You are on page 1of 56

Knyazeva, Anzhela

Other Persons: Knyazeva, Diana

Working Paper
Dividend Smoothing : An Agency Explanation and
New Evidence

Provided in Cooperation with:


Social Science Research Network (SSRN)

Reference: Knyazeva, Anzhela (2014). Dividend Smoothing : An Agency Explanation and New
Evidence. [S.l.] : SSRN.
https://ssrn.com/abstract=2504715.
https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2504715.
doi:10.2139/ssrn.2504715.

This Version is available at:


http://hdl.handle.net/11159/232195

Kontakt/Contact
ZBW – Leibniz-Informationszentrum Wirtschaft/Leibniz Information Centre for Economics
Düsternbrooker Weg 120
24105 Kiel (Germany)
E-Mail: rights[at]zbw.eu
https://www.zbw.eu/econis-archiv/

Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use:


Dieses Dokument darf zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Zwecken This document may be saved and copied for your personal
und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. Sie and scholarly purposes. You are not to copy it for public or
dürfen dieses Dokument nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle commercial purposes, to exhibit the document in public, to
Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, aufführen, vertreiben perform, distribute or otherwise use the document in public. If
oder anderweitig nutzen. Sofern für das Dokument eine Open- the document is made available under a Creative Commons
Content-Lizenz verwendet wurde, so gelten abweichend von diesen Licence you may exercise further usage rights as specified in
Nutzungsbedingungen die in der Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. the licence.
https://zbw.eu/econis-archiv/termsofuse
*
Dividend smoothing: An agency explanation and new evidence

Anzhela Knyazeva†
U.S. Securities and Exchange Commission

Diana Knyazeva
U.S. Securities and Exchange Commission

This version: July 2014

Abstract
In spite of considerable research into firm dividend behavior, dividend smoothing has eluded a definitive
explanation. This paper provides an agency interpretation of dividend smoothing and offers evidence that
variation in corporate governance and managerial incentive conflicts explains differences in intertemporal
properties of dividends. We argue that smooth dividends are an alternative to traditional corporate
governance mechanisms. Empirically, we document a greater degree of dividend smoothing, fewer
dividend cuts, and a trend towards regular incremental dividend increases at firms with weak traditional
monitoring mechanisms. The effect of governance on dividend changes is largest for firms with high free
cash flow. We document consistent patterns for total shareholder payout and overall commitment to
external claimholders. However, dividends and repurchases are not perfect substitutes and adjustments to
repurchases are secondary to the weakly governed managers’ need to sustain dividends.

JEL classification: G30, G34, G35

Keywords: dividend smoothing, intertemporal dividend decisions, corporate governance, conflicts of


interest

*
An earlier version of the paper was circulated as “Delivering on the Dividend Promise: Corporate Governance, Managerial
Incentives, and Dynamic Dividend Behavior.” The authors acknowledge financial support from the Stern School of Business at
New York University and the Simon School of Business at the University of Rochester. The authors thank Kose John, Joseph
Stiglitz, Daniel Wolfenzon, David Yermack, and Bernard Yeung for valuable discussions and Bin Chang, Vieira Elisabete,
William Greene, Gustavo Grullon, Shane Heitzman, Michael Lemmon, John Long, Sattar Mansi, Andrew Metrick, Roni
Michaely, Eli Ofek, Micah Officer, Carrie Pan, Anthony Saunders, Bill Schwert, Cliff Smith, Raghu Sundaram, Jerry Warner,
Toni Whited, Jeffrey Wurgler, Jerry Zimmerman, and seminar and conference participants at New York University, University of
Rochester, University of Michigan, Ohio State University, University of Maryland, University of North Carolina – Chapel Hill,
Emory University, University of Wisconsin, Arizona State University, University of Georgia, Baruch College, Georgia State
University, Georgia Tech, Financial Management Association, and European Financial Management Association meetings for
helpful comments. We thank Institutional Shareholder Services for providing Corporate Governance Quotient data. All errors and
omissions are our own.
The Securities and Exchange Commission, as a matter of policy, disclaims responsibility for any private publication or statement
by any of its employees. The views expressed herein are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the
Commission or of the authors’ colleagues on the staff of the Commission.

Corresponding author: Anzhela Knyazeva, Securities and Exchange Commission, 100 F Street NE, Washington, DC 20549. E-
mail: anzhela.knyazeva@gmail.com.

Electroniccopy
Electronic copy available
available at:
at:https://ssrn.com/abstract=2504715
http://ssrn.com/abstract=2504715
1. Introduction

The issue of intertemporal patterns in dividends has remained unresolved in the finance literature

for over half a century. Since Lintner (1956) and Fama and Babiak (1968) documented the

propensity of firms to smooth dividends and reluctance to make cuts, there has been a need for a

better understanding of dynamic dividend behavior. We approach this question from a corporate

governance perspective. In the presence of agency costs, stable dividends can help disgorge free

cash flow and constrain inefficient managerial behavior, however, their effectiveness is limited if

managers suspend dividends at their discretion.

This paper contributes to the existing literature in several ways. First, the analysis

examines understudied aspects of intertemporal patterns in dividends: differences in the extent of

dividend smoothing, changes to dividend levels, and the role of dividend changes in the broader

context of payout policy and financial structure adjustments. Second, our findings have

implications for the credibility of dividend commitments at firms with weak traditional

governance mechanisms. Although such commitments are implicit, our evidence strongly

supports the adherence of managers to dividend commitments. Third, our paper sheds light on

the differences between firms with weak versus strong traditional governance mechanisms with

respect to aggregate trends, such as dividend disappearance.

Holding the firm’s investment opportunities constant, weak governance mechanisms can

result in misalignment of managers and shareholders and lead to inefficient investment. Stable

dividends limit managerial discretion and free cash flow at the manager’s disposal. In firms that

find it too costly to use traditional oversight devices, an implicit commitment to stable dividends

serves as a substitute constraint on managerial behavior.

The decision to adhere to a dividend policy over time can be reconciled with managerial

self-interest. While shareholders cannot observe the quality of investment choices, they can

Electroniccopy
Electronic copy available
available at:
at:https://ssrn.com/abstract=2504715
http://ssrn.com/abstract=2504715
observe dividends, cash flow realizations, and monitoring mechanisms. All else equal, when

traditional monitoring mechanisms are weak, dividend deviations are more likely to contribute to

agency costs, resulting in firm value loss. This is rationally expected by investors. The manager

weighs gains from a dividend cut against adverse shareholder response to dividend deviations.

Myers (2000) models a dynamic tradeoff facing a self-interested manager that enters into an

implicit dividend contract with investors: the manager can forgo dividends but investors can

choose not to fund the firm’s projects (that the manager seeks to pursue). Further, as Zwiebel

(1996) and Fluck (1998, 1999) show, shareholders can attempt to intervene and increase scrutiny

of the manager if the loss of firm value from the deviation is expected to be high.

The alternative hypothesis is that weak traditional governance mechanisms lead to more

deviations from the dividend commitment as misaligned managers have more discretion to cut

dividends.

The main empirical findings are as follows. Weak traditional governance mechanisms are

associated with more stable dividends and fewer dividend cuts or omissions. Weak governance

firms pass through more cash flow increases as dividend increases, however, weakly governed

managers are cautious about the magnitude of increases (since they have to be sustained over

time) and prefer small increases. Changes in dividend levels are decreasing in the strength of

traditional governance mechanisms, particularly in the presence of large cash flow increases.

Similarly, smoothing and changes in total payout are decreasing in the strength of corporate

governance. However, repurchases and dividends are not perfect substitutes: compared to

strongly governed firms, weakly governed firms are more likely to cut repurchases when they

need to decrease payout and to increase dividends when they need to make additional cash

distributions. Our results hold across a number of governance measures, including our new

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2504715


aggregate alignment and governance index, and remain significant after accounting for potential

endogeneity.

The rest of the paper is organized as follows. The second section develops the hypothesis

and testable predictions. The third section discusses data and methodology. The fourth section

presents empirical findings. The fifth section concludes.

2. Hypotheses

Related work

Prior work shows that dividends are persistent in the data (e.g., Lintner, 1956; Fama and Babiak,

1968; Dewenter and Warther, 1998; Gugler, 2003). Michaely and Roberts (2012) find that

private firms have less persistent dividends. Several papers theoretically model dividend

smoothing (e.g., Kumar, 1988; Warther, 1994; Fudenberg and Tirole, 1995; Karpavicius, 2014).

Differently from these studies, we explore determinants of variation in dividend smoothing

across firms.

Other studies document a positive market reaction to dividend increases and a negative

market reaction to dividend cuts (e.g., Aharony and Swary, 1980; Asquith and Mullins, 1983).

Officer (2011) finds a more favorable reaction to dividend initiations for weakly governed firms.

Evidence of the value relevance of dividend changes in a setting with frictions helps motivate

our argument about the equity market response to observable dividend decisions.

Various papers examine dividend levels in the cross-section as a function of ownership

structure (e.g., Rozeff, 1982; Amihud and Li, 2006), governance (e.g., La Porta et al., 2000;

John, Knyazeva, and Knyazeva, 2011b; Hu and Kumar, 2004; Pan, 2007; Harford, Mansi, and

Maxwell, 2008), or information asymmetries (e.g., Booth and Xu, 2008). An important question

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2504715


unanswered in the above studies is whether weakly governed managers sustain dividends since

precommitment to dividends is implicit and can be rescinded by an entrenched manager.

This paper contributes to existing literature in the following ways. Our findings provide

new insights into intertemporal patterns in corporate cash distributions. We examine weakly

governed managers’ choice to smooth, uphold or deviate from dividends over time; dividend

changes in response to cash flow shocks; and dividend decisions in the context of overall payout

policy adjustment. The analysis has implications for the credibility of the implicit dividend

contract when traditional governance mechanisms are weak, hence dividends matter most from

the agency perspective yet managers can deviate from nonbinding commitments more easily.

The findings also suggest that any analysis of aggregate dividend trends should be conditional on

governance quality. Our empirical setting refines governance and alignment measures and

addresses potential endogeneity of governance to dividend decisions.

Hypothesis and empirical predictions

Imperfect alignment of managerial and shareholder incentives and shareholder inability

to observe investment decisions gives rise to agency conflicts and inefficient managerial

investments motivated by empire building, diversification, or private benefits (e.g., Jensen and

Meckling, 1976; Rozeff, 1982). Dividends can alleviate such agency conflicts (at a cost) by

limiting free cash flow available to the manager and exposing the manager to additional

monitoring (Jensen, 1986; Easterbrook, 1984). Dividends can be viewed as an implicit contract

between the manager and shareholders (Myers, 2000). Following the initial dividend adoption

decision, managers can choose whether to uphold this implicit dividend promise or to deviate

from it by cutting or eliminating dividends. Unlike the quality of investment projects chosen by

the manager, dividend changes and governance mechanisms are observable and verifiable. When

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2504715


a weakly governed manager cuts dividends, all else equal, shareholders rationally expect less

efficient investment and a larger firm value loss. In contrast, in the presence of strong

governance mechanisms, additional constraints on managerial decisions are not necessary and

managers can conserve resources by following a more flexible dividend policy.1

Our argument relates to the model of dynamic dividend behavior by a self-interested

manager in Myers (2000). A dividend cut can improve the manager’s contemporaneous utility by

offering more discretion in investment decisions. However, the manager’s expected utility from

continuing in the firm is decreased by adverse shareholder reaction to the observable dividend

decision: In the Myers (2000) model, investors can limit the amount of capital provided to the

firm in response to a deviation from the implicit dividend contract. The resulting decrease in the

availability of capital constrains the manager from undertaking privately beneficial investment

projects in the future, should internal cash flow become insufficient. If expected firm value loss

from the manager’s decision is substantial, the manager can also face the threat of intervention or

additional scrutiny from shareholders. (In a related vein, Zwiebel (1996) and Fluck (1998, 1999)

model the manager’s dynamic tradeoff between current gains and future control challenge threats

in the context of capital structure choice.) Therefore, the manager’s dividend change decision

solves a dynamic tradeoff presented by these opposite effects.

The main takeaway is that weak corporate governance can be consistent with a credible

implicit dividend contract. Importantly, a stable dividend policy can offset weaknesses in

traditional corporate governance mechanisms. This yields several implications for intertemporal

dividend behavior. The main testable prediction is that weakly governed managers uphold the

1
Existing empirical literature is divided on the question of signaling benefits of dividends in relation to unexpected increases in
future earnings (e.g., Benartzi, Michaely, and Thaler, 1997).

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2504715


implicit dividend promise and avoid downward deviations, resulting in a more persistent, non-

decreasing dividend path.

We now turn to dividend increases at weakly governed firms. If cash flows do not

change, managers are expected to maintain the dividend level. If cash flows temporarily

decrease, managers raise capital from external financing markets (Easterbrook, 1984). In case of

cash windfalls, managers have to increase dividends to curtail anticipated inefficient

investments. Thus, when traditional monitoring mechanisms are weak, the probability of

dividend increases is weakly higher overall and strictly higher if cash flows increase. However,

given the anticipated pressure to uphold dividends in the future, weakly governed managers will

exercise caution and avoid large increases that may become unsustainable in the future. If cash

flows continue to increase, weakly governed managers will raise dividends incrementally.

The described dynamic dividend behavior patterns have implications for overall payout

decisions of weakly governed managers. First, total cash distributions are expected to be more

persistent and payout changes are expected to be higher when governance is weak. Second,

payout policy adjustments will minimize deviations from the implicit dividend contract, leading

to more cuts in repurchases rather than cuts in dividends when managers decrease payouts.

Similarly, shareholders expect misaligned managers to distribute extra cash in the form of higher

dividends, which sustains the constraint on managerial investment behavior. Higher share

repurchases have a weak commitment effect since the timeline and amounts of payouts are less

certain, compared to regular quarterly cash dividends.

