You are on page 1of 13

Radical dematerialization and

degrowth
rsta.royalsocietypublishing.org
Giorgos Kallis
ICREA Professor, ICTA, Autonomous University of Barcelona,
Bellaterra, Catalunya, Spain
Review GK, 0000-0003-0688-9552
Cite this article: Kallis G. 2017 Radical
dematerialization and degrowth. Phil. Trans. R. The emission targets agreed in Paris require a
Downloaded from https://royalsocietypublishing.org/ on 03 October 2023

radical reduction of material extraction, use and


Soc. A 375: 20160383.
disposal. The core claim of this article is that a
http://dx.doi.org/10.1098/rsta.2016.0383 radical dematerialization can only be part and parcel
of degrowth. Given that capitalist economies are
Accepted: 1 March 2017 designed to grow, this raises the question of whether,
and under what circumstances, the inevitable
‘degrowth’ can become socially sustainable. Three
One contribution of 19 to a theme issue economic policies are discussed in this direction:
‘Material demand reduction’. work-sharing, green taxes and public money.
This article is part of the themed issue ‘Material
Subject Areas: demand reduction’.
materials science, energy

Keywords:
degrowth, dematerialization, decarbonization
1. Introduction
Nation states committed in Paris to significant reductions
in carbon emissions. Reducing carbon emissions requires
Author for correspondence: reducing material use [1]. This dematerialization is
Giorgos Kallis ‘radical’, first because of its unprecedented scale, and
e-mail: giorgoskallis@gmail.com second, because of the significant social, cultural and
political changes it will entail [2]. The thesis of this paper
is that radical dematerialization is not compatible with
economic growth. Less material use will, in all likelihood,
come only with less output, that is with a smaller
economy. Vice versa, policies of radical dematerialization
will slow down the economy. Capitalist economies,
however, become unstable when they do not grow [3].
Economic slowdowns often have negative social effects.
The question is then whether, and how, could we
manage, or even prosper, without growth [3,4]. A main
obstacle to strict policies for dematerialization is their
presumed negative effect on growth. This rests on the
assumption that a lack of growth is always disastrous.
If the absence of growth is manageable, then this makes
it easier to implement policies that drastically reduce
material demand.

2017 The Author(s) Published by the Royal Society. All rights reserved.
Section 2 outlines the field of ecological economics (EE) and its understanding of the economic
2
process. This provides the theoretical and empirical backbone for the claims made in this article.
Section 3 argues that it is unlikely that material use will be reduced if the economy grows.

rsta.royalsocietypublishing.org Phil. Trans. R. Soc. A 375: 20160383


........................................................
Section 4 explains why the efficiency and demand policies espoused by Allwood et al. [2] are
unlikely to be compatible with economic growth. Section 5 presents three economic policies in
the direction of sustainable degrowth and §6 concludes.

2. Ecological economics, an economics where matter matters


In 1989, economists and natural scientists that were dissatisfied with the treatment of
environmental problems by mainstream economics founded the society for EE [5]. EE aspires to
Downloaded from https://royalsocietypublishing.org/ on 03 October 2023

rethink economics from an ecological point of view [6]. It is a diverse field of research reclaiming
the classical economic approach, in which land and resources were essential factors of production.
Five basic insights from EE are presented below:

(1) The economy is a process of material transformation driven by human and non-human
work.
(2) Efficiency improvements lead to more, not less, resource use.
(3) Factors of production—resources, labour and capital—are complements, not substitutes.
(4) Services embody significant amounts of energy and materials.
(5) Externalities are cost-shifting successes.

(a) The economic process is a material process driven by work


The economy is a complex process that converts raw materials (and energy) into useful goods and
final services. The conversion and final use of energy and materials inevitably produces waste.
Nicholas Georgescu-Roegen (G-R) [7] proposed a theory of the economic process based on the
principles of thermodynamics. G-R’s work is the departure point for EE, though there was a long
lineage of ecological thinking in economics before [8]. From a thermodynamic point of view, what
the economy does is process materials and ‘convert high quality (low entropy) raw materials
into goods and services, while disposing of, and dissipating, large and growing quantities of
high entropy materials and energy waste (that is waste heat)’ ([9], 139). All economic goods have
a material origin—hence G-R’s phrase that ‘matter matters’ [9]. But what moves the economy?
The engine of the economy is work [9]. This view dates back to classical political economy,
for which labour was the central analytical category. Production is the outcome of work.
Humans work to transform raw materials into useful products. This is what ‘adds value’ to
unprocessed raw materials [10]. But humans do not work alone. They often use the work of
draft animals, appropriate the work of non-human species such as bees, and, crucially, exploit
the vast amounts of work supplied from fossil fuels for free. Fossil fuels are solar energy captured
by photosynthesis, accumulated over millions of years below the ground. To appropriate this free
work from nature, humans have to put work and energy. But the free work they appropriate from
fossil fuels is much more than the work they put in.
An important indicator in this respect is the Energy Return on Energy Investment (EROI).
This is the ratio of the amount of energy produced to the amount of energy used to produce
it [11]. To drill oil, you use electricity; to build a photovoltaic park, you have to power schools
that train engineers and machines that extract the minerals that go into the panels [11,12]. Fossil
fuels are a stock [7], a reservoir of ‘bottled photosynthesis’. The Sun’s energy may be vast in
comparison, but it is a diffuse flow. Energy and land have to be spent to concentrate the Sun’s
power [7]. A lot of energy has to be spent to capture and store solar power. Hence its EROI is
likely to remain lower than that of fossil fuels [11,12]. The appropriation of net energy though
is crucial for economic growth.
Economic growth is a process whereby increasing amounts of human and non-human work
process raw materials and energy, faster and faster. Civilizations before the advent of capitalism
experienced very slow rates of economic growth. What was it that capitalism did differently? The
3
major innovation was that surplus work from humans and fossil fuels was concentrated in the
hands of a class of people—‘capitalists’, the owners of the means of production—who did not just

