You are on page 1of 12

PERGAMON Social Science & Medicine 48 (1999) 535±546

Using conjoint analysis to take account of patient


preferences and go beyond health outcomes: an application
to in vitro fertilisation
Mandy Ryan *
Health Economics Research Unit, Department of Public Health, University of Aberdeen Medical School, Foresterhill, Aberdeen AB25
2ZD, UK

Abstract

There has been an assumption in the health economics literature that health outcomes are all that need to be
considered when attempting to measure the bene®ts from health care interventions. This is most evident in the
development of the quality adjusted life year (QALY) approach to bene®t assessment. This paper challenges this
view and considers the technique of conjoint analysis (CA) as a methodology for both taking account of patient
preferences and considering attributes beyond health outcomes. The technique is applied to in vitro fertilisation. CA
is shown to be sensitive to considering health outcomes, nonhealth outcomes and process attributes. It is also shown
to be internally consistent and internally valid. The paper demonstrates the application of CA to estimating
willingness to pay indirectly. It is argued that bene®t assessment within health economics should extend beyond
health outcomes and future research should investigate more thoroughly the potential application of CA in this
area. However, methodological issues need addressing before the instrument becomes an established evaluative
instrument. # 1998 Elsevier Science Ltd. All rights reserved.

Keywords: Health economics; Patient preferences; Conjoint analysis; Willingness to pay; In vitro fertilisation

1. Introduction comes in the provision of health care. This is done


using the example of the provision of in vitro fertilisa-
Health economists have devoted much attention to tion (IVF). Economic evaluations of IVF have im-
valuing the bene®ts of health care interventions, using plicitly assumed that the only factor of importance to
quality adjusted life years (QALYs) and, more users is whether they leave the service with a child.
recently, healthy year equivalents (HYEs) (Williams, Analysts have estimated a cost `per live birth', `per
1985; Kind, 1988; Mehrez and Gafni, 1989; Mehrez and maternity' or per some other narrow medical de®nition
Gafni, 1991, 1993; Gafni et al., 1993; Buckingham, of success (Bartels, 1987; Batman, 1988; Wagner and
1993). While de®nitions of the bene®ts of health care St Clair, 1989; Page, 1989; Webb and Holman, 1990;
interventions have been enhanced in recent years, the Haan, 1991; Neumann et al., 1994). The usual applied
emphasis has remained on health outcomes (Cadman welfare economics framework requires bene®t assess-
et al., 1986; Boyle et al., 1991; Torrance et al., 1992; ments to consider all e€ects of treatment on well-
Feeny et al., 1994). One aim of this paper is to con- being, both positive and negative, including, in this
sider the importance of attributes beyond health out- case, the experiences of the majority of users who leave
the service childless.
A second aim of this paper is to demonstrate how
* Tel.: +44-1224-681-818 ext. 54965; fax: +44-1224-662- the application of a technique known as conjoint
994; e-mail: m.ryan@abdn.ac.uk. analysis (CA) can take account of patient preferences

0277-9536/98/$ - see front matter # 1998 Elsevier Science Ltd. All rights reserved.
PII: S 0 2 7 7 - 9 5 3 6 ( 9 8 ) 0 0 3 7 4 - 8
536 M. Ryan / Social Science & Medicine 48 (1999) 535±546

within the delivery of health care. Whilst the technique In the United States CA has been used by noneco-
is applied speci®cally to the area of IVF, its appli- nomists within the area of health care to examine fac-
cation in health service research more generally is also tors important to patients in the provision of health
discussed. With respect to IVF, it is shown how CA care systems (McClain and Rao, 1974; Parker and
can be used to establish whether a given attribute of Srinivasan, 1976; Wind and Spitz, 1976; Chakraborty
the service is important, the relative importance of the et al., 1993, 1994). In the UK it has been used to esti-
various attributes of the service, the trade-o€s individ- mate: the monetary value of reducing time spent on
uals make between attributes and how willingness to waiting lists (Propper, 1990, 1995), the trade-o€s indi-
pay (WTP) (the monetary value of any given attribute) viduals make between the location of clinic and wait-
can be estimated indirectly. ing time in the provision of orthodontic services (Ryan
In Section 2 background information is provided on and Farrar, 1995); women's preferences for surgical
CA. Following this, the methods and results from an versus medical management of miscarriage (Ryan and
application of CA to IVF are outlined (Section 3). Hughes, 1997), preferences for magnetic resonance
Attention is given to whether attributes beyond the imaging (MRI) in the investigation of knee injuries
narrow outcome of `having a child' are important. (Bryan et al., 1998), women's preferences for the treat-
Consideration is also given to some methodological ment of menorraghia (San Miguel et al., 1997), patient
issues in the application of CA, namely internal con- preferences in the doctor±patient relationship (Vick
sistency, internal validity and estimation of willingness and Scott, 1998) and patient preferences for blood
to pay indirectly (Section 4). The results are presented transfusion support (Van der Pol and Cairns, 1998).
in Section 5. Finally issues of design and methodology
are discussed (Section 6). 2.2. Theoretical background to CA

