You are on page 1of 20

World Development Vol. 36, No. 2, pp.

325–344, 2008
Ó 2007 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved
0305-750X/$ - see front matter
www.elsevier.com/locate/worlddev
doi:10.1016/j.worlddev.2007.06.011

Breakthrough? China’s and India’s Transition


from Production to Innovation
TILMAN ALTENBURG
German Development Institute, Bonn, Germany

HUBERT SCHMITZ
Institute of Development Studies, Sussex, UK

and

ANDREAS STAMM *
German Development Institute, Bonn, Germany
Summary. — China and India have become major producers of products and services for global
markets. This article explores to what extent they are also building up innovation capabilities. It
draws on a combination of approaches—innovation systems, global value chains and professional
networks—to analyze four of the most dynamic industries. We find that mounting innovation
efforts only rarely materialized in cutting-edge innovations but suggest that if capital accumulation
proceeds at the current pace, innovation capabilities will rapidly be built up in China and, with a
time lag, India. We conclude by setting out the implications for both the developed and the devel-
oping world.
Ó 2007 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

Key words — Asia, China, India, innovation, technology, catch-up

1. INTRODUCTION started its export drive much earlier, its trade/


GDP ratio is much higher and it forms part
China’s and India’s growth and transforma- of an East Asian production network. This pro-
tion has attracted attention for two reasons: duction network has brought about a major
first, because it suggests that catching up with shift in production capability from Western
the OECD countries continues to be possible. Europe and North America to East Asia. In
Second, because it affects the whole world, fact, one of the most striking facts about the
resulting in new opportunities but also posing global distribution of industrial activities is
new threats. This has given rise to the notion the massive dispersal of production capability
of ‘‘Asian Drivers’’ of global change (see intro- away from the OECD countries to the develop-
duction to this Special Issue by Kaplinsky and ing world, in particular to East Asia. The mag-
Messner). The Asian Driver hypothesis is radi- nitude and speed of change in the global
cal: it says that while the OECD countries con- distribution of production capability is histori-
tinue to be important, the change comes cally unprecedented.
primarily from Asia, in particular China but
increasingly also India. This hypothesis has be-
gun to define the agenda of global political
economy—for both researchers and policy * The authors are grateful for very constructive
makers. comments from Raphie Kaplinsky, Rasmus Lema, and
In the case of China, the external effects are two anonymous referees. Final revision accepted: June 4,
much bigger than those of India because it 2007.
325
326 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

In contrast, innovation capabilities have shown in the literature on the Asian Tigers
remained remarkably concentrated in the Euro- (e.g., Hobday, 1995) but China and India are
pean Union, United States, and Japan. different in a way which is critical for the build-
However, this is beginning to change. There up of innovation capabilities. The combination
are indications that China and India are devel- of their large size and fast growth transforms
oping significant innovation capabilities. the dynamics in a number of ways. At least this
Although OECD countries are still ahead in is what we hypothesize in Section 2. The large
virtually all technological fields, the gap sepa- and growing internal market and the enormous
rating them from China and India has nar- capital accumulation resulting from long peri-
rowed within a few years. If the catch-up ods of fast growth give government and firms
process continues at the current pace, the Asian exceptional power to purchase, negotiate, and
Drivers could have major effects on both the trade which needs to be taken into account if
developed and developing world—albeit in dif- we want to understand China’s and India’s pro-
ferent ways. The European Union, United cess of catching up.
States, and Japan compete above all on the Attempts to come to an overall judgement
basis of their innovative power. Will the bed- concerning the innovative power of Chinese
rock of their prosperity crumble? Developing or Indian industry have yielded poor results.
countries may benefit from imports of cheaper This is shown in Section 3 which tries to assess
and more appropriate technology-based prod- the progress made on the basis of available
ucts, but may find it even more difficult to overall indicators. Section 4 therefore analyzes
upgrade into the respective markets if China four specific industrial sectors which, even
and India successfully combine cutting-edge though based on secondary sources, provide
technological capabilities and low-cost produc- initial answers to our main question. The ob-
tion. served differences in trajectories underline the
Before investigating such repercussions, we difficulty of generalization. We show, however,
need to understand whether and how China that in all four cases, China and India have
and India are progressing from production to managed to narrow the technological gap but
innovation. This is the question which drives their innovation capabilities do not yet suffice
this paper. The problem is that this is an area to seriously challenge global technological lead-
of enormous uncertainty, marked by big ers. Furthermore, we highlight how in each sec-
knowledge gaps and controversy. While some tor the interaction of national and international
authors predict a substantial shift in the global forces is critical to understand the dynamics.
distribution of innovation activities, others Section 5 summarizes the findings and dis-
stress that China’s and India’s innovative capa- sects which trends favor technological catch-
bilities remain weak. Dissecting the claims and up and which ones might hamper it. All in all,
counterclaims and constructing a convincing we are optimistic about the prospects for
account from the fragments of evidence are catch-up, especially in China, provided the
not easy. This paper therefore combines taking two countries succeed in handling certain over-
stock and framing questions for future all economic and political risks.
research. Throughout, our search for answers Section 6 reflects on the implications for the
is guided by both theory and attention to con- OECD countries and the developing world.
text specificity. Given the unclear picture and remaining risks
The paper is structured as follows: Section 2 for catch-up in China and India it presents sce-
provides the analytical groundwork, stressing narios and questions for future research rather
that no single approach is sufficient to under- than wild speculation on the future. Overall,
stand the catch-up process. The innovation sys- the article re-affirms that the global distribution
tems approach provides the key elements and of innovation activities is beginning to shift
relationships at the local and national level eastwards but that the speed and depth of this
but has no analytical grip on the trans-border shift remain unclear.
relationships which are important to under- A brief clarification on terminology: in order
stand the buildup of innovation capabilities. to make a judgement on whether and how Chi-
We draw therefore on the global value chain na and India are catching up with the major
and professional network approaches to bring OECD countries, we need to define what we
in the global connections. mean by catching up. If one defines catching
The need to focus on the mutual reinforce- up in terms of the ability to compete on the
ment of local and global linkages has been basis of factor cost advantages, there is no
BREAKTHROUGH? CHINA’S AND INDIA’S TRANSITION 327

question that China (and to a lesser extent China and India are developing processes,
India) have caught up. In many sectors, the products or services new to the world (cut-
share of China in global markets has risen rap- ting-edge innovations).
idly, in particular at the expense of OECD
countries. Catching up in this sense is about
the accumulation of production capabilities 1— 2. ANALYTICAL FRAMEWORKS
which can be done by using and adapting exist-
ing knowledge. When we refer to catching up in While there is little hard evidence on the
this paper, we mean something more ambi- extent to which China and India have built up
tious: the transition from production to innova- innovation capabilities, there is a flurry of
tion capabilities. We define the latter in terms of analyses suggesting that the OECD monopoly
creating new knowledge and putting it to pro- in innovation is breaking up and that new
ductive use. innovation capabilities are emerging in China
This distinction between production and and India. A key feature of this debate is that
innovation capabilities draws on the work of the authors focus on a few specific factors
Bell and Pavitt (1995), Bell and Albu (1999), which contribute to the buildup of innovation
Figeuiredo (2001), Ariffin and Figueiredo capabilities, deduced from a specific approach.
(2004). We recognize that the distinction is The main argument in this section is that no
problematic. Using it specifically in this paper single approach is sufficient, that we need to
is problematic because the case material on combine analytical frameworks to capture the
China and India is rarely organized around this buildup of innovation capabilities in China
distinction. Using it more generally is problem- and India.
atic because innovation often involves
knowledge adaptation. And this knowledge (a) The innovation systems approach
adaptation can be considered both part of the
production and part of the innovation capabil- This approach has been used to analyze both
ity. Often there is a continuum between the the Chinese and Indian achievements (Krish-
two. However, as stressed by Bell (1984) a long nan, 2007; Li, 2005) and is probably the most
time ago, there is no automatic continuum. On influential approach worldwide. The starting
the contrary, over the recent decades, the two point for innovation systems research is that
have decoupled. While products and services innovation is an interactive process (Lundvall,
made in China and India (and other developing 1988). This was a significant departure from
countries) conquered world markets, there was the previously dominant approach which
no corresponding accumulation of innovation focused on what happened inside the firm.
capabilities in these countries. The question is The interaction between producer and user
whether this is now changing. became the focus of analysis—the relationships
Our use of the term ‘‘catching up’’ is also which producers and users have with special-
related to the distinction between production ized support institutions. The innovation
and innovation capabilities. The buildup of system consists of the enterprises which pro-
production capabilities often entails adapting duce and use innovation and the public and
existing knowledge and thus minor innova- private organizations which carry out basic
tions. For the purpose of this paper, technolog- and applied research, train, advise, fund, coor-
ical catch-up has occurred when more than dinate, and regulate.
such minor adaptations have been made. The central proposition of the innovation
‘‘Technological’’ can be both in the hard sense, systems approach is that the innovative capa-
new knowledge embodied in machinery, and in bility depends on the density and quality of
the soft sense, new knowledge reflected in new relationships among enterprises and the rela-
ways of organizing the firm or the supply chain. tionships between enterprises and support insti-
This gives rise to the question of ‘‘new to tutions. Hence the approach goes much beyond
whom’’? The OECD (1997) guidelines for traditional approaches which suggest that
collecting and using innovation data (Oslo government should limit itself to providing a
Manual) distinguish between different degrees liberal business environment and investing in
of novelty: new to the firm, new to the coun- human capital, but regard supporting specific
try/region/relevant market, and new to the sectors, clusters or networks as frills which
world. While taking into account this contin- complicate the story and have at best marginal
uum, our ultimate question is to what extent explanatory power.
328 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

