You are on page 1of 10

Transport Policy 69 (2018) 10–19

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Transport Policy
journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/tranpol

Analyzing willingness to improve the resilience of New York City's T


transportation system
Chen Wang, Jiayi Sun, Roddy Russell Jr., Ricardo A. Daziano∗
School of Civil and Environmental Engineering, Cornell University, USA

A R T I C LE I N FO A B S T R A C T

Keywords: Hurricane Sandy revealed the higher-risk vulnerability to natural hazards of civil infrastructure systems in
Willingness to pay coastal megacities such as New York. Traditional sources of funding for both recovering from disasters and
Contingent valuation preventing future damages are not only limited, but also do not account for benefit transfers of the externalities
Discrete choice experiment induced by the provision of resilient infrastructure. In principle, property owners should be willing to pay (WTP)
Hurricane Sandy
an amount equal to the perceived benefit, if this positive externality is internalized by them following some
pricing mechanism. In this paper, we analyze the willingness of residents to financially support improvements in
the resilience to extreme events of the transportation system in New York City. Choice microdata was collected
for over 1500 residents of the metropolitan NYC area. Several logit-type models were estimated and the pre-
ferred model was a discrete-continuous heterogeneity mixture that allows for the derivation of flexible dis-
tributions of willingness to pay. Using hypothetical scenarios of recovery, the annual willingness to pay for
individuals who missed work ands self identify as politically liberal ranges from $120 to $775, whereas for those
individuals that were not directly affected the range is $15-$50.

1. Introduction: extreme weather and disruptions to mobile units such as trains and buses out of low-lying areas, placing
transportation sandbags and tarps at the entrances of subways and over vent to pre-
vent flooding, and preemptively clearing debris from drains and pumps
New York City has one of the largest and busiest transportation (Kaufman et al., 2012). Bus services, subway services, and commuter
systems, both in the US and in the world. Any disruption to this system and regional rail train services were shut down the night before Sandy
has far-reaching and serious ramifications (NYS 2100 Commission, made landfall in order to allow the city time to prepare. This left many
2013). One of the largest disruptions in the system's history came in people no other option but to either walk or use a car or taxi. At the
October of 2012 in the form of Hurricane Sandy. According to the same time, many of these precautions proved successful: almost all
National Centers for Environmental Information, Sandy was the second subway and bus services were restored just a few days after the storm,
costliest and second deadliest tropical cyclone between 1980 and 2014 and all three major airports in the area (LaGuardia, Newark, and JFK)
(FEMA, 2013), with Hurricane Katrina being first in both categories opened within two days after the storm (Kaufman et al., 2012). Despite
(NCEI, 2016). Although it is difficult to predict how climate change will these efforts, much damage was still done; for example, some PATH
affect future storms, the change in sea levels can be predicted. One train stations were still closed weeks after the storm. Infrastructure
estimate puts the mean annual sea level rise between 12 and 23 inches especially in Lower Manhattan and parts of Brooklyn and Queens near
by the decade 2080 (Climate Risk Information, 2009). According to the the shore line was greatly affected, with tunnels and subways inundated
NYS 2100 Commission, the maximum rise could be as high as six feet in with storm and sea water, and surface and overground transport se-
NYC and Long Island (NYS 2100 Commission, 2013). Not only are sea verely damaged by high winds and torrential rain. Some sections of
levels themselves increasing, but so are their rates of change. As of now, subway lines were closed for up to 14 months. At one time, the MTA
sea level rise increases at a rate of 0.86–1.5 inches per decade; 150 alone estimated about five billion dollars in damage was done after
years ago, these rates were as low as 0.34–0.43 inches per decade Sandy passed over (MTA, 2012).
(Climate Risk Information, 2009). Plans, such as MTAs ‘Fix & Fortify’, have been made to improve the
Several measures were taken before Sandy made landfall to try and resilience of the transport infrastructure in the metro area. However,
prevent damage to transportation infrastructure, including moving projects like these are very costly. Some of the funding comes from the


Corresponding author.
E-mail address: daziano@cornell.edu (R.A. Daziano).

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.tranpol.2018.05.010
Received 26 November 2017; Received in revised form 5 April 2018; Accepted 20 May 2018
Available online 28 May 2018
0967-070X/ © 2018 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
C. Wang et al. Transport Policy 69 (2018) 10–19

