalism cannot function without laws protecting private
found. One example commonly cited is Congo under the Bel- property and impersonal contracts. The new imperial history
gian king Leopold 11, who made no secret of his intention to reminds us that the states that pursued capitalist integration
strip Congo of its commercially valuable natural resources for were not only militarily strong, but institutionally different
personal enrichment. But as a general theory of empires, from their predecessors and contemporaries. Doffing our hat
extraction and exploitation pose too many problems. It is not to institutional economic history, then, we can say that the
easy to define the 19th century European empires in Asia and modern empires were legislating states. A signal distinction
Africa as a common bundle of intentions, strategies and between the old neo-Marxist imperial history and the new im-
effects. As the maverick Marxist Bill Warren pointed out long perial history is that in the former the state was an agent of
ago, the belief that the empire underdeveloped the tropical resource extraction, whereas in the latter, the state was a legis-
world overlooked a number of positive changes in the third lator. Simply stated, modern empires were states that made
world that had owed their origin to the imperial connection.5 laws necessary for world capitalism to function.

Economic & Political weekly ШШ February 25, 2012 vol xlvii no 8 99

This content downloaded from


14.139.242.231 on Fri, 06 Oct 2023 12:56:48 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
How useful is this idea - that empires were a particular kind law was a joint product of the Indian business organisation
of legislators - to the study of Indian history? and the European merchants' reading of the Indian business
organisation.
British India as a Legislating State The question, then, is the following: what did the English
Our impression of the British rule in India tends to be coloured East India Company think it was doing when it decided to cre-
by the elaborate display of power and pomp in which the colo- ate new laws for the acquired territories? Attempts to answer
nial ruling order liked to surround itself. The display itself was this question meet with a significant problem. Cultural histori-
quite a complex thing, as it drew images and inspiration from ans and economic historians tend to approach the question of
a variety of roots. There was at one level an English penchant the origin of colonial law from radically opposed angles.
for recreating an aristocracy in whichever part of the world Economists, especially new institutional economic history,
they ruled. But in implementing that drive in India, the Eng- would see in law an instrument to address transaction costs. In
lish also borrowed ideas and symbolisms current in the world a colonial setting these costs and their remedies may arise
of the princely states. At times the real orient and the oriental from particular sources, but law is still a solution to inefficient
trappings became indistinct. Be that as it may, from an eco- forms of market exchange. Historians, especially "postcolonial"
nomic history angle, the display of power was only an illusion. historians, would treat law as a tool of governance and control.
Although it was a militarily strong state, in fiscal terms, British In a colonial setting, governance and citizenship are defined
India was one of the poorest states in the contemporary world. differently from a free society. But law is not a benign solution
In the 1820s, average tax per person in the three "presiden- to an efficiency problem; it is an instrument of imperialism.
cies" of India was less than one-tenth of that in England, and These two views on colonial law do not meet; in fact, they are
half or less in relation to almost all the other British colonies, contradictory. Any suggestion that colonial law could be a
whether located in the temperate or the tropical regions. In solution to a societal problem is likely to be readily dismissed
terms of tax per person or tax-gross domestic product (gdp) by the postcolonial historians, for whom discourses on "rule of