rsta.royalsocietypublishing.org Phil. Trans. R. Soc. A 375: 20160383


........................................................
store this surplus, or ceremoniously waste it for prestige, as elites and Royal courts did before,
but put it back into production [13]. Capitalists invested in machines, which made it possible
to appropriate more work from humans and nature, creating ever-more surplus. A substantial
portion of surplus was directed to science, research and development that led to the invention
of new machines, and the appropriation of more work from nature, further fuelling this cycle
of growth.
Empirical facts confirm this theory. There is a strong correlation between the input of useful
energy—that is energy left after subtracting the energy lost in its production and conversion—
Downloaded from https://royalsocietypublishing.org/ on 03 October 2023

and economic output [14]. Economists accounting for growth attribute it mostly to ‘total factor
productivity’—a name given to all factors other than capital and labour that affect growth—a
shorthand for ‘technological progress’. But as Ayres & Warr [9] show total factor productivity is
strongly associated with the amount of energy used and the efficiency of conversion of energy
inputs into useful work. Technological progress is therefore progress in using more energy, more
efficiently.
If energy is a ‘cause’ of economic growth, as these studies suggest that it is, and if fossil fuels
are a unique source of high EROI, then decoupling growth from fossil fuels is less likely than
conventionally believed. If the economic process is the application of energy and human work
on the transformation of materials, then economic growth is also likely to be strongly coupled
with material use (see §3). Couldn’t, however, economic growth and resource use be decoupled
by using resources more efficiently?

(b) Efficiency and scale


Energy and materials can indeed be used more efficiently. This is precisely what new technologies
do. With the invention of the steam engine, for example, a given quantity of coal produced much
more useful work than before. This, however, led to an increase, not a decrease in the use of coal,
as noted at the time by economist Stanley Jevons. The ‘Jevons paradox’ is the name given to this
counterintuitive—from a resource conservation standpoint—outcome, whereby a more efficient
use of resources leads to more, not less resource use [15]. A simple economic explanation is that a
resource used more efficiently costs less as a result. The demand for it and consumption increase
(rebound), compensating for the savings from the more efficient use. Does this always have to be
the case? Can’t the rebound be less than the savings?
In principle yes, but in practice one finds that the total use of resources increases as a
result of technological improvements that increase resource efficiency. The same is the case with
improvements in labour productivity. Increases in labour productivity have not led to masses of
unemployed people—the increase in total production as a result of increased labour productivity
led to the employment of more, not fewer, workers [15]. To understand why this happens, one has
to look at the underlying growth dynamic of capitalism. As more surplus is extracted from a given
amount of labour or a given stock of resources, this surplus is invested into more production,
which in turn requires more resources and more labour. Efficiency brings growth, which annuls
the savings from efficiency. It is unlikely that resource use will be avoided this way, unless a
concrete limit is imposed upon the maximum allowable scale of resource use—or in the case of
labour, the maximum amount of hours workers can work [16].
Couldn’t resources however be spared by ‘substituting’ them in the production process?
Instead of using more materials or energy, couldn’t we use more capital or more labour?

(c) The complementarity of the factors of production


Capital machinery is not produced from thin air—it has also a material origin. Machines are the
product of human work and energy and they are made with raw materials. To produce machines,
energy and materials are used. Substituting energy and materials with machines in production
4
will not necessarily save energy or resources. What about labour though?
If we were to substitute energy and resources with human labour, this would spare resources,

rsta.royalsocietypublishing.org Phil. Trans. R. Soc. A 375: 20160383


........................................................
but would not grow the economy. Growth is the result of substituting labour with energy and
adding to the work of humans the free work of fossil fuels. This is what is behind rises in
‘labour productivity’. What appears as an increase in productivity is, partly, a substitution of
the work done by human muscles and brains with the work done by fossil fuels [17]. Fossil
fuels did not simply substitute the ‘horse power’ of horses—they brought millions of new, and
cheaper, ‘horses’ into production. Reversing this and making humans again do more of the
work presently done by energy may increase employment, but would make the economy less
productive, reducing output.
Downloaded from https://royalsocietypublishing.org/ on 03 October 2023

