You are on page 1of 7

Pharmacies

J-R Borrell, University of Barcelona, Barcelona, Spain


C Cassó, University of Barcelona, Barcelona, Spain, and Northeastern University, Boston, MA, USA
r 2014 Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.

Glossary have been in use for some time and which may only cause
Double marginalization Phenomenon in which pricing minor adverse effects when not used properly. There is
of any good or service turns out to be excessive because not usually enough competition among providers of such
only manufacturers that have upstream market power medicines among innovator brands, other brands, and
overcharge in equilibrium equating its marginal costs and generic alternatives. In many jurisdictions, direct to
marginal revenue from its residual demand but retailers consumer advertising is only permitted for OTC drugs, but
also overcharge as they can profit from their dominant in others such as in the US, direct to consumer advertising is
position downstream equating again marginal costs to the also permitted for pharmacy-only and prescription-only
marginal revenue from its residual demand. It is called medicines.
double marginalization when upstream and downstream Pharmacy-only medicines Medicines that can only be
firms are separated. When both are vertically integrated in obtained from a pharmacy outlet, but which do not require
one unique firm, the phenomenon disappears and price a doctor’s prescription. Such medicines may be dispensed
turns out to be lower as the vertically integrated firm only with the advice and assistance of a pharmacist.
equates marginal cost to marginal revenue just once. Usually, these are medicines that have been available for
Over-the-counter (OTC) medicines Medicines that can some time and that have no serious adverse effects when
be offered in pharmacies, or in some jurisdictions in other properly taken.
retail outlets, and that can be readily available to the public Prescription-only medicines Medicines for which a
from the store shelves. Usually, these are medicines that doctor’s prescription is a legal requirement.

Introduction on those that rely much more on a regulated command and


control framework.
Dispensing medical drugs is a profession that combines the In Section Benefits and Risks from Regulating Pharmacies
particularities of a professional service and retail industry. The an assessment of the pros and cons of quality, entry, and price
focus here is on retail pharmacy, leaving aside the special regulations is dealt with.
character of hospital pharmacies.
First, pharmacists are responsible for a range of pro-
Challenges and Policy Options
fessional services including offering advice and assistance to
those receiving their medication. Pharmacists are responsible
Societies face a twofold challenge when organizing pro-
for making sure that people receive their medication safely
fessional retail pharmacy markets.
and professionally. Second, a network of pharmacies and
First, the structure of the market should address the fol-
other retail outlets is a major vehicle for public policies de-
lowing to ensure that
signed to make pharmaceuticals available and affordable to
the public throughout a jurisdiction. However, different jur- 1. the consumers get assistance and advice that is free from
isdictions do this differently. There is no single ‘template’ the personal interests of prescribers;
policy model that fits all jurisdictions. 2. the consumers receive assistance and advice that is free
In the middle- and low- income countries, there is tension from the personal interests of dispensers, particularly when
between policies aimed at safe and proper dispensing and a prescription is not filled; and
those aimed at availability and affordability. 3. that the pharmacists and their assistants are professionals
This article focuses on the policy challenges that arise qualified in medicine and pharmacy.
in setting up the rules and regulations governing this pro-
Second, pharmacies are retail outlets that serve the cause of
fessional trade, the tradeoffs that need to be evaluated when
better access: through which professionals make affordable
designing markets in health care and the role of health eco-
pharmaceuticals available to the local public. Key drivers of
nomics in promoting public policy.
availability and affordability are the following:
The article is organized into four sections. After the intro-
ductory section, the key policy instruments that are available 1. Reimbursement arrangements: These should ensure that
to policy-makers and societies are highlighted and described there are sufficient retail outlets or other distribution
(Section Challenges and Policy Options). The focus is on the channels for pharmaceuticals across the country to dis-
differences between the quality, entry, and price regulations pense the medicines that are reimbursed by health care
that characterize policies based on a competitive market and organizations.