In a typical CA study individuals are presented with


hypothetical scenarios involving di€erent levels of attri-
2. Conjoint analysis
butes which have been identi®ed as important in the
provision of a good or service and asked to rank the
2.1. What is conjoint analysis?
services, rate them or make pairwise choices. Within
market research ranking and rating exercises have
Conjoint analysis is a technique for establishing the
proved the most popular. Transport economists devel-
relative importance of di€erent attributes in the pro-
oped the pairwise comparison approach from the econ-
vision of a good or a service. It can also be used to
omic theory of random utility (McFadden, 1973). It
estimate how individuals trade between these attributes
may be argued that individuals are used to making
i.e. the rate at which they are willing to give up one
such choices since it is the type of exercise in which
unit of an attribute for an increase in another attri-
they engage on a daily basis. In contrast, individuals
bute. This is known as the marginal rate of substi-
seldom carry out ranking and rating type exercises for
tution (MRS). If cost is included as an attribute then
decisions made every day. For these (related) reasons
this MRS represents WTP1.
the `choice' approach is developed and applied in this
CA has its origin in market research, where it has
paper.
been used to identify factors in¯uencing the demand
The decision making process within the pairwise
for commodities (Cattin and Wittink, 1982). It has
choice framework can be seen as a comparison of two
also been used widely in transport economics
indirect utility (or bene®t or satisfaction) functions.
(Wardman, 1988) and environmental economics (Rae,
The respondent is asked to make a series of pairwise
1981a,b; Desvouges et al., 1983; Magat et al., 1988;
choices. For each comparison s/he chooses (or prefers)
Swallow et al., 1992; Opaluch et al., 1993) and was rec-
the alternative that leads to the higher level of utility.
ommended to the UK Treasury as a method for evalu-
Thus, the individual chooses health care intervention B
ation of quality in the provision of public services
over A if
(Cave et al., 1993).
U AB , Y, Z† > U AA , Y, Z†: 1†
1
WTP is based on the premise that the maximum amount U(.) represents the individual's indirect utility (or ben-
of money an individual is willing to pay for a commodity is
e®t) function, AB are the attributes of health care inter-
an indicator of the utility or satisfaction to her of that com-
modity. WTP is thus a monetary measure of the value or ben- vention B, AA are the attributes of health care
e®t of a given health care intervention. Traditionally studies intervention A, Y is the individual's income and Z rep-
have directly asked individuals their WTP, using either the resents the socio-economic characteristics of the indi-
open-ended, payment card or closed ended approach (Ryan et vidual that in¯uence their utility. It is assumed that
al., 1997). individuals compare health care interventions on the
M. Ryan / Social Science & Medicine 48 (1999) 535±546 537

basis of health outcomes (HO), nonhealth outcomes treatment over another when all attributes included in
(NHO) and process attributes (P). Further, whilst the the model are the same (Ryan and Hughes, 1997).
individual knows the nature of their utility function, Parameters ai, aj and ak indicate whether the relevant
the researcher will not. This introduces the concept of attribute is important (as indicated by its signi®cance
random utility, where an error term is included in the level) as well as how important (as indicated by its
utility function to re¯ect the unobservable factors in relative size). The ratio of any two parameters is the
the individual's utility function. Thus, within this MRS between these attributes. If cost is included as an
framework, the individual will choose B over A if attribute then the monetary value of each attribute can
be estimated. Finally, unobservable factors in the indi-
V HOB , NHOB , PB , Y, Z† ‡ eB
vidual's utility function are represented by e.
> V HOA , NHOA , PA , Y, Z† ‡ eA : 2†

V(.) is the measurable component of utility estimated 3. Methods


empirically, HOj, NHOj and Pj are, respectively, the
health outcomes, nonhealth outcomes and process 3.1. Establishing the attributes
attributes of the health care intervention being con-
sidered (j = A, B) and ej re¯ects the unobservable fac- In a previous study (Ryan, 1995) six attributes were
tors in the individual's utility function. Assuming a identi®ed as signi®cant predictors of utility from
linear utility function V(.), the utility to be estimated undergoing IVF. These were: chance of taking home a
in moving from A to B is baby, follow-up support, time on the waiting list, con-
X X tinuity of sta€, cost and attitudes of sta€. These attri-
DV ˆ fbB ‡ biB HOiB ‡ bjB NHOjB
butes included health outcomes, nonhealth outcomes
X and process type attributes (see Table 1).
‡ bkB PkB ‡ Y ‡ Z ‡ eB g ÿ fbA
X X 3.2. Levels of attributes
‡ biA HOiA ‡ bjA NHOjA
X A number of issues were raised when de®ning the
‡ bkA PkA ‡ Y ‡ Z ‡ eA g, 3†
levels, including identi®cation of the appropriate range
which can be simpli®ed as for levels, what the intervals should be and how to de-
X X X ®ne qualitative levels. Obviously levels should be realis-
DV ˆ ac ‡ ai HOi ‡ aj NHOj ‡ ak Pk ‡ e: 4† tic. There would be no point in o€ering individuals a
100% chance of leaving the service with a child since
ac, ai, aj and ak (i = 1, n, j = n + 1, m and this is not a realistic option. Levels of attributes also
k = m + 1, l) represent the parameters of the model need to be set such that individuals are willing to trade
to be estimated. Parameter ac is the constant term for between them, i.e. if the levels for cost or chance of
the model and re¯ects preferences for one type of leaving the service with a child were set with too broad

Table 1
Attributes and levels included in the CA study

Attribute Levels and de®nition

Process attributes
Attitudes of sta€ toward you `bad' Ð uncaring and unsympathetic
`good' Ð caring and sympathetic
Continuity of contact with same sta€ `no' Ð you see many di€erent sta€
`yes' Ð you see the same sta€ on all visits
Time on waiting list for IVF attempt (months) 1, 3, 6, 18, 36
Cost to you of IVF attempt (£) 0, 750, 1500, 2500, 3000

Health outcome
Chance of taking home a baby (%) 5, 10, 15, 25, 35

Nonhealth outcomes
Follow-up support `no' Ð no support
`yes' Ð you get support
538 M. Ryan / Social Science & Medicine 48 (1999) 535±546

Table 2
Di€erence between choices in CA study: clinic B minus clinic A di€erences

Type 1 Type 2

Choice Attitudes Chance Continuity Time on Cost to Follow-up Attitudes Chance Continuity Time on Cost to Follow-
of sta€a of taking of contact waiting you of supportb of sta€1 of taking of contact waiting you of up
home a with same list IVF home a with same list for IVF supportb
baby sta€b for IVF attempt baby sta€b IVF attempt
(%) (months) (£) (%) (months) (£)