Debt is an alternative way of constraining managers as it requires the manager to make

regular payments and imposes the threat of bankruptcy in the case of deviations (Jensen, 1986;

John, Knyazeva, and Knyazeva, 2011b). Both debt and implicit dividend commitments reduce

the firm’s cash flow through a cash distribution to external claimholders. Both forms of

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2504715


commitment are costly (cost of external financing when internal cash flow is insufficient as well

as specific costs such as tax disadvantage of dividends, bankruptcy costs, and agency costs of

debt). Like with dividends, deviations from debt commitments lead to significant negative

consequences, so changes to debt and dividend commitments could act as partial substitutes.

Our testable predictions are summarized below. All else equal, we expect weak

traditional governance mechanisms to be associated with:

(1) more dividend smoothing

(2) fewer dividend cuts

(3) (weakly) more dividend increases (but a smaller magnitude of increases)2

(4) more overall payout smoothing (with a preference towards the use of repurchase cuts for

lowering payouts and dividend increases for raising payouts and partial substitution between debt

and dividend commitment changes)

Alternatively, weak traditional governance mechanisms may increase managerial

discretion with respect to dividend deviations, resulting in less smoothing and more dividend

cuts. We believe this is less likely for two reasons. First, this paper focuses on US firms and

examines the role of firm-level monitoring mechanisms in an environment with strong overall

investor protections, which is different from countries with few investor protection laws where

potential for adverse shareholder action is limited (La Porta et al., 2000). Second, in a setting

with a developed stock market and more dependence on equity financing, meeting shareholder

concerns is likely to be more important than in economies that are more dependent on bank

financing.

2
Given that dividend cuts tend to be significantly larger in magnitude, changes in dividend levels are most likely decreasing in
the strength of traditional corporate governance mechanisms.

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2504715


3. Data

Sample

The main tests use the sample of U.S. firms from Compustat Annual for 1993–2004. Sensitivity

tests extend the sample period through 2009 (certain governance metrics are unavailable, so we

modify the governance index definition accordingly). Tests of the propensity to pay dividends

use the full sample of firms. Tests of intertemporal dividend behavior use the sample of past

dividend payers. We exclude financial firms (SIC 6000–6999), regulated utilities (SIC codes

4900–4949), observations with assets below 20 mln, firms incorporated outside the US, and

LBOs. CRSP monthly file is used to obtain dividend data for ordinary common shares, unless

specified otherwise. Certificates, ADRs, shares of beneficial interest, units, Americus trust

components, closed-end funds, and REITs are excluded. Dividend is defined as the annual sum

of ordinary quarterly cash dividends (CRSP distribution code 1232), adjusted for splits and stock

dividends, unless specified otherwise.

Governance and alignment mechanisms

The Appendix contains detailed variable definitions. We use proxies for monitoring by boards,

institutional blockholders, corporate control markets, lower separation of ownership and control

in single class firms, and CEO-level alignment characteristics (CEO Characteristics), as well as

the aggregate of the above measures, Alignment and Governance Index (AGI). We convert

continuous measures into annual rankings, defined such that higher values correspond to stronger

governance, and rescale them to [0,1].

The proportion of outside directors on the board (see, e.g., Rosenstein and Wyatt, 1990;

Agrawal and Knoeber, 1996; Knyazeva, Knyazeva, and Masulis, 2013), small board size

(Yermack, 1996), separation between the CEO and key committees (Shivdasani and Yermack,

1999), and the frequency of board meetings (Vafeas, 1999) have been tied to the intensity of

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2504715


board monitoring. Institutional blockholders,3 especially public pension funds, have been viewed

as more active monitors (Cremers and Nair, 2005). Further, concentration of institutional

ownership in the hands of a few blockholders is likely to strengthen monitoring incentives.

Antitakeover defenses can shield managers from the discipline of the corporate control market

and shift more bargaining power from to shareholders to managers (see, e.g., Gompers, Ishii, and

Metrick, 2003; Bebchuk and Cohen, 2005; Bebchuk, Cohen, and Ferrell, 2005; Bertrand and

Mullainathan, 2003). The G index comes from the Gompers et al. (2003) dataset and the

Bebchuk et al. (2005) E index is constructed from RiskMetrics data. Certain CEO characteristics

can affect the degree of alignment of manager and shareholder interests. Longer CEO tenure in

the firm may increase managerial power over the board (Shivdasani and Yermack, 1999). CEO

age could be associated with a shorter horizon of the manager in the firm and potential

misalignment with shareholder interests. Higher CEO ownership can facilitate alignment (used in

some of the tests). Dual classes of shares exacerbate the separation of voting and cash flow

rights. Dual class firms are identified in Gompers, Ishii, and Metrick (2005) for 1994–2002 and

in RiskMetrics for the remaining years. The five measures described above are equally weighted

to construct AGI. For robustness, we define AGI using rescaled continuous variables instead of

rankings; simplify AGI to the core index dimensions available for a longer sample period; and

perform factor analysis of individual governance measures from the main sample and

Institutional Shareholder Services (ISS) Corporate Governance Quotient provisions and

construct governance factors. Our results are highly robust to alternative governance metrics.

Prior work has raised concerns about endogeneity in the relation between managerial

ownership, governance, and firm performance (see, e.g., Himmelberg, Hubbard, and Palia, 1999;

3
Amihud and Li (2002) argue that a lower degree of information asymmetry between management and institutional owners is the
underlying reason for the negative relation between institutional ownership and dividend payout.

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2504715


Palia, 2001; Brick, Palia, and Wang, 2005; Chidambaran, Palia, and Zheng, 2006; Core, Guay,

and Rusticus, 2006; Hermalin and Weisbach, 1998). To the extent that dividend commitments

and strong corporate governance are alternative ways of curbing inefficient investment, firms

may jointly choose optimal dividend policy and governance quality depending on the relative

costs of monitoring and persistent dividends. Although no empirical test or correction can fully

eliminate endogeneity, we recognize this concern and attempt to address it in several ways.

First, we use the instrumental variables approach.4 Instruments should predict corporate

governance but they should not affect dividend changes, except through the governance channel.

We propose the following determinants of firm-level governance quality: (i) industry governance

practices; (ii) state laws; (iii) initial corporate control market conditions; and (iv) market demand

for governance. Industry-wide governance quality is less related to dividend decisions of

individual firms, but it offers a standard against which shareholders can benchmark firm-level

governance. Strong governance practices in the firm’s industry increase the likelihood of strong

governance at the sample firm and reduce the manager’s ability to resist monitoring. State

antitakeover laws are likely to influence the adoption of antitakeover defenses by individual

firms and may also affect internal governance mechanisms (for instance, firms may implement

stronger internal governance mechanisms to offset reduced corporate control market discipline).

Initial corporate control market conditions are likely to affect the initial governance structure but

not future dividend changes. We measure initial market-wide takeover activity with the fraction

of firms delisted due to M&As in the first year that the firm was listed in CRSP. Investor demand

for governance is also likely to affect firm-level governance, without a direct effect on dividend

4
Instrumental variables estimates are consistent if governance is endogenous but instruments satisfy excludability and relevance
conditions. Ordinary least squares estimates are more efficient if governance is exogenous. We use the auxiliary regression
version of the Durbin-Wu-Hausman test (see Davidson and MacKinnon, 1993; Hausman, 1978) and the difference of Hansen-
Sargan statistics (C statistic) to test the exogeneity of governance measures (probit model tests follow Rivers and Vuong (1988)).
We recognize potential concerns regarding the power of these tests and consider the results suggestive.

10

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2504715


changes. We define the industry governance premium as the difference in asset-weighted

market-to-book for the strong governance subsample (AGI above median) and the weak

governance subsample (AGI below median) of industry firms.5 In addition, portfolio structure of

the firm’s institutional owners affects investor attention span and focus on monitoring

mechanisms. While investors with concentrated portfolios are more likely to demand good

governance, distracted investors are more likely to exit. We use the average Herfindahl index of

portfolio holdings (excluding the stake in the sample firm) across all institutional investors with

stakes in the firm.

Second, we consider external shocks to governance structure associated with the adoption

of second-generation antitakeover laws and post-Enron governance reforms. A number of states

adopted business combination, control share acquisition, and fair price laws in the 1980s and

early 1990s (Bertrand and Mullainathan, 2003). In the more hostile takeover market of the

eighties, the passage of antitakeover laws was equivalent to a decrease in governance. The event

represented a shock to the governance of firms incorporated in affected states. If our hypothesis

holds, the addition of antitakeover laws would, all else equal, weaken monitoring and necessitate

an increased dividend commitment by weakly governed firms. Conversely, the passage of

Sarbanes-Oxley as well as the inclusion of board governance requirements in stock exchange

listing standards following Enron and related scandals represents another governance shock

(Grinstein and Chhaochharia, 2007). If our hypothesis holds, stronger governance resulting from

these reforms should lead to lower dividends and more significant dividend cuts.

Finally, we use firm fixed effects to control for unobservable firm-level heterogeneity.

We also consider dividend changes as a function of lagged dividend and governance metrics.

5
The construction of the measure is similar in spirit to the Baker and Wurgler (2004) dividend premium.

11

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2504715


Control variables

An important part of the manager’s objective function is the strength of ownership incentives.

Fenn and Liang (2001) find that managerial ownership is positively associated with payout in

firms with high agency costs, while stock option compensation is negatively associated with

dividends. We obtain data on CEO ownership and stock options from Execucomp. Dividend

choice is also conditional on the availability of cash flow and investment opportunities, which

reflects the extent of the free cash flow problem. Firm size is expected to have a positive effect

on dividends (Fama and French, 2001). Risky firms are expected to pay lower dividends (Hoberg

and Prabhala, 2009; Jagannathan, Stephens, and Weisbach, 2000). Other controls include

information asymmetry, liquidity, and industry conditions (change in median industry dividend).

Summary statistics for the main variables are presented in Appendix B.

4. Results

Univariate evidence

The first set of results presents univariate tabulations of governance and dividend trends in our

sample. Since univariate tests do not account for omitted controls potentially correlated with

dividends, we use these results to illustrate the governance effects and motivate our further

multivariate analysis.

Figure 1 illustrates differences in the persistence of dividends in the weakest and

strongest governance index quartiles. Dividend persistence is highest for firms in the bottom

quartile of governance.

Figure 2 shows the unconditional probability of dividend cuts and increases by

governance subsample. Consistent with our predictions, firms with the strongest traditional

governance mechanisms make twice as many dividend cuts as firms with the weakest

12

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2504715


governance. Further, strong governance firms are one and a half times less likely to raise

dividends.

Table 1 presents univariate tests of dividend characteristics for high and low governance

subsamples using quartile and median definitions. Weakly governed firms are two times more

likely to be dividend payers. Conditional on paying dividends, weakly governed firms exhibit

significantly more dividend smoothing, avoid dividend cuts, and are more likely to increase

dividends. (Since dividend cuts are considerably larger in magnitude than dividend increases,

avoidance of dividend cuts drives greater dividend smoothing among weakly governed firms.)

Univariate differences are highly statistically significant and in line with our conceptual

arguments.

[Table 1]

Fama and French (2001) document the aggregate trend of disappearance of dividend

payers, which they attribute to changing sample composition and propensity to pay among past

payers. Although governance data does not extend to the start of their thirty-year sample period,

we can draw some relevant inference from our sample. Figure 3 shows the evolution of

dividends at firms in the bottom versus top governance quartiles. Since we require the

availability of governance and compensation data, our sample firms are larger, have more assets

in place, and are more likely to pay dividends compared to firms in the Fama and French (2001)

sample. The weakest governance subsample saw less dividend disappearance and more

reappearance of dividend payers, whereas the strongest governance relative subsample

experienced a larger relative decline in dividend incidence between the start and the end of our

sample period (Figure 3). Overall, during our sample period, dividend payers disappeared at

varying rates, depending on the governance of the firms in question.

13

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2504715


Determinants of propensity to pay dividends

Before proceeding to the analysis of intertemporal dividend behavior among dividend-paying

firms, it is important to address the drivers of being a dividend payer in the first place. The

governance analysis of the propensity to pay dividends follows John, Knyazeva, and Knyazeva

(2011b). The adoption of a dividend commitment is less likely when firms can fall back on less

costly traditional monitoring mechanisms to keep agency conflicts in check.

[Table 2]

The signs and significance of the controls are generally consistent with the expectations

based on earlier literature (e.g., Fama and French, 2001). For instance, firms with more assets in

place pay higher dividends. Dividends are more likely to be present in firms with a high return

on assets. Similarly, larger firms are more likely to adopt dividends. Risky cash flows reduce the

likelihood of dividends since it is more costly for firms to commit to cash outflows. Presence of

significant managerial equity stakes and CEO stock options decreases the probability that the

firm will be a dividend payer, consistent with agency theory and empirical findings in Fenn and

Liang (2001). Liquidity is negatively associated with dividends, consistent with Banerjee,

Gatchev, and Spindt (2007). Analyst following, included as a proxy for low information

asymmetry between the firm and investors, is negatively related to the incidence of dividends,

similarly to Booth and Xu (2008).

Intertemporal dividend behavior

Table 3 examines differences in dividend smoothing. We estimate dividend smoothing using a

partial adjustment dividend model. We regress the difference between current and lagged

dividend level on lagged dividend and controls. The degree of dividend smoothing is computed

as one plus the coefficient on lagged dividend. A higher coefficient on lagged dividend reflects a

higher level of dividend smoothing. To capture the effect of governance on dividend smoothing,

14

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2504715


we interact lagged dividend and governance on the right-hand side. The interaction term enters

with a significant negative coefficient. Consistent with our testable predictions, firms with

stronger overall governance quality exhibit less dividend smoothing.6

[Table 3]

The effects are strongest for board and blockholder monitoring measures. Takeover

defenses are not significant. The corporate control market has become less hostile over time, and

our sample for this set of analyses starts in 1993 due to the availability of firm-level governance

data. Tests of intertemporal dividend behavior are performed in the sample of past dividend

payers, so we use a selection model to evaluate potential selection bias.7 Although the selection

term is significant, interaction terms of interest continue to enter with negative signs (Columns

III and IV). Overall, the findings support prediction (1): weakly governed managers engage in

more dividend smoothing, consistent with upholding the implicit dividend contract.