Initially the focus was on the national innova- external actors. Therein lies the case for
tion system (Freeman, 1995), but then it tended combining it with two recent approaches that
to shift to regional or local innovation systems enable us to understand these external linkages:
(Iammarino, 2005). This occurred for two rea- the global value chain and the global
sons: there are enormous variations within professional network approach. These latter
countries, especially big countries, and geo- approaches, however, are weak when it comes
graphical and cultural proximity facilitate the to understanding the local organizational and
interactive process which is at the heart of the institutional context, hence our argument for
innovation systems research. In other words, combining them with the innovation system
innovation is regarded as a socially and spa- approach. 4
tially embedded interactive learning process The need to draw on the global value chain
that cannot be understood independently of approach is particularly glaring in the Chinese
its region-specific institutional and cultural con- case. As shown by Enright, Scott, and Chang
text. This perspective has led to a rich stream of (2005), the rapid growth of Chinese manufac-
research, mainly in OECD countries (Braczyk, tured exports can only be understood if we
Cooke, & Heidenreich, 1998; Edquist, 1997) grasp the insertion of Chinese enterprises into
but increasingly also in developing countries global value chains. What insights can we
(Cassiolato, Lastres, & Maciel, 2003). It is fur- derive from the global value chain approach
ther supported by the research on industrial for our concern of trying to understand the
clusters which does not always focus on innova- transition from production to innovation capa-
tion but underlines the importance of synergies bilities?
and interaction for competitiveness (Porter, To answer this question one needs to start
2001; Schmitz & Nadvi, 1999). 2 with the acquisition of production capabilities.
Taken together, these studies have trans- The speed with which these capabilities were
formed our understanding of why some coun- acquired is due to the integration of developing
tries or regions succeed and others fail. The country producers into chains co-ordinated by
problem is that they only depict part of the lead firms based in the United States, European
story and fail in two respects: Union, or Japan—or their intermediaries from
First, the innovation systems approach has Taiwan and Hong Kong. The rapid acquisition
no analytical grip on the relationships to key of production capabilities results from the dual
actors outside the region. Therefore we empha- role of these lead firms: they are extremely
size the need to integrate the analysis of territo- demanding but they also need to provide con-
rially bounded innovation systems with structive monitoring so that these demands
approaches that focus on trans-border linkages are met. This does not mean all producers join-
(Humphrey & Schmitz, 2002). ing such value chains can expect to learn fast
Second, the understanding of the dynamics of from their customers. Lead firms only provide
innovation systems remains poor. 3 How do the this support where they define the product
structures of interaction develop and change and where they perceive a risk of supplier fail-
over time? There is very little understanding ure (Schmitz, 2006). This has been the typical
about the emergence of knowledge-creating situation in much sourcing from China and
systems in contexts previously limited to other low income countries. In this sense the
knowledge using and little understanding of global value chain approach helps to explain
the timescales involved (Bell, 2006). the massive and rapid dispersal of production
capabilities away from the OECD countries.
(b) Conceptualizing external linkages As regards the spread of innovation capabili-
ties, the approach is more ambiguous, revealing
The innovation systems approach is weak both forces that might block and constellations
when it comes to understanding the role of that accelerate the dispersion of innovation
external linkages. Yet these external linkages activities. To explain this, one needs to distin-
are very important in complementing or trans- guish between different types of chains with dif-
forming the internal linkages. Innovation sys- ferent power constellations. In captive chains
tems analysis is not blind to the operation of (Gereffi, Humphrey, & Sturgeon, 2005), the
external players and relationships but it can global buyer has co-ordinating power and can
only acknowledge their relevance in a descrip- set the terms under which other firms in the
tive way. It has no analytical apparatus to deal chain operate. The acquisition of capabilities,
with the different kinds of relationships with which is in the buyers’ interest, is likely to
BREAKTHROUGH? CHINA’S AND INDIA’S TRANSITION 329

progress fast and might even be supported, backward linkages, but also cross-border merg-
notably the knowledge-using activities geared ers and acquisitions (UNCTAD, 2000); and the
to strengthening the producers’ existing posi- migration of scientists and entrepreneurs be-
tion in the global value chains. The acquisition tween leading and late-comer countries.
of capabilities, which is against the buyers’ Saxenian’s (2006) analysis of the Indian soft-
interests, is less likely to thrive and might even ware cluster in Bangalore and the Chinese com-
be discouraged, notably knowledge-creating puter cluster of Zhongguancun/Beijing shows
activities in chain co-ordination, design and this clearly. She attributes the buildup of entre-
marketing. In a nutshell, the upgrading oppor- preneurial and innovation capabilities above all
tunities of local enterprises are often structured to the strong professional and personal networks
by the relationships in global value chains that have developed between these new innova-
(Altenburg, 2006a; Schmitz, 2006). These tive regions in China and India and the old inno-
opportunities vary with the way the chains are vative regions in the United States. The central
organized. figures in these networks are what she calls the
This approach of distinguishing between dif- ‘‘The New Argonauts’’—highly mobile, techni-
ferent types of chains proved very useful in cally skilled entrepreneurs, engineers, and scien-
understanding the successes and failures in tists mostly of Indian/Chinese origin, with
innovation. The main insights provided by substantial research and work experience in the
recent value chain research are United States, applying their skills and capital
— The power of the lead firm is indeed crit- in their country of origin. The feared ‘‘brain
ical but relationships change over time and drain’’ has turned into ‘‘brain circulation,’’ in
new innovation opportunities emerge for those countries which—like China and India,
suppliers willing to make the required invest- and Korea and Taiwan at an earlier stage—expe-
ment (Altenburg, 2006b; Schmitz, 2006). rienced prolonged periods of high economic
— Operating in several types of chains is growth which created demand for highly skilled
particularly critical for acquiring innovation people. This is not just about return migration.
capabilities: producing to the specification of The ‘‘New Argonauts’’ often operate in both
the lead firm in a global chain often provides the old and new regions, travel frequently be-
access to new designs or processes (devel- tween them, maintain close professional rela-
oped elsewhere) while national chains can tionships on both sides and have strong
be more conducive to developing innovation professional associations on both sides. 5
capabilities, because the power relationships Clearly these highly talented, motivated and
with customers tend to be more symmetrical mobile people and their networks play a key
and there is more space for working with the role in the acquisition, transfer, adaptation,
national customers on design, marketing, and creation of knowledge. The analysis of
and branding (Mitsuhashi, 2005; Navas-Ale- these global professional networks seems criti-
man, 2006). cal for understanding the accumulation of
— Even in captive global chains, spaces for innovation capabilities in China and India but
innovation open up for local suppliers. The again, on its own this approach is not sufficient.
outsourcing of lead firms includes not just As shown in later sections, combining the
routine activities but increasingly also approaches presented here is essential for
knowledge-intensive activities, even includ- understanding the advances and limitations
ing R&D and design services (Ernst, 2002; made in China’s and India’s quest to become
UNCTAD, 2005). The resulting buildup of major innovation powers.
innovation capability is, however, mostly
limited to non-strategic areas. (c) Understanding the dynamics
— The lead firms’ dispersion of knowledge-
intensive activities is heavily concentrated in What insights does the innovation literature
a few specialized clusters (Ernst, 2002; Stur- provide on the dynamics of the catch-up pro-
geon, 2002). Local synergies matter. cess? The analysis most relevant for our con-
The global value chain approach thus pro- cerns is provided by Hobday (1995). His main
vides insights which are highly relevant to conclusion is that rather than leap frog, local,
understand innovation systems. Add to this and foreign firms (in the East Asian Tiger econ-
that innovation systems are not only linked to omies) engaged in a painstaking and cumula-
the global economy via value chains, but also tive process of learning and moving forward
via two other mechanisms: via forward and in incremental ways: ‘‘a hard slog rather than
330 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