Encyclopedia of Health Economics, Volume 3 doi:10.1016/B978-0-12-375678-7.01305-5 49


50 Pharmacies

2. Competition: Competitive pressure upstream helps retail products and services having little or nothing to do with
pharmacists to get the best deal from wholesalers and health or health care. These ‘chemists’ compete with other
manufacturers, with pharmacies ideally offering good deals retail outlets that sell over-the-counter (OTC) drugs without
to their customers and passing on to them most of the gain doctor prescription, other medicinal products and any other
from the upstream competitive interaction. product and service.
3. Behavioral regulations: These ensure that providers, whe- In the middle- and low-income countries, all types of
ther independent pharmacies or companies running regulation can be found depending on the historical circum-
pharmacy chains, do not abuse the public if they reach a stances of each. However, middle- and low-income countries
dominant position in distribution and dispensing in their often have unregulated retailers that effectively sell many types
catchment geographical areas. of pharmaceutical drugs usually with neither a pharmacist-
manager on the premises nor qualified assistant. Such outlets
Given the objectives of safety/proper dispensing and typically neither satisfy the obligation to sell a full line of
availability/affordability, legislatures and governments regu- drugs, nor ensuring that they dispense prescription-only drugs
late key elements of the industry. There are three well estab- only when a qualified prescriber prescribes them.
lished traditions in high-income countries regarding the two There are six policy instruments used by most countries in
main objectives. In most countries of continental Europe, the the world that distinguish these three different pharmacy
trade is generally reserved to licensed community pharmacies models: (1) restrictions to practice: professional licensing;
owned by independent pharmacists or by national, regional, (2) ownership restrictions; (3) separation of prescribing and
or local governments. There are therefore rules limiting own- dispensing; (4) pharmacist management, supervision, and
ership of pharmacies to those who are licensed or employees assistance; (5) zoning; and (6) price regulation.
of or contractors to the State. There are also rules that limit the
number of pharmacies that each licensed pharmacist can own
(usually a one-pharmacy-per-pharmacist rule). Moreover, in
Restrictions to Practice: Professional Licensing
many countries, community pharmacies are subject to entry
restrictions based on various tests of need. Professional licensing in retail pharmacy, that is, restricting the
In most European countries, chains are not permitted; practice of pharmacy to qualified professionals is the law in
vertical integration of retail pharmacies with medicine almost all countries across the globe.
wholesalers or manufacturers is not permitted. Community Countries differ in licensing retail pharmacy according to
pharmacies are obliged to sell the full line of authorized how ‘the practice of pharmacy’ is defined: (1) whether, or
medicines in each country and deliver some health care ser- not, the ownership of a pharmacy is part of the practice of
vices for other mandated health care providers. pharmacy, and as such, it is reserved only to pharmacists;