ratio, the relative position of British India worsened in the law" are a cover for imperialism. If we take the economists'
early 20th century when compared with the other emerging road, the British were trying to strengthen the institutional
economies of the time, chiefly Japan and Russia. Why was the basis for market exchange, where the pre-existing basis fell
record of tax collection so poor in British India? Taxing the short in a number of ways. If we take the historians' road, the
rich and the powerful is always risky for a ruler. A policy of British were trying to appropriate means of regulation and
limited interference in local political structures, also known as control of Indian society.8
"indirect rule", made it doubly difficult in India to raise reve- I find it difficult to follow either of these two roads. The
nues by almost any other means than the land tax imposed on postcolonial writers assume, without good reason, that the
the peasants. But then, geography and climate reduced the profit motive of merchants had little role to play in the making
productivity of land to exceedingly low levels, and depressed of modern laws. Law, in this view, was a top-down phenome-
tax collection in turn. However powerful the raj might pretend non, rather than being a response to the demand by economic
to be, its reach as a state was as severely constrained by these agents for more efficient and risk-free rules. A pure govern-
factors as that of any pre-European state in India. ance theory of law cannot be convincing to an economic histo-
To the same extent, that its capacity to spend on capital- rian for what it omits from its vision, namely, the demand for
intensive development projects was limited, the regime focused law by businesses that faced particular forms of transaction
energies upon indirect and low-cost, if labour-intensive, deve- cost, and the role of economic actors in making rather than
lopment projects that involved supplying law and knowledge simply adapting to colonial law. Cultural historians of India,
to private enterprise. According to one reading of colonial pol- inspired by Edward Said's book about the European percep-
icy proposed by the late Morris David Morris, the empire tions of north Africa and west Asia, suggest that the British in
adapted to its own small size by taking a "night-watchman" the 18th century had their actions guided by a conception of
stance.7 It saw itself as the means to create enabling conditions Indian society and about themselves as a superior power.9 This
for private enterprise to flourish, by offering a single umbrella story does not work for 18th century Bengal, where colonial
of law, one official language, and uniform channels of transac- law began. The British in the 18th century did not come from
tion in scientific and technological knowledge. The British the governing classes in England, but were petty merchants,
India represented a different and a more modern kind of state sailors and soldiers trading a little on the side. Their actions
insofar as it created the economic institutions necessary for were instead guided by a conception of the Indian mercantile
global capitalism to function. world, and this conception had been in the making during the
An economic historian would immediately object, did not preceding 150 years of doing business with the Indians. Impe-
capitalism already exist in India before the empire? After all, rial law had economic roots, not political roots. On the other
the whole reason that the East India Company was present in hand, the economic theory that suggests that colonial law was
India was to take a share of Indian business. This is absolutely a response to the failings of indigenous institutions, needs to
right. And because it is right, we cannot understand the British first describe the indigenous institutions and make a convinc-
Indian institutions without reference to the Indian business ing case that these were really not good enough to address
modern forms of transaction. Institutional economists tend to
world of the 18th century. In effect, the new capitalistic rule of

