You are on page 1of 5

Economics Letters 106 (2010) 200–204

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Economics Letters
j o u r n a l h o m e p a g e : w w w. e l s ev i e r. c o m / l o c a t e / e c o l e t

Violent conflict and economic growth: Some time-series evidence


Martha A. Starr ⁎
Department of Economics, American University, 4400 Massachusetts Ave. NW, Washington, DC 20016, United States

a r t i c l e i n f o a b s t r a c t

Article history: This paper uses time-series methods to examine interrelationships between growth and violent conflict in
Received 16 September 2007 Sub-Saharan Africa. Results show bidirectional causalities, but the key determinant of conflict risk is prior
Received in revised form 25 November 2009 conflict experience, not fluctuations in economic growth.
Accepted 2 December 2009
© 2009 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
Available online 31 December 2009

Keywords:
Conflict
Growth
Sub-Saharan Africa
Structural VAR

JEL classification:
D74
E2
O11
O55

1. Introduction quantitative studies of violent conflicts (see, e.g. Enders and Sandler,
2000, 2002), although they have not much been used specifically to
The 1980s and 1990s saw a substantial increase in the number of investigate how growth and conflict relate. An important exception is
violent conflicts around the globe, related to the break-up of the the study by Blomberg, Hess and Orphanides (2004) which has a
former Yugoslavia, the disintegration of the Soviet Union, and different focus from the present paper, but implements a model quite
outbreaks of civil wars across Sub-Saharan Africa. In an influential similar to ours. The advantage of using time-series methods is that,
paper, Collier and Hoeffler (2004) argued that poor economic growth rather than estimating one equation of a two-equation system as
plays a causal role in giving rise to and sustaining violent civil previous work has done, vector auto-regression expressly allows us to
conflicts, because low or declining incomes reduce the opportunity account for the possibility of two-way causalities between growth and
costs associated with rebelling against governments against which conflict, and to quantify the relative importance each plays in the
people hold grievances. Econometrically, it is not necessarily easy to other's variance. In brief, we indeed find evidence that growth shocks
establish how growth and conflict are related. A likelihood of two-way raise conflict risks and that conflict shocks lower growth — but the
causality is widely recognized: low growth may raise conflict risks, role of one in explaining the other is extremely small. Rather, present
but escalation of conflict may itself lower growth. Thus, if a regression conflict risks are strongly driven by prior conflict experience: once a
is run in which conflict risk is a function of contemporaneous or conflict breaks out, it takes a long time for the risk of further conflict to
lagged growth, estimated effects of growth on conflict will be biased if trail down.
there are unobserved factors which both increased conflict risks and
depressed growth. Determining how exogenous changes in growth 2. Data and specification
affect conflict risk is important for gauging the potential of growth-
promoting policies to attenuate conflict risks. To conceptualize the relationship between conflict and growth, we
This paper reinvestigates this question, using time-series methods specify a bivariate panel vector auto-regression as follows:
and panel data on 44+ countries of Sub-Saharan Africa over the
1960–2005 period. Time-series methods have been widely used in
L
Conflictit = βc + βgc0 Growthit + ∑ βccs Conflictit−s ð1Þ
s=1
L
⁎ Tel.: +1 202 885 3747. + ∑ βgcs Growthit−s + εcit
E-mail address: mstarr@american.edu. s=1

0165-1765/$ – see front matter © 2009 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
doi:10.1016/j.econlet.2009.12.001
M.A. Starr / Economics Letters 106 (2010) 200–204 201