By contrast, in the US and Canada there are no entry re- (2) whether the management of the pharmacy is part of the
strictions: there is free entry. Pharmacy chains owned by lim- practice of pharmacy, and as such, it is also reserved only to
ited or public companies are common, although such pharmacists; and (3), whether dispensing of medicines is part
companies contract licensed pharmacists to manage the ser- of the practice of pharmacy and as such is also reserved only to
vice under stringent professional codes. There are also many pharmacists.
independent pharmacies owned by professionals that com- In high-income countries, pharmaceutical retailing is re-
pete with the company-owned chains. Both independent served to pharmacists. It includes professional owners of
pharmacies and chains are obliged to sell the full line of au- independent pharmacies and professionals, who should be
thorized medicines and drugs in each country. However, they hired to manage, organize, even supervise or assist part or all
contract in a voluntary basis with mandated health care pro- retailing of medicines at each one of the outlets of any com-
grams (Medicare and Medicaid in the US), and with health pany operating a chain of pharmacies. This restriction is
maintenance organizations, the extra services related to the commonly observed and generally enforced.
reimbursement of drugs within the health plans. By contrast, in middle- and low-income countries there are
The UK, Ireland, and the Netherlands adopt an intermediate gray or second-tier outlets that sell medicines. Such outlets
regulatory stance. There is no formal regulation limiting the have no pharmacist owning the outlet, or to manage, organize,
entry of pharmacies. Entry is effectively restricted by contracts supervise, or assist the dispensing of medicines.
with the mandatory health care organizations. Potential en- Availability and affordability problems in middle- and low-
trants do not effectively enter without securing a contract and income countries are so severe that the authorities do not
such organizations award them only after considering carefully enforce professional licensing regulations on the grounds that
the incremental benefits and costs of new pharmacy openings. such enforcement may further reduce the reach of their weak
In these three countries, pharmacies (‘chemists’ in the UK) distribution networks. Having a licensed pharmacist per-
are independent retail outlets that contract to fill prescriptions forming these duties is perceived as an excessive cost of ser-
covered by the mandated health care organizations. They also vicing in the outlet, partly fixed and partly marginal, that
dispense pharmacological products prescribed by physicians would eventually increase the price of the dispensing service.
not paid by the mandated health care organizations, and they This is particularly true when medicines are sold without any
also sell other medical products not requiring a prescription, pharmacist involvement in the preparation of packages with
as well as a wide range of common hygiene and health-related convenient labels and patient information leaflets containing
products. Some have broadened their range to embrace pho- clear and comprehensible directions for use. Mexico is among
tography and other chemical-based product lines, and even the few countries in the world in which the law clearly allows
Pharmacies 51