Table 4 reports the effects of governance on the direction of dividend changes. Consistent

with prediction (2), weakly governed managers are less likely to announce dividend cuts and

omissions. Board and blockholder monitoring and CEO alignment have the most significant

effects. The results in the table also support prediction (3): weakly governed managers are

overall more likely to raise dividends, all else equal. This suggests that a typical dividend

commitment entails not only dividend smoothing, but also a smooth upward-sloping dividend

path. These results provide a more accurate picture of evolution of dividends over time

conditional on the strength of governance: persistent dividends serve to mitigate observable

6
Tests in Columns I and II do not reject the null hypothesis of exogeneity of AGI, CEO ownership, and interaction terms, which
suggests that ordinary least squares estimates are consistent.
7
The selection equation uses the lagged proportion of dividend payers in the firm’s industry, lagged industry median dividend
level, dummy for having a positive dividend in the firm’s initial year in the sample (since 1980), and the industry-level version of
the market dividend premium (based on Baker and Wurgler, 2004), as well as controls from the main equation (with log of
lagged net sales as a proxy for size), sales growth, and index of state laws. The selection model is also partly identified through
the nonlinearity of the functional form.

15

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2504715


weaknesses in traditional governance mechanisms while strong governance mechanisms allow

for more dividend variability and more frequent cuts.

[Table 4]

In Panel A of Table 5 we present regressions of changes in dividend levels, which take

into account the magnitude of dividend adjustments. Corporate governance has a negative effect

on dividend changes, consistent with more dividend cuts and fewer dividend increases at well

governed firms. In turn, managers at weakly governed firms are less likely to deviate from the

implicit dividend commitment. The most significant effects are due to board structure,

blockholder monitoring, CEO alignment characteristics, and the presence of a single class of

shares. Governance effects continue to hold after correcting for selection (Columns III and IV)

and endogeneity (Columns V and VI).8 An increase in the governance index by one standard

deviation (0.10) lowers dividend changes by approximately 7%.

[Table 5]

Panel B (Columns V and VI) examines the magnitude of dividend increases. Since

weakly governed managers face more shareholder pressure to adhere to the level of dividends,

they are more conservative with respect to the magnitude of increases. We find that while weakly

governed managers are more likely to raise dividends overall, they prefer moderate dividend

increases to substantial increases. Small incremental adjustments make the new dividend level

easier to sustain and future cuts less likely.

Panel B also reports the effects of governance on dividend changes around cash flow

shocks. As expected, the governance effect is concentrated in subsamples of large and persistent

cash flow increases. Weakly governed managers choose dividend increases both to meet current

8
Tests in Columns I and II reject the exogeneity of suspected governance variables, which suggests that ordinary least squares
estimates are inconsistent and a correction for endogeneity is needed. First-stage statistics - Anderson likelihood ratio test and
Cragg-Donald test – support the relevance and strength of instruments. With the caveat about the power of the Hansen-Sargan
excludability test, instruments also satisfy the excludability condition.

16

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2504715


shareholder demands based on available cash flow data and to set a dividend level that can be

sustained in the future without costly cuts. As a result, weakly governed managers raise

dividends in response to large or persistent cash flow increases, which are more likely to draw

shareholder attention, but ignore small or temporary cash flow increases.

Governance shocks

Next, we exploit a quasi-natural experiment associated with the passage of second-generation

state antitakeover laws and post-Enron governance reforms. Corporate governance changed

around those events for reasons that were arguably exogenous to individual firms’ decisions and

largely unrelated to dividend behavior. To the extent that changes in corporate governance

around the shock had an exogenous component, we are able to sharpen the identification of

governance effects on dividends and mitigate some of the potential concerns about the

endogeneity of corporate governance to dividend behavior.

The first shock involves the passage of second-generation state antitakeover laws. By

deterring hostile takeover attempts, state antitakeover laws can weaken corporate control market

discipline (see, e.g., Bertrand and Mullainathan, 2003; John, Knyazeva, and Knyazeva, 2011b).

We treat the passage of state antitakeover laws as a governance-decreasing shock. Bertrand and

Mullainathan (2003) provide years of passage of business combination, control share acquisition,

and fair price laws by state.9 Consistent with our hypothesis, the results in Table 6, Panel A show

that the passage of antitakeover laws had a positive effect on dividend changes.

[Table 6]

The second shock involves improvements in governance through post-Enron governance

reforms (the passage of Sarbanes-Oxley and the adoption of board and committee independence

9
The main sample began in 1993 due to the availability of firm-level governance data. In turn, the sample used in this test mainly
spans the eighties. Greater prevalence of hostile takeover attempts during that period likely made antitakeover provisions a more
influential mechanism of external monitoring.

17

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2504715


requirements by major stock exchanges). The presence of exogenous variation in corporate

governance proxies around the shock helps us identify the governance effect. In line with our

argument and earlier results, the levels and changes of dividends are decreasing in changes in

governance around the shock (Table 6, Panel B). Further, the decrease in dividends after the

reforms was larger for firms that did not have a majority of independent directors on the board

prior to the shock, thus had to raise board governance quality, and for firms that have attained a

majority of independent directors on the board after the shock.

While it is hard to rule out endogeneity, taken together these results reduce the likelihood

that reverse causality or omitted variables affecting governance levels are driving our findings.

Other shareholder payouts and debt

The analysis presented so far has focused on intertemporal dividend behavior. However,

dividends are only one element of the larger set of financial policies that firms establish with

consideration of agency conflicts (John, Knyazeva, and Knyazeva, 2011b). Our predictions

extend to persistence and changes in total payout. In the first two columns of Table 7, persistence

and changes in total payout to shareholders are decreasing in the strength of governance,

consistent with prediction (4).

[Table 7]

The next question is whether repurchase changes serve as substitutes for dividend

changes when weakly governed managers implement payout adjustments. Although repurchases

are also a way of returning cash to shareholders, they lack the commitment features of dividends.

If changes in dividends and repurchases are perfect substitutes from the standpoint of remedying

governance problems, governance quality should not affect the choice between dividend changes

and repurchase changes, holding the direction of the payout change constant. We do not find

perfect substitutability. Weakly governed managers prefer to cut payout through repurchases.

18

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2504715


They are also more likely to use dividend increases when increasing payout, consistent with the

focus on dividend commitment.

Debt can constrain managers through regular interest payments, in which case our

predictions for dividend changes should also extend to changes in total commitments to external

claimholders (dividends paid to shareholders and interest paid to debtholders). Consistent with

prediction (4), Table 8 shows that changes in total payments to external claimholders are

decreasing in the strength of governance. Thus, the effect of governance on dynamic dividend

behavior extends to adjustment in overall commitments. Unlike repurchases, debt payments are

associated with a significant cost of deviation, which increases the likelihood that debt

commitments and dividend commitments are partly substitutable in the intertemporal context.

We examine this issue in the first two columns of the table by regressing dividend changes on

debt changes and controls (without assumption of causality). The coefficient on debt is negative

and significant, consistent with partial substitution between dividend and debt changes.

[Table 8]

Robustness and discussion

We perform a number of sensitivity tests to evaluate the robustness of our findings. Table 9

explores interactions of the governance effect on intertemporal dividend behavior with various

firm and industry characteristics.

[Table 9]

In addition to directly affecting dividend changes, corporate governance is expected to

influence the relation between dividend changes and cash flow changes. The relation between

cash flow changes and dividend changes is strongest when corporate governance is weak

(Column I). In a related result, the effect of corporate governance on dividend changes is more

pronounced for firms with limited growth or investment opportunities, which are likely to have

19

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2504715


high free cash flow (Column II). In addition, all else given, weakly governed managers’ dividend

changes respond to shareholder demand. There is more pressure to increase (maintain) dividends

after periods of poor performance (Column IV-V) and in industries where investors value

dividends more (Column VI). Similarly, governance has a larger effect on dividend changes in

industries dependent on external financing (Column III), consistent with the Myers (2000)

capital market rationale for sustaining dividends over time. Managers in such industries are more

likely to have to raise external financing in the future. Therefore, they face a greater need to meet

investor demands and mitigate low monitoring intensity with dividends.

The first three columns of Panel A of Table 10 include firm effects to mitigate

endogeneity concerns by controlling for unobserved firm-level heterogeneity. The results are

consistent with the findings shown in previous tables.

[Table 10]

Additional causality checks predict dividend changes using lags of governance and

changes in governance instead of governance levels. Past governance and changes in governance

have a negative effect on dividend changes (even after controlling for past dividend changes).

Simultaneous equations regressions examine the effect of dividends on governance as well as the

effect of governance on dividends. Governance has a negative effect on dividend changes, but

dividend changes do not significantly affect governance.

Panel B of Table 10 examines alternative governance measures. Column I explores

possible nonlinearities by looking at the effect of AGI above and below the median on dividend

changes. Both effects are negative, significant, and similar in magnitude, which does not appear

to indicate nonlinearity.

AGI uses firm rankings based on continuous governance characteristics. An alternative

version of the index that uses rescaled values of continuous characteristics instead of rankings

20

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2504715


yields similar results (Column II). AGI, Board Monitoring, Blockholders, and CEO

Characteristics measures rely on equal weighting of component characteristics. In Column IV,

factor analysis of underlying governance variables is used to check the reliability of AGI. The

underlying variables are sufficiently highly correlated, so factors related to observable

governance characteristics can be identified. The requirement that eigenvalues exceed one yields

seven factors that cumulatively explain 86.6% of variation in the underlying variables. Based on

factor loadings, governance factors that affect dividend changes are qualitatively similar to

governance indexes in the main analyses: presence and concentration of blockholdings,

coordination costs as a function of the number of blockholders and directors, separation of

ownership and control in dual class firms, board independence, and CEO characteristics.

Similarly, in Column IV dividend changes are regressed on governance factors based on

Institutional Shareholder Services (ISS) Corporate Governance Quotient provisions. Alternative

governance data and variable definitions produce consistent results.

Several other factors can affect costs and benefits of dividends, so additional controls are

introduced in Panel C of Table 10. DeAngelo, DeAngelo, and Stulz (2006) support the life-cycle

theory of dividends and find a higher propensity to pay dividends among firms with a higher

fraction of earned equity. The governance result continues to hold after controls for the share of

retained earnings in assets and year of entry dummies are added. Miscellaneous controls include

the share of tangible assets in total assets, stock performance, and bond rating (to proxy for the

cost of debt as an alternative commitment device). For robustness we also use alternative

dependent variable and sample definitions. Tests of changes in dividends per share scaled by

lagged price, changes in cash overall cash dividends scaled by lagged market value, and tests in

the full sample of firms, including firms that did not pay dividends in the previous period, yield

similar results.

21

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2504715


In the last three columns of the table, the full sample of firms, including firms that did not

pay dividends in the previous period, is analyzed instead of the sample of past dividend payers.

The governance result continues to hold throughout these robustness checks.

It is possible that an omitted variable associated with the proximity of the firm to

financial distress is driving some of the managerial behavior associated with a dividend

commitment. For instance, firms that are at low risk of financial distress can feasibly sustain a

stable dividend policy whereas distressed firms may undertake dividend cuts out of necessity. To

check whether the governance findings are driven by distress, Panel D of Table 10 uses Altman’s

z-score in robustness tests of dividend changes and dividend cuts. First, z-score itself is used as a

control in the regression. Second, the analysis is repeated using an indicator variable for firms

that are less likely to be financially distressed (with z-scores of 3 and higher). As expected,

dividend changes are decreasing in the likelihood of financial distress and dividend cuts are more

frequent among distressed firms. However, the governance results continue to hold and do not

appear to be driven by proximity to distress.

In Panels E and F of Table 10, we extend the sample period to 2009. We make some

modifications to the AGI index due to data availability, however, the index continues to capture

the main dimensions of internal and external corporate governance and CEO characteristics. It

averages firm rankings based on board governance (board independence and inverse of board

size), CEO characteristics and alignment (CEO ownership and inverse of CEO tenure), and

corporate control market oversight (inverse of the Bebchuk et al. (2005) index of takeover

defenses). In Panel E, we control for additional industry variation by using three-digit SIC

industry fixed effects instead of Fama-French industry definitions. In Panel F, we filter out

geographic variation using state-county fixed effects. As John, Knyazeva, and Knyazeva (2011a)

demonstrate, a firm’s location is an important dimension of shareholder monitoring costs and

22

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2504715


agency costs of free cash flow. Fixed effects capture variation along the central versus remote

location dimension as well as a broad range of differences across remotely located firms that can

affect agency conflicts. (The time-invariant central location indicator is absorbed by county fixed

effects, so it is not reported.) The main results are highly robust to these changes. We note there

is somewhat less dividend persistence in the extended sample. Governance and alignment quality

is negatively related to dividend smoothing and dividend changes. As before, firms with better

governance and managerial alignment have a significantly higher likelihood of dividend cuts and

omissions and a lower likelihood of dividend increases or initiations. The effect of single versus

dual classes of shares is not statistically significant after we account for the main governance and

alignment index.

Table 11 uses an event study to examine the market reaction to dividend cuts and

increases by dividend payers. Event study results reveal that shareholders react differently to

dividend decisions of weakly governed and strongly governed managers.10 The market reaction

to dividend changes is significantly larger for weakly governed managers. Since the dividend

constraint is more important for preventing suboptimal managerial behavior when governance is

weak, dividend changes have more significant effects on shareholder value, all else equal.

[Table 11]

An alternative explanation for dividend smoothing among weakly governed managers is

an extension of the Bertrand and Mullainathan (2003) “quiet life” hypothesis. Dividend changes

potentially release new information that the market can use to update beliefs about the manager’s

quality. Dividend cuts attract costly market scrutiny of managerial actions while dividend

increases expand the constraint imposed on the manager, which can precipitate future cuts.

10
Our event study tests of dividend changes by dividend payers complement the evidence in Officer (2011) on dividend
initiations by non-payers.

23

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2504715


Entrenched managers interested in a quiet life could smooth dividends, avoid dividend changes

in either direction (cuts as well as increases), and make additional cash distributions through

more flexible repurchases that can be cut easily in the future. Contrary to the quiet life

explanation, our results suggest that weakly governed managers also raise and initiate dividends

more often and distribute additional cash through repurchases less often.

