You are on page 1of 8

6836 Bee Caves Rd.

B2 S100, Austin, TX 78746 (512) 327-7200


www.Hoisington.com

Quarterly Review and Outlook


Second Quarter 2016

The Separate Constraints of does not produce better results. It produces worse
Deficit Spending and Debt results, a situation we term a policy trap.

Real per capita GDP has risen by a paltry Deficit spending is a separate matter
1.3% annualized since the current expansion from debt. If the starting point were a situation
began in 2009. This is less than half of the 2.7% of no federal debt, a discussion of expenditure
average expansion since the records began in multipliers would be sufficient. However, that
1790. One of the most persistent impediments is not the case. Federal debt levels are already
to growth has been the drag from fiscal policy, extremely elevated, and the trend is escalating
a constraint that is likely to become even more steadily higher.
severe in the next decade. The standard of living,
or real median household income, has only When deficits and debt impair growth,
declined in the 2009-2016 expansion and stands a sequence of events impacting other critical
at the same level reached in 1996. barometers of economic performance takes
place. Saving is increasingly misallocated,
Six considerations indicate federal finance shifting income that generates public and
will produce slower growth: (1) the government private investment into investments that are
expenditure multiplier is negative; (2) the either unproductive or counterproductive. Real
composition of spending suggests the multiplier is investment in plant and equipment falters,
likely to trend even more negative; (3) the federal which in turn pulls productivity, employment
debt-to-GDP ratio moved above the deleterious and economic growth down. When the policy
90% level in 2010 and has stayed above it for response to poor economic performance is ever-
more than five years, a time span in which research higher levels of debt, the economy’s growth
shows the constriction of economic growth to becomes more feeble, which over time causes
be particularly severe. It will continue to move demographics to erode, a common pattern in
substantially further above the 90% threshold as highly indebted countries. Then the deterioration
debt suppresses the growth rate; (4) debt is likely in real investment, productivity and demographics
to restrain economic growth in an increasingly reverberate to the broader economy through
nonlinear fashion; (5) the first four problems negative feedback loops that suggest that as
produce negative feedback loops from federal debt moves ever higher, the restraining effect
finance to the economy through the allocation of on economic growth turns nonlinear. While
saving, real investment, productivity growth and some economists have called these headwinds,
eventually to demographics; and (6) the policy they should be more appropriately viewed as
makers force the economy into a downward spiral symptoms that originated with the deficits and the
when they rely on more debt in order to address debt. And these symptoms will persist as long as
poor economic performance. More of the same the debt problems continue.

Page 1
Quarterly Review and Outlook Second Quarter 2016

These indirect influences of debt on


Federal Outlays as a % of Total Outlays
economic growth, as well as how this process Discretionary and Mandatory
fiscal year
has proceeded in Japan, illustrates these points. 80% 80%

Japan, burdened by a massive debt overhang for 70% Mandatory 70%


almost three decades and a 25-year policy trap,
provides a road map for the United States, which 60% 60%

is in a much earlier stage of debt overhang. 50% 50%

40% 40%
Deficit Spending Restrains
30% Discretionary 30%
Economic Growth
20% 20%
1962 1967 1972 1977 1982 1987 1992 1997 2002 2007 2012
Negative multiplier. The government Sources: Office of Management and Budget. Through 2015.