a leap frog’’ (p. 200). This process is analyzed in long emphasized that technological and institu-
terms of interacting technology and market tional change need to go hand in hand. More
transition from OEM, to ODM and OBM. 6 recently, Nelson (2004, p. 365) has stressed that
The empirical analysis then shows why and the ‘‘social technologies are more difficult to
how these transitions were managed in some acquire than the physical.’’ These social tech-
industries more successfully than others. The nologies are embodied in norms and values,
key analytical messages are (using our termi- organizational forms, incentive systems, laws
nology) understanding the dynamics requires and codes of conduct, public policies, adminis-
a focus on the interaction of local and global trative procedures, and the like (Nelson & Sam-
linkages (confirming the point we made above) pat, 2001). These insights from the innovation
and a focus on the gradual movements from literature need to be taken into account in
using to adapting to creating knowledge— assessing the catch-up process of China and
rather than a search for the big leaps forward. India.
The question is whether Hobday’s frame- However, we also need to ask whether the
work is too limiting for the Chinese and Indian limits of tradability are changing. The organi-
case. His analysis concentrated on the Asian zation of the innovation process has changed
Tigers, all very successful but comparatively fundamentally in recent years. Many innova-
small economies. China and India have internal tion activities that used to be carried out in-
markets which are large and growing very rap- house are moved out to independent suppliers
idly. The combination of size and fast growth of knowledge-intensive business services or are
makes a difference—at least potentially—in transferred to key suppliers. This ‘‘organiza-
two ways: tional decomposition of the innovation pro-
— Capital accumulation is possible on a cess’’ (Schmitz & Strambach, 2007) makes it
much bigger scale. This enables both easier to target and purchase specific knowl-
countries to invest heavily in R&D and skills edge workers or their services.
development, to buy enormous quantities of This is particularly relevant for a country
embodied technology in different forms— with extraordinary resources to invest in the
licenses, machinery, brands, and even entire necessary skills and hire the bearers of codified
hi-tech firms—and to hire leading interna- and tacit knowledge from abroad. Can strong
tional scientists, managers, and consultants government agencies and the companies which
on an unprecedented scale. they support acquire the necessary system ele-
— Both countries are highly attractive for ments and integrate them in a short period of
FDI (although India lags behind), including time? Do the ‘‘New Argonauts’’ (Saxenian,
a kind of FDI that makes ample use of local 2006) open up a fast track for developing the
scientists and engineers. Especially China required ‘‘social technologies’’ (Nelson, 2004)?
takes advantage of the fact that the world’s More generally, are the thresholds of codifiabil-
major investors seek access to its large and ity and tradability shifting with the changing
growing market in order to oblige investors organization of the global knowledge economy,
to share technologies. The government is and if so, what does this imply for the catch-up
trading market access for technology. opportunities of large and rapidly growing
This extraordinary combination of economic economies, like China and India? Sections 4
purchasing and political bargaining power and 5 seek to address these important ques-
needs to be incorporated in the analysis: does tions.
it enable China and/or India to join the league
of innovating countries?
This in turn gives rise to a question which is 3. MEASURING CHINA’S AND INDIA’S
old but acquires new significance. How trad- ADVANCE
able is the knowledge required to innovate?
The innovation systems literature draws atten- Where do China and India stand in the
tion to the limits of tradability, emphasizing international pecking order? How much has
that much knowledge is tacit and built up in a their position changed in recent years? Are
cumulative and path dependent way (Stram- there indicators which enable us to make an
bach, 2004). Knowledge is sticky and not easily overall judgement? This section shows why
transferable. Caution is also advised by those such an assessment is difficult and what existing
who have studied the wider institutional and indicators tell us about China’s and India’s pro-
social context of innovation. Pérez (1989) has gress.
BREAKTHROUGH? CHINA’S AND INDIA’S TRANSITION 331

(a) The difficulty of measuring innovation indicators show enormous progress in the Chi-
nese case. Since 1999, China’s spending on
Assessments of where China and India stand R&D has increased by more than 20% each
regarding their innovation capabilities, if and year. In 2005, it reached 1.3% of gross domestic
how rapidly they are catching up with OECD product, up from 0.7% in 1998 (Wilsdon &
countries diverge considerably. There are four Keeley, 2007, p. 4). In contrast, India’s R&D
interrelated reasons that can explain this: expenditure as percentage of GDP has fluctu-
First, it is notoriously difficult to measure and ated around 0.8% since the 1990s. 8
compare innovation capabilities (see, e.g., Free- India’s most important input factor into the
man & Soete, 2007; Tijssen & Hollanders, innovation system is human capital. The
2006). While within the OECD some compara- annual enrolment at the level of graduate or
bility of relevant indicators has been achieved above has risen from 6.6 million in 1995/96
through the elaboration of a whole family of to 9.8 million in 2004. Among those the per-
guidelines (e.g., the ‘‘Frascati-Manual’’ or the centage studying engineering has increased
‘‘Oslo-Manual’’), 7 the same does not hold for from 6.0% to 11.2%. Each year around
comparisons between OECD and catching-up 350,000 engineering graduates are released to
countries that have not been involved in this the labor market. Estimates of annual science
collective process. PhDs range from 5,000 to more than 6,700
Second, the most conspicuous indicators that (Bound, 2007, p. 9). In China, the investment
seem to confirm the rapid advance of China in human resources is even more impressive.
and India are input factors, while output and The number of researchers increased by 77%
outcome indicators show only modest progress. during 1995–2004 (OECD, 2006). In 2004
With the available information it is impossible around half a million postgraduates were
to assess whether the gap between effort and counted in science, medicine, and engineering,
achievement is due to the normal maturation and 23,500 PhDs awarded, whereof 70% in
time for innovations or whether it is due to inef- science-related subjects (Wilsdon & Keeley,
ficiencies in the emerging innovation system. 2007, p. 17). However, the above authors also
Third, innovation-related data generally de- stress considerable quality problems in second-
scribe the performance of the actors within a gi- ary, tertiary, and post-graduate education in
ven territory. However, territorially bounded both China and India.
innovation systems are increasingly overlapping Foreign companies both contribute to and
with cross-border networks and often global draw on the pool of local talents. Corporations
value chains through which knowledge is trans- such as Microsoft, IBM, Motorola, Google,
mitted. This leads to the question of whose inno- Siemens, Volkswagen, and Honda have estab-
vation capabilities are actually reflected in lished R&D centers in China and India, bring-
national data. For example, rapid increases of ing in their own expertise and using the highly
high-technology exports may be due to expan- educated but cheap local workers to pursue
sion in computer assembly. Or foreign lead firms their innovation strategies. By the end of
may produce hi-tech products without being 2006, about 750 foreign-funded R&D centers
embedded in the national innovation systems. had been set up in China (China Daily, Decem-
Fourth, international comparison of Chinese ber 12, 2006). Simultaneously, China’s and In-
and Indian innovation efforts and achievements dia’s own corporations, such as Huawei
is further complicated by huge internal dispari- Technologies (China) and Infosys (India), are
ties. This leads to the ‘‘hall of mirrors’’ effect increasingly ‘‘going global’’ and investing stra-
(Leadbeater & Wilsdon, 2007, p. 11). Some indi- tegically in subsidiaries to tap local knowledge
cators, while large in absolute terms, seem rather hubs and to strengthen linkages with interna-
insignificant when population size is used as tional clients (UNCTAD, 2006, p. 130f).
deflator. On the other hand, when the indicators Looking at output indicators there are signs
are related to per capita income, they imply a that China and India might catch-up more
much stronger performance of China and India. rapidly in science than in technological innova-
tion. Within 10 years—from 1995 to 2004
(b) Indicators of China’s and India’s innovation China’s contribution to global production of
efforts and performance scientific publications rose from 2.05% to
6.52% (Wilsdon & Keeley, 2007, p. 14). India’s
Keeping in mind these measurement prob- scientific performance is much weaker. The
lems, what does the available data tell us? Input country ‘‘accounted for only 2.19% of the
332 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