state and federal government, some from the Department of Empirical results indicate that the distribution of willingness-to-pay is
Transportation. Some also comes from revenue. Shutting down the bimodal.
entire system not only loses revenue, but also causes a loss of money the
system already has. One way the MTA, for example, makes up for a 2. Literature review: financially supporting resilience investments
deficit is to introduce a fare hike. On March 22, 2015, commuters saw
the fourth fare hike for New York City Transit up to $2.75 per ride since Although not directly related to the specific case study of this paper,
2009. Citizens complained saying that the paycheck they receive stays which we find to be unique, there is a well-established literature that
the same even when the fares increase. However, the fare hike is in- looks at the pre and post-disaster challenges in the catastrophe risk
tended to help solve the financial obstacles MTA faces, and to support insurance market (Jaffee and Russell, 1997; Grace et al., 1998, 2003;
projects such as ‘Fix & Fortify’ to make the system more resilient to Froot, 2001; Kunreuther et al., 2002; Kleindorfer and Klein, 2003;
inclement weather. Kunreuther, 2006; H. C. Kunreuther and Michel-Kerjan, 2009; Kousky,
The damages from Sandy come at great cost for all of the areas 2011; Paudel, 2012; Wang et al., 2017). Regarding demand-side dy-
affected. In New Jersey alone, over $3 billion in transportation-related namics of catastrophe risk insurance, there is strong evidence that
recovery expenditures were predicted between 2012 and 2015 (Mantell property owners often do not fully insure their property nor do they
et al., 2013). There were also additional, non-monetary costs. In a invest in pre-event mitigation activities that can reduce losses
survey of eight different residence locations including the five bor- (Kunreuther, 1996; Kriesel and Landry, 2004; Kunreuther and Pauly,
oughs, New Jersey, the Northern suburbs, and Long Island, six of the 2004; Dixon et al., 2006; Wang et al., 2017). Property owners fre-
eight locations reported an increase in travel time immediately after quently do not have adequate financial resources to recover losses they
Hurricane Sandy, sometimes by as much as two and a half hours do experience, and may demand relief from the government
(Kaufman et al., 2012). These increased travel times correlated to an (Kunreuther and Pauly, 2004). In fact, evidence shows that major dis-
increase in the frustration levels of commuters. All of the locations asters are often followed by large, unplanned government expenditures
surveyed reported some level of frustration due to transportation issues, that create major difficulties for local and state government budgets
with the most extreme frustration levels being experienced by those (Kunreuther and Pauly, 2006). Over-reliance on post-disaster relief
from Staten Island. from the government may create serious stress on the private insurance
All of these factors – monetary costs due to damages from the storm, market (Kunreuther and Pauly, 2004).
time lost due to an impaired transportation system, and increased levels Using discrete choice theory for modeling insurance decisions by
of frustration – demonstrate why it is important and necessary to make property owners has appeared as a novel avenue of research. In parti-
the transportation system of New York City and the surrounding areas cular, recent studies have looked at the determination of willingness to
more resilient. pay for flood insurance, usually in the Netherlands (Brouwer and Akter,
Traditional sources of funding for both recovering from disasters 2010; Botzen and Van Den Bergh, 2012; Brouwer and Schaafsma, 2013;
and preventing future damages are not only limited, but also do not Dekker et al., 2016) but also in the US has emerged as well (H.
account for benefit transfers of the externalities induced by the provi- Kunreuther and Michel-Kerjan, 2009; Wang et al., 2017). These studies
sion of resilient infrastructure. For instance, the construction of massive analyze behavioral response in terms of willingness to pay (premium)
structures such as surge barriers to protect coastal urban areas provokes for a given insurance cover, which may have an associated deductible.
a positive externality on the residential value of the properties in the In addition to review past studies of flood and homeowners insurance,
area. This positive externality results from lower expected damage Wang et al. (2017) specify mixed logit models for the choice of pur-
coming from lower flood risks. In principle, property owners should be chase of flood and wind insurance, using stated-preference data from
willing to pay an amount equal to the perceived benefit if this positive North Carolina. The study finds that purchasing insurance is more likely
externality is internalized by them following some pricing mechanism. for higher income and younger homeowners with recent previous
Monetizing these benefit transfers can be used as a tool not only to hurricane experience and living in floodplains or closer to the coast.
leverage scarce public resources, but also to achieve a socially optimal Past damage also increases the probability of buying insurance. In terms
resource allocation. An essential element is then the estimation of of willingness to pay estimates, the authors find a median of $0.55–0.65
willingness to pay, because this measure can be exploited to determine as marginal premium to reduce the deductible by $1.
the cost share residents are willing to cover to secure infrastructure In addition to the analysis of the dynamics of the catastrophe risk
systems as well as to receive the benefits from minimizing potential insurance market, there is a developing literature that looks at the role
damage. of other funding mechanisms for improving resilience to floods. In
The goal of this paper is to provide statistical inference for the particular, the following two examples analyze willingness to pay
private willingness to pay for improvements in the resilience to extreme higher taxes. In the Netherlands, Koetse and Brouwer (2015) used
events of the transportation system in New York City. To make in- choice experiments to compare different economic measures of the
ference on the willingness to pay for flood risk reductions, this paper same change in welfare and to examine the effect of reference point on
adopts an approach based on discrete choice experiments (Hensher preferences. To this end, four experiments were designed: two mea-
et al., 2005). This objective seeks to provide tools for better informing suring willingness-to-pay (WTP) and two measuring willingness-to-ac-
planning investments to improve both resilience and security of trans- cept (WTA). They found a difference between WTP and WTA values and
portation infrastructure and services. the difference was affected by flood probability. Dekker et al. (2016)
A fundamental, specific goal is to collect microdata using a unique estimated a model for WTP for flood risk reductions that included the
discrete choice experiment specifically designed for this project, where effects of preference certainty. They found that preference uncertainty
resilience is understood as recovery time of the transportation system. affects the randomness of decision making and/or the tendency to
The population of interest for this study is those coastal communities in choose the status quo choice(the adoption of a simplifying heuristic). In
the NYC area facing increased risks of flood damage. addition, they also concluded that the preference certainty has no effect
There are multiple contributions in this work. There is the design of on the marginal WTP.
an innovative discrete choice experiment that presents recovery time
after a disaster in an incremental way that is then used to derive in- 3. The data
cremental willingness to pay estimates to support that recovery. The
estimates are derived no only using standard discrete choice models, 3.1. Survey instrument
but also the state-of-the-art mixed-mixed logit model that allows for a
semiparametric representation of unobserved preference heterogeneity. Given the costs of recovery and infrastructure improvements, a

11
C. Wang et al. Transport Policy 69 (2018) 10–19

Table 2
Sample demographic statistics (N = 1552).
Respondent characteristics Percentage Income Percentage

Male 44.01 Personal Income ≤ $10,000 10.63%


Age 18-24 8.25 Pers Income >$10,000 and ≤ $19,999 6.89%
Age 25-34 19.78 Pers Income >$20,000 and ≤ $29,999 7.93%
Age 35-44 17.91 Pers Income >$30,000 and ≤ $39,999 8.96%
Age 45-54 17.78 Pers Income >$40,000 and ≤ $49,999 8.31%
Age 55-64 19.78 Pers Income >$50,000 and ≤ $59,999 9.73%
Age 65-74 13.14 Pers Income >$60,000 and ≤ $69,999 7.41%
Age 75 or older 3.35 Pers Income >$70,000 and ≤ $79,999 8.96%
Living in evacuation zones 22.81 Pers Income >$80,000 and ≤ $89,999 6.38%
Own pets 48.00 Pers Income >$90,000 and ≤ $99,999 6.05%
Single 26.61 Pers Income >$100,000 and ≤ $149,999 12.50%
Married 49.42 Personal Income >$150,000 6.25%