1 0 ÿ20 1 ÿ15 0 1 0 ÿ5 ÿ1 ÿ5 ÿ1000 0


2 ÿ1 10 0 ÿ12 0 1 0 ÿ5 0 ÿ3 ÿ500 0
3c ÿ1 ÿ20 0 18 1000 0 0 ÿ10 ÿ1 30 500 1
4d ÿ1 10 1 0 1500 0 0 10 0 ÿ5 ÿ1750 0
5 ÿ1 0 0 ÿ15 1000 1 1 ÿ5 0 30 ÿ2500 1
6 0 10 1 ÿ17 1000 1 0 ÿ10 0 12 ÿ1750 1
7c 0 0 1 ÿ12 ÿ1500 0 0 0 0 30 ÿ1000 0
8 ÿ1 ÿ20 0 ÿ17 ÿ1500 0 0 20 ÿ1 ÿ3 ÿ2500 0
9c 0 ÿ15 0 0 1000 0 1 10 ÿ1 12 ÿ1000 0
10 ÿ1 ÿ10 0 0 ÿ1500 1 1 ÿ10 ÿ1 0 500 0
11 0 10 0 18 ÿ750 0 1 0 ÿ1 ÿ3 1750 0
12 ÿ1 ÿ15 0 ÿ12 ÿ750 1 1 0 ÿ1 ÿ5 500 1

a
Taking on a value of zero for bad and unity for good.bTaking on a value of zero for no and unity for yes.cChoice that allows
check of consistency in type 1 questionnaire.dChoice that allows check of consistency in type 2 questionnaire.

intervals then individuals may not be willing to trade. 3.3. Presentation of questions
This refusal to trade may be the result of a poor ques-
tionnaire design, rather than an unwillingness to trade The attributes and levels presented in Table 1 give
rise to 1000 possible scenarios (5323=1000). The
per se. Levels of cost must extend beyond the cost that
SPSS procedure Orthoplan (SPSS, 1989) was used to
is currently being paid for the service since the actual reduce these to a `manageable level' whilst still being
cost may not represent an individual's maximum able to infer utilities for all possible scenarios. The
WTP. Levels for time on the waiting list, cost and technique results in an orthogonal main e€ects design
chance of leaving the service with a child were chosen and gave rise to 26 scenarios from the original 1000.
to be representative of the situation at the time in Evidence from the transport literature suggests that in-
dividuals can manage between 9 and 16 pairwise com-
Scotland (Ryan, 1995). De®ning levels for `quantitat-
parisons before they become tired or bored (Pearmain
ive' attributes is generally easier than for `qualitative' et al., 1991). The 26 scenarios were therefore randomly
attributes. Table 1 summarises the attributes and levels split into two equal groups. Within each group, one
included in the CA study. scenario was randomly chosen, and each of the

Fig. 1. Example of pairwise choice question in conjoint analysis questionnaire.


M. Ryan / Social Science & Medicine 48 (1999) 535±546 539

remaining 12 scenarios were compared to this scenario. ratio of the parameters (i.e. the trade-o€s between
These two groups formed the basis of two separate CA them) are given aj with aj/a4 ( j = 1, 2, 3, 5, 6) being
questionnaires (type 1 and type 2) consisting of 12 an estimate of WTP for levels of the individual attri-
pairwise choices (see Table 2). Subjects were randomly butes.
allocated between these two questionnaires. An The initial utility functions had a constant term
example of one of the pairwise choices is shown in which re¯ects the importance of attributes not included
Fig. 1. in the model. This was `suppressed' in the study by
The study sample comprised individuals attending asking subjects to assume that all aspects of the ser-
the Assisted Reproductive Unit (ARU) in Aberdeen, vice, other than those speci®ed in the questionnaire,
U.K. In a previous study, a satisfaction questionnaire were identical. Thus, from Eqs. (3) and (4), ac=0 (or
was mailed to all 1164 individuals who had attended bBÿbA=0) when there is no di€erence in the clinics
the ARU since it opened in 1989 (Ryan, 1995). Among other than those speci®ed for the six attributes
these were individuals who were on the waiting list for included in the model.
IVF, individuals who had had a `failed' attempt at To allow for nonrandom variation in coecients,
IVF and were still trying, as well as users who had left segmentation analysis was carried out. Interaction
the service both with a child and childless. terms were created between cost and income category,
Questionnaires were mailed separately to men and time and an age category and time and income cat-
women. The 466 individuals who responded to this egory. This allowed a demonstration of how such
`satisfaction' questionnaire were selected for the CA analysis can be conducted, as well as a testing of the
study. A pilot questionnaire was mailed to a random theoretical validity of the model (see below). The ®nal
sample of 52 of these individuals to test whether indi- function to be estimated was
viduals would complete the CA questionnaire, and to
DV ˆ a1 `staffatts' ‡ a2 `continuity' ‡ a31 `waitinc1'
see if trading was taking place among the chosen levels
of the attributes. The main questionnaire was mailed ‡ a32 `waitinc2' ‡ a33 `waitinc3'
to the remaining 414 individuals. Information had pre-
viously been collected on respondents age, sex, whether ‡ a34 `waitage1' ‡ a35 `waitage2'
or not they had had a child from IVF, whether they
were currently undergoing treatment and how many ‡ a36 `waitage3' ‡ a41 `costinc1'
additional IVF attempts they were willing to have.
Respondents were asked to return a slip if they did not ‡ a42 `costinc2' ‡ a43 `costinc3' ‡ a5 `chance'
want to take part in the study. Two follow-up letters
‡ a6 `follow ÿ up' ‡ e ‡ u, 6†
were sent to individuals before they were considered
nonrespondents. where `waitinc1', `waitinc2' and `waitinc1' represent the
waiting time attribute segmented by income groups 1,
3.4. Analysis of data 2 and 3, respectively, `waitage1', `waitage2' and `wait-
age 3' represent the wait attribute segmented by age
The LIMDEP random e€ects probit procedure was groups 1, 2 and 3, respectively and `costinc1', `costinc2'
used to analyse the data (Greene, 1991; Propper, and `costinc3' represent the cost attribute segmented
1995). The function to be estimated was of the form by income groups 1, 2 and 3, respectively. All other
DV ˆ a1 staff ‡ a2 cont ‡ a3 wait ‡ a4 cost variables are as de®ned above. Mean WTP was esti-
mated for all attributes within each income and age
‡ a5 chance ‡ a6 follow ‡ e ‡ u: 5† group and the Z statistic used to test whether these
mean WTP estimates were statistically signi®cantly
DV is the change in utility in moving from one IVF di€erent from one another (Bland, 1995).
clinic A to another B, sta€ is the di€erence in the sta€
attitudes between clinic A and B, cont is the di€erence
in continuity of sta€ contact, wait is the di€erence in
waiting time, cost is the di€erence in the cost of an 4. Methodological issues addressed
attempt at IVF, chance is the di€erence in the chance
of taking home a baby and follow is the di€erence in When using CA it is important to include tests of
follow up support and is the nonhealth outcome. The whether individuals appear to understand the tech-
unobservable error terms are represented by e and u, nique and are taking it seriously. This study tested for
where e is the error term due to di€erences amongst internal (theoretical) validity and consistency.
observations and u is the error term due to di€erences The results from the regression analysis were used to
amongst respondents (Ryan and Hughes, 1997). The test the internal validity of CA i.e. the extent to which
relative importance of the di€erent attributes, and the results are consistent with a priori expectations. Given
540 M. Ryan / Social Science & Medicine 48 (1999) 535±546