Certain resources may also not be substitutable. Without getting into details, standard
economic theory assumes perfect substitution between the factors of production (capital, labour,
resources), and unlimited possibilities of substitution between specific resources or materials (say
fossil fuels substituting energy from biomass). There are two problems with this.
Firstly, mutual and full substitutability means that goods and services could in principle be
produced by any of the three factors alone, without the use of the other two. This cannot be
right. To fly, a plane needs both pilots and kerosene. The factors of production are complements,
not substitutes. Machines require workers to operate them, and labour requires tools to be
productive [9]. For certain economic processes, there is a minimum requirement of each factor
without which the process cannot take place.
Secondly, it is reasonable to expect that as resources become scarce and their relative price
increases, investment will go into research and development of substitutes. As fossil fuels get
more expensive, for example, other sources of energy may emerge as substitutes. Whereas this
might have been true in the past and for certain resources, for example, substituting fuel wood
with fossil fuels, the possibility of substitution cannot be asserted a priori independently of
concrete situations. There might or there might not be a substitute for fossil fuels or certain
scarce materials. This question is one of engineering, not of economics. One cannot assume
that there will always be substitutes. And even if there are substitutes, one cannot assume that
these substitutes will be able to maintain the same scale of the economy or rates of growth.
If fossil fuels, for example, are substituted by lower EROI renewables, this will reduce the
total amount of useful work provided by energy sources and dampen the scale and growth of
the economy.
A final theoretical possibility under which the economy could dematerialize and grow is
through structural change. If a growing share of output is provided by services that use few
materials and these services substitute output from more materially intensive goods, then it
might be possible to combine growth with dematerialization.1 But do services use fewer materials
and energy?

(d) Embodied energy and materials


Products and services embody not only the materials and energy directly found in them, but also
the materials and energy spent in the various stages of their production. Howard Odum proposed
the concept of ‘Emergy’, with an m. This is the energy embedded in products and services—the
energy that went into their production. A fish, for example, embodies all the solar energy that
went into making the phytoplankton that it ate [19]. A service worker embodies all the energy
consumed for feeding, clothing, educating and moving her around.
William Rees [20], a biologist turned ecological economist, put in practice this idea with the
concept of ecological footprint. Recent research on consumption-based emissions and material
1
Note that dematerialization would last only as long as there are possibilities of substitution. When the transition has been
completed, any further growth will increase material use, no matter how dematerialized the economy is. This is the basic
insight behind Ward et al.’s [18] claim that decoupling GDP growth from environmental impact is impossible. Assuming
continuous substitutions and efficiency improvements, at some point the physical limits of efficiency improvements will be
reached, and after that any further growth will be unavoidably coupled to environmental impact.
flows, including indicators such as water or material footprint [21,22], is based on this insight:
5
behind any final product or service, there is a long chain of resource and energy use, conversion
and waste. In a metaphorical sense, all this is ‘embodied’ in the final product and marks its

rsta.royalsocietypublishing.org Phil. Trans. R. Soc. A 375: 20160383


........................................................
‘footprint’.
The next section shows that the material footprint of nations is strongly correlated with the size
of their economy. The data show that there is no absolute dematerialization to date—a tentative
confirmation of the EE theory presented in this section.

(e) Cost-shifting
The environmental costs of economic activities are often considered as ‘externalities’, costs that
Downloaded from https://royalsocietypublishing.org/ on 03 October 2023

are not accounted for within existing markets. This view presupposes the possibility of an all-
encompassing market where nothing will be external to it. In reality, ‘cost-shifting’ is a pervasive
feature of market activity, where businesses try to increase their profits by shifting their costs to
others, or to society as a whole, when and if they can [23]. Externalities are therefore cost-shifting
‘successes’, rather than market failures [23].
Ever since the colonies, growth is fuelled by the extraction of surpluses in the imperial centres
by exploiting people and environments elsewhere [24]. If such costs were internalized, probably
there would not have been growth to begin with. An ‘internalization’ of ecological or carbon
costs today would possibly bring growth to an end, especially if accumulated debts from the
past were included. This is why carbon or other environmental taxes are resisted by the powerful
economic interests that profit from the externalization of carbon or environmental costs. As Raj
Patel [25] vividly puts it, the social and ecological cost of a McDonald burger is in the order of
200$. McDonalds would not have a business if it was to internalize its costs.

3. Why dematerialization is unlikely to be compatible with economic growth


Is the use of metals and other materials bound to increase because of growth, or not? This is an
argument dating back to the publication of the Limits to growth report [26] and the response of
economists to it [27]. The Club of Rome claimed that economic growth increases material use
and will eventually exhaust mineral deposits unless slowed down. Solow [27] responded that
as prices of scarce metals increase, and technologies and substitutes are developed, the material
intensity of the economy will decline (that is the kilograms of a metal used per dollar of economic
product). Eventually, this should lead to a decline of resource use.
Efficiency (or intensity), however, is not the same with scale. We might use a resource more
efficiently, and still end up using more of it. Data on the aggregate use of materials by the global
economy show that there is only a minor reduction of the intensity of use (or, put differently, a
minor improvement of material efficiency or productivity). Yet overall material use has more than
doubled since 1980 (figure 1).2
Some authors see signs of a forthcoming dematerialization. Recent data show stagnation
of material consumption in some Western economies such as the UK [28]. Could this be a
point of ‘peak stuff’, a natural peaking of material consumption as economies reach a mature
stage, after which material use declines? ([29], see also [30]). If that were the case, growth and
dematerialization would be compatible, at least in the long-run after developing countries had
developed sufficiently to reach their ‘peak-stuff’.
As Gutowski et al. [30], however note, data on domestic material consumption does not
account for the material embedded in imported consumer goods. The true material use of a
national economy does not include only the raw materials that it extracts, imports or consumes
within its borders. It includes also the materials embedded in the finished goods or services that
it imports. The material footprint of developed nations, that is the total amount of materials

2
A question also is to what extent GDP growth might be inflated from financial services—20% of GDP in some advanced
economies—and private or public debt.
260 6
240 GDP

rsta.royalsocietypublishing.org Phil. Trans. R. Soc. A 375: 20160383


........................................................
220
index: 1980 = 100 200
180
160
material extraction
140
120
100
Downloaded from https://royalsocietypublishing.org/ on 03 October 2023

material intensity
80
1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010

Figure 1. Trends in global material extraction, GDP and material intensity (kg/$) 1980–2013 (data from the WU Global material
flows database and the World Bank; indexed values, 1980 values equal 100).