100 FEBRUARY 25, 2012 vol XLVii no 8 Е32Я Economic & Political weekly

This content downloaded from


14.139.242.231 on Fri, 06 Oct 2023 12:56:48 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
assume that the European colonists transplanted the Euro- 1772 and a devastating famine in 1770, that the Company
pean institutions on to an otherwise lawless Asia or Africa. In became serious about taking the reins of civil administration.
fact, the Europeans transplanted institutions piecemeal, In the 1770s, when a serious discussion began about the princi-
depending on a conception of indigenous laws. This sugges- ples by which the newly acquired territories in India should be
tion makes for a very important revision in institutional eco- governed, Warren Hastings, the first governor general, repre-
nomic history. Unfortunately, contributors to the comparative sented a lobby that believed that India should be governed by
economic history of institutions are not yet well-read enough the Indian law. The foundation of business practices was seen
on Asia or Africa to meet the task. to be religious, because Hindu and Islamic code books were
So, what did the Company think it was doing in the matter full of injunctions about the superiority of caste, community,
of legislation in the late 18th or the early 19th century Bengal? family, notions of purity and the importance of being virtuous
by maintaining the rules of the caste or the collective order.
What Did the Company Think It Was Doing? The Hastings project, therefore, led to an attempt to under-
The key ingredient in the early European conception of Indian stand, reconstruct, and preserve indigenous religious codes;
business was the notion of a group, the members of which gave employment to scores of orientalist legal scholars, i e,
shared a profession, restricted the exchange of property and pandits and ulemas; and saw the start of schools of Hindu and
trade secrets within the group, and maintained the cohesion of Islamic traditions in Benares and Calcutta. The concrete effect
the group by restricting marriages within it. That group was of that project in Bengal was that property right was delivered
sometimes identified with a caste, a community, or an ex- to a joint family, something in between a unitary family and a
tended family. Almost always, the equation was supported kinship group. The precise definition of the joint family was
with reference to religion. left open. Its boundaries were fluid. The understanding was
Where did this idea come from? The Europeans had been that under Indian tradition, property was usually held in com-
grappling with caste and community, which they experienced mon between descendants of an original ancestor, and there-
as business institutions established among merchants, bank- fore, property should be held in common. This was the princi-
ers and artisans, for two centuries before formal colonialism ple of impartible inheritance, and it worked in conjunction
began in 1857. Their impression of the Indian society as a col- with a flexible concept of the joint family.
lection of endogamous guilds first arose in the context of doing India, however, was a plural society, with not one but many
business with Indian merchants and skilled artisans. Euro- religious codes. The codes existed as ethos rather than as posi-
pean visitors to Indian port towns in the 17th century observedtive law. In this scenario, the government could only accord all
religious law equal status. And in order to maintain strict
that in India, significant social interaction with other commu-
nities was forbidden to merchants, bankers, and skilled arti-equality, it instituted universal procedures and a universal sys-
sans. Merchants lived in an insular social world, and mercan-
tem of courts. The legal regime that Hastings had set in motion
was neither a completely new order nor a completely tradi-
tile law existed as social conventions of endogamous guilds.
Members of the group not only shared a trade, but also mar-tional one. It was traditional in modelling law after religious
ried within the trade and had food with people who belongedcodes; it was modern in creating a single "due process of law"
in the same trade. Social insularity was not peculiar to Indianvalid for all. Colonial law followed the English common law
merchants. Even in Europe, marriage ties were carefullyprecedence in two qualified senses: (a) upholding Indian busi-
arranged. But in India, such rules were accompanied with ness
a practices about how property should be held, buttressing
the interpretation of that system with reference to religious
powerful moral force, any act of breach being deemed a sin,
inviting unusually severe punishment, excommunication andcodes, and (b) creating a single due process of law. One referee
disgrace. Books of law associated with religious codes could be
and uniform procedures would arbitrate many players.
found that sanctioned such actions against those who broke If this was the ideal, much of the 19th century history of
traditional rules. Indian law saw a retreat from the ideal.
In the presence of these insular yet wealthy communities,
Conflicts10
any state that was capitalistic in aim and familiar with the
principles of common law would be caught between two con-From the early 19th century, press, literature, Indians, Europe-
ans and administrators (like the governor John Shore) took a
tradictory goals, to establish a modern, universal, and capital-
dim view of the British Indian law. Courts and lawyers were
istic legal infrastructure that would override the community
and privilege the individual, and to recognise mercantile cus-unaffordable, served the rich and hurt the poor, were sites
where perjury won the day - dark views such as these were
toms as common law, which would amount to strengthening
the community. Legislation in the British India formed inexpressed by everyone who had seen how things actually
interaction between these two goals. In the beginning, the
worked. By the 1830s, the Hastings model was seen by many to
dominant goal was the second one, namely, to protect the
be obsolete. The Benares and Calcutta schools of law that pro-
duced Hindu and Muslim legal experts had few backers. The
group. I will argue later that the step led to too many problems,
infamous education minute drafted by T В Macaulay (1835),
and was to be slowly given up in the 19th and 20th centuries.
The East India Company came into possession of the reve-
which made the case that traditionalist Indian learning had
little practical value and should be given up in favour of a
nues of Bengal between 1757 and 1765, but it was not before