Full-time (≥ 30 h per week) job 52.45 Household Income ≤ $10,000 4.77%


Part-time/casual job 14.56 HH Income >$10,000 and ≤ $19,999 4.57%
Homemaker 3.67 HH Income >$20,000 and ≤ $29,999 5.67%
Full-time student 3.80 HH Income >$30,000 and ≤ $39,999 5.80%
Other job status 25.52 HH Income >$40,000 and ≤ $49,999 7.09%
High School Graduate 11.79 HH Income >$50,000 and ≤ $59,999 7.47%
Some College 20.30 HH Income >$60,000 and ≤ $69,999 7.93%
College Graduate 34.60 HH Income >$70,000 and ≤ $79,999 9.09%
Post-graduate degree 22.49 HH Income >$80,000 and ≤ $89,999 6.38%
White/Caucasian 77.00 HH Income >$90,000 and ≤ $99,999 7.41%
Black or African American 10.31 HH Income >$100,000 and ≤ $149,999 19.14%
Asian 7.28 Household Income >$150,000 14.69%
Hispanic 11.60

survey was designed to explore if New Yorkers are willing to financially would harm vital transportation infrastructure.
support investment to make the transportation system more resilient to 10. Responsibility: assessment of the degree of responsibility for being
extreme weather. After a first draft of the survey was created, a round of prepared for hurricanes.
two focus groups was set to pretest the instrument. After the two focus 11. Contingent valuation: this section first introduced text about the
groups, the final design of the survey was completed. The survey mechanisms (infrastructure improvements) that can be im-
comprised the following parts: plemented to prevent or reduce damage to the transportation
system when floods and hurricanes occur and improve system re-
1. Screening: to make sure the respondent was an adult living in the silience. Then there was a series of contingent valuation question to
New York Metropolitan area. determine how much the respondents were willing to pay for
2. Daily transportation patterns: this section asked the respondent to projects that would reduce the transportation recovery time.
describe his or her daily trips in the city, including frequency of 12. Funding mechanisms: this section collected data about the like-
transportation modes, average commuting time, and parking pre- lihood of supporting different funding schemes (such as increased
ferences. tax on vehicle sales, increase tax on gas, increased subway fares and
3. Past flood/evacuation experience: this section collected data about increased parking fees).
past flood and extreme weather events, including hurricanes, hur- 13. Discrete choice experiment: a series of discrete choice questions
ricane evacuation, and property damage. about the respondents' willingness to pay to improve the recovery
4. Initial Sandy disruptions: this section included a filter to know time of the transportation system.
whether the respondent was in New York City or other affected area 14. Sociodemographic data: the last section of the survey contained a
when superstorm Sandy made landfall. If that was the case, then it set of question to gather sociodemographic characteristics of the
was asked whether the respondent missed work and for how long, respondents.
and whether he or she was paid for the missed work-days.
5. Evacuation: if the respondent evacuated, it was registered when he
or she did so. Additional questions included whether the re- 3.2. The sample
spondent suffered any personal loss or knew someone who did.
6. Post Sandy Commute: data about patterns of disruption for the post The data was collected in January 2015 using an online panel of
Sandy commute was registered in this section, including days be- 1552 adult respondents living in the NYC metropolitan area. A
fore the commute returned to normal. minimum sample of 250 respondents was determined as part of the
7. Commute disruptions: this section collected more details about the design of the discrete choice experiment (Rose and Bliemer, 2009), but
disruptions experienced in the daily commute. we decided to work with a sample well above the minimum to make
8. Other Sandy disruptions: in this section, the respondent had the sure to have enough representation of different segments so that het-
opportunity to provide information about other transportation erogeneity in preferences could be analyzed. Table 2 summarizes the
disruptions (such as plans to leave the city; subway line closures; sociodemographic characteristics of the sample. Comparing the sample
abnormal traffic congestion) as well as other overall impacts and to the population resident in NYC, our sample is more female, wealthier
inconveniences (such as difficulty getting food, loss of cellphone (median household income of $78,290 in the sample vs. $55,7521 in the
signal, blackouts, lack of heating). population in dollars of 2015) and biased toward less diversity (10.31%
9. Risks associated with extreme weather events: this section asked for in the sample vs. 25.1% in the population are black or African
an evaluation of how likely a list of extreme weather events (heat
wave, heavy precipitation, storm surge, nor'easter, among others) 1
American Community Survey estimate.

12
C. Wang et al. Transport Policy 69 (2018) 10–19

Americans; 11.6% vs. 27.5% Hispanic; 7.28% vs. 11.8% Asian).2 The Table 3
sample being of an opt-in online panel (Qualtrics) explains some of the Tobit model for willingness to pay for improving resilience (open-ended con-
differences. Since the purpose of the analysis is the derivation of will- tingent valuation question).
ingness to pay estimates controlling by sociodemographics, non re- Variables Estimate s.e. t-stat
presentativity of the sample is not a main concern as all groups have
enough representation and variability; use of weights did not change Male 253.28 69.60 3.64
Lives in Evac Zone 478.27 91.03 5.25
willingnes-to-pay estimates.
Lives in brownstone 476.84 107.13 4.45
In terms of disruptions provoked by Sandy (Appendix A), re- Children: 1-2 178.30 79.33 2.25
spondents declared difficulties getting food, water, fuel, loss of cell Children: over 3 639.61 132.70 4.82
phone signal, and electric power. For example, 72.99% experienced Education college −175.04 72.64 −2.41
Hispanic 236.11 105.99 2.23
difficulty in getting fuel and 70.88% were affected by malfunctioning
Liberal 240.66 71.02 3.39
traffic signals. Fuel shortages lasted more than 3 days for 74.13% of the Times experienced hurricane −28.49 10.57 −2.70
affected respondents, whereas problems with traffic signals laste more Times evacuated 151.94 47.13 3.22
than 3 days for 59.01% of those experiencing that specific disruption. Was paid for lost workdays 176.99 70.58 2.51
65% of the respondents stated that their normal commute was dis- Know people who experienced loss −164.81 76.53 −2.15
Experienced surge at home 219.82 99.13 2.22
rupted during or immediately following Sandy. 24% of the respondents
Experienced surge in neighborhood −272.06 84.51 −3.22
stated that the disruption lasted longer than 7 days, with an average Used social media 334.70 80.25 4.17
commute disruption duration of 5.38 days. Freq user: subway 207.14 82.39 2.51
Freq user: rail 478.82 125.35 3.82
Constant −220.66 106.54 −2.07
4. Model and results
Loglikelihood −1411
4.1. Contingent valuation BIC 2918.73