L
Growthit = βg + βcg0 Conflictit + ∑ βcgs Conflictit−s ð2Þ kind with at least 1000 battle-related deaths per year. In the vector
s=1 auto-regressions, the conflict variables are entered as zero-one, so
L
+ ∑ βggs Growthit−s + εgit that the conflict equation is effectively a linear probability model.5 In
s=1 implementing the model, lag lengths were chosen using the Akaike
criteria, which in all four cases indicated an optimal lag length of five
years.6
Eqs. (1) and (2) have the following reduced-form representation:
Results are presented as impulse response functions in Figs. 1
L L and 2, which correspond to the first and second definitions of conflict
Conflictit = πc + ∑ πccs Conflictit−s + ∑ πgcs Growthit−s + μ cit respectively.7 The graphs show the estimated effects of one standard-
s=1 s=1
deviation shocks to conflict and growth; the dotted lines represent
ð3Þ
95% confidence intervals. As is clear from the figures, results are to a
large degree robust across the four specifications. All specifications
L L
Growthit = πg + ∑ πcgs Conflictit−s + ∑ πggs Growthit−s + μ git suggest that a shock to growth would lower conflict risk, although
s=1 s=1 generally in a modest and short-lived way: a one standard-deviation
ð4Þ shock to the growth rate is estimated to lower conflict risk by 1–2
percentage points for a year or two, but thereafter effects taper off.
where μ jit = πcj εcit + πgj εgit for j = c,g. Our primary interest is in Also, results are of borderline significance in specifications using the
estimating the effect of underlying shocks to growth, ε git, on the risk WDI data. In contrast, in all specifications a conflict shock pulls the
of violent conflict, as this will tell us the extent to which exogenous growth rate down by about 1 percentage point concurrently and
improvements in growth are conflict-attenuating. This effect cannot continues to depress growth for the next 3 years. Thus, we indeed find
be directly recovered from the reduced-form system because its evidence of two-way causality, although the effect of conflict shocks
innovations reflect both types of shocks. To overcome this problem, on growth is more perceptible than that for growth shocks on conflict.
we impose the additional restriction that the coefficient βgc0 in the An important result in all four specifications concerns the time
structural equation is equal to zero. This assumption, which is also profile of the effect of a conflict shock on conflict risk. As the impulse
used by Blomberg, Hess and Orphanides (2004), is motivated by the responses show, after a conflict shock occurs, it takes a long time for
intuition that a year of unexpectedly poor growth is unlikely to cause conflict risk to return to its pre-shock level: in a country that
conflict to escalate within that year, because of the time it would take experienced a conflict shock 10 years ago, the conflict risk remains 5–
discontented people to join with rebel groups and begin fighting. 6 percentage points above where it would have been had the shock
However, βcg0 is allowed to be non-zero, consistent with the not occurred, and the effect is uniformly statistically significant.8 This
observation that outbreaks of conflict often depress growth concur- time profile is strikingly similar to that found by Blomberg, Hess, and
rently, due to disruptions in production and trade and reductions in Orphanides (2004), even though their data cover different countries
investment.1 and years and their SVARs include different variables. That conflict
It is well-known that results of quantitative studies of conflict tend shocks play the dominant role in explaining variations in conflict risk
to be sensitive to changes in variable definitions, data sources, and is also clear from the variance decompositions; as shown in Table 1,
sample composition.2 To address this potential problem, we use two growth shocks account for negligible shares of the forecast error of the
sources of data on growth in real GDP per capita and two definitions of conflict equations, and while conflict shocks account for slightly larger
conflict. Data on growth in GDP per capita are taken from: (1) the shares of the forecast error in the growth equations, their levels too
Penn World Tables (Version 6.2), in which values are expressed in are very small. Taken together, these results suggest that year-to-year
constant U.S. dollars adjusted for purchasing power parity, and (2) the fluctuations in growth rates play quite a small role in variations in
World Bank's World Development Indicators (WDI), specifically the conflict risks, with the driving force instead being the tendency of
series in which values are expressed in constant local currency terms.3 conflicts to persist once they have broken out.
The Penn World Tables cover 44 countries and run from 1960 to 2004,
while the WDI data cover 47 countries and run from 1960 to 2005,
although not all countries have data for all years.4 The data on conflict 3. Concluding remarks
are taken from the Armed Conflicts Data Set (version 2007-4) of the
International Peace Research Institute of Oslo and the University of In sum, the analysis of the present paper establishes that
Uppsala (PRIO/Uppsala), which permit two definitions of conflict. In exogenous variations in growth indeed play a role in explaining
the first, a country is considered to be in “civil conflict” if it is classified variations in conflict risk in Sub-Saharan Africa, but the magnitude of
by PRIO as experiencing “a contested incompatibility which concerns the effect is modest. This suggests that, as much as raising growth is
government and/or territory where the use of armed force between anyway extremely important for Sub-Saharan countries, given the
two parties, of which at least one is the government of a state, results widespread persistence of absolute poverty, policies that raise growth
in at least 25 battle-related deaths”. In the second, a country is over the near term should not be thought of as a ‘silver bullet’ for
considered to be in “civil war” if it is experiencing a conflict of this turning conflict situations back into peace.