that lower levels of time on the waiting list and cost choice 3, clinic B in choice 7 and clinic A in choice 9.
are to be preferred, we would expect these attributes to In the type 2 questionnaire all individuals would be
have a negative sign in the regression equation. expected to prefer clinic B in choice 4. Individuals who
Similarly, given that higher levels of chance of taking answered inconsistently were assumed either to have
home a baby are to be preferred, and assuming conti- misunderstood the questionnaire or to not be taking it
nuity of care and good sta€ attitudes are preferred, we seriously, and were dropped from the analysis.
would expect these attributes to have a positive sign in CA assumes that individuals have continuous prefer-
the regression equation. No a priori assumptions were ences such that there is always some improvement in
made about the provision of follow-up support. one attribute that can compensate for a deterioration
Assuming that higher socio-economic groups have a in the level of another attribute. In the context of this
higher marginal valuation of time, we would expect a study this implies that respondents would be willing to
priori the coecient on waiting time segmented by trade lower levels of probability of leaving the service
income to be higher for higher income groups a priori. with a child for improvements in levels of the other
Assuming diminishing marginal utility of income, we attributes. This was tested for by establishing if there
would expect higher income groups to have a lower was any individual who always chose the scenario with
marginal valuation of cost and, therefore, the coe- the highest chance of leaving the service with a child.
cient on cost to be lower for higher income groups.
Assuming older people place a higher value on redu-
cing waiting time, a priori we would expect the coe- 5. Results
cient on waiting time segmented by age to increase
with age. Of the 414 questionnaire mailed, 10 were returned
Internal consistency was checked by testing the because they were sent to the wrong address, 14 were
rationality of the choices made, i.e. if one scenario is returned by individuals who did not want to take part
considered to be `better' than another, individuals are in the study, 331 questionnaires were returned com-
expected to choose that scenario. Assuming that pleted and there were 59 nonresponses. Of the 331
patients prefer good attitudes of sta€ to bad, a higher respondents, 149 were male and 182 female. Forty had
chance of taking home a baby, continuity of contact a child from IVF, 55 were currently undergoing treat-
with the same sta€, less time on the waiting list, a ment and 121 were willing to have an additional
lower cost to a higher cost and again making no a attempt.
priori assumption about follow-up support, the orthog- There was evidence that individuals understood the
onal plan resulted in four choices that, on any rational questions and answered them consistently. For the
choice process, should be preferred to others (see type 1 questionnaire all 170 respondents answered
Table 2). In the type 1 questionnaire it would be choice 3 consistently, only 3 answered choice 7 incon-
expected that all individuals would prefer clinic A in sistently and only 1 answered choice 9 inconsistently.

Table 3
Test for chance of leaving the service with a child being a dominant attribute in the choice process

Type 1 Type 2

Di€erence in chance of Prefer Prefer Di€erence in chance of Prefer Prefer


taking home a baby Clinic B Clinic A taking home a baby Clinic B Clinic A
(Clinic B ÿ Clinic A) (Clinic B ÿ Clinic A)

Choice 1 ÿ20% 32 137 ÿ5% 64 96


Choice 2 10% 117 53 ÿ5% 18 142
Choice 3 ÿ20% 170 0 ÿ10% 47 113
Choice 4 10% 40 130 10% 153 6
Choice 5 0 41 127 ÿ5% 57 103
Choice 6 10% 132 38 ÿ10% 13 146
Choice 7 0 167 3 0 36 124
Choice 8 ÿ20% 35 135 20% 155 5
Choice 9 ÿ15% 1 169 10% 123 36
Choice 10 ÿ10% 47 123 ÿ10% 6 154
Choice 11 10% 68 102 0 141 19
Choice 12 ÿ15% 34 136 0 104 57
M. Ryan / Social Science & Medicine 48 (1999) 535±546 541