0.6
0.5
0.4
0.3
0.2
0.1
0
–0.1
material footprint domestic material consumption gross domestic product

Figure 2. Relative changes in OECD material footprint, domestic material consumption, and GDP from 1990 to 2008. GDP is
calculated as purchasing power parity using 2005 US Dollars as the base year. Values are plotted as X = (Xt 2 − Xt 1 )/Xt 1 ;
t 1 = 1990. Figure from Wiedmann et al. [22].

used to produce the goods and services that they consume, increases hand in hand with the
size of their economies (figure 2). There is no sign of peak-stuff if one looks at material footprint
instead of domestic material consumption (the actual materials consumed, plus imports minis
exports). Despite substantial deindustrialization and de-agrarianization, the material demands
of the so-called ‘service economies’ continue to grow.
Take California: the information sector accounts for 8% of the total state product, 21%
together with business and professional services that include computer systems and design [31].
Agriculture’s share of the economy is down to 2%. Yet, the state’s water footprint grew almost
40% from 1992 to 2010 [21].
Research on individual metals confirms a similar story to that of aggregated material flows.
The Jevons’ paradox is confirmed for 57 different materials for all of which there is no evidence of
dematerialization. Increases in consumption and production outpace savings from technological
improvements [32]. And at the sites where metals are extracted, conflicts intensify because of the
negative environmental and social consequences of extraction [33].
The separation in the trends of domestic material consumption and material footprint in high-
income economies is not evidence that they are doing something better. It is a by-product of the
globalization of the economy. Industrializing economies produce the consumer goods of service
7
economies [30]. (The idea that one day all economies could graduate to be service economies with
saturated material consumption raises the question who would produce then their industrial

rsta.royalsocietypublishing.org Phil. Trans. R. Soc. A 375: 20160383


........................................................
goods?) This is a systemic pattern, revealed at the global scale, the only appropriate scale to
study a globalized economy with a global division of labour. At this scale, the prediction of EE is
confirmed: material extraction and consumption grow as the economy grows.
Cross-country comparisons confirm the same picture. A GDP growth (degrowth) of 1% leads
to a 0.6% growth (degrowth) of material footprint [22]. Same for carbon: a 1% increase (decrease)
in GDP leads to about 0.5–0.7% increase (decrease) in carbon emissions [34]. These are strong,
statistically significant effects, as significant as one can hope to find in econometrics. One may
well claim that the causal relationship between GDP and resource use will finally change in the
Downloaded from https://royalsocietypublishing.org/ on 03 October 2023

future with structural changes in the economy, or the advent of new materials and technologies.
But on this basis, no econometric study could ever be a basis for policy since we can always hope
that with sufficient will we can change established causal relations.
In conclusion, the more (less) an economy grows, the more (less) materials it uses. The next
section argues that the reverse holds true too. Radical dematerialization is likely to slow down
the economy.

4. Dematerialization would slow down the economy


There are four reasons why a radical material reduction is unlikely to be compatible with
economic growth.
First, material efficiency at the factory level will lead to profits that will then be reinvested for
growth in other parts of the economy. Efficiency fuels growth and increases material use. Only a
limit to the scale of the economy—and the total amount of raw materials that can be extracted and
consumed—ensures that efficiency reduces material use [35]. But if the rate of economic growth
depends on the use of resources, then such limits will also limit growth.
Second, using labour instead of new materials can reduce material use. Say for example, that
instead of knocking down and replacing commercial buildings after 40 years, we did a major
retrofit. This would require more labour, but a fraction of the material input. But isn’t this what
most pre-growth societies did? Reversing to a more labour-intensive economy will increase the
number of jobs; but is unlikely to produce profits and lead to growth. Labour productivity will go
down (see also [30]). A retrofit economy is possible, but its houses and cars may look more like
Cuba’s than California’s.
Likewise, a transition to a solar and wind economy is desirable and necessary. Given, however,
that the energy return on energy investment of renewable energies is much lower than fossil
fuels [36], decarbonization is unlikely to be compatible with a global economy at its current size—
and much less with a global economy converging to the output of a US economy growing 2 or 3%
per year.
Investments in renewable energies create jobs. In the short-term, they may act as a stimulus
for the economy. But this does not mean that in the long term it is possible to sustain growth with
diminished energy surpluses, substituting energy with human labour. Efficiency improvements,
demand reductions, and material and energy source substitutions are all necessary for a
sustainable future. But they are not compatible with more growth.
Third, consider a scenario where people fix their own phones or their cars instead of buying
new ones. The circulation of new goods in the economy would slow down. The unpaid, domestic
portion of the economy will grow, but market economy will shrink. The surpluses that drive
growth will diminish, and therefore growth will decline. An economy that grows 2% per year has
to double the speed with which it churns goods and services every 35 years. There must always
be demand to satisfy the bigger and faster production. Production requires consumption. Planned
obsolescence and an ever-faster turnover of goods are necessary if growth rates of 2–3% per year
are to be sustained. Taking consumption out of the market will inevitably slow down production.
Fourth, dematerialization and decarbonization require significant investments, for example for
8
new infrastructures. These investments will ‘crowd out’ conventional investments that typically
go towards improving labour productivity. This is also likely to dampen economic growth [37].