As stated above, the survey considered an open contingent valuation


question, where respondents were directly asked to elicit their will- In this paper, the stated-preference discrete choice experiment was
ingness to pay. Considering the question of a one-time payment to designed using a Bayesian efficient design, using the software Ngene
support investments in making subway infrastructure more resilient, (Rose and Bliemer, 2009). Efficient designs go beyond traditional ways
81.3% of the respondents indicated that they would pay less than of determining fractional factorial designs. An efficient design max-
$1000 (as a one-time payment). Only 3.61% would pay more than imizes the information extracted from each choice situation by mini-
$4000. When asked for a monthly payment, 63.23% of the respondents mizing asymptotic standard errors. In the case of a Bayesian design,
declared that they would pay less than $10 per month, whereas only there is the possibility of assuming prior parameters, which were ob-
0.19% would pay more than $200. tained from pretests of the experiment.
From the answers to this contingent valuation question, a tobit In the choice experiment, two hypothetical scenarios of infra-
model was estimated. Estimates (Table 3) can be interpreted as additive structure improvement as well as a status-quo scenario were described
components of the total willingness to pay. Taking into consideration in terms of the percentage of the transportation system being operative
that the model has a negative constant of -$220, males, young people 1–2 days, 3–5 days, 1 week, and 2 weeks after a highly disruptive ex-
(under 25 years), those living in evacuation zones, those with 3 or more treme weather event. Fig. 1 presents a sample of one of the discrete
children, non-whites, and those with a higher experience in previous choice scenarios as seen by respondents. The extreme weather event
evacuation are all willing to pay a significant, positive amount of was described as being at least as strong as hurricane Sandy. We will
money to support resilience investments. Frequent users of subway, and refer to these percentages as operative levels in the remainder of the
then even more frequent users of rail, also have significant positive paper. The two scenarios of infrastructure improvement required fi-
willingness-to-pay components. Interestingly, both suffering personal nancial support in the form of a hypothetical annual payment. The
loss and surge at home are associated with a positive willingness to pay, attribute levels are shown in Table 4.
but knowing someone who experienced loss and having experienced
surge in the neighborhood both have a negative parameter. The largest 4.3. Discrete choice experiments: inference on willingness to pay
willingness-to-pay component is for those having children over 3 years
of age, then come those who live in an evacuation zone, those living in a For modeling purposes, we considered the operative levels in-
brownstone, and frequent users of rail. These three covariates have very crementally. For example, if the operative level 1–2 days after the storm
similar point estimates. was 25%, and then increased to 35% for days 3–5, then we considered
25% for the first 1–2 days, and 10% for days 3–5. The consideration of
incremental recovery makes it possible to derive incremental will-
4.2. Discrete choice experiments – design
ingness to pay estimates for supporting a faster recovery. All estimation
was performed using the gmnl package in R (Sarrias and Daziano,
A fundamental research problem in environmental economics and
2017).
engineering is to determine the consumer valuation of environmental
As base models we estimated a multinomial logit (MNL) model, a
goods and services for which there is no market price. Building on the
mixed multinomial logit model (MIXL-N) with normally distributed
theory of random utility maximization (McFadden, 2001), choice
parameters, and a hierarchical mixed multinomial (H-MIXL-N) logit
modeling is more flexible than other stated-preference techniques, such
model where some interactions with sociodemographic variables were
as the contingent valuation method used above, because implicit prices
introduced. Fit of these competing models is presented in Table 5.
are determined within a controlled experiment that offers better
Because the models with unobserved preference heterogeneity
framing and scope. In transportation, choice modeling has become the
provided better fit and significant evidence of heterogenous pre-
standard technique for estimating the willingness to pay for travel-time
ferences, after preliminary tests, a mixed-mixed logit (MM-MNL) model
savings (used for establishing fares and tolls) and for deriving demand
with two discrete components of the Gaussian mixture was selected as
functions, especially in the case of new alternatives.
the best specification. Even though solutions with 2–5 mixture com-
ponents were tried, overfitting and overidentification can be expected
2
Population statistics from the 2010 Census. with a large number of components. For this dataset, more than 2

13
C. Wang et al. Transport Policy 69 (2018) 10–19

Fig. 1. Sample of discrete choice scenario.

Table 4 Table 6
Attributes and attribute levels for the WTP for improving resilience experiment. MM-MNL (mixture of normals logit) estimates.
Attribute Levels Variable Estimate SD t-stat