pharmaceutical products to be sold in retail outlets without pharmacy trade was reserved to a state-owned enterprise from
any pharmacist managing, supervising, or assisting the dis- 1971 to 2009. In 2009, the Swedish government started to sell
pensing. Pharmacist involvement is only mandated in the case part of the state-owned pharmacy chain in clusters and new
of dispensing psychotropic drugs. private pharmacies have been established, some in joint ven-
tures with multinational chains. The new chains compete with
the remaining part of the state-owned pharmacy chain.
Among middle- and low-income countries, Tanzania,
Ownership Restrictions
Kyrgyzstan, Uganda, and Guatemala have state-owned phar-
Many countries reserve the ownership of pharmacy retail macies and other special arrangements such as contracted
outlets to professionals or the state. Some countries allow the independent pharmacies and franchised Non-Governmental
competition of nonpharmacist-owned outlets (usually com- Organization pharmacies. The Dominican Republic project
pany chains) with independent pharmacies (owned by ‘People’s Pharmacies’ is a successful program sponsored by the
pharmacists). Others forbid professional pharmacists to own government to make available and affordable essential generic
the pharmacies in which they work. medicines for low-income families in all state-owned and
The question of pharmacy ownership is controversial. managed health care premises, including state-owned phar-
Those in favor of restricting ownership to pharmacists claim macies and hospital pharmacies. Sixteen out of the 27 EU
that the key to make the pharmacy trade professional is the Member States allow pharmacists to own only one in-
mandatory membership of the pharmacist-owner to a pro- dependent pharmacy. In the remaining 11, pharmacy chains
fessional organization. They claim that only by having the are allowed and widespread: Austria, Ireland, Netherlands,
pharmacist-owner subject to the rules and supervision of the and Sweden among the old EU Member States, and the Czech
professional body will pharmacists advise and assist patients Republic, Estonia, Latvia, Lithuania, Poland, Romania, and
in buying their medication according to the standards of safety Slovakia among the more recent ones.
and proper dispensing. Chains are widespread and compete with independent
Without such ownership restriction and professional pharmacies in the US, Canada, Mexico, and the Philippines.
supervision, the claim goes, the personal interests of South Africa (since 2004) and Kyrgyzstan have corporate
pharmacist would supersede the interests of the patient. At the managed care preferred pharmacy networks.
same time, they claim that the standards of safety and proper Ownership restrictions to just one independent pharmacy
dispensing should be decided by these professional bodies to go together with the prohibition on vertical integration with
which pharmacist-owners are affiliated and not by other wholesalers or manufacturers. By contrast, when ownership is
government or industry bodies, which may in turn again give free and chains allowed, it is very common for some chains to
priority to their interests before the patient interests. integrate vertically with wholesalers or manufacturers. In such
The main argument against the restriction of ownership of cases, economies of scale and scope may be attained and
pharmacies to licensed pharmacists is that pharmacists-owners passed on to consumers. Those economies may not be passed
can also give priority to their interests before those of their on to consumers when chains reach dominant positions in the
patients. Professional bodies, which are mainly controlled by distribution of the medicines of some affiliated manufacturers,
pharmacy owners, do not always set up the appropriate or in the distribution of all medicines in some catchment
standards of conduct, nor do they always enforce sanctions areas.
against those affiliated owners who misbehave. It may even be In the EU, the courts have upheld ownership restrictions
easier to supervise and enforce standards of conduct over when they have been questioned as being contrary to the
company chains that are liable for the conduct of their man- freedom of establishment in the internal market. Pharmacy is
agers and employees and over pharmacists employed to excluded from the rules of the internal market and the service
manage outlets in pharmacy chains. directive only when member States reserve the pharmacy trade
There are different perceptions of legal enforcement: for to a regulated health profession or a state-owned entity as a
example, about the effectiveness in different jurisdictions of means of protecting health in the context of a mandated or
the different mechanisms for setting standards of behavior, public organized health care system.
organizing external supervision, and enforcing sanctions when
there is misbehavior. Ultimately, enforcement depends on
how clear the set of rules is and how tough the judiciary is in Prescribing and Dispensing Separation
enforcement and penalty.
Separating prescription of medicines to doctors (or prescribing
Ownership restrictions are widespread in Europe. As many
nurses) and dispensing to pharmacists is a way of reducing
as 18 out of 27 EU Member States reserve ownership of any
conflicts of interest. Most countries forbid doctors from dis-
pharmacy to a licensed pharmacist. It is only the Netherlands
pensing drugs and classify medicines in one of the following
(since 2000) and Ireland among the old EU Member States
categories, depending on the level of advice and assistance that
that have free pharmacy ownership, together with most of the
pharmacist should provide:
new EU Member States: Poland, the Czech Republic, Estonia,
Lithuania, Malta, Slovakia (since 2005), and Slovenia (re- 1. Prescription-only medicines: Medicines only with the pre-
cently deregulated). Ten of the 27 EU Member States have scription of one authorized to prescribe.
state-owned community pharmacies: Bulgaria, Cyprus, Czech 2. Pharmacy-only medicines: Medicines that can be obtained
Republic, Hungary, Italy, Luxemburg, Malta, Poland, and only from a pharmacy outlet, but which do not require a
Slovenia. Sweden is the only case in which the entire prescription from an authorized practitioner.
52 Pharmacies