Economic & Political weekly ШШЗ February 25, 2012 vol xlvii no 8 101

This content downloaded from


14.139.242.231 on Fri, 06 Oct 2023 12:56:48 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
westernised curriculum in state-aided Indian schools, was communities. Earlier, communities settled disputes by pan-
partly a reflection of the growing irrelevance of traditional chayats following their own rules. No one needed to care
learning in the British Indian law court. There was no immedi- about the constitution of these bodies or the legal procedures
ate change of policy or jurisprudence, but the ideal was crack- that they followed. But now there was a divorce of procedures
ing under its own weight. What was the problem? from laws. Now the judges in the British Indian courts settled
The pursuit of traditionalism in the contents of law and community disputes by means of common procedures that
modernism in the process of law created an expensive system, applied to all. With this shift, the problems began.
expensive in money, in time, and in terms of disputatious The combination of joint rights and universal procedures
potential. There was an explosion of civil cases on property, was an explosive one. The very offer to recognise caste, family
and a widely shared suspicion that there were no reliable rules and community tradition as legal tender created a moral haz-
by which these cases might be settled. Opportunistic lawyers ard; it invited some members of castes, families, and commu-
and confused judges, staple figures in Bengali satirical writ- nities to reinvent tradition, and equally, it induced other mem-
ings of the time, made the uncertainty worse. When we read bers of the same castes, families and communities to pose a
through civil court cases of the early 19th century, we see that fierce challenge to these attempts by their brethren to capture
these disputes can be classified into three categories - conflict tradition. A very large number of property disputes in the
between the private and the public, conflict between the indi- 1800s concerned one issue - where would the right of the kin
vidual and the collective, and conflict between custom and to claim a share of a jointly-held property end. An army of pan-
contract. The wording in the last case, custom-versus-contract, dits advised the judges about which Hindu texts indicated the
is borrowed from Henry Maine, one of the key legislators in degrees of relation who could claim shares in a joint family. It
colonial India. But I will use the phrase in a different sense shifted the attention of the judges away from the contents of
from that of Maine. law to the origins of law. And it encouraged young recruits
The conflict between the public and private is a subject into the system to show off their knowledge of Hindu law to
much written on. It was introduced by David Washbrook.11 A their superiors. One judgment of 1854 observed "that under
book on the Calcutta Marwaris by Ritu Birla is a recent at- the Hindu law of inheritance current in Bengal, as laid down
tempt to deal with this sort of dichotomy in colonial law.12 in the Daya Bhaga and the Daya Karma Sangraba , the mater-
Birla has argued that the colonial state legitimised a private nal uncle succeeds in preference both to the paternal great
space within the economy where personal status ruled, and grandfather's brother's daughter's son and to the great great
made it inferior to the public space where "universal models of great grandfather's great great grandson...". Bizarre as these
modern market practice" ruled. In this case, European ideo- words might sound to us, they merely expressed a judge's des-
logy and Indian ideology are seen to have been so positioned perate attempt to discover workable formulas out of the maze
as to underscore the inferiority of one to the other. I do not of religious texts, which he could not read anyway. Such
accept this interpretation on two grounds. First, a European attempts were frequent in this time, and almost always gave
imperial ideology did not exist readymade from the beginning rise to fantastic patterns.
of colonial rule. The "universal models of modern market prac- Conflicts between the individual and the group stemmed
tice" struggled to establish themselves through an interaction from differential strength of claims over ownership of pro-
between community practices and corporate and individual perty. Even though the legal claim to property vested in a whole
enterprise in the sphere of Indo-European business. Second, as group, the moral claim differed between the head and the
I have argued before, ideas about commercial law formed in branches, and most distinctively in India, between women and
relation to business history, not in relation to a history of men. Admission of impartible inheritance of property opened
political and colonial power. a floodgate of conflict between individual and collective inter-
There was a public-private conflict present nevertheless. By ests. For example, impartible inheritance worked on condition
this phrase I mean a conflict between two incompatible princi- that women who married into the joint family had restricted
ples - ownership of property held by a private entity called the claims on property. Otherwise, remarried widows threatened
joint family that could be interpreted by its members in differ- a division of the estate. Widows had a right to maintenance,
ent ways, whereas the settlement of claims over ownership but not a share in property. This was plainly unjust when the
was done by means of a highly public instrument of the state deceased husband was the one who had created the wealth in
courts. By private, I mean, therefore, a law that defined own- the first place. In a society where many women married at 12
ership of property as a legal right, and then delivered that or 13 and life expectancy was 25 years, early widowhood was
right to a group, the constitution of which was understood common enough. Women had two escape routes from this law,
only by a few insiders. By public I mean, unlike other contribu- a bequest from the deceased husband, or adoption of a son.
tors to the literature, a universal procedural law, the existence Bequests were not easy when property was jointly held. And a
of one platform and one due process of law to settle all possible woman was required to produce documentary evidence show-
disputes, in this case, disputes about the precise constitution of ing her husband's consent to adoption. The Sudder Dewany
the group. This particular cleavage between a right and the Adawlut between 1800 and 1850 decided a large number of
mechanism to uphold that right did not exist before, because cases where a young girl produced a document purportedly
earlier rights and institutions had both been decentralised into signed by her dying husband sanctioning adoption, which
102 February 25, 2012 vol XLVii no 8 E9353 Economic & Political weekly