In the type 2 questionnaire only 6 respondents vision of IVF services. The positive signs on attitudes
answered inconsistently. Individuals providing incon- of sta€, continuity of care and chance of taking home
sistent responses were dropped from all subsequent a baby indicate that the higher these attributes are in
analysis. Because there were so few inconsistent re- clinic B relative to A, the more likely the individual is
sponses it was not possible to carry out statistical tests to choose clinic B. Similarly, negative signs on cost,
to see if these were answered inconsistently by a par- time on waiting list and follow-up support indicate
ticular group or population. that the lower these attributes are in clinic B relative
No individual always chose the scenario with the to clinic A, the more likely the individual is to choose
highest chance of leaving the service with a child, clinic B. The negative sign on follow-up support
suggesting individuals were willing to make trade-o€s suggests that having this is a disbene®t. Individuals not
between the level of probability of leaving the service wanting to discuss their infertility problems may
with a child and other attributes (see Table 3). These explain this. The coecients on the cost attribute indi-
results suggest that the level of probability of having a cate that respondents with a higher income had a
child is not a dominant attribute. This ®nding chal- lower marginal valuation of cost, re¯ecting diminishing
lenges current economic evaluations of the service marginal utility of income. As expected, older respon-
which are based purely on the cost per live birth, or dents valued a reduction in waiting time more highly
some other medical de®nition of `success'. than younger respondents. These results support the
theoretical validity of CA.
5.1. Statistical signi®cance of attributes
5.2. Size of e€ect and trade-o€ between attributes
All coecients have the expected sign and are sig-
ni®cant at the 1% level (see Table 4). This suggests A 1% increase in the chance of having a child
that all the chosen attributes are important in the pro- results in more bene®t than a one month fall in waiting

Table 4
Results from random-e€ect probit model

Variable Random e€ects Standard errora


probit model (SE)
coecients

Sta€ attitudes 0.526** 0.040


Continuity of care 0.180** 0.048
Follow-up ÿ0.123** 0.045
Chance 0.080** 0.002
Cost  income1 ÿ0.0006** 0.00005
Cost  income2 ÿ0.0005** 0.00003
Cost  income3 ÿ0.0003** 0.00004
Waiting  income1 0.003 0.007
Waiting  income2 ÿ0.001 0.006
Waiting  income3 ÿ0.012* 0.006
Waiting  age1 ÿ0.031** 0.006
Waiting  age2 ÿ0.047** 0.006
Waiting  age3 ÿ0.044** 0.007
r 0.097

n 3953
Log likelihood ÿ1821
w2 27.36 (0.001)
Correct predictions 79%

**
Signi®cant at 1% level, *signi®cant at 5% level.
Income1 < £15,000, income2 = £15,001±30,000; income3 = £31001 + . Age1 is 25±35 years,
age2 36±42 years and age 3 42 + years.
a
Standard errors estimated from the Taylor series approximation to the variance of a random
variable: Var(WTP) = 1/bj 2[var(bi) ÿ 2WTP cov(bj, bi) + WTP2var(bj)], where bj=coecient for
cost variable and bi=coecient for the ith variable (i = sta€ attitudes, chance, continuity of
care, follow-up and waiting time).
542 M. Ryan / Social Science & Medicine 48 (1999) 535±546

time or a reduction of one pound in the cost of treat- 5.3. Estimating WTP
ment for all three income groups (as indicated by the
size of the respective coecients). Good sta€ attitudes For all attributes WTP is lower for the lower income
are more important than a 6% increase in the chance groups than the higher income groups (Table 5). Those
of taking home a baby (i.e. 0.526>(0.080  6)), and in income group 3 are willing to pay signi®cantly more
continuity of care is slightly more important than a for good sta€ attitudes than income group 1
2% increase in the chance of taking home a baby (Z = 3.46; p < 0.001) and 2 (Z = 2.73; p < 0.001).
(0.180>(0.080  2)). They are also willing to pay signi®cantly more to
The ratio of the coecients shows how much of one increase their chance of having a child than income
attribute an individual would be willing to give up to group 1 (Z = 3.94; p < 0.001) and 2 (Z = 3.16;
get more of another attribute. For example, an individ- p < 0.001).
ual would be willing to have a reduction in their WTP to reduce waiting time is related to both age
chance of leaving the service with a child of 6% and income. For example, younger individuals on a
(0.526/0.080) to have good sta€ attitudes. low income are willing to pay £52 for a month's re-

Table 5
Willingness to pay estimated indirectly from random e€ects probit model

Attribute Random e€ects Z


probit model (i, j indicates
WTP (SEa) comparing income
(£) groups i and j)

Attitudes of sta€ towards you


Income 1 877 (98) 3.46 (1, 3)**
Income 2 1052 (105) 1.21 (2, 1)
Income 3 1753 (233) 2.73 (3, 2) **

Continuity of contact with same sta€


Income 1 300 (86) 1.43 (1, 3)
Income 2 360 (105) 0.44 (2, 1)
Income 3 600 (191) 1.10 (3, 2)

Follow-up support
Income 1 205 (77) 1.17 (1, 3)
Income 2 246 (92) 0.34 (2, 1)
Income 3 410 (157) 0.90 (3, 2)

Chance of having a child (% increase)


Income 1 133 (12) 3.94 (1, 3)**
Income 2 160 (12) 1.62 (2, 1)
Income 3 267 (31) 3.16 (3, 2)**

Time on waiting list (per month)


Age1 and income 1 52 (10) 2.11 (1, 3)*
Age 1 and income 2 62 (11) 0.64 (2, 1)
Age 1 and income 3 103 (21) 1.64 (3, 2)*
Age2 and income 1 78 (11) 2.77 (1, 3)**
Age 2 and income 2 94 (10) 1.08 (2, 1)
Age 2 and income 3 157 (26) 2.26 (3, 2) *
Age3 and income 1 73 (12) 2.45 (1, 3) **
Age 3 and income 2 88 (15) 0.78 (2, 1)
Age 3 and income 3 147 (28) 1.87 (3, 2) *