expenditure multiplier is negative. Based on Chart 1


academic research, the best evidence suggests the
mandatory components of federal spending will
multiplier is -0.01, which means that an additional
accelerate sharply over the next decade, causing
dollar of deficit spending will reduce private GDP
government outlays as a percent of economic
by $1.01, resulting in a one-cent decline in real
activity to move higher. There have been
GDP. The deficit spending provides a transitory
proposals for increased infrastructure spending
boost to economic activity, but the initial effect
and others for additional federal entitlements like
is more than reversed in time. Within no more
Social Security. However, the existing present
than three years the economy is worse off on a
value of all unfunded federal entitlements already
net basis, with the lagged effects outweighing the
totals $60 trillion, about ten times the amount held
initial positive benefit.
in the trust funds. When funds flow into these
accounts, they are immediately spent to cover the
More negative. Although only minimally
federal deficit, with the Treasury issuing an IOU to
negative at present, the multiplier is likely to
the trust fund. Thus, the trust funds merely hold
become more negative over time since mandatory
U.S. government debt.
components of the government spending will
control an ever-increasing share of budget outlays.
Theoretically, increased infrastructure
These outlays have larger negative multipliers.
spending could serve to reverse or halt the trend
In 2015, the composition of federal outlays was
to a more negative multiplier, if true infrastructure
68.3% mandatory and 31.7% discretionary; the
spending were to be substituted for transfer
composition was almost the exact opposite in
payments, but that is not what has been proposed.
1962, around the time this data series originated
The new infrastructure spending would be in
(Chart 1). Mandatory spending includes Social
addition to existing government programs. Any
Security, Medicare, veteran’s benefits and the
new infrastructure projects must generate a cash
Affordable Care Act. All of these programs
flow for the aggregate economy that is greater
are politically popular and conceptually may be
than what would have been generated by the
highly laudatory. However, federal borrowing
private sector.
to sustain these programs does not generate an
income stream for the economy as a whole to pay
The rising unfunded discretionary and
for these programs. As history has evidenced,
mandatory federal spending will increase the size
the continual taking on of this kind of debt will
of the federal sector, which according to first-rate
eventually cause bankruptcy.
econometric evidence will contract economic
activity. Two Swedish econometricians (Andreas
Due to the aging of America, the
Page 2
Quarterly Review and Outlook Second Quarter 2016

Bergh and Magnus Henrekson, The Journal of last panic was in 2008, so according to their
Economic Surveys (2011)), substantiate that there early work the time span has either ended, or
is a “significant negative correlation” between is close to ending. However, the six to ten year
the size of government and economic growth. time reference does not apply when debt levels
Specifically, “an increase in government size by continue to move higher over that time period. In
10 percentage points is associated with a 0.5% to the latest quarter, gross federal debt was 105.7%
1% lower annual growth rate.” This suggests that of GDP, compared to 73.5% in the final quarter
if spending increases, the government expenditure of the 2008 panic.
multiplier will become more negative over time,
serving to confound even more dramatically the A number of other studies (see Appendix
policy establishment and the public at large, both for list), along with R&R themselves, superseded
of whom appear ready to support increased, but the 2009 conclusions. In 2012 in The Journal
unfunded, federal outlays. of Economic Perspectives (a peer reviewed
publication of the American Economic
Debt Association), R&R joined by Vincent Reinhardt
(RR&R) identify the 26 major public debt
Deleterious Levels. Federal debt has overhang episodes in 22 advanced economies
subtracted, to at least some degree, from U.S. since the early 1800s, characterized by public
economic growth since about 1989 when debt debt-to-GDP levels exceeding 90% for at least
broke above 50% of GDP, a level to which five years. The five-year requirement eliminates
this ratio has never returned (Chart 2). The purely cyclical increases in debt and most of those
macro consequences of the debt are becoming caused by wars. RR&R find that public debt
increasingly significant. This may seem surprising overhang episodes reduce the economic growth
to many because of confusion about the scholarly rate by slightly more than a third, compared with
work of Carmen Reinhardt and Kenneth Rogoff growth rates when the debt metric is not met.
(R&R) in their 2009 book, This Time is Different. Additionally, among the 26 applicable episodes,
20 lasted more than a decade, and the average
The misinterpretations pertain to a key duration of the debt overhang episodes was a
point in R&R’s book and accusations of data staggering 23 years. The length contradicts the
inaccuracies in the statistical calculations. R&R notion that the correlation is caused mainly by
said debt induced panics run their course in six debt buildups during business cycle recessions
to ten years, with an average of eight years. The and confirms that the cumulative shortfall in
output from debt overhang episodes should be
Gross Federal Debt as a % of GDP massive. Finally, it is interesting to note that in 11
(Excluding Off Balance Sheet Liabilities) of these episodes interest rates are not materially
quarterly
110% 110% higher; thus, the growth-reducing effects of
100% 100% high public debt are not transmitted exclusively
90% 90% through high real interest rates.
80% 80%