This content downloaded from


14.139.242.231 on Fri, 06 Oct 2023 12:56:48 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
document was challenged by the husband's family. In the into law and by legislation overriding tradition. In property
1830s and 1840s, such claims had a reasonable hope to suc- rights, case judgments tended to uphold individual rights over
ceed; in the 1890s, these challenges were routinely dismissed. collective rights. In the sphere of exchange, legislation
In the new bustling capitalistic world of the port cities, the disassociated itself from Indian tradition altogether and
privileged claim of distant male relatives over the wife was not looked westward.
only seen as iniquitous, but also inefficient because they inter- In short, an initial drive to empower the community as an
fered with the spirit of private enterprise. embodiment of common law on property or contract had to be
Third, there was a conflict between custom and contract, by slowly abandoned. In its place, there emerged two other prin-
which I mean the failure of the group or family to secure ciples - new laws and case laws. Judges were free to choose
impersonal contracts for the sale of goods and services. To any between religious codes or ethical/moral imperatives in set-
observer of business in 19th century India, the indigenous tling disputes between family members over property. Increas-
institutions would have seemed to be more a hindrance than a ingly, they chose the latter.
help in settling disputes over sale, either because customary
Conclusions
laws were not specified in enough detail to meet the needs of
modern forms of business or because informal-personal con- I conclude by drawing out three theses - about empire, law
tract enforcement systems did not succeed in the sphere of and development. The empire thesis is the easiest one to state.
transactions between parties who did not know each other I have tried to rethink the empire, not as an extractive agent as
well enough. Think of a game of chess being played between a in Marxist historiography, but as a legislative agent as hinted
European and an Indian. The European moves a pawn two at in new imperial history. The shift in perspective is not
places and declares checkmate. The Indian objects to the move driven by a desire to "whitewash" the sordid history of many
by saying that according to Indian rules, moving the pawn two empires. Rather, the intent is to move away from the one-
places is invalid. The game will never end. Similarly, in busi- dimensional narrative of power projected by the neo-Marxist
ness, the transacting parties must agree to play by the same and the postcolonial writers, towards the possibility of multi-
rules to conduct any business at all. If buying and selling are ple narratives on empires.
done by the most elementary rules such as auction, identity of The British Empire in India was a legislating state. And yet,
the buyers and sellers matters little. But if buying and selling as the preceding paragraph would suggest, not all empires and
are done by complex rules such as long-period contract that all legislating states were similar. Where would the British India
admit of many contingencies, it is impossible to function figure in the spectrum of legislating states? Modern European
smoothly if any one party can claim recourse to ethnic or reli- empires pursued a more or less explicitly capitalistic aim -
gious laws. It was not as if laws of contract did not exist in they wanted to aid private enterprise. But what kind of private
India. The problem was that impersonal and secular laws of enterprise would they aid with law? From the slave-owning
business could not be found written down anywhere, whereas plantation in America to the jute mill of Calcutta, there is a
at the same time, the scope of business transactions between very large shift in the character of private enterprise. In keep-
parties that did not share either the same custom or an inti- ing with this diversity, modern empires pursued three types of
mate knowledge of each other expanded enormously from the legislative strategy, which I call "appropriation", "incorpora-
18th century. tion", and "standardisation". Appropriation means taking out-
Sanskrit, Arabic and Persian codes that the British Indian right possession of indigenous land and labour by the Euro-
courts made use of were almost never successful in settling pean settlers with the aid of property rights on land and labour.
trade disputes that came to these courts. In practice, busi- If this was the default strategy in the settler colonies of the
nesses exporting agricultural or craft goods from India tended New World, it had little relevance for colonial India, where the
to rely on middlemen. The middlemen carried social power, imperialists were merchants and bankers foremost rather than
that is, they were sufficiently stronger than the peasants or the sugar or cotton planters. Here another principle, incorpora-
artisans to be able to coerce or persuade the latter to fulfil the tion, took over. Incorporation would mean offering juridical
contracts. The middlemen also carried knowledge power, that autonomy to professional groups in return for their loyalty.
is, they were better-informed than the contracting merchants, Many historians have shown that this practice was wide-
often Europeans, about the peasants and the artisans. They, spread, not only in the tropical world, but also as Dominic
therefore, took advantage of the weakness of the one and the Lieven has shown in a recent book, in the Russian Empire.14
ignorance of the other to cause serious trouble to both. Agents The idea that "collaboration" was the foundation of imperial
and middlemen, in short, were part of the problem rather than rule was, in fact, first popularised by the so-called "Cambridge
the solution. As a result of the reliance on such agents, contrac- school" of Indian political history. I have shown in this essay
tual disputes exploded in the Indo-European trade and often that incorporation was indeed the policy of choice, but that it
took on violent character. Transactions in cotton, wheat, tex- was a failure because of the contradictions that it entailed.
tiles, silk, opium and indigo involved serious disagreements These contradictions resulted from the way indigenous law
that turned political in the indigo case.13 was interpreted, rightly or wrongly, identifying property own-
The system responded to these disputes in two ways, by ership with a loosely defined community. By contrast with
adopting the common law principle of elevating court rulings both appropriation and incorporation, standardisation would
Economic & Political weekly Q3S3 February 25, 2012 vol xlvii no 8 ЮЗ