rsta.royalsocietypublishing.org Phil. Trans. R. Soc. A 375: 20160383


........................................................
A retrofitting, renewable economy is desirable environmentally. People may under certain
conditions come to desire and find meaningful a shift to more manual work. They may embrace
their reduced material or energy purchasing power in the knowledge that the alternative—growth
in material and energy use followed by climate change—would be worse. Many people already
find meaning in a more frugal lifestyle, and enjoy relational instead of material goods [38].
Such ‘preferences’ may be strengthened if basic needs are secured, and wealth distributed
equitably [39]. The question is then how and under what conditions this may happen. ‘Sustainable
degrowth’ refers to such a scenario of increasing wellbeing in a context of declining output [40,41].
Downloaded from https://royalsocietypublishing.org/ on 03 October 2023

Assuming that the EE diagnosis is correct, a decline of economic output is inevitable. The
question is whether we will follow a ‘prosperous way down’ [19]; or grow more and collapse after
crossing planetary boundaries. Degrowth research investigates under what social and political
conditions the inevitable downscaling can become prosperous and not catastrophic [42,43].
This includes policies that make degrowth stable, reducing the dependence of wellbeing upon
growth [3,42].
The next section focuses on three economic policies that can act as levers of change in
a possible transition: work-sharing, green taxes and public money. These policies do not
directly target material use. Yet they are important from a radical dematerialization perspective.
They facilitate a downscaling of the economy that will reduce material use. And they secure
wellbeing in conditions of economic contraction—a likely outcome of strict dematerialization
or decarbonization policies.

5. Policies for sustainable degrowth


Without growth, unemployment increases because rising productivity reduces the amount of
labour necessary. Work-sharing refers to a reduction of the hours of paid work without loss in
income. Fewer working hours per person leave more jobs for everyone to share. If people work
less, the cost of labour may rise. The reduced output might reduce then the additional number of
jobs. But overall a reduction of working hours has a positive effect on employment [44].
Work-sharing redistributes the gains from productivity. Instead of producing profits for
capitalists, productivity serves to liberate time for workers [45]. Lange [46] shows that work-
sharing is a fundamental condition for a stable, zero-growth path in both neoclassical and
Keynesian growth models. Econometric studies suggest that reduced working hours reduce
carbon emissions and environmental pressures and increase wellbeing [47–50].
There is a limit, however, to how far work can be reduced. If the use of fossil fuels is to be
limited in the future, there will be less ‘energy slaves’ doing work for free. Humans will have
to do more of this work—if we want to work less, then we will have to suffice also with less
consumption [51,52]. In a carbon- and oil-constrained world, automation and ‘robotization’ are
not inevitable outcomes.
A risk of work-sharing is also that resource use can rebound if the liberated time is devoted to
resource-intensive leisure. A taxation policy that dis-incentivizes resource-intensive consumption
is a vital complement to work-sharing [44].
Taxation should shift from taxing work, which is a ‘good’, to taxing resource use and
environmental damage, which are ‘bads’ [16]. A carbon or resource tax (green tax) could gradually
substitute income tax, without increasing overall tax revenue. The green tax should apply not only
to domestically produced goods, but also to the resources and carbon embedded in imports.
A problem is that poor people devote a larger share of their income to resource and energy
use. The rich save a comparatively larger share of their income. In an income tax, the rich
pay more; with a green tax, the poor may end up paying more. To alleviate this, the revenue
from the green tax could be used to eliminate mostly the income tax of low (or middle)
income groups.
Green taxes are not proposed only by degrowth advocates. The difference is that from a
9
degrowth perspective, there is a recognition that strict green taxes at the scale necessary to
reduce resource and fossil fuel use, will have in all likelihood a negative effect on the economy.

rsta.royalsocietypublishing.org Phil. Trans. R. Soc. A 375: 20160383


........................................................
Work-sharing (and other policies) are then meant to deal with the social consequences of lack
of growth.
Without growth, inequalities may also rise if the rate of return to capital is higher than the rate
of growth—a larger share of national income will concentrate this way in the hands of capitalists
compared to workers [53]. Jackson & Victor [54], however, argue that less growth may suppress
the return to capital, and redistributive policies reduce inequalities. A maximum wage (income
ceiling) could act as a cap on permissible levels of inequality [55]. A return to the progressive taxes
of the 1950s and 1960s, with very high taxes for high-income brackets, combined with inheritance
Downloaded from https://royalsocietypublishing.org/ on 03 October 2023

taxes or a global wealth tax could also reduce inequalities [53].