Table 1. Performance of India’s and China’s science system


GDP SCI publications SCI publications per SCI citations SCI citations per
per capita (1997–2001) GDP/capital per year (1997–2001) GDP/capital per year
India 487 77,201 32 188,481 77
China 989 115,339 23 341,519 69
United States 36,006 1,265,808 7 10,850,549 60
United Kingdom 26,445 342,535 3 2,199,617 18
Germany 24,051 318,286 3 2,500,035 19
Source: Bound (2007, p. 15).

world’s scientific publications in 1993–97 and composite indicators such as the UNCTAD
this declined to 2.13% the period 1997–2001’’ Innovation Capability Index and the Global
(Krishnan, 2007, p. 1, see also Table 1). Competitiveness Index rankings position nei-
Still weak is China’s and India’s patent re- ther China nor India as major innovation pow-
cords. Table 2 shows the number of patents ers (see Table 3).
granted by the US Patent and Trademark Of- Obviously, such indicators are insufficient to
fice: Chinese and Indian patents have increased assess the innovation capabilities of India and
in absolute numbers as well as in relation to the China. A combination of quantitative and
totality of patents of foreign origin. However, qualitative methods is needed to judge the pro-
the level of patenting is still low. China and gress made in moving from production to inno-
India together represent just about 1% of all vation. The questions are clear but the answers
patents granted to foreigners, compared to are hard to find. Under what circumstances is
more than 6% in the case of the much smaller the growth of industrial production capabilities
South Korea. transformed and extended into the growth of
Considering this mixed picture (strong com- innovation capabilities? Are there common
mitment and technological efforts but still mod- patterns in the evolution of these innovation
est output) it does not come as a surprise that capabilities? How does insertion into global

Table 2. Patents granted by the US Patent and Trademark Office during 1963–2005, by geographic origin
Pre 1992 1995 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005
Patents of foreign origin 721,716 45,680 72,426 78,436 80,360 81,130 80,020 69,169
China, PR 337 48 119 195 289 297 404 402
India 374 27 131 178 249 342 363 384
Germany 161,305 6,600 10,235 11,260 11,280 11,444 10,779 9,011
United Kingdom 76,452 2,481 3,669 3,967 3,843 3,631 3,450 3,148
South Korea 1,229 1,161 3,314 3,538 3,786 3,944 4,428 4,352
%
China, PR 0.05% 0.14% 0.16% 0.25% 0.36% 0.37% 0.50% 0.58%
India 0.05% 0.08% 0.18% 0.23% 0.31% 0.42% 0.45% 0.56%
Germany 22.35% 14.45% 14.13% 14.36% 14.04% 14.11% 13.47% 13.03%
United Kingdom 10.59% 5.43% 5.07% 5.06% 4.78% 4.48% 4.31% 4.55%
South Korea 0.17% 2.54% 4.58% 4.51% 4.71% 4.86% 5.53% 6.29%
Source: US Patent and Trademark Office, http://www.uspto.gov/web/offices/ac/ido/oeip/taf/reports.htm#by_geog.

Table 3. China’s and India’s ranking in the Global Competitiveness Index (GCI) and three of its pillars
Country GCI Pillar 5: Higher education Pillar 7: Technological Pillar 9: Innovation
and training readiness
China 54 77 75 46
India 43 49 55 26
N = 125 countries.
Source: World Economic Forum (2006).
BREAKTHROUGH? CHINA’S AND INDIA’S TRANSITION 333

value chains influence these patterns? How do — Haier is the fifth largest producer of elec-
policy networks and support organizations of trical appliances worldwide, manufacturing
emerging innovation systems contribute? large household appliances, air conditioners,
Unraveling the dynamics is particularly diffi- LCDs and Plasma-TVs, DVD recorders and
cult. The next section provides some insights mobile phones.
into these dynamics, drawing on sectoral All these multinationals are dedicating sub-
accounts. stantial resources to innovation. Huawei, for
example, claims to invest more than US$1 bn.
in R&D and to have almost 30,000 employees
4. INSIGHTS FROM SELECT in this field (Handelsblatt, February 20, 2007).
INDUSTRIES Initially China’s buildup of capabilities relied
heavily on insertion in global value chains:
Understanding the buildup of innovation export-oriented low-cost assembly in global
capabilities requires combining different analyt- value chains to the specifications of foreign cus-
ical approaches: this was the main message of tomers. Chinese subcontractors rapidly gained
Section 2 and this is the thread running through expertise in high-volume manufacturing. Given
this empirical section. It focuses on two Chi- the increasing concentration of global produc-
nese and two Indian industries and provides tion facilities in China, the semiconductor
insights into the dynamics of the catch-up pro- industry (e.g., wafer fabs, integrated circuit
cess. While necessarily brief, it shows to what design houses, semiconductor packaging,
extent the transition from production to inno- assembly, and testing) subsequently shifted
vation has been achieved, highlights how differ- production to China, thus locating increasing
ent elements of national innovation systems parts of the value chain in the country (Price-
and global linkages have interacted, and indi- WaterhouseCoopers, 2005). Furthermore, the
cates how the size of the economy and the rapid growth of the domestic market for PCs
power of accumulation have contributed. The and consumer electronics induced the leading
chosen sectors are electronics and automobiles Chinese companies to operate in both the home
in China, and the software and space industries and export market. This allows them to achieve
in India. 9 We opted for these sectors because enormous economies of scale and to combine
they are among the largest in terms of produc- capabilities gained from operating in the global
tion and/or R&D expenditure and because they value chain with capabilities built in developing
show different trajectories arising from different own products and brands. In the case of per-
combinations of change agents. sonal computers, for example, Chinese brands
now have roughly two thirds of the domestic
(a) The electronics industry in China market (Zhou, 2005, p. 1121).
In parallel, the government made consi-
China’s success in building the world’s big- derable sectorally targeted investments in
gest production hub for global markets is innovation. ‘‘Electronics and communication
strongly associated with FDI in the electronics equipment’’ and ‘‘electronic computers and
industry (Ma, Nguyen, & Xu, 2006). The largest office equipments’’ together account for 78%
exporters are foreign, but within two decades of total industrial R&D expenditure. 10 This
several Chinese electronics firms have become was accompanied by targeting key capabilities
global players, including Huawei Technologies, in the electronics value chains, for example, an
Lenovo, and the Haier Group: R&D fund for the development of IC (inte-
— Huawei Technologies is a leading pro- grated circuit) design houses (PriceWaterhous-
vider of telecommunications networks and eCoopers, 2005, p. 4). As shown by Zhou
increasingly challenges established competi- (2005), China has been able to transform its
tors like Siemens, Cisco, and Alcatel, now leading Science Park, Zhongguancun in Beijing,
serving 31 of the world’s top 50 telecom into an innovative cluster, specialized in com-
operators. Its products encompass wireless puter hardware and software, by experimenting
products, network products, applications, with new forms of collaboration between aca-
and software, as well as computer terminals. demic institutions and the private sector and be-
— Lenovo is a global leader in the PC mar- tween Chinese enterprises and multinational
ket since it acquired the IBM Personal Com- companies.
puting Division (PCD) including its Finally, China’s industry has tapped
international research facilities. additional international knowledge pools.
334 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