This content downloaded from


14.139.242.231 on Fri, 06 Oct 2023 12:56:48 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
mean allowing one law for all, the principle of one law for one colonies.15 It should be obvious that I do not believe in this
nation or one state, or lex loci. The thesis on law is that the story. The problem in India was not how much good western
British India began with incorporation, and moved clumsily law was imported, but how much Indian law was preserved.
towards standardisation. My argument is that the attempt to fit religious, communal,
The third thesis is on economic growth. Recent research and personal codes of conduct into the common law frame-
done in the institutional economics tradition tells us that the work - where all codes were subject to contestation - created
huge potentials for contestation. There were far too many
imperial legislative project did not work well in the tropical
colonies because the colonist powers were not sufficientlycourt cases. And too many court cases are not good for eco-
motivated to transplant good European laws in the tropicalnomic growth. This is the third thesis.

notes
and Kenneth L Sokoloff, "Factor Endowments, India, Delhi: Oxford University Press, 2002,
Institutions, and Differential Paths of Growth PP 1-56.
i See, for exam
among New World Economies" in Stephen 7 "Towards a Reinterpretation of Nineteenth
Imperial Haber (ed.), How Latin America Fell Behind, Histor
Century Indian Economic History", Journal of
nity in Britain
Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press, 1997, Economic History, 23(4), 1963, pp 606-18.
York: Cambrid
pp 260-304; R La Porta, F Lopez-de-Silanes, 8 For two recent works on law within this broad
Stephen Howe
A Shleifer, R Vishny, "The Quality of Govern- framework, see Ritu Birla, Stages of Capital:
Reader, Londo
al introduction in the latter volume lists 11
ment", The Journal of Law, Economics & Organ- Law, Culture, and Market Governance in Late
isation, 15(1), 1999, pp 222-79. For a useful sur- Colonial India, Durham: Duke University Press,
themes that define modern scholarship, none
vey, see Ross Levine, "Law, Endowments, and 2009, and Mithi Mukherjee, India in the Shad-
dealing with economics. The terms "economy"
Property Rights", Working Paper 11502, Na- ows of Empire: A Legal and Political History
and "law" are missing from the index of the
tional Bureau of Economic Research, Cam- 1774-1950, New Delhi: Oxford University Press,
book. The only essay in the collection that cites
bridge, MA, 2005. 2010.
the economic literature is a polemical piece by
Nicholas Dirks, whose reading of economic his-4 Paul Baran, The Political Economy of Growth, 9 Orientalism, New York: Vintage Books, 1978.
tory consists of one paper published in the New York: Monthly Review, 1957; Walter Rod- 10 This section draws on Tirthankar Roy, Compa-
1970s presenting a cocktail of neo-Marxist de- ney, How Europe Underdeveloped Africa, Wash-
ny of Kinsmen: Enterprise and Community in
pendency theory and economic nationalism. ington DC: Howard University Press, 1974. A
South Asian History 1600-1940, Delhi: Oxford
2 С A Bayly, The Birth of the Modern World 1780-
great deal of Frank's early writings dealt with
University Press, 2009. For a shorter state-
1914, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, contemporary Latin America. Perhaps, the best
statement of his historical thesis can be found ment, see Tirthankar Roy, "Law and the Econo-
2004; Niall Ferguson, Empire: How Britain my of Early Modern India" in Debin Ma and Jan