Is degrowth, however, compatible with the way the monetary system works? Currently private
banks create money and lend it with an interest. Repaying interests creates an imperative for the
economy to grow [56]. This leads some authors to conclude that states should take back the control
of the creation of money from private banks (‘public money’, see [57]).
Money now enters the economy as debt. When a bank issues a loan, new money is created.
Before the financial crisis money and debt grew out of proportion with the real economic activity.
While private banks can only issue money as debt through loans, the state, under a public money
policy, could issue money free of debt to pay for public needs. For example, states could issue
money to finance a minimum universal basic income [55] or to subsidize green investments [57].
States would reclaim seigniorage (the difference between the nominal value of money and the cost
of producing it), and would not borrow from private banks to finance public expenditures. This
will give leverage to states to stimulate desired forms of consumption (e.g. green) and suppress
others (e.g. environmentally damaging).
Private money creation, resource and territorial expansion, and the constant push for reducing
labour costs and requirements are central features of capitalist economies. This has led some to
question whether a capitalist economy without accumulation and growth is possible (see [58]
versus [59]). Capitalist economies are characterized by relentless competition. This creates a
‘grow or perish’ imperative for individual firms, which translates into a growth imperative
for the economy as a whole. It is not impossible to imagine in theory a capitalist system
confined within limits, many firms perishing, and a few growing [58]. But the experience from
periods of stagnation and recession suggests that a capitalist system without growth is socially
unsustainable. A shrinking and limited pie intensifies distributive conflict between capitalists
and workers. Growth defuses social conflict and this is why it is essential for the stability of
capitalism [27].
Where most analysts agree is that if reforms like the ones discussed above were to
be implemented, the resulting economies would look nothing like the capitalist ones of
today [3,46,60]. Systems where wage labour is diminished, private banks are redundant—
constrained at best to the role of intermediary lenders—and resource and energy use are low
and do not expand, would be very different. To see such ‘reforms’ happen, a radical change of
political and economic power would be necessary [61]. Dittmer [62], for example, in a critical
review of public money concludes that implementing the policy would require ‘a tremendous
reconfiguration of power relations between states and finance capital’.
The above policies apply principally to ‘overdeveloped economies’ [16]—economies whose
scale could not be sustained by planetary ecosystems, if it were to become generalized. OECD
countries fall under this category. What about the very poor countries though whose basic
needs still go unmet? Gutowski et al. [30] argue that there is no historical precedent of a
country developing without industrializing, and there is no industrialization without increased
resource use. Satisfactory levels of development, as measured by the human development
index, can be achieved at lower levels of resource use than those of the richest economies
today. But generalizing even these decreased levels of resource use will overshoot planetary
boundaries [30,63,64].
This creates an impossibility theorem. If greening and dematerializing growth is not possible,
10
and if development without growth and materialization are impossible, then in the long-term
sustained development is impossible. There is some hope, however, insofar as the human

rsta.royalsocietypublishing.org Phil. Trans. R. Soc. A 375: 20160383


........................................................
development index includes GDP. It is almost tautological to claim that human development
requires GDP growth. The important question instead is: are there different understandings of
wellbeing and human development that could be materially sustainable? The work of Gough [39]
on defining a set of basic needs that could be sustainably met moves in this direction.

6. Conclusion
Downloaded from https://royalsocietypublishing.org/ on 03 October 2023

The take-home message of this article is that decarbonization and dematerialization are
incompatible with economic growth; and that strict policies for decarbonization and
dematerialization will have a negative effect on growth. This requires thinking how to manage
without growth. Three policies were indicatively discussed: sharing work, taxing resources and
energy instead of work, and creation of money by the state, redirecting it to a green transition.
All this is a tall order. Given the current political climate, opting for a voluntary ‘prosperous
way down’ is extremely unlikely. The pursuit of growth has the features of a ‘collective action’
tragedy. Without sufficient international governance, each nation is bound to pursue growth in
the search for economic and military advantage in a globalized world. The end result is likely to
be ruin for all.
Understandably, some prefer to imagine against historical experience, that it is possible
to decouple resource use from economic growth, and to fuel growth with renewable energy.
The technological achievements during the last 200 years or so of capitalism fuel this hope.
Yet previous technological achievements were energy and resource-intensive, accelerating the
transformation of matter and the fresh occupation of new territories. Capitalism has been
extremely good at relentlessly and violently expanding; there are few signs that it can be as good
at peacefully contracting.
It might well be the case that ‘the politically acceptable is ecologically disastrous while the
ecologically necessary is politically impossible’ [65]. Scientists, however, should not limit the
pursuit of truth within the confines of the politically acceptable. This article provided theoretical
and empirical evidence for such an inconvenient truth—further growth is not ecologically
sustainable.

Competing interests. I declare I have no competing interests.


Funding. This research was supported from the ‘María de Maeztu’ Unit of Excellence (MDM-2015-0552) grant
from the Spanish Ministry of Economy and Competitiveness (MINECO) and the SINALECO grant no.
CSO2014-54513-R SINALECO.

References
1. Worrell E, Carreon JR. 2017 Energy demand for materials in an international context. Phil.
Trans. R. Soc. A 375, 20160377. (doi:10.1098/rsta.2016.0377)
2. Allwood JM, Ashby MF, Gutowski TG, Worrell E. 2013 Material efficiency: providing material
services with less material production. Phil. Trans. R. Soc. A 371, 20120496. (doi:10.1098/
rsta.2012.0496)
3. Jackson T. 2008 Prosperity without growth. Economics for a finite planet. London, UK: Earthscan-
Routledge.
4. Victor PA. 2008 Managing without growth: slower by design, not disaster. Cheltenham, UK:
Edward Elgar Publishing.
5. Costanza R, Cumberland JH, Daly H, Goodland R, Norgaard RB, Kubiszewski I, Franco C.
2014 An introduction to ecological economics. Boca Raton, FL: CRC Press.
6. Spash CL. 2011 Social ecological economics: Understanding the past to see the future. Am.J.
Econ. Sociol. 70, 340–375. (doi:10.1111/j.1536-7150.2011.00777.x)
7. Georgescu-Roegen N. 1971 The entropy law and the economic process. Cambridge, MA: Harvard
11
University Press.
8. Martinez-Alier J. 1990 Ecological Economics: Energy, Environment and Society. Oxford: Basil