Willingness to pay for resilience improvement 100, 120, 250, 300, Fixed coefficients
400, 500 (in $) Inc. operative level: 3–5 days 0.1054 0.0377 2.796
Percentage of operational transportation system in 1–2 0%, 25% Inc. operative level: 1 week 0.0823 0.0301 2.734
days Random coefficients
Improvement in percentage of operational 5%, 15%, 35%, 50% Class 1
transportation system in 3–5 days Annual payment (mean) −0.0855 0.0241 −3.548
Improvement in percentage of operational 25%, 40%, 60%, 85% Operative level: 1–2 days (mean) 0.0556 0.0350 1.589
transportation system in 1 week Inc. operative level: 2 weeks (mean) 0.0824 0.0216 3.815
Improvement in percentage of operational 70%, 85%, 90%, 100% Annual payment (SD) 0.0434 0.0124 3.500
transportation system in 2 weeks Operative level: 1–2 days (SD) 0.0975 0.0704 1.385
Inc. perative level: 2 weeks (SD) 0.0349 0.0181 1.928
Class 2
Annual payment (mean) −0.0111 0.0031 −3.581
Table 5
Operative level: 1–2 days (mean) 0.1240 0.0394 3.147
Fit of competing models. Inc. operative level: 2 weeks (mean) 0.0590 0.0240 2.458
Model Loglikelihood BIC Annual payment (SD) 0.0078 0.0069 1.130
Operative level: 1–2 days (SD) 0.0284 0.0085 3.341
MNL −11921.0 23889.94 Inc. perative level: 2 weeks (SD) 0.0197 0.0064 3.078
MXL-N −9462.5 19009.83 Assigntment to class 2
H-MXL-N −9384.0 18899.88 Male 0.0951 0.0658 1.445
MM-MNL −7449.4 15172.15 Income below $70,000 −0.4821 0.3145 −1.533
Missed work after Sandy 0.4640 0.2088 2.222
Liberal 0.4280 0.1918 2.231
Conservative −0.1262 0.0734 −1.719
classes always led to a group of either non-significant or wrong-signed African American 0.0956 0.4534 0.211
parameters. The shares of the two components are the following, class Asian 0.4199 0.3282 1.279
1: 68%, and class 2: 32%. The estimates of relevant parameters are Hispanic 0.5579 0.3030 1.841
presented in Table 6.
Loglikelihood −7449.4
All the parameters have the expected signs. The annual payment
BIC 15172.15
parameter represents the marginal utility of income and is negative,
meaning that individuals value saving money. All the operative levels
are positively valued. The order of the valuation is decreasing, as faster significantly more likely to belong to class 2. As we discuss below, in-
recovery is preferred. dividuals in class 2 are willing to pay more for improving recovery of
Note how whereas class 1 (68%) exhibits more heterogeneity in the the transportation system. Hispanic and Asian males with a household
payment attribute, class 2 (32%) shows more heterogeneity in the in- income greater then $70,000 are also more likely to belong to class 2,
cremental improvements in the operative levels. Regarding assignment although the effect is not significant at the 95% level.
to classes (or weights of the mixture components), those respondents The estimated mixing distributions for the random parameters are
that are liberal and missed work after Sandy, are statistically shown in Fig. 2. These graphs are based on a normal kernel function of

14
C. Wang et al. Transport Policy 69 (2018) 10–19

Fig. 2. Estimated mixing densities of the random coefficients.

the point estimates. The estimated mixing distributions of the marginal calculation of these willingness-to-pay estimates that reside the policy
utility for both the recovery 1–2 days after the event (βopera12 ) and 2 implications of this study. To derive the WTP distribution, conditional
weeks after (βincopera2w ) are Gaussian-shaped. This result indicates that, estimates of the marginal rate of substitution between recovery time
instead of a mixture, using a normal distribution to approximate the and the annual payment – the ratio of the parameter of recovery time of
taste variations of these two attributes would be enough. The estimated interest and that of the annual payment – were produced at the in-
mixing distribution of the marginal disutility of the payment (βprice ), dividual level from the population distribution.
instead, shows two clear separated peaks in correspondence with the Individuals are willing to pay more for a faster recovery of the
values of the means of each component. Hence, the heterogeneity dis- transportation system after an extreme weather event. Note that the
tribution of the marginal disutility for the annual payment clearly willingness to pay is considerably higher for class 2 (32% share in the
seems to be multimodal (at least bimodal), a result that would have not sample), which is more likely to include individuals who missed work
been revealed by using a simple normal density as mixing distribution. during superstorm Sandy. Those individuals who missed work suffered
To monetize the estimates, we also derived post-processed will- directly the impacts of Sandy.
ingness-to-pay (WTP) measures for each attribute (Table 7). It is in the To have a better idea of the derived estimates, Table 8 shows the
total annual willingness to pay for investments in the transportation
system under differing hypothetical situations. Each scenario describes
Table 7 different recovery times for the transportation system with respect to a
Summary of individual post-processed WTP. hypothetical base level. The base scenario considers that the transpor-
WTP [$/percent-point] Mixture Class 1 Class 2 tation system is shut down 1–2 days after a highly disruptive event;
only 5% in operative 3–5 days after; one week after the system is 25%
Est. SD Est. SD Est. SD operative; and 2 weeks after the event, 70% of the system is in opera-
tion. The scenarios are ordered in increasing recovery speed. The
Operative level: 1–2 8.6377 604.44 1.1813 2.4203 14.2089 3.0806
days after event willingness to pay for each scenario is incremental with respect to the
Incremental operative 7.7826 512.22 1.5671 1.9079 12.0162 2.8634 base condition. Policy implications of these estimates are discussed
level: 3–5 days below.
Incremental operative 6.0721 457.40 1.1904 1.2859 9.6324 3.4012 Finally, density plots for the WTP measures are shown in Fig. 3. All
level: 1 week
Incremental operative 4.5678 404.62 1.0938 0.6868 6.7232 2.5661
4 post-processed WTP measures are bimodal, which explains the overall
level: large standard deviations for the mixture WTP of Table 7.

15
C. Wang et al. Transport Policy 69 (2018) 10–19

Table 8 two main groups are identified, differentiated in their degree of fi-


Simulated annual WTP for differing scenarios of recovery. nancial support. The willingness to pay for class 1 ranges from about
Situation Annual WTP ($) Scenarios $15 to $50, whereas that of class 2 ranges from $120 to $775. As a
mixture of the two groups, the range of variation is $75-$450. The class
Operative levels certain period after(%) with a higher willingness to pay (class 2, representing 32% of our
sample) is more likely to be composed by individuals who missed work
Mixture Class 1 Class 2 1–2 3–5 1 week 2 weeks
days days
during Sandy (odds ratio of 59%), self-identified as liberals (odds ratio
of 53%), with annual household income above $70,000. In the con-
Base Scenario NA NA NA 0 5 25 70 tingent-valuation question, where respondents were asked how much
Situation 1 76.80 14.27 122.79 0 10 40 80 they would pay to “support investments that would reduce the recovery
Situation 2 169.66 30.91 272.04 0 20 60 90
Situation 3 149.64 19.88 250.58 10 30 60 80
time from 3 weeks to only 3 days”, the average annual willingness to
Situation 4 305.29 51.22 490.90 10 50 80 100 pay was $192, with a standard deviation of $305. Future work should
Situation 5 261.68 31.60 438.43 30 50 70 90 explore the preferred mechanism to collect these additional funds.
Situation 6 322.40 43.50 534.75 30 50 80 100
Situation 7 295.88 27.65 506.12 50 60 70 90
Situation 8 388.75 44.29 655.38 50 70 90 100
Situation 9 377.28 29.40 655.84 70 80 90 90
5. Conclusions
Situation 10 455.11 45.07 776.00 70 90 100 100
New York City is known to many as the “city that never sleeps”.
With over eight million citizens, it is the most populated city in the
4.4. Policy implications United States. The area surrounding the city itself is known as the New
York Metropolitan Area, which includes some New York State counties
Sandy revealed some critical deficiencies in the area's transportation north of the city, parts of New Jersey, Pennsylvania, and Connecticut as
system, and, unfortunately, experts predict that future sea level rise and a combined statistical area (CSA). This CSA is also the most populated
storms will exacerbate the problems caused by these deficiencies. in the US at over 23 million people. An area with this large number of
Luckily, there are many engineering solutions to the problem of residents needs a well-built and well-maintained public transportation
transportation resilience that are currently being explored. However, system. Most people living outside New York City commute to the city
the construction, implementation and management of these solutions for both business and leisure. Not many can afford a car, or afford the
will require locating new sources of funding, possibly including taxes extremely high prices of parking in the city. Therefore, agencies such as
and usage fees, as well as guaranteeing that taxpayers and users are New Jersey Transit (NJT), Port Authority of New York and New Jersey
willing to partially support the associated costs. (PANYNJ), and Metropolitan Transportation Authority (MTA) have
This study provides evidence of individuals willingness to provide worked together to provide vital bus and rail services in the area. If
private economic resources to fund mechanisms to increase the resi- these services were to cease operations for any amount of time, the
lience of New York Citys transportation system. As described above, entire area would come to a halt as well.