Made the Modern World, London: Allen Lane, in World Accumulation, 1492-1789, New York: Luiten van Zanden (ed.), Law and Long-term
2003; John Darwin, After Tamerlane: The Glo- Monthly Review Press, 1978. The thesis argued
Economic Change: A Eurasian Perspective, Stan-
bal History of Empires, London: Bloomsbury, in this book is that historically trade has been
ford: Stanford University Press, 2011.
2008; Ronald Findlay and Kevin O'Rourke, the mechanism behind an unequal distribution 11 "Law, State and Agrarian Society in Colonial
of income and wealth in the world.
Power and Plenty: Trade, War, and the World India", Modern Asian Studies, 15(3), 1981, pp
Economy in the Second Millennium, Princeton:5 "Imperialism and Capitalist Industrialisation", 649-721; see also Peter Robb, "Law and Agrari-
Princeton University Press, 2007; Stephen New Left Review, 81, 1980, pp 3-44. an Society in India: The Case of Bihar and the
Howe, Empire: A Very Short Introduction, 6 For a fuller discussion of the relevant scholar-
Nineteenth Century Tenancy Debate" Modern
Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2002. For an ship, see Tirthankar Roy, "Rethinking the Ori- Asian Studies, 22(2), 1988, pp 319-54.
example of a long review, Frederick Cooper, gins of British India: State Formation and Mili-
12 Stages of Capital.
"Empire Multiplied: A Review Essay", Compar- tary-Fiscal Undertakings in an Eighteenth Cen-
ative Studies in Society and History, 46(2), tury World Region", Modern Asian Studies, 13 Tirthankar Roy, "Indigo and Law in Colonial
2004, pp 247-72. forthcoming. The term "military-fiscal" is em- India", Economic History Review, 64(Si), 2011,
ployed in discussions on state formation in In- PP 60-75.
3 For example, Daron Acemoglu, Simon John-
son, and James A Robinson, "The Colonial Ori- dia, see P J Marshall (ed.), Eighteenth Century 14 Empire: The Russian Empire and Its Rivals, New
gins of Comparative Development: An Empiri- in Indian History: Evolution or Revolution?, Haven: Yale University Press, 2002.
cal Investigation", American Economic Review, Delhi: Oxford University Press, 2003, pp 1-30; 15 For example, Acemoglu, Johnson, and Robinson,
91(5), 2001, pp 1369-401; Stanley L Engerman and Seema Alavi (ed.), Eighteenth Century in "Colonial Origins".

SAMEEKSHA TRUST BOOKS

China after 1978: Craters on the Moon


The breathtakingly rapid economic growth in China since 1978 has attracted world-wide attention. But the condition of more than 350 million workers

is abysmal, especially that of the migrants among them. Why do the migrants put up with so much hardship in the urban factories? Has post-reform
China forsaken the earlier goal of "socialist equality"? What has been the contribution of rural industries to regional development, alleviation of poverty

and spatial inequality, and in relieving the grim employment situation? How has the meltdown in the global economy in the second half of 2008 affected
the domestic economy? What of the current leadership's call for a "harmonious society"? Does it signal an important "course correction"?
A collection of essays from the Economic & Political Weekly seeks to find tentative answers to these questions, and more.

Pp viii + 318 ISBN 978-81-250-3953-2 2010 Rs 350

Available from

Orient Blackswan Pvt Ltd


www.orientblackswan.com
Mumbai Chennai New Delhi Kolkata Bangalore Bhubaneshwar Ernakulam Guwahati Jaipur Luckno
Contact: ¡nfo@orientblackswan.com

104 February 25, 2012 vol XLVii no 8 GEC3 Economic & Political weekly

This content downloaded from


14.139.242.231 on Fri, 06 Oct 2023 12:56:48 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms

You might also like