5. Conclusion

Although on average dividends tend to be sticky, intertemporal patterns in dividends vary

considerably across firms, and systematic empirical evidence on the underlying determinants of

dynamic dividend behavior is scarce. This paper analyzed the issue from the perspective of

sustainability of the implicit dividend contract conditional on agency conflicts and provided new

evidence of firm differences in dividend smoothing and incremental payout decisions.

Weakly governed managers engage in more dividend smoothing and make fewer

dividend cuts. Changes in the dividend level are decreasing in the strength of governance.

Besides making fewer cuts, weakly governed managers undertake more dividend increases. As

weakly governed managers balance the need to meet shareholder expectations and set a

sustainable dividend level, they adjust dividends only in response to large cash flow shocks and

avoid substantial one-time dividend increases.

Weak governance has a positive effect on the persistence and changes in total payout.

However, dividend and repurchase changes are not perfect substitutes: weakly governed

managers cut payouts through decreases in repurchases and distribute additional cash through

higher dividends. Payout adjustments appear to preserve (and when necessary, expand) the

dividend commitment, subjecting the manager to an implicit obligation to shareholders with a

pre-specified timeline and levels of cash payouts. Changes in total commitments to shareholders

24

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2504715


and debtholders are similarly decreasing in governance, although changes in dividends and debt

act as partial substitutes in the dynamic context. The paper has also examined changes in

governance and external sources of variation in governance.

Some issues are open for future research. While this paper has focused on dividend

smoothing, an extensive accounting literature has examined earnings smoothing and Leuz,

Nanda, and Wysocki (2003) have linked earnings management to weak legal environments. It

would be of interest to examine the joint determination of dividend and earnings smoothing in

settings with varying corporate governance quality. We have considered the intertemporal

relation of dividends, repurchases and debt changes. Future work could analyze the relation

between dividend changes and other value-relevant corporate decisions, such as investment.

25

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2504715


References

Agrawal, A., Knoeber, C., 1996. Firm performance and mechanisms to control agency problems
between managers and shareholders. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis
31(3), 377–397.
Aharony, J., Swary, I., 1980. Quarterly dividend and earnings announcements and stockholders'
returns: An empirical analysis. Journal of Finance 35(1), 1–12.
Amihud, Y., Li, K., 2006. The declining information content of dividend announcements and the
effect of institutional holdings. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 41(3),
637–660.
Asquith, P., Mullins, D. W., 1983. The impact of initiating dividend payments on shareholders’
wealth. Journal of Business 56(1), 77–96.
Baker, M., Wurgler, J., 2004. Appearing and disappearing dividends: The link to catering
incentives. Journal of Financial Economics 73(2), 271–288.
Banerjee, S., Gatchev, V., Spindt, P., 2007. Stock market liquidity and firm dividend policy.
Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 42, 369–398.
Bebchuk, L., Cohen, A., 2005. The costs of entrenched boards. Journal of Financial Economics
78, 409–433.
Bebchuk, L., Cohen, A., Ferrell, A., 2005. What matters in corporate governance? Review of
Financial Studies 22(2), 783–827.
Benartzi, S., Michaely, R., Thaler, R., 1997. Do changes in dividends signal the future or the
past? Journal of Finance 52, 1007–1034.
Bertrand, M., Mullainathan, S., 2003. Enjoying the quiet life? Corporate governance and
managerial preferences. Journal of Political Economy 111(5), 1043–1075.
Booth, L., Xu, Z., 2008. Who smoothes dividends? Working paper.
Brick, I., Palia, D., Wang, C.-J., 2005. Simultaneous estimation of CEO compensation, leverage,
and board characteristics on firm value.
Chidambaran, N., Palia, D., Zheng, Y., 2006. Does better corporate governance “cause” better
firm performance? Working paper.
Core, J. E., Guay, W. R., Rusticus, T. O., 2006. Does weak governance cause weak stock
returns? An examination of firm operating performance and investors’ expectations.
Journal of Finance 61(2), 655–687.
Cragg, J., Donald, S., 1993. Testing identifiability and specification in instrumental variable
models. Econometric Theory 9, 222–240.
Cremers, M., Nair, C., 2005. Governance mechanisms and equity prices. Journal of
Finance 60 (6), 2859–2894.
Davidson, R., MacKinnon, J. G., 1993. Estimation and inference in econometrics. Oxford
University Press.
DeAngelo, H., DeAngelo, L., Stulz, R., 2006. Dividend policy and the earned/contributed capital
mix: a test of the life-cycle theory. Journal of Financial Economics 81, 227–254.
Dewenter, K., Warther, V., 1998. Dividends, asymmetric information, and agency conflicts:
Evidence from a comparison of the dividend policies of Japanese and U.S. firms. Journal
of Finance 53, 879–904.

26

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2504715


Easterbrook, F., 1984. Two agency-cost explanations of dividends. American Economic Review
74, 650–659.
Fama, E., Babiak, H., 1968. Dividend policy: An empirical analysis. Journal of the American
Statistical Association 63, 123–1161.
Fama, E., French, K., 2001. Disappearing dividends: changing firm characteristics or lower
propensity to pay? Journal of Financial Economics 60, 3–43.
Fenn, G., Liang, N., 2001. Corporate payout policy and managerial stock incentives. Journal of
Financial Economics 60, 45–72.
Fluck, Z., 1998. Optimal financial contracting: dept versus outside equity. Review of Financial
Studies 11(2), 383–418.
Fluck, Z., 1999. The dynamics of the management-shareholder conflict. Review of Financial
Studies 12(2), 379–404.
Fudenberg, D., Tirole, J., 1995. A theory of income and dividend smoothing based on
incumbency rents. Journal of Political Economy 103(1), 75-93.
Gompers, P., Ishii, J., Metrick, A., 2003. Corporate governance and equity prices. Quarterly
Journal of Economics 118(1), 107–155.
Gompers, P., Ishii, J., Metrick, A., 2005. Extreme governance: An analysis of dual-class
companies in the United States. Working paper.
Griliches, Z., Mairesse, J., 1984. Productivity and R&D at the firm level. In R&D, patents, and
productivity / ed. Z. Griliches. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 339–374.
Grinstein, Y., Chhaochharia, V., 2007. Corporate governance and firm value: The impact of the
2002 governance rules. Journal of Finance 62(4), 1789–1825.
Gugler, K., 2003. Corporate governance, dividend payout policy, and the interrelation between
dividends, R&D, and capital investment. Journal of Banking and Finance 27, 1297–1321.
Hansen, L., 1982. Large sample properties of generalized method of moments estimators.
Econometrica 50(3), 1029–1054.
Harford, J., Mansi, S., Maxwell, W., 2008. Corporate governance and firm cash holdings.
Journal of Financial Economics 87(3), 535–555.
Hausman, J., 1978. Specification tests in econometrics. Econometrica 46(6), 1251–1271,
Hermalin, B., Weisbach, M., 1998. Endogenously chosen boards of directors and their
monitoring of the CEO. American Economic Review 88, 96–118.
Himmelberg, C., Hubbard, R., Palia, D., 1999. Understanding the determinants of managerial
ownership and the link between ownership and performance. Journal of Financial
Economics 53, 353–384.
Hoberg, G., Prabhala, R., 2009. Disappearing dividends, catering, and risk. Review of Financial
Studies 22(1), 79–116.
Hu, A., Kumar, P. 2004. Managerial entrenchment and payout policy. Journal of Financial and
Quantitative Analysis 39(4), 759–790.
Jagannathan, M., Stephens, C., Weisbach, M., 2000. Financial flexibility and the choice between
dividends and stock repurchases. Journal of Financial Economics 57, 355–384.
Jensen, M., 1986. Agency costs of free cash flow, corporate finance, and takeovers. American
Economic Review 76, 323–329.
Jensen, M., Meckling, W., 1976. Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior, agency costs and
ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics 3, 305–360.

27

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2504715


John, K., Knyazeva, A., Knyazeva, D., 2011a. Does geography matter? Firm location and
corporate payout policy. Journal of Financial Economics 101(3), 533–551.
John, K., Knyazeva, A., Knyazeva, D., 2011b. Governance and payout precommitment:
Antitakeover laws, structure of payouts, and the dividend-debt tradeoff. Working paper.
Karpavičius , S., 2014. Dividends: Relevance, rigidity, and signaling. Journal of Corporate
Finance 25, 289–312.
Knyazeva, A., Knyazeva, D., Masulis, R., 2013. The supply of corporate directors and board
independence. Review of Financial Studies 26(6), 1561-1605.
Kumar, P., 1988. Shareholder-manager conflict and the information content of dividends.
Review of Financial Studies 1, 111–136.
La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., Vishny, R.W., 2000. Agency problems and
dividend policies around the world. Journal of Finance 55, 1–33.
Leuz, C., Nanda, D., Wysocki, P., 2003. Earnings management and institutional factors: An
international comparison. Journal of Financial Economics 69, 505–527.
Lintner, J., 1956. Distribution of incomes of corporations among dividends, retained earnings,
and taxes. American Economic Review 46, 97–113.
Michaely, R., Roberts, M., 2012. Corporate dividend policies:: Lessons from private firms.
Review of Financial Studies 25, 711–746.
Myers, S., 2000. Outside equity. Journal of Finance 55, 1005–1037.
Officer, M., 2011. Overinvestment, corporate governance, and dividend initiations. Journal of
Corporate Finance 17(3), 710–724.
Palia, D., 2001. The endogeneity of managerial compensation in firm valuation: A solution.
Review of Financial Studies 14, 735–764.
Pan, C., 2007. Why are firms with entrenched managers more likely to pay dividends? Working
paper.
Rivers, D., Vuong, Q. H., 1988. Limited information estimators and exogeneity tests for
simultaneous probit models. Journal of Econometrics 39(3), 347–366.
Rosenstein, S., Wyatt, J. G., 1990. Outside directors, board independence, and shareholder
wealth. Journal of Financial Economics 26(2), 175–191.
Rozeff, M. S., 1982. Growth, beta and agency costs as determinants of dividend payout ratios.
Journal of Financial Research 3, 249–259.
Shivdasani, A., Yermack, D., 1999. CEO involvement in the selection of new board members:
An empirical analysis. Journal of Finance 54(5), 1829–1853.
Vafeas, N., 1999. Board meeting frequency and firm performance. Journal of Financial
Economics 53, 113–142.
Warther, V., 1994. Dividend smoothing: A sleeping dogs explanation. Working paper.
Yermack, D., 1996. High market valuation of companies with a small board of directors. Journal
of Financial Economics 40, 185–211.
Zwiebel, J., 1996. Dynamic capital structure under managerial entrenchment. American
Economic Review 86, 1197–1215.

28

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2504715


Appendix A. Sample and variables

Sample
The main sample is based on Compustat Annual (1993–2004), excluding foreign firms, firms with total assets less than 20 mln,
financials (SIC 6000–6999), regulated utilities (SIC 4949–4999), and firms with missing Compustat, governance or
compensation data. The extended sample in Panels E and F of Table 10 uses the 1996–2009 sample period.

Alignment and governance variables


Board Monitoring index assigns equal weights to annual firm rankings based on board independence (high fraction of
independent directors and low fraction of employee directors on the board; source: RiskMetricsa); annual firm ranking based on
board size (low board size; source: RiskMetricsa); key committees (dummies for the absence of CEO from nominating,
compensation, governance, and audit committees11; source: RiskMetricsa); annual firm ranking based on frequency of board
meetings (source: Execucomp).
Blockholders index assigns equal weights to blockholder presence (5% public pension fund blockholder and 5% institutional
blockholder dummies); annual firm rankings based on largest institutional stake (largest institutional stake, largest ‘other
institutional investor’ stake, largest public pension fund stake); annual firm rankings based on holdings concentration
(concentration of 5% institutional blockholdings and concentration of all institutional holdings);annual firm rankings based on
institutional owner count (low number of public pension fund owners, low number of institutional owners). Source: Thomson
Financial 13f filings. Public pension funds are listed in Cremers and Nair (2005) (also, Missouri State Employees Retirement
System, Pennsylvania Public School Employees' Retirement System).
CEO Characteristics index assigns equal weights to annual firm rankings based on CEO age (source: RiskMetricsa) and CEO
tenure in the firm (source: Execucomp). Rankings are rescaled to [0,1] such that higher values reflect shorter CEO age and
tenure.
External Governance is annual firm ranking based on the Gompers, Ishii, and Metrick (2003) G index, rescaled to [0,1] such that
higher values reflect the presence of fewer antitakeover provisions. Source: RiskMetricsb.
Single Class of Shares is dummy variable equal to 1 if the firm has one class of shares; 0 if the firm has dual classes of shares.
Source: 1994–2002 - Gompers, Ishii, and Metrick (2005); 1993, 2003, 2004 - RiskMetricsb.
Alignment and Governance Index (AGI) assigns equal weights to Board Monitoring, Blockholders, CEO Characteristics, External
Governance, Single Class of Shares.
a
– Board of directors data was available starting in 1996; 1993–95 were filled in with 1996 data.
b
– Takeover defenses data was available for 1993, 1995, 1998, 2000, 2002, and 2004; gap years were filled in using adjacent
years.

The extended sample uses Alignment and Governance Index 2 (AGI2) and Single Class of Shares for 1996-2009. Due to data
changes in RiskMetrics that affect the availability of the G index and the constraints on our availability of blockholder data, we
use a modified AGI definition, AGI2. AGI2 is constructed as the average of firm rankings, rescaled to [0,1], based on Board
Independence (fraction of independent directors on the board), Board Size (inverse), the Bebchuk et al. (2005) index of takeover
defenses (inverse), CEO tenure (inverse), and CEO ownership. Data is available from RiskMetrics. Gap years for takeover
defense data are filled in using adjacent years.

Instruments
Instruments for AGI and CEO Ownership:
State Laws – the index that assigns 1 for the presence of each of the following state antitakeover laws: business combination law;
control share acquisition law; cash out law; fair price law; director’s duties law; antigreenmail (recapture of profits) law; firms
are ranked based on the index in a given year; the variable is rescaled to [0,1] such that higher values reflect the presence of
fewer antitakeover laws.