Fig. 3. Estimated mixing densities of the willingness-to-pay measures.

16
C. Wang et al. Transport Policy 69 (2018) 10–19

In this project, a survey was designed to collect data on the dis- proxy for those individuals who experienced major disruptions in their
ruptions that individuals experienced during and after superstorm routines, reducing their earnings in some cases – are more likely to pay
Sandy. 1552 adults living in the metropolitan area of New York City more for improving recovery of the transportation system. A similar
participated in the online survey. For those who were in an area af- effect is observed for individuals who identified themselves as politi-
fected by Sandy, more than 20% experienced subway line and station cally liberal. These variables defined a specific class of residents, which
closures, and limited bus service for at least one week. 30% of those we labeled as ‘class 2’. Using hypothetical scenarios of recovery, the
affected stated that they considered superstorm Sandy a major disrup- willingness to pay as an annual for ‘class 1’ ranges from about $15 to
tion. $50, whereas that of class 2 ranges from $120 to $775. For the mixture,
The empirical dataset was complemented with a unique discrete the range of variation is $75-$450. These estimates provide evidence of
choice experiment. In the experiment, respondents faced differing sce- the existence of a positive willingness to pay for funding resilience in-
narios of the expected transportation system recovery after an extreme vestments in New York city.
weather event (as strong as superstorm Sandy) under a hypothetical
annual payment. Recovery was expressed in terms of the percentage of
the system being operative in discrete times after the disruptive shock. Acknowledgements
With a nonlinear specification, the preferences with respect to both
recovery and payment turned out to be heterogeneous in the sample. This research was partly supported by UTRC/RF Grant No: 49198-
Whereas some components of recovery seem to be normally dis- 21-26 (data collection and main analysis) as well as by the Center for
tributed, payment heterogeneity is better represented by a bimodal Transportation, Environment, and Community Health (CTECH) (tech-
distribution that can be reasonably approximated by a mixture of two nical work to produce the postprocessed willingess to pay estimates).
normal distributions. The estimate of the weights of the mixture – Assistance in reviewing previous studies and in suggesting some of the
modeled as a logit-type function of subject covariates – revealed that survey questions by Melissa Fickel as part of her undergraduate summer
individuals who missed work after Sandy hit the area – which acts as a research is appreciated.

Appendix A. Supplementary data

Supplementary data related to this article can be found at http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.tranpol.2018.05.010.

Appendix A. Reported Sandy-provoked disruptions

Table 1
Stated disruptions and their duration.

Not at all A few hours 1–2 days 3–5 days 1 week 1–2 weeks 2 + weeks

Subway line closures 42.00% 6.97% 17.90% 12.82% 7.97% 6.26% 6.08%
Subway station closures 42.65% 6.67% 16.77% 11.70% 8.74% 7.03% 6.44%
Closed bridges 49.20% 7.38% 18.25% 11.16% 6.91% 4.19% 2.89%
Closed tunnels 50.27% 5.55% 16.72% 11.05% 7.56% 4.49% 4.37%
Abnormal traffic congestion 31.42% 7.32% 18.37% 15.06% 13.17% 9.04% 5.61%
Limited bus service 41.29% 6.62% 17.66% 13.88% 10.40% 7.03% 3.13%
Commuting 2X + longer 37.27% 7.21% 16.60% 15.53% 11.16% 7.56% 4.67%
Forced to change routes 31.19% 6.85% 16.48% 16.60% 12.40% 9.74% 6.73%
Working at alternate sites 59.60% 4.13% 10.22% 9.75% 7.62% 4.96% 3.72%
Severe transit crowding 45.36% 5.43% 13.29% 11.40% 10.63% 7.97% 5.91%
Difficulty getting fuel 26.99% 5.79% 13.11% 17.48% 18.02% 11.64% 6.97%
Difficulty getting food 46.01% 9.21% 20.26% 10.63% 6.91% 4.31% 2.66%
Difficulty getting water 56.53% 8.45% 14.83% 8.51% 5.73% 4.02% 1.95%
Loss of cell signal 38.81% 17.90% 15.95% 12.64% 8.09% 4.67% 1.95%
Loss of electric power 28.59% 11.52% 12.17% 17.07% 12.99% 12.52% 5.14%
Malfunction of traffic signals 29.12% 8.68% 20.38% 17.84% 13.05% 7.68% 3.25%

17
C. Wang et al. Transport Policy 69 (2018) 10–19

Appendix B. Discrete choice models and unobserved preference heterogeneity

Because preferences are likely to vary across individuals, econometric models of choice have moved toward flexible ways of incorporating
unobserved preference heterogeneity. In general, consider the following logit-type random indirect utility of individual i for alternative j and time (or
‘choice situation’) t:

Uijt = x ijt βi + εijt , (1)
where x ijt is a K × 1 vector of alternative attributes; εijt is an i.i.d. type 1 extreme value tasgte shock; and the preference parameter vector βi is
unknown but is assumed to vary randomly in the population.
The distribution of βi is known as heterogeneity or mixing distribution and can be either discrete, continuous or a combination of the two.
Assuming a parametric continuous mixing density f (βi θ ) , where θ are the parameters of this distribution. For example, the most common mixing
specification is to consider multivariate normally distributed preferences, i.e. βi ∼ N (β, Σ) which leads to the common mixed logit with normally
distributed parameters. Note that in this case, βi = β + Lηi , where ηi ∼ N (0, I) , and L is the lower-triangular Cholesky factor of Σ .
To accomodate both observed and unobserved preference heterogeneity, the following hierarchical specification of βi can be used:
βi = β + Πwi + Lηi , (2)
where wi is a set of M individual characteristics, and Π is a K × M matrix of additional parameters.
The mixing distribution can also be discrete, leading to a latent class logit model (Kamakura and Russell, 1989; DeSarbo et al., 1995; Bhat, 1997;
Greene and Hensher, 2003; Shen, 2009). In a latent class logit model, an individual i has a set of fixed preference parameters βq with probability ωiq –
i.e., Pr(βi = βq) = ωiq , where ∑q wiq = 1 and ωiq > 0 . The discrete mixing distribution (or class assignment probability) is unknown to the analyst, but
the number of classes Q (segments with differing preferences) is set before estimation. The model is completed with a logit specification for the class
assignment probabilities:
exp(hi⊤γq)
ωiq = Q
,
∑q = 1 exp(hi⊤γq) (3)
where hi denotes a set of socioeconomic. The parameters of a refernce class – usually the first class – are normalized to zero (γ1 = 0 ) for identifi-
cation.
Let yijt = 1 if individual i chooses j on occasion t, and 0 otherwise. Then, the unconditional probabilities of the sequence of choices by individual i
for MIXL and LC are respectively given by:
yijt
T J ⊤
⎧ ⎡ exp(x ijt βi )⎤ ⎫
Pi (θ ) = ∫ ⎨∏ ∏ ⎢ ∑
J
exp(x ⊤
β )
⎥ f (β ) dβ
⎬ i i
t j ⎢
⎣ j=1 ijt i ⎥
⎦ ⎭

yijt
Q ⎧T J ⎡ ⊤
exp(x ijt βq)⎤ ⎫
Pi (θ ) = ∑ ⎨∏ ∏ ⎢ J ⎥ ωiq .
q t j ⎢ ∑ exp(x ijt βq) ⎥ ⎬

⎩ ⎣ j=1 ⎦ ⎭
Note that both expressions are basically the same, with the mixed logit being a continuous mixture; and the latent class logit, a discrete mixture.
On the one hand, mixed logit models impose a very specific shape for the distribution of preferences (such as the normal, which unimodal,
unbounded, and symmetric); on the other hand, latent class logit models are flexible and easy to interpret but within a class there is no unobserved
preference heterogeneity. To exploit the benefits of both specifications, researchers have proposed the use of a discrete-continuous mixture model.
The idea behind the double mixture model is simple: there is a discrete number of clusters of individuals (just as in the latent class logit model),
but within each cluster preferences are modeled according to a mixed logit model with a multivariate normal heterogeneity distribution. From a
statistical point of view, this discrete-continuous representation of preference heterogeneity is interpreted as a Gaussian mixture. Gaussian mixtures –
i.e., a linear combination of normal distributions – can approximate any continuous distribution, including multimodal distributions, to a desired
level of accuracy. The resulting logit-type model with a Gaussian mixture is known in the recent choice modeling literature as the mixed-mixed logit
(MM-MNL) model (Bujosa et al., 2010; Keane and Wasi, 2013; Greene and Hensher, 2013).
The main assumption of the mixed-mixed logit model is:
βi ∼  (βq, Σq) with probability ωiq for q = 1, …, Q, (4)
which leads to the following expression of the unconditional probability of the sequence of choices made b individual i:
ijty
Q ⎛ T J ⊤ ⎞
⎧ ⎡ exp(x ijt βi ) ⎤ ⎫
Pi (θ ) = ∑ ωiq ⎜

∫ ⎨∏ ∏ ⎢ J ⊤ ⎥
∑ exp(x ijt βi ) ⎥ ⎬
fq (βi ) dβi ⎟,

q=1 t j ⎢
⎣ j=1 ⎦ ⎭ (5)
⎝ ⎩ ⎠
where fq (βi ) = N (βq, Σq) . Due to the complex expression of the choice probability, estimation in the gmnl package (Sarrias and Daziano, 2017) uses
a Monte-Carlo approximation of the sequence of individual choices as well as an analytical expression of the gradient.

References intercity travel. Transport. Sci. 3, 3448.


Botzen, W.J.W., Van Den Bergh, J.C., 2012. Monetary valuation of insurance against flood
risk under climate change. Int. Econ. Rev. 53 (3), 1005–1026.
Bhat, C., 1997. An endogenous segmentation mode choice model with an application to Brouwer, R., Akter, S., 2010. Informing micro insurance contract design to mitigate