70% 70%
The U.S. has currently met RR&R’s
60%
Avg. = 55.2%
60%
criteria for slowing growth. Gross government
50% 50%
debt exceeded 90% of GDP in 2010 and has
40% 40%
continued to move higher since then, thus
30% 30%

20% 20%
exceeding the consecutive five-year benchmark.
52 55 58 61 64 67 70 73 76 79 82 85 88 91 94 97 '00 '03 '06 '09 '12 '15
Source: Federal Reserve Board, Bureau of Economic Analysis. Office Management and Budget.
Equally important, the debt problem is worsening.
Through Q1 2016.
Chart 2 At the end of this year the government debt-to-

Page 3
Quarterly Review and Outlook Second Quarter 2016

GDP ratio will have surpassed 100% in each of Budget Office, debt will increasingly bite into the
the past five years, thus debt is moving into a economy’s growth rate, which is a situation well
significantly higher range. documented in Japan.

Nonlinear effects, Causal Factors, Japan's Debt Linkages


Feedback Loops and the Policy Trap. Research
has found that debt begins reducing economic For the past quarter century, Japan has
growth at relatively low levels of government illustrated the nonlinear debt/growth trap. The
debt-to-GDP, and that this impact increases as ratio of government debt-to-GDP has more than
the debt level rises. In addition, as the debt ratio quadrupled, increasing from 50.9% in 1989
moves extremely high, the debilitating impact to 209.2% in 2015. And, as indicated by the
on growth speeds up. Or, as the mathematician aforementioned research, the Japanese household
would say, the effect is nonlinear. gross saving rate fell from 26.6% in 1989 to 6.6%
in 2015. Productivity growth averaged 3.2% from
European researchers, as well as RR&R, the start of the data in the early 1980s through
offer causal explanations for the heavy drag on 1991, and dropped to 0.5% in the latest 10-year
economic growth. They argue that the debt effects period, just as the academic studies suggested
are explained, at least partially, by a misallocation would happen. Finally, Japan reached the RR&R
of the limited amount of private saving as well threshold of 90% government debt-to-GDP in
as the likelihood that the private saving is less 1999 and has exceeded that level every year since
than in situations when debt is relatively low. then.
In turn, these adverse savings effects reduce
real investment in the private sector, which then These effects occurred even though
leads to a deterioration of productivity growth, the Bank of Japan (BOJ) tried to ameliorate
profitability, labor market dynamics and economic the consequences with massive purchases of
growth. Japanese government debt. By 2015, the BOJ
owned one-third of total Japanese government
This line of reasoning is complicated, debt outstanding. The non-linear relationship is
but the linkage can be explained as follows. As evident. In spite of these efforts, nominal GDP
the government takes on more debt to support in Japan contracted 0.12% from 2000 to 2015,
household income, consumers believe that saving sharply worse than the 1.9% increase from 1990
for retirement or contingency is not as necessary to 2000, a growth rate that was already quite
since the government promises to fund income subpar for Japan.
and medical care needs for those retiring. The
saving rate is, therefore, lower. Since saving
Deteriorating Demographics:
from income must equal real investment, the latter
drops. With real investment weaker, productivity,
A Consequence of Extreme Indebtedness
profitability and economic growth follow suit.
Although not identified in the studies,
The presumption of policy makers is another linkage may also explain the increasingly
that more deficit spending and debt is needed to negative economic performance. Demographics
address economic underperformance. While the deteriorate when excessive debt overhangs persist.
intentions are well-meaning, the policy makers In their panic year of 1989, Japan’s demographics
unwittingly cause an even faster rate of economic were poor compared to those of the United States.
deterioration. In view of the future levels projected Importantly, after more than a quarter century of
by such impartial sources as the Congressional trying to solve a debt problem with higher levels