Acquisition of foreign firms—as in the case of quite unlikely that China may join the league
IBM PCD—has helped not only to acquire of countries with domestic innovation capabili-
brand reputation but also to access interna- ties in the automotive industry, especially given
tional R&D networks. The new Lenovo now the fact that the industry is characterized by
has R&D centers in China, Japan, and the Uni- mergers and acquisitions that will leave only a
ted States. Similarly, Huawei has created a net- few globally integrated auto firms and first-tier
work of global R&D centers in China, India, suppliers in the market (Noble, 2006).
United States, Sweden, and Russia. Another However, public and private efforts to catch-
important international connection was the re- up technologically are underway. It is esti-
turn migration of Chinese scientists and entre- mated that in 2004, 1.4% of revenues in the
preneurs from the United States, essential in Chinese automotive industry have been used
particular for the semiconductor industry in for R&D. Local manufacturer Geely even
Shanghai (Sternberg & Müller, 2005). China’s claims to invest 10% of revenues in R&D (No-
government supports this process providing ble, 2006). Some national programs are target-
incentives for returnees with technological skills ing cutting-edge innovations in fields like the
(Yusuf, Nabeshima, & Perkins, 2006, p. 32). In development of hybrid cars and hydrogen fuel
the case of the electronics industry, the Chinese cells. Increasingly demanding government
government thus comes close to what From- standards for fuel efficiency and pollution con-
hold-Eisebith (2007) calls the ‘‘master of the trol increase pressure to innovate from the
scales’’: global, national, and local. demand side. Complementing national R&D
efforts, the global leaders increasingly shift
(b) The auto industry in China automotive engineering and R&D offshore,
with China being the main destination. In
Regarding the Chinese automotive industry, 2005, 130 auto and parts companies, including
industry analysts agree that domestic innova- industry leaders like General Motors and
tion capabilities still lag far behind leading Volkswagen, had built up R&D facilities in
nations, although production capabilities have China. There are two reasons for this. One is
grown rapidly. While two decades ago China that these companies want to make use of a
did not have any relevant automobile industry, growing pool of skilled engineers and techni-
it is now the fourth-largest producer in the cians to cut their research expenditure. The
world (Noble, 2006). The industry is fueled by other one is government pressure. To get
the rapid expansion of domestic demand. approbation, foreign investors need to undergo
According to projections by Goldman Sachs, a screening process and have to make conces-
the Chinese market for automobiles will in- sions, for example, committing themselves to
crease from 19 million units in 2005 to 199 mil- invest in R&D and to share technologies. Sim-
lion in 2025, overtaking even the US market ilarly, foreign manufacturers have a greater
(Wilson, Puroshothaman, & Fiotakis, 2004, p. chance to be considered in public tenders if
23). they set up R&D centers in China. Chinese
Increasing competitiveness is reflected in the authorities ‘‘swap market for technology’’
fact that China’s automobile and autoparts (Long, 2005, p. 334).
exports are rapidly increasing, although from As in the case of electronics, some national
a low level; in 2004 its share in the global manufacturers try to buy know-how and
market was still as low as 0.7% (WTO, 2005). property rights in the global market. China’s
Its strength is mainly in labor-intensive auto largest auto parts manufacturer Wanxiang
component exports which are based on cost acquired, merged with, or established 30
advantages, although China’s companies have companies in eight countries, including United
recently developed their own car brands and States, England, and Germany (Gao, 2004).
started exporting these to low-end markets. Shanghai Automotive Industries Corporation
All this, however, shows improved and (SAIC) intends to develop its own car based
expanded production capabilities rather than on Chinese technologies. For this purpose
innovation capabilities. Auto production is SAIC acquired a majority stake in Korean
almost fully carried out under licence from for- Ssangyong for US$500 million (Frankfurter
eign manufacturers. Most product development Allgemeine Zeitung, June 22, 2005). It remains
is based on reverse engineering, and no signifi- to be seen whether such acquisitions really
cant indigenous technological development has give the expected boost to innovation capabil-
yet occurred. At first sight it therefore seems ities.
BREAKTHROUGH? CHINA’S AND INDIA’S TRANSITION 335

(c) The software industry in India try has taken on more complex work in recent
years. While at the end of the 1980s, around
In India, software is the most outstanding 90% of the overall export work was done
sector in terms of rapidly building indigenous onsite, subsequently this share has declined
innovation capabilities. After 1984 and espe- rapidly to 30% in 2005, reflecting a rapid
cially from the mid-nineties onwards the indus- growth of offshore development. This implies
try has grown in a spectacular way, achieving that the countries’ capabilities in independently
average annual growth rates of more than managing projects with a larger degree of
30% over the past decade. The National Asso- autonomy from customers have considerably
ciation of Software and Service Companies increased.
(Nasscom) estimates that the software and ser- The industry continues to be dominated by
vices sector employed nearly 1.3 million per- more routine-based tasks (such as application
sons in 2006. Revenues from these sectors development and maintenance). However, re-
reached US$30.3 billion in the same year (Nass- cent indications suggest that a highly dynamic
com, 2007). The industry is dominated by segment of firms is stretching beyond low
major domestic champions, Tata Consultancy value-added service by complementing routine
Services (TCS), Infosys, Wipro Technologies, activities with innovative niche services (Lema,
and Satyam, each with revenues above US$1 2007). Moreover, the knowledge-intensive busi-
billion. But in recent years subsidiaries of major ness lines—engineering services, R&D, and
IT multinationals, such as IBM and Accenture, software products—are growing fast. These ac-
have expanded their Indian operations aggres- counted for US$2.9 billion in sales in 2004 and
sively, some of them with revenues in excess in 2007 this figure is projected to rise to US$6.5
of US$500 million. IBM currently employs billion, amounting to a share of 17% of total
more than 60,000 people in India (Dossani & services (Nasscom, 2007). Intel, Cisco, Siemens,
Kenney, 2007). SAP, and many other TNCs have opened cen-
The seeds for these achievements were laid by ters for chip design or software research in Ban-
the Indian government in the 1950s onwards by galore and other emerging Indian clusters. All
investing heavily in engineering education and this indicates that India is currently increasing
research institutions in the national innovation its innovation capabilities and the ability to
system (Kumar, 2001). These included universi- compete globally for knowledge-intensive ser-
ties, technical colleges, and other training and vice tasks.
research centers. India graduated an estimated The insertion in global value chains was the
500,000 engineers in 2006. But besides its focus key for India’s success. High growth was and
on skills development the government did not continues to be based on a highly successful
support the industry throughout the 1970s penetration of global software markets. Ex-
and early 1980s. Trade and FDI policies were ports accounted for nearly 80% of industry
rather disadvantageous for the globalizing sales in 2006 (Nasscom, 2007). The presence
industry. To offset deficiencies in the business of a large number of highly educated Indians
environment in the early 1990s, the central gov- in the West, particularly United States, has also
ernment established a network of national soft- been important. In 1986, for instance, about
ware technology parks which provide 59% of Indian Institute of Technology gradu-
broadband connectivity based on satellite and ates in computer science and engineering emi-
fiber technology, single-window clearance sys- grated (Siwek & Furchgott-Roth, 1993, p.
tem to software exporters, and incubation 140). Moreover, from the 1980s large service
services. Today, over 6,000 companies nation- providers such as TCS started to offer onsite
wide benefit from this national Software Tech- programming services (‘‘body shopping’’),
nology Parks of India programme. sending teams of programmers to clients in
For a long time, Indian IT-software produc- the United States and other OECD countries.
tion was associated with low-cost programming Indian IT-specialists working in the US com-
services, high in demand from Western compa- puter and software industry were important in-
nies seeking operational cost advantages. Func- ter-cultural mediators, establishing contacts to
tioning as ‘‘virtual extensions’’ of these western the emerging IT-sector in India and facilitating
customers, Indian IT firms followed strict contracts for onsite and offshore projects. In-
design guidelines established by contracting dian nationals are the main beneficiaries of
companies (Lema, 2006). While this type of the H1-B Visa which the United States issues
engagement model is still dominant, the indus- to attract foreign professionals. Adding to the
336 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