11
Where the name of a director’s primary employer was available, the accuracy of the CEO flag was checked manually.

29

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2504715


Industry Governance – industry state median of internal governance index that equally weights Board Monitoring, Blockholders,
and CEO Characteristics.
Initial Takeover Activity – proportion of CRSP firms delisted due to M&A in the year that the firm first appeared in CRSP.
Technology – equals 1 for firms with two-digit SIC codes 28, 35, 36, 38 (following Griliches and Mairesse [1984]); 0 otherwise.
Portfolio Structure – concentration of portfolio holdings (excluding holdings of the sample firm) of an average institutional
blockholder with a stake in the firm; concentration of holdings is measured using the Herfindahl index; equally weighted average
over blockholders with a stake in the firm is used; a blockholder is an institutional investor with a 5% or higher stake in the firm.
Governance Premium – market premium for strong governance defined as the difference of the log of asset-weighted average
market-to-book ratio of firms with AGI above and below the sample median (computed at the three-digit SIC level; two-digit SIC
level if not available; one-digit SIC industry level if not available). The variable is related to the dividend premium used in Baker
and Wurgler (2004).
In regressions that include Board Monitoring, Blockholders, CEO Characteristics, External Governance, Single Class of Shares,
and CEO Ownership as individual variables, similar instruments are used, with Industry Governance redefined accordingly.
In regressions that include interactions of governance and lagged dividend, Industry Median Lagged Dividend and Dividend
Premium (similar to Baker and Wurgler, 2004, but computed at the industry level) are added to Governance Premium, Initial
Takeover Activity, Technology, Industry Governance, and State Laws.

Dependent and control variables


Div is the annual ordinary dividend per share (CRSP, distribution code 1232) adjusted for stock dividends and splits, except as
specified otherwise. (Tests on the extended sample use Compustat data on common dividends per share.)
LagDiv is the one-year lag of Div.
D_Div equals 1 if Div is positive, and 0 otherwise (defined for all firms).
The remaining dividend variables are defined for past dividend payers only, unless the table specifies otherwise.
DiffDiv is the difference between Div and LagDiv.
∆Div is DiffDiv divided by LagDiv.
∆Div2 is DiffDiv, divided by lagged closing share price (CRSP).
D_DivIncr equals 1 if ∆Div is positive, and 0 otherwise.
D_DivDecr equals 1 if ∆Div is negative, and 0 otherwise.
ρ(Div,LagDiv) is the correlation between Div and LagDiv (used in univariate tests).
∆Div3 is the difference in annual cash dividends based on Compustat (0 if missing) scaled by lagged Market Value (common
equity minus book value of common equity plus book value of total assets), times 100 (Compustat).
Payout is the sum of cash dividends and Repurchases (purchases of common and preferred stock; 0 if missing), divided by
Market Value, times 100 (Compustat).
LagPayout is one-year lag of Payout.
DiffPayout is the difference between Payout and Lag_Payout.
∆Payout is the change in the sum of cash dividends and Repurchases, divided by lagged Market Value, times 100 (Compustat).
∆Commit is the change in the sum of cash dividends and interest (0 if missing), divided by lagged Market Value, times 100
(Compustat).
CEO Ownership is the ratio of shares owned by the CEO to common shares outstanding (Execucomp).
Cash Flow is the ratio of EBITDA to lagged total assets (Compustat).
Firm Size is the log of lagged total assets (Compustat).
Market-to-Book is the ratio of Market Value to book value of total assets (Compustat).
Cash Flow Volatility is the log of the standard deviation of income before extraordinary items (operating income after
depreciation in Table 10, Panels E and F) scaled by assets, based on up to twelve quarters of data(Compustat quarterly).
Analyst Following is the log of the number of one-year-ahead analyst earnings forecasts (I/B/E/S).

30

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2504715


CEO Stock Options is the percentage of stock option holdings of the CEO to common shares outstanding (Execucomp).
Firm Taxes is the ratio of income taxes to pretax income (Compustat).
Liquidity is the log of annual average bid-ask spread (CRSP).
∆Leverage is leverage ratio minus lagged leverage ratio (Compustat)
∆Interest is the change in interest payments (0 if missing) divided by lagged Market Value, times 1000 (for ease of interpretation)
(Compustat).
Retained Earnings is ratio of retained earnings to book value of total assets (Compustat).
Stock Performance is average CRSP monthly stock return net of value-weighted index return (Compustat).
Tangible Assets is the ratio of property, plants, and equipment (net) to book value of total assets (Compustat).
Bond Rating equals 1 if the firm has a long-term domestic issuer credit rating, and 0 otherwise (Compustat).
z-score is the Altman z-score defined as 1.2x(working capital/total assets) plus 1.4x(retained earnings/total assets) plus
3.3x(EBIT/total assets) plus 0.6x(market value of equity/book value of total liabilities) plus 1.0x(sales/total assets) (Compustat).
Lower values indicate greater proximity to financial distress.

31

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2504715


Appendix B. Summary statistics
Panel A: Summary statistics of the main governance and alignment variables
Underlying governance characteristics Corr. w/AGI Mean Median SD
Board Monitoring 0.402 0.590 0.592 0.121
Fraction of independent directors on the board 0.053 0.633 0.667 0.178
a. Independence
Fraction of employee directors on the board -0.037 0.215 0.182 0.115
b. Size Board size (log) -0.438 2.206 2.197 0.278
CEO not on nominating committee 0.058 0.925 1.000 0.264
CEO not on compensation committee 0.026 0.983 1.000 0.129
c. Committees
CEO not on governance committee 0.060 0.977 1.000 0.151
CEO not on audit committee 0.027 0.991 1.000 0.094
d. Meetings Number of board meetings (log) 0.149 1.895 1.946 0.354
Blockholders 0.427 0.477 0.499 0.188
Public pension fund blockholder (at 5% or higher) 0.301 0.047 0.048 0.027
a. Presence
Institutional blockholder (at 5% or higher) 0.280 0.824 1.000 0.337
Largest institutional owner stake 0.259 8.975 8.488 4.079
b. Largest stake Largest ‘other (type 5) institutional investor’ stake 0.144 5.678 4.794 4.649
Largest public pension fund stake 0.151 1.206 0.783 1.388
Concentration of all institutional holdings 0.311 0.057 0.049 0.035
c. Concentration
Concentration of 5% institutional blockholdings 0.336 0.051 0.046 0.038
The number of public pension fund owners (log) -0.292 1.993 2.169 0.553
d. Number
The number of institutional owners (log) -0.354 5.000 4.956 0.723
CEO Characteristics 0.514 0.525 0.539 0.232
a. Age CEO age (log) -0.447 3.998 4.007 0.131
b. Tenure CEO tenure (log) -0.364 1.527 1.609 1.007
External Governance 0.508 0.450 0.439 0.290
Gompers, Ishii, and Metrick (2003) G Index -0.497 9.328 9.000 2.710
Single Class of Shares 0.449 0.932 1.000 0.252
Statistics above are based on the full sample. All correlations are significant at 5%.

32

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2504715


Panel B: Summary statistics of the main dependent and control variables
Mean Median Std. Dev.
Dividend Difference 0.013 0.010 0.090
Dividend Change 0.050 0.030 0.310
Dividend Increase 0.559 1.000 0.497
Dividend Decrease 0.094 0.000 0.292
AGI 0.563 0.566 0.096
Board Monitoring 0.578 0.582 0.117
Blockholders 0.440 0.461 0.194
CEO Characteristics 0.511 0.523 0.230
External Governance 0.370 0.315 0.280
Single Class of Shares 0.916 1.000 0.276
CEO Ownership 0.018 0.002 0.048
Cash Flow 0.177 0.167 0.092
Firm Size 7.695 7.536 1.469
Market-to-Book 1.885 1.567 1.092
Cash Flow Volatility -1.577 -1.676 1.535
Analyst Following 2.219 2.359 0.839
CEO Stock Options 0.918 0.609 1.028
Firm Taxes 0.360 0.362 1.682
Liquidity -1.827 -1.917 0.591

33

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2504715


Figure 1. Governance and dividend smoothing
Smoothing of dividends among dividend payers (firms with a positive lagged dividend), by strength of governance. “Weak Gov”
subsample includes observations in the bottom quartile of the Alignment and Governance Index (AGI) - AGI below 0.51. “Strong
Gov” subsample includes observations in the top quartile of AGI - AGI above 0.63. Sample and variable definitions are presented
in Appendix A. For each subsample, persistence is defined for the entire sample period, for the subperiod ending in 1999, and for
the subperiod starting after 1999.

Figure 2. Governance and dividend changes


Percentage of observations that experienced a dividend increase, no change in dividends, and a dividend decrease. “Weak Gov”
subsample includes observations in the bottom quartile of the Alignment and Governance Index (AGI) - AGI below 0.51. “Strong
Gov” subsample includes observations in the top quartile of AGI - AGI above 0.63. Sample and variable definitions are presented
in Appendix A.
Strong Gov Weak Gov

Decrease Decrease
14% 7%

Increase
44%

Increase
No
68%
Change
25%

No
change
42%

34

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2504715


Figure 3. Dividend incidence over time, by strength of governance
Average proportion of dividend payers across all firms in subsamples with different strength of governance in 1996-2009.
Sample and variable definitions are presented in Appendix A. “Weak Gov” subsample includes observations in the bottom
quartile of the Alignment and Governance Index 2 (AGI2). “Strong Gov” subsample includes observations in the top quartile of
AGI2.

35

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2504715


Table 1. Univariate evidence
Univariate evidence of differences in dividend properties in subsamples based on AGI. Sample and variable definitions are
presented in Appendix A. The first set of tests uses bottom and top AGI quartiles. The second set of tests uses below-median and
above-median AGI subsamples. Statistical significance of differences in means at 1%, 5%, and 10% levels is denoted with ***, **,
and *, respectively.

Weak Gov Strong Gov


(bottom quartile of AGI) (top quartile of AGI)

***
D_Div (all firms) 0.77 0.36
***
ρ(Div,LagDiv) 0.98 0.91
***
D_DivDecr 0.07 0.14
***
D_DivIncr 0.67 0.43
***
∆Div 0.09 0.01

Weak Gov Strong Gov


(AGI below median) (AGI above median)

***
D_Div (all firms) 0.74 0.45
***
ρ(Div,LagDiv) 0.97 0.93
***
D_DivDecr 0.07 0.12
***
D_DivIncr 0.64 0.48
***
∆Div 0.08 0.02

36

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2504715


Table 2. Determinants of dividend payer status

Probit estimation of the probability of being a dividend payer. Sample and variable definitions are presented in Appendix A.
Regressions include Fama-French industry dummies, year dummies, and the proportion of dividend payers in the firm’s industry
in the previous period. Robust z-statistics with clustering by firm are in parentheses. Significance at 1%, 5%, and 10% levels is
denoted with ***, **, and *, respectively.

Dependent variable: D_Div D_Div D_Div D_Div


I II III IV
***
AGI -3.346
-8.77
Board Monitoring -0.425
-1.54
***
Blockholders -0.994
-4.52
**
CEO Characteristics -0.280
-2.13
***
External Governance -1.056
-7.33
***
Single Class of Shares -0.623
-4.40
** ** ***
CEO Ownership -1.359 -1.359 -1.969 -1.159
-2.06 -2.06 -2.82 -1.64
*** *** *** ***
Cash Flow 1.239 1.239 1.278 1.225
3.67 3.67 3.77 3.59
*** *** *** ***
Firm Size 0.610 0.610 0.518 0.495
12.02 12.02 10.19 9.76
*** *** *** ***
Sales Growth -0.378 -0.378 -0.435 -0.409
-3.87 -3.87 -4.31 -4.12
Market-to-Book -0.017 -0.017 -0.029 -0.031
-0.56 -0.56 -0.91 -0.95
*** *** *** ***
Cash Flow Volatility -0.199 -0.199 -0.172 -0.180
-5.19 -5.19 -4.47 -4.60
*** *** *** ***
Analyst Following -0.261 -0.261 -0.300 -0.315
-4.50 -4.50 -5.18 -5.27
*** *** *** ***
CEO Stock Options -0.114 -0.114 -0.116 -0.113
-3.98 -3.98 -3.93 -3.81
*** *** *** ***
Liquidity -0.359 -0.359 -0.349 -0.330
-5.81 -5.81 -5.61 -5.33
Obs. 9851 9851 9851 9851
Pseudo-R2 0.37 0.37 0.40 0.40

37

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2504715


Table 3. Dividend smoothing
OLS (Columns I-II) and selection model (Columns III-IV) regressions of Dividend Difference. Sample and variable definitions
are presented in Appendix A. Regressions include Fama-French industry dummies, year dummies, and change in industry median
dividend. The selection equation includes controls from the main equation, sales growth, lagged log of sales (instead of Firm
Size), lagged industry proportion of dividend payers, lagged industry median dividend, dummy for having a positive dividend in
the first year the firm was present in the sample (going back to 1980), Dividend Premium, Technology, and State Laws, and is
estimated using the full maximum likelihood method. λ is Inverse Mills Ratio. Davidson-MacKinnon and difference-in-Sargan
(C) statistics test the exogeneity of AGI, CEO Ownership, and the interaction terms. Robust t(z) statistics clustered by firm are in
parentheses. Significance at 1%, 5%, and 10% levels is denoted with ***, **, and *, respectively.