Page 4
Quarterly Review and Outlook Second Quarter 2016

Japan Births lowest year of the past 25 years, at only 12.5 per
Thousands
annual
Thousands 1000. A case could be made that debt could shove
200 200
1989 = 103,900
2015 = 83,804
the U.S. economy along the downward growth/
180 -19.3% decline 180
population spiral so evident in Japan.
160 160

140 140 A Forward Look


120 120
In the opening remarks to her June 15th
100 100
press conference, Chairwoman Yellen used the
80 80
phrase, “headwinds weighing on the economy.”
60 60 She further explained, “These headwinds—which
59 63 67 71 75 79 83 87 91 95 99 '03 '07 '11 '15
Source: Ministry of Health, Labour & Welfare, Haver Analytics. Through December 2015. include developments abroad, subdued household
Chart 3 formation, and meager productivity growth—
could persist for some time.” These domestic
of debt, their demographics are far worse. For and foreign items that she correctly sighted,
example, the number of births fell by 19.3% however, are merely symptoms of the massive
from 1989 to 2015 (Chart 3). With fewer births, debt overhangs existing worldwide. Transitory
labor force entries decline, and eventually so does growth spurts, like the one in the quarter just
employment. As time passes this will place rising ended, are unlikely to be sustained. Sporadic but
debt burdens on a falling number of people, thus weakening growth will remain intact as long as
prolonging the economic misery in Japan. the debt problems continue to worsen.

While the U.S. demographics are Elevated debt levels are producing poor
considerably more robust than in Japan, they did business conditions worldwide. According to
start exhibiting a parallel decline 25 years ago the Netherlands Bureau of Economic Policy
when high levels of U.S. government debt began Analysis’s (NBEPA) World Trade Monitor, the
reducing the trend rate of economic growth (Chart year-over-year change of the three-month average
4). The U.S. birth rate fell from the highs in the in the value of goods that crossed international
1940s and 1950s until the mid-1970s, on what borders has been hovering around 0% for the last
was generally believed to be lifestyle changes. six months. This is a dramatic slowdown from
However, from the mid-1970s until 1990 the birth the 4.5% average growth rate registered since
rate moved irregularly higher, reaching 16.7 per the end of the 2009 recession. Moreover, the last
1000. The latest year available recorded the second six months constitutes the weakest period since
U.S. Birth Rate
the recession. United States exports and imports
Births/1000 Population, annual confirm this deteriorating trend. In the latest
32 32

30
1990 = 16.7
30
twelve months, real U.S. exports and imports
2014 = 12.5

28 28
both contracted 1.6%. Such declines could only
26 26
reflect a predominance of fragile global conditions
24 24 and confirmation that the world lacks an engine
22 22 of growth.
20 20

18 18 For 2016 as a whole, we expect nominal


16 16 GDP to subside to around 2.5%, down from 3.1%
14 14 in 2015. Year-over-year M2 growth has been
12
1909 1919 1929 1939 1949 1959 1969 1979 1989 1999 2009
12 above 6.5%, but M2 velocity dropped to the lowest
Sources: National Center for Health Statistics, Haver Analytics. Through 2014.
level since early 1950 in the first quarter. Such a
Chart 4