rsta.royalsocietypublishing.org Phil. Trans. R. Soc. A 375: 20160383


........................................................
Blackwell
9. Ayres RU, Warr B. 2009 The economic growth engine: how energy and work drive material prosperity.
Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.
10. Moore JW. 2015 Capitalism in the Web of Life. Ecology and the Accumulation of Capital. London,
UK: Verso.
11. Murphy DJ, Hall CA. 2010 Year in review—EROI or energy return on (energy) invested.
Ann. NY Acad. Sci. 1185, 102–118. (doi:10.1111/j.1749-6632.2009.05282.x)
12. Odum HT. 1973 Energy, ecology, and economics. Ambio 2, 220–227.
13. Bataille G. 1988 The accursed share, vol. 1, 22. New York, NY: Zone Books.
Downloaded from https://royalsocietypublishing.org/ on 03 October 2023

14. Cleveland C, Costanza C, Hall CAS, Kaufman R. 1984 Energy and the U.S. economy: a
biophysical perspective. Science 225, 890–897. (doi:10.1126/science.225.4665.890)
15. Alcott B. 2014 Jevons’ paradox. In Degrowth: a vocabulary for a new era (eds G D’Alisa,
F Demaria, G Kallis). London, UK: Routledge.
16. Daly HE. 1991 Steady-state economics, 2nd edn. Washington, DC: Island Press.
17. Stern DI. 2011 The role of energy in economic growth. Ann. NY Acad. Sci. 1219, 26–51.
(doi:10.1111/j.1749-6632.2010.05921.x)
18. Ward JD, Sutton PC, Werner AD, Costanza R, Mohr SH, Simmons CT. 2016 Is Decoupling
GDP growth from environmental impact possible? PLoS ONE 11, e0164733.
19. Odum HT, Odum EC. 2008 A prosperous way down: principles and policies. Boulder, CO:
University Press of Colorado.
20. Rees WE. 1992 Ecological footprints and appropriated carrying capacity: what urban
economics leaves out. Environ. Urban. 4, 121–130. (doi:10.1177/095624789200400212)
21. Fulton J. 2015 California’s water footprint: recent trends and framework for a sustainable
transition. PhD thesis. University of California Berkeley, USA.
22. Wiedmann TO, Schandl H, Lenzen M, Moran D, Suh S, West J, Kanemoto K. 2015 The material
footprint of nations. Proc. Natl Acad. Sci. USA 112, 6271–6276. (doi:10.1073/pnas.1220362110)
23. Kapp KW. 1970 Environmental disruption and social costs: a challenge to economics. Kyklos
23, 833–848. (doi:10.1111/j.1467-6435.1970.tb01047.x)
24. Hornborg A. 1998 Towards an ecological theory of unequal exchange: articulating world
system theory and ecological economics. Ecol. Econ. 25, 127–136. (doi:10.1016/S0921-
8009(97)00100-6)
25. Patel R. 2010 The value of nothing: how to reshape market society and reclaim democracy. New York,
NY: Picador.
26. Meadows DH, Meadows DL, Randers J, Behrens WW. 1972 The limits to growth. New York,
NY: Universe Books.
27. Solow RM. 1973 Is the end of the world at hand? Challenge 16, 39–50. (doi:10.1080/05775132.
1973.11469961)
28. Goodall C. 2011 ‘Peak Stuff’: Did the UK reach a maximum use of material resources in the
early part of the last decade. A research paper for Carbon Commentary, 13.
29. Pearce F. 2012 Peak planet: are we starting to consume less? New Scientist 214, 38–43.
(doi:10.1016/S0262-4079(12)61566-8)
30. Gutowski T, Cooper D, Sahni S. 2017 Why we use more materials. Phil. Trans. R. Soc. A 375,
20160368. (doi:10.1098/rsta.2016.0368)
31. Investopedia. 2016 California’s economy: the 9 Industries driving GDP Growth, http://
www.investopedia.com/articles/investing/011416/californias-economy-9-industries-
driving-gdp-growth.asp (last accessed 6 October 2016).
32. Magee CL, Devezas TC. 2016 A simple extension of dematerialization theory: incorporation
of technical progress and the rebound effect. Technol. Forecast Soc. Change 117, 196–205.
33. Conde M. 2017 Resistance to mining. A review. Ecol. Econ. 132, 80–90. (doi:10.1016/j.ecolecon.
2016.08.025)
34. Burke, PJ, Shahiduzzaman M, Stern DI. 2015 Carbon dioxide emissions in the short run: the
rate and sources of economic growth matter. Global Environmental Change, 33, 109–121.
35. Daly HE, Farley J. 2011 Ecological economics: principles and applications. Washihgton, DC: Island
Press.
36. Murphy DJ, Hall CA. 2010 Year in review—EROI or energy return on (energy) invested. Ann.
12
NY Acad. Sci. 1185, 102–118.
37. van den Bergh JC. 2017 A third option for climate policy within potential limits to growth.