Dependent variable: DiffDiv DiffDiv DiffDiv DiffDiv


Model: OLS OLS Selection Selection
I II III IV
** **
LagDiv 0.067 0.082 0.066 ** 0.082 **
2.11 2.03 2.12 2.06
***
LagDiv*AGI -0.165 -0.163 ***
-2.97 -2.96
** **
LagDiv*Board Monitoring -0.064 -0.065
-2.27 -2.34
*** ***
LagDiv*Blockholders -0.079 -0.077
-3.81 -3.76
LagDiv*CEO Characteristics -0.018 -0.017
-1.22 -1.16
LagDiv*External Governance -0.007 -0.008
-0.50 -0.55
LagDiv*Single Class of Shares -0.027 -0.026
-1.10 -1.09
AGI 0.026 0.011 0.022 0.008
1.14 0.45 0.98 0.33
* * *
CEO Ownership 0.064 0.055 0.060 0.052
1.71 1.75 1.63 1.68
*** *** *** ***
Cash Flow 0.223 0.210 0.226 0.213
8.70 8.34 9.00 8.65
*** *** *** ***
Firm Size 0.015 0.012 0.017 0.014
6.14 4.81 6.69 5.32
* *
Market-to-Book -0.002 -0.003 -0.002 -0.003
-1.35 -1.76 -1.46 -1.85
*** *** *** ***
Cash Flow Volatility -0.009 -0.009 -0.010 -0.009
-4.77 -4.59 -5.04 -4.85
** ** ** **
Analyst Following 0.008 0.008 0.007 0.007
2.55 2.51 2.29 2.28
CEO Stock Options -0.002 -0.001 -0.002 -0.002
-1.24 -1.03 -1.64 -1.41
Firm Taxes -0.001 -0.001 -0.001 -0.001
-0.58 -0.59 -0.55 -0.56
*** *** *** ***
Liquidity -0.020 -0.020 -0.021 -0.021
-6.66 -6.64 -6.91 -6.89
*** ***
λ 0.011 0.010
λ (s.e.) 0.003 0.003
Obs. 5564 5564 9851 9851
R2 0.16 0.17
Adj. R2 0.15 0.16
Davidson-MacKinnon test 1.18 1.20
C statistic 5.31 5.26

38

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2504715


Table 4. Dividend cuts and increases
Probability of dividend cuts (Columns I-II) and dividend increases (Columns III-IV). The probit model with correction for
endogeneity is estimated using Newey’s two-step efficient estimation. Sample and variable definitions are presented in Appendix
A. Regressions include Fama-French industry dummies and year dummies. The Rivers and Vuong (1988) statistic tests the
exogeneity of governance and CEO Ownership. The estimate of correlation of the selection equation and main equation residuals
from the selection model (rho) is not significantly different from zero. z-statistics are in parentheses. Significance at 1%, 5%, and
10% levels is denoted with ***, **, and *, respectively.

Dependent variable: D_DivDecr D_DivDecr D_DivIncr D_DivIncr


I II III IV
*** ***
AGI 0.032 -0.082
3.93 -10.40
*** ***
Board Monitoring 0.013 -0.028
2.87 -6.29
*** ***
Blockholders 0.008 -0.018
2.63 -6.81
** ***
CEO Characteristics 0.010 -0.019
2.32 -4.30
**
External Governance 0.001 -0.011
0.25 -2.22
* ***
Single Class of Shares 0.316 -0.950
1.90 -6.02
*** ***
CEO Ownership 0.061 0.135 -0.215 -0.291
1.61 1.60 -5.94 -3.53
*** *** *** ***
Cash Flow -0.042 -0.040 0.035 0.032
-9.81 -8.82 9.30 7.64
Firm Size -0.087 -0.030 -2.E-04 -0.068
-1.58 -0.41 0.00 -0.94
* *** ***
Market-to-Book 0.069 0.060 0.152 0.159
1.85 1.45 4.38 3.92
*** *** *** **
Cash Flow Volatility 0.158 0.140 -0.119 -0.096
4.36 3.48 -3.61 -2.46
*** ***
Analyst Following -0.048 0.022 -0.290 -0.371
-0.68 0.24 -4.42 -4.01
* * *** ***
CEO Stock Options 0.054 0.075 -0.202 -0.217
1.85 1.94 -7.14 -5.58
Firm Taxes -0.008 -0.010 0.010 0.011
-0.52 -0.63 0.64 0.65
*** *** *** ***
Liquidity 0.253 0.252 0.149 0.148
5.02 4.78 3.17 2.85
Obs. 5564 5564 5564 5564
** *** ***
Rivers-Vuong test 6.05 6.18 118.24 85.29
Rho (selection bias) -0.010 -0.011 -0.060 0.057
Rho (s.e.) 0.075 0.077 0.082) 0.082

39

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2504715


Table 5. Dividend changes
Sample and variable definitions are presented in Appendix A. Panel A presents OLS (Columns I-II), selection model (Columns III-IV),
and 2SLS (Columns V-VI) regressions of ∆Div. The selection model is similar to Table 3. Davidson-MacKinnon and difference-in-
Sargan (C) statistics test exogeneity of governance and CEO Ownership. Hansen-Sargan statistic tests exogeneity of instruments.
Anderson-Rubin and Cragg-Donald statistics test instrument irrelevance. Panel B presents 2SLS regressions of ∆Div in subsamples with
large (above-median) cash flow increases (Column I); small (below-median) cash flow increases (Column II); persistent cash flow
increases (followed by cash flow increases, or decreases below 1%) (Column III); temporary cash flow increases (followed by cash flow
decreases exceeding 1%) (Column IV). Multinomial logit regressions of the dividend change decision (Columns V-VI) use the variable
that equals 1 for decreases; 2 for no change; 3 for small or moderate increases (bottom two terciles); 4 for substantial increases (top
tercile). Regressions include Fama-French industry dummies, year dummies and change in industry median dividend. Robust t(z)
statistics clustered by firm are in parentheses. Significance at 1%, 5%, and 10% levels is denoted with ***, **, and *, respectively.
Panel A: Dividend changes
Dependent variable: ∆Div ∆Div ∆Div ∆Div ∆Div ∆Div
Model: OLS OLS Selection Selection 2SLS 2SLS
I II III IV V VI
***
AGI -0.238 -0.249 *** -0.688 ***

-4.64 -4.99 -4.31


** ** **
Board Monitoring -0.077 -0.081 -0.182
-1.97 -2.11 -2.03
*** *** **
Blockholders -0.142 -0.146 -0.109
-4.28 -4.44 -1.98
*** *** **
CEO Characteristics -0.077 -0.075 -0.191
-4.20 -4.18 -2.37
External Governance 0.018 0.012 -0.104
1.04 0.70 -1.10
** ** ***
Single Class of Shares -0.043 -0.044 -0.102
-2.40 -2.54 -2.98
*** * *** *
CEO Ownership 0.263 0.164 0.248 0.159 -1.222 -2.000
2.72 1.75 2.58 1.70 -1.64 -1.23
*** *** *** *** *** ***
Cash Flow 0.690 0.650 0.707 0.665 0.657 0.657
7.97 7.54 8.32 7.88 7.13 6.58
*** ** *** ***
Firm Size 0.025 0.017 0.032 0.023 0.008 0.005
3.85 2.40 4.93 3.37 0.83 0.40
Market-to-Book -0.003 -0.005 -0.003 -0.006 0.001 0.004
-0.42 -0.87 -0.51 -0.95 0.17 0.45
*** *** *** *** *** ***
Cash Flow Volatility -0.034 -0.032 -0.036 -0.034 -0.030 -0.028
-5.80 -5.57 -6.20 -5.95 -4.46 -3.75
*** *** *** ***
Analyst Following 0.033 0.030 0.029 0.027 0.013 0.007
3.27 3.05 2.88 2.66 0.90 0.33
CEO Stock Options -0.006 -0.006 -0.009 -0.008 -0.011 -0.014
-1.15 -1.07 -1.60 -1.49 -1.54 -1.56
Firm Taxes 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001
0.92 0.88 1.05 1.01 0.72 0.71
Liquidity 0.008 0.007 0.003 0.002 0.013 0.013
1.06 0.88 0.44 0.31 1.37 1.26
*** ***
λ 0.046 0.044
λ (s.e.) 0.01 0.01
Obs. 5564 5564 9851 9851 5564 5564
R2 0.20 0.21 0.15 0.10
Adj. R2 0.19 0.20 0.14 0.09
*** **
Davidson-MacKinnon test 6.18 2.42
*** ***
C statistic 12.29 17.17
Hansen-Sargan test 4.86 3.88
*** ***
Cragg-Donald statistic 112.05 30.58
*** ***
Anderson-Rubin statistic 110.94 30.49

40

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2504715


Panel B: Dividend changes in response to shocks
Magnitude of Magnitude of
Dependent variable: ∆Div ∆Div ∆Div ∆Div
increase increase
Multinomial logit: Multinomial logit
Model: 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS moderate increase moderate vs.
vs. no change substantial increase
Large cash Small cash Persistent cash Temporary cash
Sample: All firms All firms
flow increases flow increases flow increases flow increases
I II III IV V VI
** *** *** **
AGI -0.620 -0.305 -0.634 -0.376 -0.726 -0.072
-2.50 -1.41 -2.76 -1.60 -5.34 2.12
***
CEO Ownership -0.283 -0.082 -1.031 -0.482 -0.635 0.512
-0.26 -0.09 -0.98 -0.52 -1.57 3.99
*** ** *** *** *** **
Cash Flow 1.017 0.456 0.670 0.575 0.842 0.721
6.81 2.53 3.83 4.11 4.74 2.25
* *** ***
Firm Size 0.025 0.022 0.046 0.023 0.063 0.033
1.64 1.60 2.95 1.49 3.88 0.25
** *
Market-to-Book -0.011 0.012 0.005 0.001 0.030 0.038
-1.04 1.05 0.46 0.08 2.07 1.94
*** *** *** ** *** **
Cash Flow Volatility -0.042 -0.025 -0.063 -0.023 -0.020 -0.043
-3.77 -2.63 -5.61 -2.49 -2.62 -2.21
** ***
Analyst Following 0.031 0.001 0.011 -0.023 -0.068 0.041
1.39 0.05 0.47 -1.09 -2.05 3.06
** *** **
CEO Stock Options -0.010 -0.006 -0.013 -0.025 -0.061 0.006
-0.98 -0.60 -1.11 -2.09 -3.64 2.09
** *
Firm Taxes 0.001 -0.018 -0.002 0.000 0.007 -0.002
0.80 -2.45 -1.43 0.07 1.77 -1.45
** ***
Liquidity 0.016 0.022 0.031 0.022 -0.053 0.097
1.20 1.61 2.14 1.47 -0.30 6.00
Obs. 1390 1385 1260 1162 5564 5564
R2 0.24 0.27 0.15 0.18
Adj. R2 0.20 0.24 0.11 0.13
2
Pseudo R 0.15 0.15

41

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2504715


Table 6. Governance shocks
Panel A presents OLS regressions of ∆Div for years [-1,+1] around state antitakeover law adoption (Column I) and for years
1983–1991 (Columns II-III). Antitakeover Law Adopted equals 1 in the year of the passage and the year following the passage of
a state antitakeover law. Antitakeover Laws Index assigns 1 for each of the three antitakeover laws in Bertrand and Mullainathan
(2003). D(Antitakeover Law) equals 1 if Antitakeover Laws Index is positive; 0 otherwise.
Panel B presents OLS regressions of DiffDiv (Column I) and first differences in ∆Div (Column II) on first differences in Absolute
AGI (constructed using actual values of continuous and discrete governance characteristics) for years 2001–2003. Column III
presents OLS regressions of Div on Post-Reform x No Indep. Director Majority Before to estimate the effect of governance
reforms for firms lacking independent director majority on the board in 2000. Column IV presents OLS regressions of Div on
Post-Reform x No Indep. Director Majority Before x Indep. Director Majority After to estimate the effect of governance reforms
for firms lacking independent director majority on the board in 2000 that established an independent director majority on the
board in 2002 and onwards, for years 2000–2004.
Sample and variable definitions are presented in Appendix A. Dividend is the annual dividend per share from Compustat Annual
in Panel A and the annual ordinary dividend per share (CRSP, distribution code 1232) adjusted for stock dividends and splits in
Panel B. Execucomp data starts in 1992, so Panel A omits CEO Ownership and CEO Stock Options. Regressions include Fama-
French industry dummies. Panel B includes year dummies. Panel A, Column III includes year trend. Robust t-statistics clustered
by firm are in parentheses. Significance at 1%, 5%, and 10% levels is denoted with ***, **, and *, respectively.

Panel A: Antitakeover laws


Dependent variable: ∆Div ∆Div ∆Div
Sample period: [-1,+1] 1983–1991 1983–1991
I II III
***
Antitakeover Law Adopted 0.122
2.61
***
Antitakeover Laws Index 0.039
3.71
**
D(Antitakeover Law) 0.049
1.97
** *** ***
Cash Flow 0.689 1.063 1.088
1.99 5.31 5.40
Firm size -0.020 -0.013 -0.013
-0.62 -0.80 -0.83
** *** ***
Market-to-Book -0.077 -0.066 -0.071
-2.01 -2.73 -2.94
Firm risk -0.022 0.004 0.004
-0.73 0.25 0.25
Analyst following 0.010 0.001 -0.002
0.47 0.04 -0.15
Firm taxes 0.031 0.011 0.011
0.31 0.17 0.17
Liquidity 0.018 -0.007 -0.007
0.64 -0.51 -0.51
Obs. 1136 3773 3773
R2 0.04 0.03 0.03
2
Adj. R 0.00 0.01 0.01

42

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2504715


Panel B: Post-Enron governance reforms
Dependent variable: DiffDiv Diff. in ∆Div Div Div
Period: 2001–03 2001–03 2000–04 2000–04
I II III IV
** **
Change in Abs. AGI -0.193 -0.561
-2.36 -2.21
**
Post-Reform x No Indep. Director Majority Before -0.114
-2.32
Post-Reform x No Indep. Director Majority Before x -0.137 **
Indep. Director Majority After -2.57
*
CEO Ownership 0.118 0.077 1.487 1.451
1.75 0.44 1.11 1.09
*** *** ** **
Cash Flow 0.263 0.608 0.397 0.399
3.90 5.07 1.99 2.00
*** ***
Firm size 0.008 0.015 0.145 0.146
1.38 1.33 5.75 5.81
**
Market-to-Book -0.001 -0.022 -0.011 -0.011
-0.38 -2.00 -0.74 -0.72
* **
Firm risk -0.009 -0.023 0.011 0.011
-1.81 -2.29 0.53 0.52
* *** ***
Analyst following 0.012 0.012 -0.105 -0.104
1.68 0.87 -4.37 -4.36
CEO stock options 0.000 0.000 -0.014 -0.013
-0.01 -0.01 -0.92 -0.84
** *** ***
Firm taxes -0.002 0.014 -0.010 -0.010
-0.51 2.07 -3.10 -3.09
*** * *** ***
Liquidity -0.025 -0.044 -0.323 -0.328
-2.72 -1.95 -9.81 -9.71
Obs. 1259 1249 1894 1894
2
R 0.15 0.13 0.40 0.40
Adj. R2 0.12 0.09 0.39 0.38

43

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2504715


Table 7. Intertemporal payout behavior
OLS regressions of total payout changes and persistence. Tests do not reject exogeneity of the interaction of governance
measures and lagged payout, governance and CEO Ownership, so OLS is used. Multinomial logit regression of the form of
payout decreases (Column III) using the categorical variable that takes on 1 in case of no decrease in payout; 2 decrease in
repurchases only; 3 decrease in dividends. Multinomial logit regression of the form of payout increases (Column IV) using the
categorical variable that takes on 1 in case of no increase in payout; 2 increase in repurchases only; 3 increase in dividends. The
portion of the results for the likelihood of a dividend decrease (increase) versus a decrease (increase) in repurchases only is
reported. Sample and variable definitions are presented in Appendix A. Regressions include Fama-French industry dummies,
year dummies, and change in industry median dividend. Robust t(z) statistics clustered by firm are in parentheses. Significance at
1%, 5%, and 10% levels is denoted with ***, **, and *, respectively.