18
C. Wang et al. Transport Policy 69 (2018) 10–19

climate change catastrophe risks using choice experiments. Environ. Hazards 9 (1), Kousky, C., 2011. Managing natural catastrophe risk: state insurance programs in the
74–88. United States. Rev. Environ. Econ. Pol. 5 (1), 153–171.
Brouwer, R., Schaafsma, M., 2013. Modelling risk adaptation and mitigation behaviour Kriesel, W., Landry, C., 2004. Participation in the national flood insurance program: an
under different climate change scenarios. Climatic Change 117 (1–2), 11–29. empirical analysis for coastal properties. J. Risk Insur. 71 (3), 405–420.
Bujosa, A., Riera, A., Hicks, R.L., 2010. Combining discrete and continuous representa- Kunreuther, H., 1996. Mitigating disaster losses through insurance. J. Risk Uncertain. 12
tions of preference heterogeneity: a latent class approach. Environ. Resour. Econ. 47 (2–3), 171–187.
(4), 477493. Kunreuther, H., 2006. Disaster mitigation and insurance: learning from Katrina. Ann. Am.
Climate Risk Information, 17 Feb. 2009. New York City Panel on Climate Change. http:// Acad. Polit. Soc. Sci. 604 (1), 208–227.
www.nyc.gov/html/om/pdf/2009/NPCC%5c%5fCRI.pdf. Kunreuther, H., Meyer, R., Zeckhauser, R., Slovic, P., Schwartz, B., Schade, C., Luce, M.F.,
Dekker, T., Hess, S., Brouwer, R., Hofkes, H., 2016. Decision uncertainty in multi-attri- Lippman, S., Krantz, D., Kahn, B., Hogarth, R., 2002. High stakes decision making:
bute stated preference studies. Resour. Energy Econ. 43, 57–73. normative, descriptive and prescriptive considerations. Market. Lett. 13 (3),
DeSarbo, W., Ramaswamy, V., Cohen, S., 1995. Market segmentation with choice-based 259–268.
conjoint analysis. Market. Lett. 6, 137147. Kunreuther, H.C., Michel-Kerjan, E.O., 2009. At War with the Weather: Managing Large-
Dixon, L., Clancy, N., Seabury, S.A., Overton, A., 2006. The National Flood Insurance scale Risks in a New Era of Catastrophes. MIT Press.
Program's Market Penetration Rate: Estimates and Policy Implications. RAND, Santa Kunreuther, H., Pauly, M., 2004. Neglecting disaster: why don't people insure against
Monica, CA 2006. large losses? J. Risk Uncertain. 28 (1), 5–21.
Federal Emergency Management Agency (FEMA), 2013. Hurricane Sandy FEMA After- Kunreuther, H., Pauly, M., 2006. Rules rather than discretion: lessons from hurricane
action Report. . http://www.fema.gov/media-library-data/20130726-1923-25045- Katrina. J. Risk Uncertain. 33 (1–2), 101–116.
7442/sandy%5c%5ffema%5c%5faar.pdf. Kunreuther, H., Michel-Kerjan, E., 2009. At War with the Weather: Managing Large-scale
Froot, K.A., 2001. The market for catastrophe risk: a clinical examination. J. Financ. Econ. Risks in a New Era of Catastrophes. MIT Press, Cambridge.
60 (2), 529–571. Mantell, N.H., Seneca, J.J., Michael, L.L., Irving, W., 2013. The Economic and Fiscal
Grace, M.F., Klein, R.W., Kleindorfer, P.R., 1998. Overview of Catastrophe Insurance Impacts of Hurricane Sandy in New Jersey. Rep. Rutgers. http://www.esf.edu/glrc/
Markets in the U.S., the Wharton Catastrophe Risk Management Project. library/documents/EconomicandFiscalImpactsofSandy%5c_2013.pdf.
Grace, M.F., Klein, R.W., Kleindorfer, P.R., Murray, M.R., 2003. Catastrophe insurance: McFadden, D., 2001. Economic choices. Am. Econ. Rev. 91 (3), 351–378.
consumer demand, markets and regulation. 1 (1), 76–91. Metropolitan Transportation Authority (MTA), 2012. MTA 2013 Final Proposed Budget,
Greene, W.H., Hensher, D.A., 2003. A latent class model for discrete choice analysis: November Financial Plan 2013-2016. http://web.mta.info/mta/budget/nov2012/
contrasts with mixed logit. Transp. Res. Part B Methodol. 37 (8), 681698. November%5c%5f2012%5c%5fFinancial%5c%5fPlan%5c%5fVol%5c%5f1.pdf.
Greene, W.H., Hensher, D.A., 2013. Revealing additional dimensions of preference het- National Centers for Environmental Information (NCEI), 2016. Billion-dollar Weather and
erogeneity in a latent class mixed multinomial logit model. Appl. Econ. 45 (14), Climate Disasters: Table of Events. http://www.ncdc.noaa.gov/billions/events.
1897–1902. NYS 2100 Commission, 2013. Recommendations to Improve the Strength and Resilience
Hensher, D.A., Rose, J.M., Greene, W.H., 2005. Applied Choice Analysis: a Primer. of the Empire States Infrastructure. Albany, NY January, 11.
Cambridge University Press. Paudel, Y., 2012. A comparative study of public–private catastrophe insurance systems:
Jaffee, D.M., Russell, T., 1997. Catastrophe insurance, capital markets, and uninsurable lessons from current practices. Geneva Pap. Risk Insur. - Issues Pract. 37 (2),
risks. J. Risk Insur. 205–230. 257–285.
Kamakura, W., Russell, G., 1989. A probabilistic choice model for market segmentation Rose, J.M., Bliemer, M.C., 2009. Constructing efficient stated choice experimental de-
and elasticity structure. J. Market. Res. 26, 379390. signs. Transport Rev. 29 (5), 587–617.
Kaufman, S., Qing, C., Levenson, N., Hanson, M., 2012. Transportation during and after Sarrias, M., Daziano, R.A., 2017. Multinomial logit models with continuous and discrete
Hurricane Sandy. individual heterogeneity in R: the gmnl package. J. Stat. Software 79 (2), 1–46.
Keane, M., Wasi, N., 2013. Comparing alternative models of heterogeneity in consumer Shen, J., 2009. Latent class model or mixed logit model? A comparison by transport mode
choice behavior. J. Appl. Econom. 28 (6), 1018–1045. choice data. Appl. Econ. 41 (22), 29152924.
Kleindorfer, P.R., Klein, R.W., 2003. Regulation and markets for catastrophe insurance. Wang, D., Davidson, R.A., Trainor, J.E., Nozick, L.K., Kruse, J., 2017. Howeowner pur-
In: Advances in Economic Design. Springer Berlin Heidelberg, pp. 263–279. chase of insurance for hurricane-induced wind and flood damage. Nat. Hazards 88,
Koetse, M.J., Brouwer, R., 2015. Reference dependence effects on WTA and WTP value 221245.
functions and their disparity. Environ. Resour. Econ. 1–23 Koetse2015.

19

You might also like