rsta.royalsocietypublishing.org Phil. Trans. R. Soc. A 375: 20160383


........................................................
Nat. Clim. Change 7, 107–112. (doi:10.1038/nclimate3113)
38. Kasser T. 2017 Living both well and sustainably: a review of the literature, with some
reflections on future research, interventions and policy. Phil. Trans. R. Soc. A 375, 20160369.
(doi:10.1098/rsta.2016.0369)
39. Gough I. 2017 Recomposing consumption: defining necessities for sustainable and equitable
well-being. Phil. Trans. R. Soc. A 375, 20160379. (doi:10.1098/rsta.2016.0379)
40. Asara V, Otero I, Demaria F, Corbera E. 2015 Socially sustainable degrowth as a
social–ecological transformation: repoliticizing sustainability. Sustainability Sci. 10, 375–384.
(doi:10.1007/s11625-015-0321-9)
Downloaded from https://royalsocietypublishing.org/ on 03 October 2023

41. Kallis G. 2011 In defence of degrowth. Ecol. Econ. 70, 873–880. (doi:10.1016/j.ecolecon.
2010.12.007)
42. Kallis G, Kerschner C, Martinez-Alier J. 2012 The economics of degrowth. Ecol. Econ. 84,
172–180. (doi:10.1016/j.ecolecon.2012.08.017)
43. Demaria F, Schneider F, Sekulova F, Martinez-Alier J. 2013 What is degrowth? From
an activist slogan to a social movement. Environ. Values 22, 191–215. (doi:10.3197/
096327113X13581561725194)
44. Kallis G, Kalush M, O’Flynn H, Rossiter J, Ashford N. 2013 ‘Friday off’: reducing working
hours in Europe. Sustainability 5, 1545–1567. (doi:10.3390/su5041545)
45. Gorz A. 1994 Capitalism, socialism, ecology. London, UK: Verso. London.
46. Lange T. 2017 Macroeconomics without growth. PhD thesis, University of Hamburg,
Germany.
47. Alesina A, Glaeser E, Sacerdote B. 2005 Work and leisure in the US and Europe: Why so different?
NBER Macroeconomic Annual Volume 20, NBER Working Paper No. 11278. Washington, DC:
National Bureau of Economic Research.
48. Pouwels B, Siegers J, Vlasblom JD. 2008 Income, working hours, and happiness. Econ. Lett. 99,
72–74. (doi:10.1016/j.econlet.2007.05.032)
49. Rosnick D, Weisbrot M. 2007 Are shorter hours good for the environment? A comparison
of US and European energy consumption. Int. J. Health Serv. 37, 405–417. (doi:10.2190/
D842-1505-1K86-9882)
50. Knight KW, Rosa EA, Schor JB. 2013 Could working less reduce pressures on the
environment? A cross-national panel analysis of OECD countries, 1970–2007. Glob. Environ.
Change 23, 691–700. (doi:10.1016/j.gloenvcha.2013.02.017)
51. Sorman AH, Giampietro M. 2013 The energetic metabolism of societies and the degrowth
paradigm: analyzing biophysical constraints and realities. J. Cleaner Prod. 38, 80–93.
(doi:10.1016/j.jclepro.2011.11.059)
52. Kallis G. 2013 Societal metabolism, working hours and degrowth: a comment on Sorman and
Giampietro. J. Cleaner Prod. 38, 94–98. (doi:10.1016/j.jclepro.2012.06.015)
53. Piketty T. 2014 Capital in the 21st century. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
54. Jackson T, Victor PA. 2016 Does slow growth lead to rising inequality? Some theoretical
reflections and numerical simulations. Ecol. Econ. 121, 206–219. (doi:10.1016/j.ecolecon.
2015.03.019)
55. Alexander S. 2014 Basic and maximum income. In Degrowth: a vocabulary for a new era (eds
G D’Alisa, F Demaria, G Kallis), pp. 146–149. London, UK: Routledge.
56. Van Griethuysen P. 2010 Why are we growth-addicted? The hard way towards degrowth
in the involutionary western development path. J. Cleaner Prod. 18, 590–595. (doi:10.1016/
j.jclepro.2009.07.006)
57. Mellor M. 2010 The future of money: from financial crisis to public resource. London, UK: Pluto
Press.
58. Lawn P. 2011 Is steady-state capitalism viable? Ann. NY Acad. Sci. 1219, 1–25. (doi:10.1111/
j.1749-6632.2011.05966.x)
59. Skidelsky E, Skidelsky R. 2012 How much is enough?: money and the good life. UK: Penguin.
60. Kallis G, D’Alisa G, Demaria F (eds). 2014 Degrowth: a vocabulary for a new era. London, UK:
Routledge.
61. Blauwhof FB. 2012 Overcoming accumulation: Is a capitalist steady-state economy possible?
13
Ecol. Econ. 84, 254–261. (doi:10.1016/j.ecolecon.2012.03.012)
62. Dittmer K. 2015 100 percent reserve banking: a critical review of green perspectives. Ecol. Econ.

rsta.royalsocietypublishing.org Phil. Trans. R. Soc. A 375: 20160383


........................................................
109, 9–16.(doi:10.1016/j.ecolecon.2014.11.006)
63. Steinberger JK, Krausmann F, Getzner M, Schandl H, West J. 2013 Development and
dematerialization: an international study. PLoS ONE 8, e70385. (doi:10.1371/journal.
pone.0070385)
64. Lamb WF, Rao ND. 2015 Human development in a climate-constrained world: what the past
says about the future. Glob. Environ. Change 33, 14–22. (doi:10.1016/j.gloenvcha.2015.03.010)
65. Wackernagel M, Rees W. 1998 Our ecological footprint: reducing human impact on the earth (No. 9).
Vancouver, Canada: New Society Publishers.
Downloaded from https://royalsocietypublishing.org/ on 03 October 2023

You might also like