Form of payout Form of payout


decreases: increases:
DiffPayout ∆Payout
dividends vs. dividends vs.
repurchases only repurchases only
I II III IV
***
LagPayout -0.480
-8.95
**
LagPayout*AGI -0.185
-2.39
** *** ***
AGI 0.006 -0.969 0.074 -0.807
1.64 -2.16 4.16 -4.88
CEO Ownership -4.5E-04 0.330 -0.045 -0.008
-0.07 0.61 -0.90 -0.85
*** ** *** ***
Cash Flow 0.018 0.969 -0.255 1.611
5.89 2.34 -6.51 4.02
*** *** ** **
Firm Size 0.001 0.229 -0.008 0.092
3.00 4.54 -2.47 2.21
*** *** **
Market-to-Book -0.001 0.156 0.005 0.057
-2.67 4.49 2.11 1.25
*** *** *** **
Cash Flow Volatility -0.001 -0.142 0.009 -0.063
-2.84 -3.42 3.08 -2.27
*
Analyst Following 2.5E-04 -0.045 -0.008 -0.018
0.49 -0.64 -1.68 -0.16
*** ***
CEO Stock Options 0.001 0.045 0.002 -0.048
2.83 1.31 0.76 -4.13
Firm Taxes 7.4E-05 -0.025 -0.001 0.006
0.70 -1.38 -0.31 0.41
*** ***
Liquidity -0.003 0.101 0.016 0.026
-5.00 1.57 5.51 1.00
Obs. 7704 7704 5564 5564
R2 0.32 0.03
Adj. R2 0.31 0.02
2
Pseudo R 0.09 0.14

44

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2504715


Table 8. Changes in overall commitment (to shareholders and debtholders)
2SLS regressions of ∆Div (Columns I-II) and OLS estimation of ∆Commit (Column III). Tests do not reject the exogeneity of
governance and CEO Ownership, so OLS is used. The added instruments include median ratio of tangible assets to total assets,
plus median leverage ratio (Column I) or median change in interest payments (Column II) at the industry state level. Regressions
include Fama-French industry dummies, year dummies, and change in industry median dividend or commitment. Robust t-
statistics clustered by firm are in parentheses. Significance at 1%, 5%, and 10% levels is denoted with ***, **, and *, respectively.

Dependent variable: ∆Div ∆Div ∆Commit


I II III
*** *** **
AGI -0.703 -0.694 -0.124
-4.20 -4.37 -1.96
***
∆Leverage -1.698
-5.73
**
∆Interest -2.748
-2.34
* * **
CEO Ownership -1.519 -1.238 0.293
-1.88 -1.67 2.51
*** *** ***
Cash Flow 0.654 0.647 0.568
5.69 7.01 7.50
***
Firm size -0.009 0.006 -0.062
-0.75 0.62 -6.80
***
Market-to-Book -0.003 0.000 -0.054
-0.38 0.04 -9.27
** *** ***
Firm risk -0.018 -0.028 0.045
-2.32 -4.28 5.59
***
Analyst following 0.019 0.014 0.055
1.25 0.97 4.85
*
CEO stock options -0.013 -0.011 0.001
-1.65 -1.54 0.09
Firm taxes 0.001 0.001 0.003
0.35 0.69 1.33
Liquidity 0.006 0.012 0.005
0.57 1.35 0.42
Obs. 5564 5564 9253
2
R -0.01 0.15 0.089
Adj. R2 -0.02 0.14 0.083

45

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2504715


Table 9. Corporate governance and dividend behavior: interaction effects
OLS regressions of ∆Div. Sample and variable definitions are presented in the Appendix. AGI is interacted with ∆Cash Flow
(change in Cash Flow scaled by lagged Cash Flow); High Free Cash Flow (equals 1 if Cash Flow is positive and Market-to-Book
or sales growth is below three-digit SIC industry median); Ext. Fin. Dependence Ind. (three-digit SIC industry median ratio of net
external financing issues to total assets); Past Performance Ind. (lagged three-digit SIC industry median of average monthly
return in excess of CRSP value-weighted index return); Past Performance Ind. Adj. (lagged average monthly return in excess of
CRSP value-weighted index return, minus Past Performance Ind.); Dividend Premium (difference of the log of asset-weighted
market-to-book for dividend-paying firms and for zero-dividend firms at the three-digit SIC industry level, two-digit SIC industry
level if not available, or one-digit SIC industry level if not available). Regressions include Fama-French industry dummies, year
dummies, dummies for the year of entry into CRSP database, and change in industry median dividend. Robust t(z) statistics
clustered by firm are in parentheses. Significance at 1%, 5%, and 10% levels is denoted with ***, **, and *, respectively.
I II III IV V VI
*** *** *** *** *** ***
AGI -0.237 -0.214 -0.245 -0.226 -0.235 -0.234
-4.62 -4.10 -4.90 -4.24 -4.31 -4.58
**
AGI*Cash Flow Change -0.039
-2.11
**
AGI*High Free Cash Flow -0.037
-2.41
***
AGI*Ext. Fin. Dependence Ind. -2.128
-3.77
***
AGI*Past Performance Ind. 2.217
4.33
***
AGI*Past Performance Ind. Adj. 3.843
7.80
**
AGI*Dividend Premium -0.046
-2.12
*** *** *** *** *** ***
CEO Ownership 0.261 0.257 0.269 0.298 0.273 0.263
2.69 2.67 2.85 3.02 2.67 2.77
*** *** *** *** *** ***
Profitability 0.711 0.674 0.676 0.624 0.576 0.690
8.01 7.80 8.06 7.18 6.69 8.02
*** *** *** *** *** ***
Firm size 0.027 0.026 0.025 0.023 0.023 0.025
4.14 3.91 3.82 3.24 3.33 3.85
Market-to-Book -0.002 -0.004 -0.001 -0.004 -0.004 -0.001
-0.40 -0.66 -0.18 -0.63 -0.67 -0.12
*** *** *** *** *** ***
Firm risk -0.035 -0.034 -0.036 -0.034 -0.032 -0.034
-5.98 -5.80 -6.26 -5.49 -5.25 -5.85
*** *** *** *** *** ***
Analyst following 0.032 0.032 0.035 0.039 0.035 0.033
3.12 3.23 3.47 3.75 3.33 3.31
CEO stock options -0.006 -0.006 -0.008 -0.006 -0.005 -0.007
-1.09 -1.12 -1.37 -1.10 -0.93 -1.23
Firm taxes 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001
0.85 0.86 0.80 1.05 1.04 0.87
Liquidity 0.009 0.008 0.009 0.000 -0.007 0.008
1.10 0.97 1.11 0.02 -0.76 0.99
***
Equity Dependence Ind. 1.283
3.81
*
Stock Performance 0.263 0.377
1.32 1.77
Obs. 5561 5564 5434 5117 4837 5564
R2 0.20 0.20 0.20 0.21 0.23 0.20
Adj. R2 0.19 0.19 0.19 0.20 0.22 0.19

46

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2504715


Table 10. Robustness: estimation methodology, selection criteria, and variable definitions
Sample and variable definitions are presented in Appendix A.
Panel A presents probit regressions of D_DivDecr (Column I) and D_DivIncr (Column II) with firm random effects; firm fixed
effects regression of ∆Div (Column III); simultaneous equations regressions of ∆Div (Column IV) (AGI and CEO Ownership
equations include ∆Div, controls from the main equation, and instruments); and OLS regressions of ∆Div on one-year lags of
AGI and CEO Ownership (Column V) and changes in AGI and CEO Ownership (Column VI).
Panel B presents 2SLS regressions of ∆Div on alternative AGI measures: Column I - AGI Below Median and AGI Above Median,
equal to AGI when AGI is below (above) sample median, and equal to 0 otherwise (industry proportion of firms with AGI above
median is used as an additional instrument); Column II - AGI (Abs.), defined using actual values of continuous governance
variables rescaled to [0,1] instead of firm rankings (industry governance and governance premium instruments are redefined
accordingly). Column III uses Aggregate Governance Factors (AGF) based on factor analysis of underlying governance
characteristics included in AGI (eigenvalues above 1 were used to select AGF and labels were based on governance
characteristics with highest factor loadings): AGF1 Blockholder Presence/Concentration (largest blockholding, blockholder
presence, concentration of blockholdings); AGF2 Coordination of Blockholders/Board (number of institutional investors, number
of public pension fund blockholders, low board size); AGF3 Board Committee/CEO Separation (CEO is not a member of any of
the four key committees / nominating committee / corporate governance committee); AGF4 Single Class of Shares; AGF5 Weak
External Governance (classified board, limits to amend bylaws, limits to call special meetings, limits for written consent); AGF6
Board Independence (fraction of independent directors, low fraction of employee directors, largest public pension fund
blockholding); AGF7 CEO Characteristics (young age, short tenure). AGF explain 86.6% of variation in underlying variables,
with Cronbach’s α of 0.74 indicating considerable unidimensionality of underlying variables and reliability of AGF. Industry
governance instruments are redefined accordingly. Column IV uses ISS Factors (ISSF) based on factor analysis of Institutional
Shareholder Services (ISS) Corporate Governance Quotient characteristics for 2001–2004: ISSF1 Boards/Governance 1 (board
independence, governance committee, board governance guidelines, stock ownership guidelines); ISSF2 Boards/Governance 2
(committee independence, board governance guidelines, reasonable cost of option plan); ISSF3 Weak External Governance
(majority vote requirements to approve mergers and to amend charter/bylaws, classified board, poison pill). ISSF explain 85.4%
of variation in underlying variables. Cronbach’s α of 0.70 indicates reliability of ISSF. Industry governance instruments are
redefined accordingly.
Panel C presents 2SLS regressions of ∆Div (Column I); ∆Div2 in the full sample (Column III); ∆Div3 in the sample of past
payers (Column III) and in the full sample (Column IV). Additional controls are introduced.
Panel D presents 2SLS regressions of ∆Div (Columns I-II) and probit regressions of D_DivDecr with correction for endogeneity
(Columns IV-VI). The probit model with correction for endogeneity is estimated using Newey’s two-step efficient estimation.
Panels E and F use the 1996–2009 sample period and control for additional industry and regional variation. Panels present logit
regressions of D_DivDecr (for past dividend payers) and D_DivIncr (for past dividend payers and the full sample) and OLS
regressions of ∆Div and dividend smoothing (DiffDiv on LagDiv) for past dividend payers. We use Compustat data on common
dividends per share. Panel E uses three-digit SIC industry dummies instead of Fama-French industry dummies. Panel F adds
location dummies at the county level. The results are highly robust.
In Panels A-D and F, regressions include Fama-French industry dummies (unless firm effects are included), year dummies and
change in industry median dividend (Panel A, Columns IV-VI; Panel B; Panel C; Panel D, Columns I-II). In Panel C, regressions
include dummies for year of entry into CRSP. In Panel E, regressions include three-digit SIC industry dummies. In Panel F,
regressions include county dummies are included. Robust t(z) statistics clustered by firm are in parentheses. Significance at 1%,
5%, and 10% levels is denoted with ***, **, and *, respectively.