**
P < 0.01; *P < 0.05.aStandard errors estimated from the Taylor series approximation to
the variance of a random variable: Var(WTP) = 1/bj 2[var(bi) ÿ 2WTP cov(bj,
bi) + WTP2var(bj)], where bj=coecient for cost variable and bi=coecient for the ith variable
(i = sta€ attitudes, chance, continuity of care, follow-up and waiting time).
M. Ryan / Social Science & Medicine 48 (1999) 535±546 543

duction in waiting time, other things equal, compared future applications of CA should include pilot work to
to £62 for the middle income group of the same age establish the range of monetary valuations (San
and £103 for the higher income group of the same age. Miguel et al., 1997). The issues raised here are similar
A similar relationship is observed for the middle and to those raised in devising the bid vector in a closed
older age groups. These results all provide support for ended WTP study (Ryan et al., 1997).
the theoretical validity of the technique. Since IVF is not freely available on the UK
National Health Service, the cost attribute was de®ned
as `cost to you per IVF per attempt'. However, this
6. Discussion and conclusion may not be realistic when the health care intervention
being valued is collectively funded. Much can be learnt
Evidence has been presented that, within the context from attempts to apply the direct WTP technique to
of IVF, users are concerned with more than whether value collectively-funded health care interventions.
they leave the service with a child. Individuals are will- Here there has been a movement away from asking
ing to trade changes in the probability of leaving the patients WTP at the point of consumption to the use
service with a child with other attributes. The paper of ex ante insurance based or taxation based questions
clearly provides evidence that there is utility beyond (O'Brien and Gafni, 1996; Olsen and Donaldson,
health outcome. This should come as no surprise since 1998). Future applications of CA to collectively-funded
the health services satisfaction literature has been health care interventions should explore this approach.
reporting such ®ndings for many years. It is unlikely In this study individuals were presented with 12
that these results are speci®c to IVF. This suggests choices, and, for each of them, asked whether they pre-
that, assuming the goal of health care interventions is ferred clinic A or clinic B (see Fig. 1) i.e. individuals
to maximise utility, account should be taken of factors were forced to make a choice between A and B.
beyond health outcomes when valuing bene®ts from Future application of CA should consider giving indi-
health care interventions. However, those adopting an viduals the option of indicating indi€erence or not
`extra welfarist' approach to valuing health care may choosing. If such an approach were taken, alternative
challenge this conclusion (Culyer, 1989, 1990). statistical techniques, such as ordered probit, would be
Results from a CA study are potentially very useful appropriate (McKelvey and Zavoina, 1975; Ryan and
to policy makers. Many of the factors identi®ed as Farrar, 1995; Van der Pol and Ryan, 1996).
nonhealth outcomes and process attributes are capable An important question in economic evaluations is
of being directly in¯uenced by policy makers. Within whether to elicit values from users or the community.
the context of this study, the results could be used to In this study the value of users were considered. This
help in the design of a given infertility clinic with given had the advantage that respondents had experience of
resources, and to help decide how to spend additional the IVF clinic and, therefore, had relatively informed
money to improve a clinic. The monetary measure of preferences across the attributes. Gafni (1991) has
bene®ts can be directly compared with costs within the argued that within the context of a publicly provided
framework of a cost±bene®t analysis (CBA). health care system it is the views of the community
A number of interesting issues were raised. that are relevant. A problem with the community
Regarding de®ning levels for attributes, the researcher approach is that the community is unlikely to have
would be encouraged to use quantitative rather than good knowledge of health care interventions. The
qualitative levels. For example, `continuity of care' results of a CA study critically depend on the way in
may have been better de®ned as `you see one member which subjects are informed about the hypothetical
of sta€ throughout', `you see two±four', or `you see choices they are asked to make. When community pre-
®ve or more'. Where this is not possible a clear de®- ferences are being elicited it may be more important to
nition of the qualitative levels should be provided such use interviews, interactive computer software and
that all respondents are interpreting them in the same visual aids. This is again ultimately an empirical ques-
way. When the researcher is faced with numerous tion. Again, literature on patient decision-making may
qualitative levels, interviews, interactive computer soft- be helpful here in o€ering advice on ways of presenting
ware (Pearmain et al., 1991) and visual aids may be a information to the general community (Levine et al.,
better method to collect data, although this is ulti- 1992; Elit et al., 1996).
mately an empirical question. The literature on patient CA is potentially a very useful tool for bene®t
decision-making may be helpful here (Levine et al., assessment in health economics. However, methodo-
1992; Elit et al., 1996). logical work is needed before CA becomes an estab-
Including cost as an attribute to estimate WTP lished evaluative instrument (Ryan et al., 1996). This
raises questions concerning the range of levels and the study achieved a relatively high response rate, as well
de®nition of cost in a collectively funded health care as high levels of internal consistency and internal val-
system. In establishing levels for the cost attribute, idity. These results are consistent with ®ndings from
544 M. Ryan / Social Science & Medicine 48 (1999) 535±546