3. Over-the-counter (OTC) medicines: Medicines that can be There is a cost–benefit tradeoff to be evaluated by policy
made readily available to the public in other retail outlets – makers: having a pharmacists manage, supervise, and assist in
as well as in pharmacies. the dispensing of medicines is expensive, particularly in the
countries that lack qualified professionals, and the pricing of
In the legislation, prescribing by a doctor or a nurse-pre-
medicines will reflect these extra costs.
scriber and dispensing by a pharmacist is the general rule in
Europe, the US, and Canada. However, Austria, Belgium,
Czech Republic, Cyprus, Finland, France, Greece, Hungary,
Malta, Slovenia, and the UK allow exceptionally doctors in Zoning: Restricting Entry and Location of Pharmacies by
rural areas to perform both the prescribing and dispensing of Tests of Need
pharmaceuticals in order to make sure the availability of
In most of continental Europe, independent pharmacists are
service in remote areas.
subject not only to tight licensing regulations that restrict the
By contrast, many countries, particularly in Asia and Latin
trade to licensed professionals but also to government regu-
America, have dispensing doctors or integrated health centers
lations that limit the number of pharmacies that can be open
and pharmacies. The problem with this integration is that
to the public in any given catchment geographic area. In 17 of
dispensing doctors are influenced in their prescribing de-
the 27 EU Member States, entry restrictions under the formal
cisions by their personal financial incentives at dispensing.
form of zoning, quotas, or distance regulations apply. Among
The Philippines have encouraged the separation of prescribing
these countries, Slovakia has deregulated entry since 2005 and
and dispensing since 1995, and fees have been designed to
Slovenia is deregulating it. Hungary experienced some de-
financially promote such separation since 2002. By contrast,
regulation of entry and reregulation between 2007 and 2010.
South Korea has clearly mandated the separation of pre-
Portugal introduced some less restrictive entry conditions
scribing and dispensing. However, enforcement of pre-
in 2006.
scription-only and pharmacy-only rules varies strongly across
When zoning is in place, pharmacies are authorized to
countries. In many higher-income countries, and in most
enter after some needs test, usually when the population to be
middle-and low-income countries, dispensing prescription-
served reaches some specified threshold. Three EU Member
only medicines without any doctor prescription is widespread.
States have explicit distance regulations: Greece, Hungary, and
In these cases, the advice of pharmacists is the key to
Spain. Another three Member States (the Netherlands, Ireland,
making sure that the safety and proper dispensing of medi-
and the UK) indirectly control the number and location of
cines to patients is paramount. In such settings, financial in-
pharmacies by awarding contracts from national health ser-
centives also apply: there is a lot of evidence that pharmacists’
vices to a restricted number of community pharmacies.
financial interests have an impact on the kind of advice and
Among the Member States, only, Bulgaria, Cyprus, the Czech
sales services they provide.
Republic, Estonia, Germany, and Poland do not restrict entry
according to any population need test.
Outside the EU, Norway at one time restricted entry. Cur-
rently, entry is free but pharmacy market shares are restricted.
Pharmacist Management, Supervison, and Assistance
Entry is also free in Iceland, the US, Canada, and the Philip-
Most countries require that a pharmacist should manage the pines. In Latin America, there are cases like the Dominican
service and be responsible for ensuring that the pharmacy Republic where minimum distance entry regulations are in
(whether independent or within a chain) complies with all operation, and in countries like Chile and Mexico where the
professional rules, regulations, and standards. They also number and location of pharmacies is freely determined.
require that at least one pharmacist is always present and in South Africa has a restrictive system as new pharmacies have to
charge of supervising or assisting in the dispensing of obtain a certificate of need. It also operates a system of com-
pharmaceuticals. petitive price bidding for franchises. Mali has placed some
This is easier said than done in independent pharmacies, limits to opening a pharmacy at the capital, Bamako, with the
particularly in ‘mom-and-pop’ pharmacies in middle- and (unsuccessful) intention of moving new entrants to rural
low-income countries. It is not clear cut whether enforcement areas. India has passed more liberal legislation between 2000
of the rules of the profession is easier in company-owned and 2004. Mexico and the Philippines have been very suc-
pharmacy chains as competitors and pharmacists unions cessful in promoting the entry of pharmacy chains only for
usually track compliance, or when all pharmacies are in- dispensing generics brands, boosting availability, and afford-
dependently owned and supervised by a professional body ability of medicines throughout their territories.
governed by pharmacy owners or independent experts.
As mentioned before in the section Restrictions to Practice:
Professional Licensing, Mexico is among the few countries in
Price Regulation
which the law allows pharmaceuticals to be sold in retail
outlets without any pharmacist managing, supervising, or as- Pricing regulation in the pharmacy industry takes the form of
sisting in their dispensing. Pharmacist involvement is required mandated dispensing fees, maximum margins (percentage
only when dispensing psychotropic drugs. Moreover, as pre- over the final price), or markups (percentage on the manu-
viously observed, many low- and middle-income countries do facturer’s or wholesale price). Margins or markups can be fixed
not enforce the law requiring pharmacist management, or regressive with respect to prices, and there might be rules
supervision, and assistance when retailing medicines. mandating that no discounts and promotions are offered to
Pharmacies 53