Page 5
Quarterly Review and Outlook Second Quarter 2016

slump is to be expected when the wrong type of year government bond yields in Japan, Germany,
debt increasingly dominates the total. France, and many other European countries much
lower than in the United States. In fact, the 10-
Surging energy, rents and insurance costs year yield has turned negative in both Japan and
boosted the year-over-year rise in the inflation rate Germany. Foreign investors will continue to be
to 1% in May, compared with several negative attracted to long-term U.S. Treasury bond yields.
readings in 2015. These costs are likely to push Investment in Treasury bonds should also have
the 12-month inflation rate slightly higher, but further appeal to domestic investors, as the second
the bulge in these relative prices will not lead to quarter likely marks the high point of economic
higher aggregate inflation. Slow top-line growth performance this year. The slowdown ahead will
in nominal GDP will ultimately force consumers cut the already weak nominal growth trajectory.
to bid down prices on discretionary goods and Consequently, with the normal lag, the annual
services. As such, the faster currently observed inflation rate, which most importantly impacts
inflation should pass. 30-year treasury yields, should begin to turn down
as the year moves to a close.
With slowing nominal economic growth,
treasury bond yields are likely to continue
working lower. Stressed conditions in major
overseas economies have pushed 10- and 30-
Van R. Hoisington
Lacy H. Hunt, Ph.D.

Page 6
Quarterly Review and Outlook Second Quarter 2016

PERFORMANCE

HIMCO’s Macroeconomic Composite, which is invested in U.S. Treasury securities only, registered
a net return of 7.4% for the second quarter of 2016, well above the 2.2% return of the Barclays U.S.
Aggregate Index. For the past three, five, ten, fifteen and twenty year annualized periods HIMCO’s
composite net returns outperformed the Barclays U.S. Aggregate Index by 8.1%, 8.8%, 4.8%, 4.0% and
3.4%, respectively. Additionally, for the past one, three, five, ten, fifteen and twenty year annualized
periods HIMCO's composite net returns have outperformed the S&P 500.

Macroeconomic Fixed Income Composite Performance


FISCAL YEAR ENDING JUNE 30, 2016
PERCENT CHANGE

Annualized
Q2 YTD One Three Five Ten Fifteen Twenty
2016 2016 Year Year Year Year Year Year
HOISINGTON
MANAGEMENT 7.4% 17.1% 21.3% 12.5% 12.9% 10.1% 9.3% 9.3%
(gross of fees)

net of fees 7.4% 16.9% 21.0% 12.2% 12.6% 9.9% 9.1% 9.1%

Barclays
2.2% 5.3% 6.0% 4.1% 3.8% 5.1% 5.1% 5.7%
U.S. Aggregate Index
Barclays U.S. Treasury
7.2% 16.8% 20.2% 11.0% 11.2% 8.9% 8.0% 7.7%
30yr Bellwether
Barclays U.S. Treasury
1.4% 4.3% 4.7% 2.8% 2.8% 5.1% 4.7% 5.2%
5yr Bellwether
Barclays U.S. Treasury
0.1% 0.2% 0.2% 0.1% 0.1% 1.1% 1.5% 2.5%
3 mo. Bellwether

CPI (est.) 1.2% 1.9% 1.0% 1.1% 1.3% 1.7% 2.0% 2.2%

S&P 500 2.5% 3.9% 4.0% 11.7% 12.1% 7.4% 5.8% 7.9%

Hoisington Investment Management Company (HIMCO) is a registered investment adviser specializing in the management of fixed income portfolios and is not affiliated with any parent organization. The
Macroeconomic Fixed Income strategy invests only in U.S. Treasury securities, typically investing in the long-dated securities during a multi-year falling inflationary environment and investing in the short-dated
securities during a multi-year rising inflationary environment.

The Barclays U.S. Aggregate Bond Index represents securities that are SEC-registered, taxable and dollar denominated. The index covers the U.S. investment grade fixed rate bond market, with index components
for government and corporate securities, mortgage pass-through securities and asset-backed securities. The Barclays Bellwether indices cover the performance and attributes of on-the-run U.S. Treasuries that
reflect the most recently issued 3m, 5y and 30y securities. CPI is the Consumer Price Index as published by the Bureau of Labor Statistics. S&P 500 is the Standard & Poor's 500 capitalization weighted index of
500 stocks. The Barclays indices, CPI and S&P 500 are provided as market indicators only. HIMCO in no way attempts to match or mimic the returns of the market indicators shown, nor does HIMCO attempt
to create portfolios that are based on the securities in any of the market indicators shown.