other studies (Ryan and Farrar, 1995; Ryan and References


Hughes, 1997; San Miguel et al., 1997; Bryan et al.,
1998; Vick and Scott, 1998; Van der Pol and Cairns, Bartels, G., 1987. Government expenditure on IVF programs:
1998). The study also highlighted the need for meth- an exploratory study. Prometheus 5, 302±304.
odological work concerning how the data should be Batman, G., 1988. IVF in Australia. Commonwealth
collected and the sensitivity of the results to the range Department of Community Services and Health, Canberra.
Bland, M., 1995. An Introduction to Medical Statistics.
and levels of attributes chosen. Further issues that
Oxford University Press, Oxford.
need addressing include testing the reliability and
Boyle, M., Furlong, W., Torrance, G., Feeny, D., 1991.
external validity of the technique and issues around Reliability of the health utilities index Ð mark III used in
the functional form of the utility function. Stated pre- the 1991 cycle 6. General Social Survey Health
ference techniques have long been criticised for the Questionnaire. Working Paper 94-7. McMaster University,
hypothetical nature of the questions posed and doubts Ontario.
expressed as to whether individuals behave as stated in Buckingham, K., 1993. A note on HYE (healthy years equiv-
such surveys (Mitchell and Carson, 1989). Whilst a alent). Journal of Health Economics 11, 301±309.
limited amount of work has established the reliability Bryan, S., Buxton, M., Sheldon, R., Grant, A., 1998.
and validity of CA within the areas of market research Magnetic Resonance imaging for the investigation of knee
and transport economics (Ryan, 1995), it is not clear injuries: an investigation of preferences. Health Economics,
in press.
how applicable this work is to health economics, and
Cadman, D., Goldsmith, C., Torrance, G., Boyle, M.,
work is clearly needed in this area. Regarding the func- Furlong, W., 1986. Final Report to Ontario Ministry of
tional form of the model, the application of CA in this Health: Development of a Health Status Index for Ontario
study is based on the premise that the objective of Children.
health care resources is to maximise utility. It is also Cattin, P., Wittink, D., 1982. Commercial use of conjoint
the case that the utility function estimated in this study analysis: a survey. Journal of Marketing 46, 44±53.
was highly constrained i.e. a linear function based on Cave, M., Burningham, D., Buxton, M., Hanney, S., Pollitt,
six attributes. Future work using CA should ensure C., Scanlan, M., Shurmer, M., 1993. The Valuation of
that the utility function is correctly speci®ed, both in Changes in Quality in the Public Services. HMSO, London.
terms of the attributes included, and the functional Chakraborty, G., Gaeth, G., Cunningham, M., 1993.
form estimated. Understanding consumers preferences for dental service.
Journal of Health Care Marketing 21, 48±58.
In conclusion, evidence has been provided of the im-
Chakraborty, G., Ettenson, R., Gaeth, G., 1994. How consu-
portance of factors beyond having a child in the infer- mers choose health insurance. Journal of Health Care
tile person's utility function. This ®nding has Marketing 14, 21±33.
important implications for future economic evaluations Culyer, A.J., 1989. The normative economics of health care
of IVF. There is no reason to believe this treatment is ®nance and provision. Oxford Review of Economic Policy
the only health care intervention where utility bearing 5, 34±58.
arguments extend beyond health outcomes. Future Culyer, A.J., 1990. Commodities, characteristics of commod-
economic evaluations should take this into account. ities, characteristics of people, utilities and quality of life.
CA was promoted as a tool for taking account of the In: Baldwin, S., Godfrey, C., Propper, C. (Eds.), Quality of
trade-o€s between health, nonhealth and process attri- Life: Perspectives and Policies. Routledge, London.
Desvouges, W.H., Smith, V.K., McGivney, M.P., 1983. A
butes. It was shown to be internally consistent and
Comparison of Alternative Approaches for Estimating
theoretically valid, as well as capable of estimating
Recreation and Related Bene®ts of Water Quality
WTP indirectly. However, further methodological Improvements. Oce of Policy Analysis, U.S.
work is needed before the instrument becomes an Environmental protection Agency, Washington DC.
established evaluative instrument. Elit, L.M., Levine, M.N., Gafni, A., 1996. Patients' prefer-
ences for therapy in advanced epithelial ovarian cancer:
developing, testing and application of a bedside decision
Acknowledgements instrument. Gynecologic Oncology 62, 329±335.
Feeny, D., Torrance, G., Goldsmith. C., Furlong. W. and
I am grateful to all respondents who completed Boyle. M., 1994. A multiattribute approach to population
questionnaires and to Gavin Mooney, Cam health status. Working paper 94-5. McMaster University,
Ontario.
Donaldson, Emma McIntosh, Phil Shackley and anon-
Gafni, A., 1991. Willingness to pay as a measure of bene®ts:
ymous referees for comments on earlier drafts of this
relevant questions in the context of public decision-making
paper. Financial support from the Medical Research about health care programmes. Medical Care 29, 1246±
Council (MRC) and Chief Scientist Oce of the 1252.
Scottish Oce Department of Health (SODH) are Gafni, A., Birch, S., Mehrez, A., 1993. Economics, health and
acknowledged. The views expressed in the paper are health economics: HYEs versus QALYs. Journal of Health
those of the author. Economics 12, 325±340.
M. Ryan / Social Science & Medicine 48 (1999) 535±546 545