the public, or that such discounts should be subject to a prevent undesired drug interactions. In the case of OTC drugs,
maximum. the pharmacist also assumes the duty of advising the patient
Entry restrictions in Europe are typically coupled with price regarding her decision on which drug is better for her specific
or retail margin regulations. Seventeen out of 25 EU Member minor ailment.
States (all but Romania and Bulgaria, for which the authors do In contract theory terms, the patient is the principal and
not have information) set the pharmacy markups by regu- pharmacist is her agent. However, the agent has an infor-
lation. Discounts are not allowed. The other eight set max- mation advantage. The pharmacist decides whether to invest
imum markups or fees for services allowing competition in effort in providing a high-quality service, or shirk and provide
discounts and promotions. a low-quality service. The patient knows, but only imperfectly,
Discounts to final consumers are allowed only in Cyprus, about the quality of the service received after the purchase.
the Czech Republic, Estonia, Lithuania, the Netherlands, Pol- This is a simple and typical hidden information situation
and, Portugal, and Slovakia. Denmark, France, Germany, Ire- usually termed a ‘screening problem.’ It can lead to quality
land, and Spain allow for limited discounts in medicines not deterioration phenomenon through adverse selection of ser-
listed for mandatory health care systems reimbursement. The vice providers in the market. Patients would like to screen the
Netherlands, the UK, and Spain mandate some clawbacks to high and low quality of service pharmacies out of the pool of
the national health systems that get back from pharmacies part available pharmacies. The separating equilibrium with full
of the discounts obtained from wholesalers and manufacturers. information is the one that allows the patients to pay for the
In general in the EU, pharmacists are paid a fixed but re- high- or low-quality service, depending on their preferences
gressive margin with respect to the price of each medicine and willingness to pay. For example, patients receiving new
sold. In Ireland, the Netherlands, and Slovakia pharmacists treatments may prefer to pay for a high-quality service,
are paid a fixed fee for service, and in the case of the UK their whereas patients with chronic diseases receiving repeat pre-
purchase costs are reimbursed and there is a separate fixed fee scriptions may prefer to pay less for a low-quality service.
for service. When patients cannot distinguish the pharmacy type due
In the US and Canada, pricing is free but it is agreed with to the lack of information regarding the provider, and only
Health Maintenance Organizations and the federal programs uniform pricing is available as arbitrage is almost costless, the
(Medicare and Medicaid) for reimbursed medicines. well-known problem of adverse selection is encountered. All
Australia, New Zealand, and Syria have also regressive pharmacies would end up by serving only at the low price and
margin with respect to final prices to consumers. By contrast, low-quality level.
in most low- and middle-income countries, pricing is regu- Professional licensing may be used so as to regulate min-
lated as a fixed margin over prices to consumers. imum quality standards: it screens the more able providers
and deters shirking. Almost any licensing requirement im-
poses a fixed cost of entry that may drive out the least able
providers: the entry cost is simply not affordable for the
Benefits and Risks from Regulating Pharmacies
potential entrants with lower abilities.
Quality deterioration may also occur when there are no
Having reviewed entry and price regulation in the world-wide
information asymmetries, when providers serve the marginal
industry, now it is time to turn to some economic analysis of
consumer having the lowest willingness to pay for quality.
the rationale for such regulations and review the practical
Minimum quality standards can help to avoid such outcomes.
experience with such regulations.
Such regulations are supposed to drive quality up, lifting it
To start with it is required to assess how quality deterior-
closer to the willingness to pay by the average consumer. In
ation can result both in the presence and absence of infor-
doing so, these regulations can raise welfare. Professional li-
mation asymmetries. When quality deterioration is present, all
censing and rules restraining management, supervision, and
four regulations outlined before (professional licensing,
advising only to professional pharmacists may help out to
ownership restrictions, prescribing, and dispensing separation
monitor minimum standard quality regulations.
and management/supervision/assistance mandates) may help
the industry to reduce it at a reasonable cost. Then the pros
Licensing, externalities, and public goods
and cons of entry and pricing regulations are reviewed.
Professionals in general, and pharmacists in particular, pro-
vide services not only to their consumers but sometimes also
to the public at large in the form of externalities or by pro-
Regulating the Quality of Service
viding public goods. When pharmacists dispense vaccines, it is
Quality deterioration not only their customers that gain some surplus but also the
Professional services, in general, involve the application of public at large thanks to an externality in the form of a re-
professional human capital in order to judge individual cases. duced probability of other people contracting the disease in
As a result of this peculiarity of the professional trades, the question. Likewise, when pharmacists dispense narcotics or
quality of the service provided is difficult to assess objectively. antibiotics only with a proper prescription, it is not only that
In the case of the pharmacy business, in general, a medical their patients benefit but also the public in general. Avoiding
doctor makes the judgment as to which drug treatment is drug dependence or antibiotic resistance is something that
appropriate for each patient. Among the pharmacists’ duties, improves other people’s health.
the most important is to fill the prescription correctly, to ad- The regulation of professional behavior is usually justified
vise the patient how best to comply with the treatment, and to by rationales such as these. Codes of conduct for filling
54 Pharmacies