47

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2504715


Panel A: Alternative estimation methodology and causality checks
Dependent variable: D_DivDecr D_DivIncr ∆Div ∆Div ∆Div ∆Div
Model: Random effects probit Fixed effects 2SLS OLS OLS
I II III IV V VI
*** *** *** ***
AGI 0.144 -0.855 -0.361 -0.688
3.93 -5.71 -4.83 -5.36
***
Lag AGI -0.209
-4.81
**
∆AGI -0.210
-2.37
* * **
CEO Ownership -0.129 0.564 -0.136 -1.222
-1.65 1.72 -0.71 -2.05
***
Lag CEO Ownership 0.259
3.10
***
∆ CEO Ownership -1.071
-3.58
*** *** *** *** *** ***
Cash Flow -0.447 2.119 0.890 0.657 0.610 0.602
-9.80 12.63 12.36 10.85 7.60 7.42
*** *** *** *** ***
Firm size -0.015 0.064 0.048 0.008 0.037 0.040
-2.97 3.03 3.04 1.01 5.96 6.52
* ** **
Market-to-Book 0.007 0.039 0.013 0.001 -0.003 -0.001
1.75 2.44 1.97 0.20 -0.49 -0.27
*** ** *** *** ***
Firm risk 0.018 -0.019 -0.015 -0.030 -0.033 -0.034
4.49 -1.31 -2.32 -5.44 -6.48 -6.53
*** *** ** *
Analyst following -0.020 0.076 0.064 0.013 0.016 0.015
-3.16 2.88 4.85 1.20 2.01 1.81
** **
CEO stock options 0.005 -0.035 -0.006 -0.011 0.000 -0.001
1.62 -2.45 -0.91 -2.45 -0.05 -0.22
Firm taxes -0.001 0.007 0.002 0.001 0.002 0.002
-0.87 1.24 1.11 0.43 0.97 1.09
*** *
Liquidity 0.030 0.012 -0.011 0.013 -0.002 -0.002
5.19 0.51 -1.00 1.66 -0.21 -0.29
*** ***
Lag ∆Div 0.273 0.281
7.62 7.88
AGI equation -0.004
∆Div -0.33
CEO Ownership equation 0.011
∆Div 1.50
Obs. 5564 5564 5564 5564 4768 4768
2
R (within) 0.11
2
Pseudo-R 0.10 0.10
R2 0.26 0.25
2
Adj. R 0.25 0.24

48

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2504715


Panel B: Alternative measures of governance and managerial alignment
I II III IV
***
AGI Below Median -1.442
-3.55
***
AGI Above Median -1.199
-3.68
***
AGI (Abs.) -1.276
-2.92
***
AGF1: Blockholder Presence/Concentration -0.031
-2.99
*
AGF2: Coordination of Blockholders/Board -0.036
-1.68
AGF3: Board Committee/CEO Separation -0.001
-0.20
***
AGF4: Single Class of Shares -0.026
-2.56
AGF5: Weak External Governance -0.001
-0.08
**
AGF6: Board Independence -0.046
-2.44
**
AGF7: CEO Characteristics -0.047
-2.01
**
ISSF1: Boards/Governance 1 -0.038
-2.00
ISSF2: Boards/Governance 2 0.000
-0.02
**
ISSF3: Weak External Governance 0.033
1.98
* ***
CEO Ownership -1.382 1.337 -2.087 0.003
-1.72 3.05 -1.54 0.01
*** *** *** ***
Cash Flow 0.646 0.667 0.620 0.944
6.88 7.63 6.13 3.43
***
Firm size 0.005 0.023 -0.009 0.023
0.47 2.61 -0.58 1.43
Market-to-Book 0.000 -0.007 -0.004 -0.028
-0.05 -0.89 -0.57 -1.43
*** *** *** ***
Firm risk -0.029 -0.033 -0.031 -0.052
-4.18 -5.02 -4.37 -3.23
*** ***
Analyst following 0.015 0.044 0.006 0.067
1.01 3.58 0.35 2.58
*
CEO stock options -0.013 0.001 -0.009 0.020
-1.64 0.13 -1.16 1.92
Firm taxes 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.005
0.76 0.85 0.90 1.10
Liquidity 0.013 0.009 0.012 -0.018
1.37 1.05 1.25 -0.51
Obs. 5564 5564 5564 1077
R2 0.11 0.13 0.11 0.32
Adj. R2 0.10 0.12 0.10 0.28

49

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2504715


Panel C: Alternative measures of dividends, controls, sample selection criteria
Dependent variable: ∆Div ∆Div2 ∆Div3 ∆Div3
Model: 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS
Sample: Past dividend payers Full sample Past dividend payers Full sample
I II III IV
*** *** *** ***
AGI -0.809 -1.407 -0.420 -0.523
-3.98 -4.43 -2.81 -3.76
** ***
CEO Ownership -1.973 -3.618 -0.073 -0.939
-2.09 -2.62 -0.12 -1.57
*** *** *** ***
Profitability 0.598 0.244 0.576 0.198
6.35 3.42 6.77 5.76
* **
Firm size 0.017 -0.033 0.022 0.001
1.37 -1.89 2.47 0.11
Market-to-Book -1.4E-04 0.002 -0.009 0.002
-0.02 0.27 -1.48 0.79
*** * *** **
Firm risk -0.024 -0.015 -0.014 -0.008
-3.23 -1.88 -2.57 -2.43
Analyst following -0.002 0.018 0.016 0.004
-0.11 1.03 1.39 0.48
* **
CEO stock options -0.015 -0.019 -0.003 -0.005
-1.74 -2.04 -0.63 -1.26
Firm taxes 0.001 -0.001 3.3E-04 -1.5E-04
0.66 -0.42 0.18 -0.13
*
Liquidity 0.018 -0.008 -0.010 -0.007
1.68 -0.69 -1.36 -1.20
*** ***
Retained Earnings 0.167 0.021 0.080 0.005
4.98 1.57 2.97 0.95
*
Stock Performance 0.125 0.186 0.298 0.107
0.63 1.29 1.76 1.46
Tangible Assets -0.037 -0.013 -0.036 -0.002
-0.91 -0.25 -1.29 -0.07
* ** *
Bond Rating -0.028 -0.041 -0.015 -0.016
-1.80 -2.07 -1.44 -1.89
Obs. 5523 9802 6043 9804
2
R 0.12 -0.18 0.14 0.01
2
Adj. R 0.10 -0.19 0.12 -4.0E-03

50

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2504715


Panel D: Financial distress
Dependent variable: ∆Div ∆Div D_DivDecr D_DivDecr D_DivDecr D_DivDecr
Model: 2SLS 2SLS Probit with correction for endogeneity
I II III IV V VI
*** *** ***
AGI -0.717 0.030 0.029
-4.04 3.34 3.09
* *** ***
Board Monitoring -0.152 0.012 0.012
-1.94 2.96 2.81
** *** ***
Blockholders -0.108 0.008 0.008
-2.06 2.59 2.75
** * *
CEO Characteristics -0.157 0.007 0.008
-2.25 1.88 1.87
*
External Governance -0.163 0.002 0.001
-1.80 0.42 0.12
*** * *
Single Class of Shares -0.109 0.327 0.306
-3.35 1.78 1.65
*
CEO Ownership -1.561 -1.473 0.061 0.100 0.046 0.107
-1.82 -1.06 1.42 1.31 1.07 1.30
*** *** *** *** *** ***
Cash Flow 0.602 0.607 -0.037 -0.035 -0.037 -0.035
6.47 6.32 -8.50 -7.82 -8.49 -7.74
* *
Firm Size 0.007 0.009 -0.119 -0.084 -0.112 -0.055
0.60 0.71 -1.91 -1.18 -1.71 -0.69
*** *** *** *** ** **
Market-to-Book -0.034 -0.033 0.256 0.252 0.096 0.088
-3.55 -3.49 5.22 5.08 2.50 2.08
*** *** *** *** *** ***
Firm Risk -0.027 -0.027 0.142 0.130 0.158 0.141
-3.63 -3.48 3.61 3.06 4.08 3.33
Analyst Following 0.016 0.017 -0.053 -0.012 -0.062 0.000
1.00 0.91 -0.70 -0.14 -0.82 0.00
CEO Stock Options -0.012 -0.012 0.046 0.054 0.045 0.060
-1.48 -1.42 1.52 1.49 1.46 1.53
Firm Taxes 0.001 0.001 -0.008 -0.010 -0.009 -0.010
0.66 0.70 -0.53 -0.61 -0.55 -0.63
*** *** *** ***
Liquidity 0.010 0.010 0.244 0.246 0.243 0.244
1.00 1.01 4.73 4.68 4.71 4.60
*** *** *** ***
z-score 0.018 0.018 -0.106 -0.104
3.46 3.40 -5.11 -4.75
*** ***
z-score>3 -0.290 -0.247
-4.20 -3.19
Obs. 5238 5238
2
R 0.12 0.12
Adj. R2 0.11 0.11
2
Pseudo-R 0.15 0.15 0.15 0.15

51

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2504715


Panel E: Extending the sample period and controlling for additional industry variation
Dependent variable: D_DivDecr D_DivIncr D_DivIncr ∆Div
Sample: Past dividend payers Past dividend payers Full sample Past dividend payers
I II III IV V VI VII VIII
*** *** *** *** *** *** * *
AGI2 0.986 0.979 -1.030 -1.033 -1.607 -1.606 -0.103 -0.102
2.80 2.78 -2.58 -2.60 -4.42 -4.42 -1.70 -1.69
Single Class
0.159 0.112 -0.027 -0.015
of Shares
1.22 0.66 -0.16 -0.74
*** *** *** *** *** *** *** ***
Cash Flow -3.092 -3.107 5.318 5.301 5.008 5.011 0.874 0.876
-5.77 -5.79 9.09 9.11 11.49 11.54 8.85 8.85
*** *** *** *** *** ***
Firm Size 0.000 -0.005 0.283 0.280 0.468 0.468 0.015 0.015
-0.01 -0.16 7.37 7.35 12.54 12.55 3.03 3.05
*** *** ** *
Market-to-Book 0.213 0.211 -0.006 -0.008 -0.045 -0.045 -0.018 -0.018
5.31 5.27 -0.13 -0.15 -1.24 -1.23 -1.97 -1.95
Cash Flow *** *** *** *** *** *** *** ***
0.649 0.646 -0.554 -0.556 -0.705 -0.705 -0.055 -0.055
Volatility
6.49 6.48 -4.47 -4.48 -6.01 -6.00 -2.71 -2.70
No. of obs. 6897 6897 6897 6897 13134 13134 6897 6897
Pseudo-R2 0.08 0.08 0.14 0.14 0.23 0.23
R2 0.11 0.11
2
Adj. R 0.08 0.08
(continued)
Dependent variable: DiffDiv
Sample: Past dividend payers
IX X
** **
LagDiv -0.092 -0.119
-2.54 -2.31
** **
LagDiv*AGI2 -0.190 -0.184
-2.46 -2.36
LagDiv*Single Class of Shares 0.024
0.70
*** ***
Cash Flow 0.333 0.325
8.30 8.11
*** ***
Firm Size 0.029 0.029
10.19 10.03
*** ***
Market-to-Book -0.009 -0.009
-3.01 -2.90
*** ***
Cash Flow Volatility -0.031 -0.031
-4.05 -3.99
AGI2 0.056 0.050
1.44 1.27
Single Class of Shares -0.003
-0.20
Obs. 6897 6825
R2 0.20 0.20
2
Adj. R 0.17 0.17

52

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2504715


Panel F: Extending the sample period and controlling for additional geographic variation
Dependent variable: D_DivDecr D_DivIncr D_DivIncr ∆Div
Sample: Past dividend payers Past dividend payers Full sample Past dividend payers
I II III IV
*** *** *** **
AGI2 1.313 -1.332 -1.975 -0.146
3.20 -2.87 -4.78 -2.05
*** *** *** ***
Cash Flow -3.373 5.790 5.576 0.925
-5.41 8.73 11.33 9.03
*** *** **
Firm Size 0.036 0.259 0.484 0.013
1.15 6.34 11.69 2.41
*** **
Market-to-Book 0.223 -0.034 -0.045 -0.021
4.85 -0.58 -1.04 -2.09
Cash Flow Volatility 0.737 -0.521 -0.706 -0.039
6.82 -4.03 -5.57 -1.76
Obs. 6151 6151 11576 6151
Pseudo-R2 0.10 0.17 0.27
R2 0.13
2
Adj. R 0.08
(continued)
DiffDiv
Sample: Past dividend payers
V
**
Lag_Div -0.089
-2.32
***
Lag_Div*AGI2 -0.217
-2.63
***
Cash Flow 0.377
8.88
***
Firm Size 0.027
8.31
***
Market-to-Book -0.011
-3.12
***
Cash Flow Volatility -0.026
-3.16
AGI2 0.074
1.61
Obs. 6151
R2 0.21
2
Adj. R 0.17

53

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2504715


Table 11. Market reaction to dividend announcements
Regressions of cumulative abnormal returns (CARs) around dividend announcements. Columns I, II, and IV examine dividend
increases and decreases (excluding omissions). Column III includes dividend omissions. Quarterly dividend increases and
decreases were identified from CRSP data. Dividend omissions were identified from CRSP data and FACTIVA search of major
business publications. We require that the firm have a positive lagged regular quarterly cash dividend per share on ordinary
common shares (CRSP distribution code 1232). We exclude Americus Trust components, closed-end funds, and REITs. Other
sample criteria are similar to the main sample. CARs are computed from the market model (using CRSP value-weighted return)
over the [-1,+1] event window (Columns I-III) and [-2,+2] event window (Column IV). Sample and variable definitions are
presented in Appendix A. For this table, ∆Div is the change in quarterly dividends per share. Regressions include Fama-French
industry dummies, year dummies, and industry median of the dependent variable. Robust t-statistics clustered by firm are in
parentheses. Significance at 1%, 5%, and 10% levels is denoted with ***, **, and *, respectively.

[-1,+1] (incl.
[-1,+1] [-1,+1] [-2,+2]
omissions)
I II III IV
** *** *** ***
∆Div 0.514 0.758 0.851 0.922
2.55 2.98 3.17 3.26
*** *** *** *
D_DivDecr -0.013 -0.012 -0.020 -0.011
-2.86 -2.79 -2.72 -1.83
∆Div x D_DivDecr -0.354 -0.420 -0.568 -0.537
-0.92 -1.09 -1.36 -1.20
** ** ** **
∆Div x AGI -0.882 -0.891 -0.843 -0.835
-2.38 -2.43 -2.18 -2.09
∆Div x D_DivDecr x AGI 0.803 0.829 1.096 1.039
1.15 1.19 1.47 1.27
∆Div x Cash Flow -0.557 -0.405 -0.762
-1.24 -0.88 -1.36
∆Div x Market-to-Book 0.019 -0.012 -0.007
0.52 -0.36 -0.18
∆Div x CEO Ownership -0.004 -0.002 -0.005
-0.66 -0.36 -0.99
*
∆Div x CEO Stock Options -0.032 -0.055 -0.026
-1.75 -1.63 -1.05
* *
∆Div x Analyst Following -0.054 -0.083 -0.094
-1.15 -1.76 -1.75
Obs. 3385 3334 3413 3334
2
R 0.12 0.12 0.14 0.11
Adj. R2 0.10 0.10 0.13 0.10

54

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2504715

You might also like