Returns are shown in U.S. dollars both gross and net of management fees and include the reinvestment of all income. The current management fee schedule is as follows: .45% on the first $10 million; .35%
on the next $40 million; .25% on the next $50 million; .15% on the next $200 million; .05% on amounts over $300 million. Minimum fee is $5,625/quarter. Existing clients may have different fee schedules.
To receive more information about HIMCO please contact V.R. Hoisington, Jr. at (800) 922-2755, or write HIMCO, 6836 Bee Caves Road, Building 2, Suite 100, Austin, TX 78746.
Past performance is not indicative of future results. There is the possibility of loss with this investment.

Information herein has been obtained from sources believed to be reliable, but HIMCO does not warrant its completeness or accuracy; opinion and estimates constitute our judgment as of this date and are subject
to change without notice. This material is for informational purposes only.

Page 7
Quarterly Review and Outlook Second Quarter 2016

APPENDIX

1. Arcand, Jean-Louis, Enrico Berkes and Ugo Panizza. "Too Much Finance?" IMF Working Paper,
Number 12/161 (June 2012).

2. Buttiglione, Luigi, Philip Lane, Lucrezia Reichlin and Vincent Reinhart. "Deleveraging? What
Deleveraging.” Geneva Reports on the World Economy 16, International Center for Monetary and
Banking Studies (September 2014).

3. Cecchetti, Stephen G., M S Mohanty and Fabrizio Zampolli. “The real effects of debt.” BIS Working
Paper, number 352 (September 2011).

4. Checherita, Cristina and Philipp Rother. “The Impact of High and Growing Government Debt on
Economic Growth, An Empirical Investigation for The Euro Area.” European Central Bank Working
Paper, Number 1237 (August 2010).

5. Dobbs, Richard, et al. “Debt and (Not Much) Deleveraging.” McKinsey Global Institute (February
2015).

6. Jorda, Oscar, Moritz Schularick and Alan M. Taylor. "When Credit Bites Back: Leverage, Business
Cycles, and Crises." NBER Working Paper, Number 17621 (November 2011).

7. Kumar, Manmohan S. and Jaejoon Woo. "Public Debt and Growth." IMF Working Paper, Number
10/174 (July 2010).

8. Mian, Atif and Amir Sufi. "Consumers and the Economy, Part II: Household Debt and the Weak U.S.
Recovery.” Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Economic Letter (January 2011).

9. Mian, Atif and Amir Sufi. House of Debt. University of Chicago Press, 2014.

10. Mian, Atif and Amir Sufi. "Household Leverage and the Recession of 2007-2009.” IMF Economic
Review Volume 58 (August 2010): Pages 74-117.

11. Pattillo, Catherine, Helene Poirson and Luca Antonio Ricci. "External Debt and Growth." Review of
Economics and Institutions Volume 2, Number 3, Article 2 (Fall 2011).

12. Reinhart, Carmen M., Vincent R. Reinhart and Kenneth S. Rogoff. "Public Debt Overhangs:
Advanced-Economy Episodes since 1800." Journal of Economic Perspectives Volume 26, Number 3
(Summer 2012): Pages 69-86.

13. Roxburgh, Charles, et al. "Debt and Deleveraging: The global credit bubble and its economic
consequences.” McKinsey Global Institute (January 2010).

14. Roxburgh, Charles, et al. “Debt and Deleveraging: Uneven progress on the path to growth.”
McKinsey Global Institute (January 2012).

15. Taylor, Alan M. “The Great Leveraging.” NBER Working Paper, Number 18290 (August 2012).
Page 8

You might also like