prescriptions, checking for drug interactions, serving chronic obtain excess profits or pure regulatory rents. The European
patients, and so on, contribute to the benefit of both patients Commission has initiated infringement proceedings against
and the public at large. Pharmacists also produce positive countries that operate over tight entry and ownership regu-
externalities in their role of gatekeepers. lations on the grounds that restricting freedom of establish-
Pharmacists are paid for these services. Some argue that, ment is neither an adequate nor a proportional public
while performing these duties, the pharmacist should keep the interest policy. On the contrary, the EC argues that it is a way
associated rents. The threat of being expelled from the licensed of guaranteeing rents for incumbent pharmacies. The Euro-
profession would then also entail loss of rents that further pean Commission has initiated infringement proceedings
restrains them from underperformance. Entry restraints and against Austria, Bulgaria, France, Germany, Italy, Portugal,
professional body oversight is thus viewed as a mechanism for and Spain, though the results of infringement proceeding
encouraging compliance with their professional obligations. have been modest.
Alternatively, the pharmacist might be paid for preventive Attempts to reform entry and pricing regulations are
services. problematic as the incumbents occupying the upper tail of the
distribution and who gain most from the restrictions will
invest heavily in lobbying to avoid policy reforms.
Regulating Entry through A Needs Test and Pricing
Theory is ambiguous as to whether there is scope for welfare Concluding Remarks
enhancing entry regulations in markets of differentiated
products in the retail pharmacy industry. The literature has Countries should choose the combination of policy options
identified instances in which restrictions in the number of according to their efficiency and feasibility in any constrained
suppliers or price controls, or a combination of both, may be environment.
welfare increasing. Getting prices right (i.e., close to average costs, whether by
In each locality, entry brings the benefits of greater price competition, regulation, or contractual arrangement) is key to
competition and better local availability (access). Consumers approaching an optimum. It makes entry regulation un-
gain from both, receiving cheaper medication and having necessary. However, it should be borne in mind that any good
outlets closer to where they are located. Each new entrant price regulation or contractual arrangement has to get the
steals business from the pharmacies located in their catchment number of pharmacies right when setting the price.
area but at the same time brings benefits to consumers. In Adjusting the price to the costs in different localities is also
industries in which there are no fixed costs of entry (an up- important and difficult but it is essential to make sure that
front cost not related to the volume of business), free entry is pharmacies are available and open to the public throughout
welfare enhancing. the territory.
Free entry may, however, be excessive. Entry is excessive When countries do not have the institutions, the human
whenever differentiation by location is low (consumers are not capital or the technology to get the pricing right or to get the
willing to pay for having more pharmacies at different locations right number of pharmacies, they have to evaluate whether
in any catchment area). In this case, entrants add less to the capture drives regulation toward undesirable outcomes and
consumer surplus when they enter the market than the amount whether free pricing and entry is an attainable and reasonable
they reduce the profits to incumbents by stealing their business second best.
from them. So, if the fixed costs of servicing patients are large,
there is scope for a welfare enhancing regulation that restricts
entry. At the same time, competition in each catchment area
Acknowledgment
will take the form of an oligopoly game, so there might be also
scope for pricing regulation. The equilibrium pricing game
The authors acknowledge the unconditional research
drives pricing in oligopoly well above marginal or average costs.
grants from the Spanish Ministry of Science and innovation
The more general models of pricing in oligopoly games
(ECO2009-06946), the Catalan Government (SGR2009-
with product differentiation show that the Nash equilibrium
1066), and RecerCaixa (unconditional research grant from
implies prices that differ from marginal costs. Additionally,
Fundació La Caixa, the philanthropic arm of the savings bank,
when pharmacies have dominant positions in their catchment
La Caixa).
areas, there is also room for policy to avoid what it is known
as double marginalization, when the upstream market of
manufacturers or wholesalers is not competitive enough.
Double marginalization appears when prices turn out to be See also: Health Services in Low- and Middle-Income Countries:
excessive not only because manufacturers or wholesalers have Financing, Payment, and Provision. Infectious Disease Externalities.
upstream market power to overcharge in equilibrium but also Internal Geographical Imbalances: The Role of Human Resources
retailers can overcharge as they can profit from their dominant Quality and Quantity. Markets in Health Care. Markets with Physician
position downstream. Limiting this double marginalization by Dispensing. Occupational Licensing in Health Care. Pharmaceutical
allowing manufacturers or the government to set the final Marketing and Promotion. Pharmaceutical Pricing and
price can be welfare enhancing. Reimbursement Regulation in Europe. Primary Care, Gatekeeping,
However, private interests might lobby for entry re- and Incentives
strictions and pricing regulations to ensure that pharmacists
Pharmacies 55