‘‘brain circulation’’ many of the emigrated pro- survive without continued subsidies. Its innova-
fessionals have returned to India once the over- tive capability is impressive but its economic
all conditions for the IT-industry improved. viability is shaky.
They brought back technological expertise, Space programs require an extraordinarily
inter-cultural knowledge, and contacts (Saxe- broad array of technologies including optics
nian, 2006). design, electronics and telecommunications sys-
tems, software development, new materials,
(d) The space industry of India advanced combustion technologies, testing,
and evaluation. The development of the related
The Indian space industry represents yet capabilities has generated spillovers into differ-
another very different trajectory. Industry ent manufacturing industries. In addition, the
development here is largely research-driven great number of technologies required for the
and relies to a great extent on a network of space programme calls for enhanced capacities
public institutions strongly supported by gov- to manage very complex systems of closely
ernment R&D funds. 13% of India’s research intertwined technologies. National-level pro-
budget goes into space research (Thomas, 2006, jects, which involved a great number of
p. 6). Despite being a national ‘‘pet project,’’ research institutions as well as public and
relationships with foreign knowledge hubs—in private enterprises, helped to develop these
this case mainly public space agencies like capabilities which are crucial for systems inte-
NASA—were crucial for technological learning. gration in other industries. Hence India’s space
Starting to develop capabilities immediately programme is the result of a deliberate effort to
after independence, India has built one of the build an Indian-owned sectoral innovation sys-
world’s leading national space programs cover- tem.
ing three major complementary areas: satellites, However, international linkages were funda-
missiles, and ground systems. The country has mental in all phases of development. Unlike
the ability to design, produce, and launch its in most other industrial sectors, the main
own satellites, to control and track them from sources of foreign technology were institutional
the ground, and to receive and process complex partners rather than private foreign investment.
remote sensing data gathered by the satellites. In early phases, NASA, as well as ITU, UNDP,
In the area of satellites, India’s space pro- and other international organizations, sup-
gram comprises communications satellites (for ported the program through donations, train-
telecommunication, television broadcasting, ing, and increasingly joint research programs.
and meteorological services) and remote sens- Later on, French, Russian, and German space
ing satellites (for resource survey and manage- research organizations as well as ESA were
ment, environmental monitoring, and important partners. Furthermore India sent a
meteorological services). Its technological capa- great number of scientists and engineers to be
bilities evolved from TV-camera-based systems trained in industrialized countries and the In-
in the late 1970s to state-of-the art high resolu- dian Space Research Organisation generously
tion imaging systems (Kasturirangan, 2004, p. sponsors participation of Indian scientists in
841). India has developed and launched its collaborative space research programs with for-
own remote sensing satellite, intermediate- eign space agencies (Baskaran, 2005).
range ballistic missiles for civilian and military
purposes and powerful rockets based on Rus- (e) The alignment of global and national forces
sian technology. Ground system technologies
comprise rocket launching facilities, spacecraft In sum, the case studies have shown impres-
control, and tracking facilities as well as facili- sive progress in Chinese and Indian industries.
ties for receiving, processing, and utilizing satel- Both countries are increasingly mastering
lite data. India has made significant advances in sophisticated production processes, meeting
all these technologies (Baskaran, 2005). international quality standards as well as pro-
India is now one of the main providers of sat- ductivity levels. Enhanced competitiveness is
ellites in the civilian domain, and revenues from reflected in rapidly increasing global market
commercial applications help to recover some shares in a number of industries. This reflects
of the costs of the annual space budget. The growing capabilities for technology absorption
global satellite manufacturing industry, how- and reverse engineering as well as minor incre-
ever, is plagued by significant over-capacity, mental innovations. Comparing both countries,
and it is not sure whether India’s industry will China has a broader industrial basis, is more
BREAKTHROUGH? CHINA’S AND INDIA’S TRANSITION 337

integrated globally than India, attracts more access foreign technology and link up with
R&D outsourcing and is on the whole scienti- global R&D. India’s software industry is a
fically more advanced. India on the other hand similar case of engaging in global value chains.
ranks higher on the Global Competitiveness In- The ‘‘New Argonauts’’ (Saxenian, 2006) were
dex, reflecting a perceived superiority of its pri- critical in the formation of such value chains.
vate businesses. China’s automotive industry emerged as a
However, a focus on results suggests both typical import-substitution industry based on
countries lag far behind that of leading OECD multinational corporations. In contrast to
countries. None of the successful industries has other countries, however, Chinese government
brought about major cutting-edge innovations. partners are in a rather strong bargaining po-
Comparative advantages remain primarily sition to trade access to foreign technology for
based on lower factor costs. These advantages, access to the national market. In addition,
however, are no longer confined to simple capital accumulation in Chinese firms is
labor-intensive activities. Furthermore, both sufficiently strong to acquire foreign firms
countries have stepped up their innovation and brand names and to offer long-term con-
efforts, and there are good reasons to assume tracts to foreign project developers. Finally,
that the technological gap will be further India’s space project, although considered a
narrowed in a number of industries (see Section strategic national project, strongly built on
5). research cooperation with international space
What explains this partial success? More spe- agencies.
cifically, to what extent was it due to invest- In all these industries, global linkages were
ments in territorially bounded innovation flanked by considerable investments in domestic
systems, and what has been the role of global innovation systems, especially in R&D and the
linkages? Although there is a marked variation development of advanced skills. Both govern-
among the trajectories of different industries, ments have shown a clear commitment to sci-
all industries in our sample show a combination ence and innovation, define sector-specific
of successfully tapping into international pools technological targets and allocate resources
of knowledge on the one hand, and strong accordingly. As exemplified by the space indus-
investments in national skills development and try, some industries are science-driven and re-
innovation capabilities on the other. 11 Integra- lied on national research funding. But also in
tion in GVC helped to link up with the most the other sectors, effective research institutions,
innovative lead users of technology, to train sci- technology parks, and other dedicated institu-
entists and engineers in advanced countries, tions were set up to indigenize foreign and de-
and to master up-to-date production technolo- velop own technologies. Even in the case of
gies. Furthermore it helped to achieve econo- the Indian software cluster, which is sometimes
mies of scale and accumulate the capital heralded as an example of development with
necessary for substantial investments in innova- ‘‘benign neglect’’ (Pack & Saggi, 2006) of the
tion systems back home. These in turn helped government, a number of case studies show
to strengthen absorptive capacities, to make that the government played an active role in
good use of external knowledge for national developing the necessary skills and institutional
projects, and to raise the attractiveness of the support (Krishnan, 2007).
two countries for new types of knowledge- National efforts to increase innovation capa-
intensive collaboration. bilities in turn made the two countries attrac-
Activities that kept national innovation sys- tive for multinational corporations willing to
tems open for inflows from international pools shift R&D and other knowledge-intensive ser-
of knowledge were a crucial success factor, vices to their subsidiaries in China and India
although the type of linkages with the global or contract domestic service providers for this
economy varied strongly. China’s electronics purpose. Although this is in most cases still rel-
industry started by attracting export-oriented atively simple adaptive R&D, there is a clear
FDI on the basis of cost advantages in semi- trend to move into more sophisticated R&D
skilled labor. Thus multinational lead firms services (UNCTAD, 2005). This way, the devel-
in global value chains triggered this develop- opment of the national innovation system and
ment. At later stages, highly skilled scientists strategic integration in global value chains
and engineers returned from the United States, and international research communities may
and finally the acquisition of foreign compa- well create a virtuous circle of technological
nies enabled emerging Chinese enterprises to catch-up.
338 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