Greene, W., 1991. Limdep User's Manual and Reference Propper, C., 1995. The disutility of time spent on the UK
Guide, version 6.0. Econometric Software Inc., Australia. National Health Service waiting list. Journal of Human
Haan, G., 1991. E€ects and costs of in vitro fertilisation. Resources 30, 677±700.
International Journal of Technology Assessment in Health Rae, D., 1981a. Visibility impairment at mesa verde national
Care 7, 585±593. park: An analysis of bene®ts and costs of controlling emis-
Kind, P., 1988. The design and construction of quality of life sions in the four corners area. Prepared for the Electric
measures. University of York Discussion Paper No. 43, Power Research Institute. Charles River Associates,
University of York, York,. Boston, MA.
Levine, M.N., Gafni, A., Markham, B., MacFarlane, D., Rae, D., 1981b. Bene®ts of improving visibility at great
1992. A bedside decision instrument to elicit a patient's pre- smoky national park. Draft report prepared for Electric
ference concerning adjuvant chemotherapy for breast can- Power Research Institute. Charles River Associates,
cer. Annals of Internal Medicine 117, 53±58. Boston, MA.
Magat, W.A., Viscusi, W.K., Huber, J., 1988. Paired compari- Ryan, M., 1995. Economics and the patient's utility function:
son and contingent valuation approaches to morbidity risk an application to assisted reproductive techniques. Ph.D.
valuation. Journal of Environmental Economics and thesis, University of Aberdeen.
Management 15, 395±411. Ryan, M., Farrar, S., 1995. Brie®ng Paper for the NHS in
McClain, J., Rao, V., 1974. Trade-o€s and con¯icts in evalu- Scotland, No. 6: Conjoint Analysis: a New Tool for
ation of health system alternatives: methodology for analy- Eliciting Patients' Preferences. Health Economics Research
sis. Health Services Research 9, 35±52. Unit, University of Aberdeen.
McFadden, D., 1973. Conditional logit analysis of qualitative Ryan, M., Hughes, J., 1997. Using conjoint analysis to value
choice behaviour. University of California at Berkeley, CA. surgical versus medical management of miscarriage. Health
McKelvey, R., Zavoina, W., 1975. A statistical model for the Economics 6, 261±273.
analysis of ordinal level dependent variables. Journal of Ryan, M., Scott, A., Farrar, S., Shackley, P., McIntosh, E.,
Mathematical Sociology 4, 103±120. Vick, S., 1996. HERU Discussion Paper No. 02/96: Using
Mehrez, A., Gafni, A., 1989. Quality-adjusted life years, uti- Conjoint Analysis in Health Care: Unresolved
lity theory and health-years equivalents. Medical Decision
Methodological Issues. University of Aberdeen, Aberdeen.
Making 9, 142±149.
Ryan, M., Ratcli€e, J., Tucker, J., 1997. Using willingness to
Mehrez, A., Gafni, A., 1991. The healthy-years equivalents:
pay to value alternative models of antenatal care. Social
how to measure them using the standard gamble approach.
Science & Medicine 44, 371±380.
Medical Decision Making 11, 140±146.
San Miguel, F., Ryan, M., McIntosh, E., 1997. Health
Mehrez, A., Gafni, A., 1993. Healthy-years equivalents versus
Economics Research Unit Discussion Paper 07/97:
quality-adjusted life years. Medical Decision Making 13,
Establishing Women's Preferences for the Treatment of
287±292.
Mennoraghia Using the Technique of Conjoint Analysis.
Mitchell, R.C., Carson, R.T., 1989. Using Surveys to Value
University of Aberdeen, Aberdeen.
Public Goods. Resources for the Future, Washington DC.
SPSS, 1989. Inc. SPSS Categories. SPSS Inc., Chicago.
Neumann, P., Soheyla, D., Gharib, M.D., Weinstein, M.C.,
Swallow, S., Opaluch, J., Weaver, T., 1992. Siting noxious fa-
1994. The cost of a successful delivery with in vitro fertiliza-
tion. New England Journal of Medicine 331, 239±243. cilities: an approach that integrates technical, economic and
O'Brien, B., Gafni, A., 1996. When do the `dollars' make political consideration. Land Economics 68, 283±301.
sense? Towards a conceptual framework for contingent Torrance, G., Zhang, Y., Feeny, D., Furlong, W., Barr, R.,
valuation studies in health care. Medical Decision Making 1992. Multiattribute preference functions for a comprehen-
16, 288±299. sive health status classi®cation system. Working paper 92-
Olsen, J.A., Donaldson, C., 1998. Helicopters, hearts and 18. McMaster University, Ontario.
hips: using willingness to pay to set priorities for public sec- Van der Pol, M., Cairns, J., 1998. Establishing patient prefer-
tor health care programme. Social Science & Medicine 46, ences for blood transfusion support: an application of con-
1±12. joint analysis. Journal of Health Services Research and
Opaluch, J., Swallow, S., Weaver, T., Wessells, C., Wichelns, Policy 3, 70±76.
D., 1993. Evaluating impacts from noxious facilities: includ- Van der Pol, M., Ryan, M., 1996. Using conjoint analysis to
ing public preferences in current siting mechanisms. Journal establish consumer preferences for fruit and vegetables.
of Environmental Economics and Management 24, 41±59. British Food Journal 98, 5±12.
Page, H., 1989. Economic appraisal of in vitro fertilisation: Vick, S., Scott, A., 1998. What makes a perfect agent? A pilot
discussion paper. Journal of the Royal Society of Medicine study of patients' preferences in the doctor±patient relation-
82, 99±102. ship. Journal of Health Economics, in press.
Parker, B., Srinivasan, V., 1976. A consumer preference Wagner, M.G., St Clair, P.A., 1989. Are in vitro fertilisation
approach to the planning of rural primary health-care fa- and embryo transfer of bene®t to all?. Lancet 300, 1027±
cilities. Operations Research 24, 991±1025. 1030.
Pearmain, D., Swanson, J., Kroes, E., Bradley, M., 1991. Wardman, M., 1988. A comparison of revealed preference
Stated Preference Techniques: a Guide to Practice. Steer and stated preference models. Journal of Transport
Davis Gleave and Hague Consulting Group, Hague. Economics and Policy 22, 71±91.
Propper, C., 1990. Contingent valuation of time spent on Webb, S.M., Holman, C.D.J., 1990. Methodology used to
NHS waiting list. The Economic Journal 100, 193±199. monitor and evaluate in vitro fertilisation and related pro-
546 M. Ryan / Social Science & Medicine 48 (1999) 535±546

cedures in western Australia, 1983±1987. Community Wind, Y., Spitz, L., 1976. Analytical approach to marketing
Health Studies 14, 235±245.
Williams, A., 1985. Economics of coronary artery bypass decisions in health care organisations. Operations Research
grafting. British Medical Journal 291, 326±329. 24, 973±990.

You might also like