Further Reading European Commission (2008). Pharmaceutical sector inquiry. Preliminary Report,
DG Competition Staff Working Paper, Brussels.
Abood, R. (2007). Pharmacy practice and the law (5th ed). Sudbury, MA: Jones Mankiw, N. G. and Whinston, M. D. (1986). Free entry and social inefficiency.
and Bartlett Publishers. RAND Journal of Economics 17, 48–58.
Alderighi, M. and Piga, C. A. (2012). Selection, heterogeneity and entry in ÖBIG (2006). Surveying, assessing and analyzing the pharmaceutical sector in the
professional markets. Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2194391 or 25 EU Member States. Report Commissioned by the DG Competition –
http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2194391 European Commission, Office for Official Publications of the European
Anderson, S. (2002). The state of the world’s pharmacy: A portrait of the pharmacy Communities, Brussels.
profession. Journal of Interprofessional Care 16(4), 391–404. Roberts, M. J. and Reich, M. R. (2011). Pharmaceutical reform: A guide to
Arruñada, B. (2006). Managing competition in professional services and the burden improving performance and equity. Washington, DC: The World Bank.
of inertia. In Claus-Dieter, E. and Isabela, A. (eds.) European competition law Schaumans, C. and Verboven, F. (2008). Entry and regulation. Evidence from health
annual 2004: The relationship between competition law and the (liberal) care professions. RAND Journal of Economics 22, 490–504.
professions 2006, pp. 51–71. Oxford and Portland Oregon: Hart Publishing. Waterson, M. (1993). Retail pharmacy in Melbourne: Actual and optimal densities.
Borrell, J. R. and Fernández-Villadangos, L. (2009). Assessing excess profits from Journal of Industrial Economics 41, 403–419.
different entry regulations: The case of pharmacies in Spain, Xarxa de Recerca WHO/HAI (2011). Competition policy. In: Review Series on Pharmaceutical Pricing
en Economia Aplicada (XREAP) Working Papers, 2009–3. Barcelona. Policies and Interventions, WHO/HAI Project on Medicine Prices and Availability,
Borrell, J. R. and Fernández-Villadangos, L. (2010). Clustering or scattering: The Working Paper 4. Geneva: World Health Organization and Health Action
underlying reason for regulating distance among retail outlets, Xarxa de Recerca International.
en Economia Aplicada (XREAP) Working Papers, 2010–12. Barcelona.

You might also like