5. HOW LIKELY ARE CHINA AND INDIA In addition, some formerly ‘‘tacit’’ elements
TO CATCH-UP? of innovation systems can today largely be cod-
ified and are thus more ‘‘tradable.’’ For exam-
The case studies have shed some light on ple, quality management systems (such as ISO
China’s and India’s achievements and their 9000f) and practices of supply chain manage-
remaining challenges. In this section we ask ment have since the late 1980s been laid down
whether it is realistic to extrapolate recent in a series of standardized procedures that are
trends and assume a process of increasing tech- today applied on a global scale. Hence it
nological mastery which will eventually result becomes relatively easier to hire experienced
in path-breaking innovations, in leaps in pro- service providers who have the expertise to
ductivity and higher economic returns. We ar- put whole subsystems into operation—pro-
gue that it would be premature to give a vided the customers can pay for it, which is def-
definite answer to this question. Both countries initely the case in key sectors of the Chinese and
are still at a crossroads and several develop- Indian economies. Nanjing Automobile in
ments may derail their catch-up process; there China, for example, transferred whole MG
are doubts to the extent to which common Rover teams, including the director of quality,
assumptions about technological catch-up pro- to China; likewise, Chinese automobile manu-
cesses apply to these very large and fast grow- facturers hired large design companies from
ing economies. But we can identify some of the United Kingdom for long-term develop-
the key issues that will determine (relative) suc- ment projects (The Economist Intelligence
cess or failure and put forward questions for Unit, 2006).
further research. Another specific feature of large and fast
As indicated in Section 2, research on growing countries is their government’s bar-
innovation systems has not yet shed much light gaining power vis-à-vis foreign technology own-
on the relationships between those elements ers—which is obviously related to the
that can be bought in global technology mar- exceptional market potential. Especially the
kets (patents, licenses, equipment) and labor Chinese government deliberately trades market
markets (scientists, engineers) and those that access for technologies, obliging investors to
require careful adaptation to national condi- share technologies if they want to sell to the
tions, mutual acculturation, and local learning domestic market. Likewise there is competition
processes. The literature (e.g., Nelson, 2004) among universities and research centers world-
emphasizes the extraordinary relevance of wide to form alliances with counterpart institu-
social institutions that are deemed indispens- tions in India and China to market their
able to lubricate the interactive processes of courses and tap into the growing local talent
technology development, thus implicitly assum- pools.
ing a necessarily slow process of institutional Moreover, Chinese and Indian researchers
maturing. There are indications, however, that and engineers are increasingly integrating in
due to their sheer size and growth dynamic transnational scientific and technical communi-
China and India may leapfrog certain develop- ties (Saxenian, 2006). This applies both to glo-
ments. As shown in the case studies, fast bal research networks, such as the Human
growth and high savings rates enable China, Genome project, and to global intra-firm com-
and increasingly also India, to invest not only munities in TNCs, where Chinese and Indians
in huge infrastructure projects but also in major occupy leading positions in management and
R&D programs, to set up first-class research research. Truly globalized company networks
and training institutions and technology parks, and scientific networks, rather than nation
to acquire foreign licenses and even entire states or regions, may become the relevant loci
firms, to provide competitive salaries and of innovation. Participation of research centers
well-equipped research facilities to lure top or individual researchers in such networks
researchers away from the United States and opens additional pipelines for cross-border
other industrialized countries, and so on. In a knowledge flows.
nutshell, capital accumulation allows these big The combination of market size and expan-
Asian economies to simultaneously purchase sion, bargaining power, enormous capital
substantial amounts of embodied knowledge accumulation, heavy investment in human
and make substantial investments in R&D resources, FDI, and strong presence in global
and a highly skilled and globally integrated professional networks make China’s and
workforce. India’s catch-up process unique. Future
BREAKTHROUGH? CHINA’S AND INDIA’S TRANSITION 339

research will need to show whether this tems to supply the necessary highly skilled
combination of factors enables China and workforce in times of rapidly increasing
India to leapfrog certain processes and devel- demand.
op innovation systems and dynamics specific — Economies of scale and the level of inter-
to large fast growing economies. In this con- nationalization: Although Chinese and
text, it will be particularly interesting to exam- Indian firms are rapidly globalizing, most
ine whether the return migrants, attracted by of them are still minor players in the global
the prospects of fast upward mobility and market, and in some activities their global
capable of straddling very different cultures, entry may come too late for the ongoing glo-
help to develop new blends of ‘‘social technol- bal round of mergers and acquisitions. In
ogies.’’ the global market for large passenger air-
Other elements that are crucial to assess both craft, for example, only two global produc-
countries’ prospects for catch-up, but fraught ers remain. Similar concentration processes
with uncertainties, include the following: are on their way in other (e.g., automotive
— The sustainability of the growth process: and satellite) industries and might force late-
As stressed above, the buildup of innovation comers like China and India to abandon
capabilities can only proceed at the current their efforts to catch-up. At the same time,
pace if the two economies continue to grow global technological leaders are increasingly
at high rates. This cannot be taken for operating—and carrying out research—in
granted. To assess the likelihood of an eco- all major markets to register new market
nomic crisis that would slow capital accu- trends at an early stage and be able to tap
mulation down, however, is beyond the into new developments. As newcomers, most
scope of this paper and probably beyond Chinese and Indian multinationals are not
the grip of scientifically based projections yet fully embedded in foreign markets and
in general. networks. This is a critical constraint, for
— The availability of appropriate human example, for Indian software providers
capital in quantitative and qualitative terms: who have not yet built up networks compa-
China’s and India’s investment in human rable to those of their United States and
resources has created an advantage for local European competitors. 12 As shown in the
firms and R&D institutions as well as incen- cases of Lenovo and Huawei, however,
tives for TNCs to shift knowledge-based other emerging multinationals succeeded in
operations to China and India. China is building up such international R&D
the first and India the third global destina- networks.
tion for R&D outsourcing (UNCTAD, — The importance of domestic user-producer
2005). Even if most of this is adaptive linkages: Innovation systems research
R&D, many centers are winning increasingly emphasizes feedback loops between produc-
demanding contracts as scientific expertise ers and demanding users with a high quality
and local business linkages develop. This consciousness and willingness to pay for
opens up another important avenue for tech- high-end brand products as important driv-
nological catch-up. At the same time, the ers of innovation (Lundvall, 1988). Such
modernization process requires huge interactive loops seem underdeveloped in
amounts of managers, engineers, scientists, China and India. Further research will have
and other highly skilled workers in a wide to show to what extent integration in global
range of private and public activities, both value chains can compensate for weak local
innovation-related and for ‘‘mundane’’ user-producer linkages. In addition it
administrative tasks (Yusuf et al., 2006, p. remains to be seen at what pace the number
50). There are indications that the rapidly of demanding consumers increases in each
increasing innovation efforts in both coun- of the two countries and to what extent this
tries are not matched by equally evolving will foster the emergence of a quality culture
capabilities in the management of the inno- that drives innovation.
vation system and its elements. Krishnan — The role of industrial policy: The useful-
(2007) identifies seven quite severe weak- ness of industrial policies is hotly debated,
nesses in India’s innovation system which mainly because there are doubts about the
are to a large extent related to a shortage ability of policymakers to identify the right
of critical skills. The potential for catch-up intervention mechanisms and to withstand
thus depends on the ability of education sys- political capture. 13 Some of the promising
340 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

industries in both China and India, however, (a) Implications for advanced countries
emerged on the basis of targeted policies,
trade-related investment measures, and even Is China’s and India’s innovation drive a
discretionary deals with foreign investors. threat to the OECD countries? This is a
Today both countries are increasingly forced central question in the current debate on the
to play by the rules of the WTO. Stricter costs and benefits of offshoring. Some consider
enforcement of agreements on trade and it as an opportunity to drastically lower costs in
intellectual property will make it more a wide range of industries; others stress the
difficult to copy designs and processes, thus threat not only to simple routine jobs but
limiting the scope for reverse engineering. increasingly also to knowledge-intensive
This problem may prove to be especially employment in OECD countries. 14 India and
severe in China, where many industries are China are by far the most important hotspots
heavily dominated by foreign investors. for global offshoring of IT related jobs, at this
However it is also likely to limit the dyna- stage mainly in the production of services, but
mism of India’s drug industry (Thomas, increasingly also in R&D. However, the poten-
2006, p. 14ff). Although it is hard to judge tial for job relocation is probably more limited
to what extent past industrial policies really than initially thought, at least in the short run
helped to catch-up technologically, it is (Stamm, 2005).
obvious that the rules of the game are now The blurry picture of the current catch-up
changing. process in both countries makes it difficult to
In sum, China especially seems to have a predict its long-term effects on OECD coun-
solid foundation for catching up in a number tries. Three scenarios can be distinguished:
of industries. Its unique combination of — High impact scenario: China and India
market size and growth, emphasis on skills manage to catch-up technologically in the
development and innovation, and the govern- short term, challenging industrialized coun-
ment’s bargaining power strongly favor tech- tries in their core competencies and markets.
nological upgrading. We have shown that a Innovation rents of European firms, and the
country that accumulates capital at China’s associated welfare gains, shrink substantially
pace can buy in enterprises, talents, and even or even disappear. Offshoring of knowledge-
complex technological solutions, and set intensive activities to China and India
strong incentives for technology transfer. Put strongly increases and becomes common
differently, many elements of national practice even in cutting-edge products and
innovation systems seem to have become more services.
‘‘tradable.’’ Some—especially politically — Low impact scenario: Catching up is
embedded—institutions though may take more hampered or gets stuck due to a loss of eco-
time to develop, and it is difficult to assess the nomic dynamism, mainly for reasons exter-
time horizons necessary to overcome the nal to the innovation system, for example,
respective institutional barriers. Conditions in political or environmental reasons. The
India are somewhat different. Market institu- unique capability to invest in innovation
tions are generally better developed than in systems gets lost. The OECD countries gain
China, but India lags behind in terms of capi- time to consolidate their position as
tal accumulation, R&D expenditure, attrac- technological leaders, and their loss of jobs
tiveness for FDI, and other drivers of remains largely limited to low to medium
innovation, thus leading us to assume a slower skilled positions (call centers, standard
catch-up process. engineering).
— Mixed blessing scenario: China and India
maintain a strong upward trend in science,
6. IMPLICATIONS FOR THE REST OF technology, and innovation, but this is
THE WORLD largely compensated by increased technolog-
ical efforts in OECD countries. The latter
China’s and India’s advances in building up lose some innovation activities (e.g., indus-
innovation capabilities have implications for trial design) to China and India, but main-
advanced and developing countries. This final tain the lead in strategic innovation fields.
section sets out possible scenarios and identifies Losses are balanced by increased markets
questions for future research. in Asia.
BREAKTHROUGH? CHINA’S AND INDIA’S TRANSITION 341