1 5
Although the opposite assumption is far less compelling on a priori grounds, it was Note that the data show minimal evidence of unit roots. Non-stationarity is
also used for structural factorization as a robustness check. The strong persistence of rejected for both GDP series in the tests of Levin, Lin and Chu; Breitung; Im, Pesaran
the conflict process is also quite clear in these results, though other results differ. Here and Shin; and Hadri. It is also rejected for the two conflict series in all tests, except that
growth is quite strongly driven by conflict shocks (with the latter accounting for 90% of Levin, Lin and Chu.
6
or more of the former's forecast error at a 10-year horizon), and a positive shock to The models were also run including period dummies for the years 1960–69, 1970–
growth actually raises conflict risks by 1–2 percentage points. While one can conceive 79, 1980–89, and 2000–2005, which may be important for capturing the continent-
of reasons for these results, weight should not be placed on them, given the low wide deceleration of growth in the 1960s (Deaton, 1999). Including period dummies
plausibility of the identifying assumption. has the disadvantage of reducing estimation samples to countries for which growth
2
See Fearon (2005) and Hegre and Sambanis (2006). data are available for all five decades. Even so, results were qualitatively very similar to
3
Both data sets were accessed online on Sept 10, 2007. Note also that the PWT data those presented here.
7
are chain-weighted while the WDI data use fixed weights. For all four models, all characteristic roots lie within the unit circle, indicating that
4
In the PWT the average number of years of data per country is 40.4; for the WDI it stability conditions are satisfied.
8
is 37.6. The three countries for which the PWT does not have data but the WDI does For reference, in 1960–2005, the average probability that a country was experiencing a
are Angola, the Seychelles, and Sudan. conflict in a given year was 16.8% for civil conflicts and 7.4% for civil wars.
202
M.A. Starr / Economics Letters 106 (2010) 200–204
Fig. 1. Impulse response functions: conflicts defined as 25+ combat deaths.
M.A. Starr / Economics Letters 106 (2010) 200–204
Fig. 2. Impulse response functions: conflicts defined as 1000+ combat deaths.

203
204 M.A. Starr / Economics Letters 106 (2010) 200–204

Table 1 References
Variance decomposition (percent contribution).
Blomberg, S., Hess, G., Orphanides, A., 2004. The macroeconomic consequences of
Share of forecast error Share of forecast error terrorism. Journal of Monetary Economics 51, 1007–1032.
for conflict explained for growth explained Collier, P., Hoeffler, A., 2004. Greed and grievance in civil wars. Oxford Economic Papers
by growth shocks, in by conflict shocks, in 56, 663-595.
specification: specification: Deaton, A., 1999. Commodity prices and growth in Africa. Journal of Economic
Perspectives 13 (3), 23–40.
Forecast horizon (years): 1(a) 1(b) 2(a) 2(b) 1(a) 1(b) 2(a) 2(b) Enders, W., Sandler, T., 2000. Is transnational terrorism becoming more threatening? A
1 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.6 1.4 0.8 1.3 time-series investigation. Journal of Conflict Resolution 44, 307–332.
2 0.3 0.0 0.0 0.0 1.2 3.2 0.8 1.3 Enders, W., Sandler, T., 2002. Patterns of transnational terrorism, 1970–1999:
alternative time-series estimates. International Studies Quarterly 46, 145–165.
3 0.4 0.0 0.2 0.1 1.3 3.4 1.3 1.7
Fearon, J., 2005. Primary commodity exports and civil war. Journal of Conflict
4 0.4 0.1 0.2 0.1 2.0 3.7 1.6 2.0
Resolution 49, 483–507.
5 0.4 0.1 0.2 0.2 2.1 3.7 1.6 2.0 Hegre, H., Sambanis, N., 2006. Sensitivity analysis of empirical results on civil war onset.
… Journal of Conflict Resolution 50, 508–535.
10 0.4 0.1 0.5 0.3 2.1 3.9 1.7 2.1

Acknowledgments

I am grateful to Robert Blecker, Tom Hertz, Arturo Porzecanski,


Larry Sawers, Frances Stewart, and seminar participants at American
University for valuable comments on earlier versions of this work.

You might also like