(b) Implications for developing countries Grace, 2005). Companies in both countries,
with government support, are investing in
The effects, which China’s and India’s build- the development of cars which are small,
up of innovation capabilities might have on the cheap, and energy efficient, using biofuel
developing world, are also hard to judge but and fuel cells (Noble, 2006). The desirabil-
the questions that arise are clear. ity of investing in ‘‘appropriate products’’
— Do China’s and India’s advances in inno- is clear, but it is not yet clear which config-
vation open up new production opportunities uration of factors leads to such investments
for other low wage countries? In the case being made.
of the smaller ‘‘Asian Tigers,’’ growth and — Are China and India providing the most
transformation led to rising labor costs effective centers of learning for the talents
and the location of labor-intensive stages of the developing world? Universities in
of the value chain in countries with lower India and China have long received stu-
wages. Will the same happen in China dents from other parts of the developing
and India? Their labor reserves seem nearly world. But for decades, the greatest talents
inexhaustible but the limits in their labor were sent to universities in North America
supply are also apparent. In the case of and Western Europe. Families, govern-
China this is due to demographic trends ments, foundations, and other donors
and in the case of India there is the ques- assumed that this was the best investment
tion of whether its education system will in the future. To what extent does this
provide ‘‘employable workers’’ in sufficient assumption remain valid? Given the mas-
numbers. sive investment in higher education—in
— Will China and India provide access to particular in science and engineering—and
technology at lower cost? Capital goods given the closer relationships between the
and knowledge-intensive business services academic and corporate circles, China and
are likely to be cheaper—compared with India can now offer some excellent centers
those bought from OECD countries. But of learning. How do they compare with
what about proprietary technology? Will the best in United States and United King-
access be easier? Will licensing fees be dom? There are likely to be enormous vari-
lower? Does it matter—in terms of access ations by specialization and location. But
and cost—whether the innovating company once costs are taken into account, do China
is domestic or foreign owned? Access to and India provide more effective options
and price of technology have been fought for developing countries?
over for decades—in multilateral fora and To conclude, in the past three decades the
bilateral negotiations between OECD and global division of labor has undergone far-
the developing world. A shift seems now reaching changes. Production capabilities have
on its way but how substantial is it? What shifted eastward at an unprecedented pace,
will be the scope and depth of ‘‘South– while innovation capabilities have remained
South’’ technology alliances? Will the alli- remarkably concentrated in OECD countries.
ances be primarily between the likes of Our analysis suggests that, although China’s
China, India, Brazil, Mexico, and South and India’s technological efforts have rarely
Africa, or will smaller/weaker countries materialized in cutting-edge innovations at this
benefit? stage, they have created conditions to attract
— Are the product or process innovations the key elements of first-class innovation sys-
coming out of China and India more suited tems. The prospects for making the transition
to the needs of the developing world? Inno- from production to innovation capabilities
vating companies in China and India are seem good, provided growth and capital accu-
likely to be influenced by the requirements, mulation continue at a high pace. This creates
factor endowments, and demand conditions challenges for the rest of the world. The main
of their home market that may turn out to question for the leading OECD countries is
be much closer to those of other developing whether they can retain their jobs and pros-
countries. Examples include the develop- perity based on innovation rents and the main
ment of low-cost generic drugs, new vac- question for the developing world is whether
cines for tropical diseases, new HIV/AIDS innovations coming from China and India im-
treatment derived from traditional Chinese prove their possibilities of generating sustain-
medicine (Chaturvedi & Chataway, 2006; able income growth.
342 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

NOTES

1. Forbes and Wield (2002, p. 3) go one step further where innovative activities are often not considered
and suggest that ‘‘catching up is about increasing value- R&D in the strict sense and the related expenditures not
added through production of goods and services per counted in the national statistics.
employee.’’
9. Other industries in which China has built up
2. Some scholars argue that sectoral dynamics are innovation capabilities include missile and spacecraft,
more important than territorial dynamics and have biotechnology, telecommunications, and permanent
therefore focused on the Sectoral Innovation System magnetic levitation rail transport. In the case of Indian
(Malerba, 2002). In substance, this approach is, how- industries, significant advances have been made in—
ever, closer to the value chain approach discussed below. among others—pharmaceuticals, the media industry,
missile and satellite technology, nuclear and solar
3. The dynamics of innovation systems are rarely the energy, and telecommunications.
focus of analysis. For an exception, see Lee and
Tunzelmann (2005). 10. National Bureau of Statistics of China (2005, Table
21ff).
4. The importance of combining different approaches
and scales is also emphasized by Kim and Tunzelmann 11. This is confirmed by Hennemann and Liefner
(1998) and Fromhold-Eisebith (2007). (2006) who show that firms in China’s most innovative
regions rely on a combination of national and interna-
5. This is supported by research on return migration to tional knowledge flows.
India and China (Commander, Kangasniemi, & Win-
ters, 2003; Sternberg & Müller, 2005). 12. Balaji Parthasarathy, Indian Institute of Informa-
tion Technology, personal communication.
6. Original equipment manufacture, own design man-
ufacture, and own brand manufacture. 13. See, for example, Pack and Saggi (2006) for a
critical, and Cimoli et al. (2006) for an affirmative
7. For an historical overview on 40 years of developing perspective.
science, technology, and innovation indicators, see
Freeman and Soete (2007). 14. A ‘‘Google-Search’’ of the word Offshoring on
Websites hosted on German servers, in February 2007
8. Here again methodological considerations call for a resulted in more than 1 million hits.
cautious interpretation. The most dynamic technology
sectors in India are software and IT-enabled services,

REFERENCES

Altenburg, T. (2006a). Governance patterns in value Fransman, & K. King (Eds.), Technological capabil-
chains and their development impact. European ity in the Third World. London: Macmillan.
Journal of Development Research, 18(4), 498–521. Bell, M. (2006). Time and technological learning in
Altenburg, T. (2006b). Opportunities for Asian countries industrialising countries: How long does it take?
to catch up with knowledge-based competition. In B. How fast is it moving (if at all)? International Journal
A. Lundvall et al. (Eds.), Asia’s innovation systems in of Technology Management, 36(1/2/3), 25–39.
transition (pp. 21–53). Cheltenham: Elgar. Bell, M., & Albu, M. (1999). Knowledge systems and
Ariffin, N., & Figueiredo, P. N. (2004). Internationali- technological dynamism in industrial clusters in
sation of innovative capabilities: Counter-evidence developing countries. World Development, 27(9),
from the electronics industry in Malaysia and Brazil. 1715–1734.
Oxford Development Studies, 32(4), 559–583. Bell, M., & Pavitt, K. (1995). The development of
Baskaran, A. (2005). From science to commerce: The technological capabilities. In Irfan ul Haque (Ed.),
evolution of space development policy and technol- Trade and international competitiveness. Economic
ogy accumulation in India. Technology in Society, 27, Development Institute, Washington: The World
155–179. Bank.
Bell, M. (1984). Learning and the accumulation of Bound, K. (2007). India: The uneven innovator. London:
industrial capacity in developing countries. In M. Demos.
BREAKTHROUGH? CHINA’S AND INDIA’S TRANSITION 343

Braczyk, H.-J., Cooke, P., & Heidenreich, M. (Eds.). Hennemann, S., & Liefner, I. (2006). Kooperations- und
Regional innovation systems. The role of governance in Innovationsverhalten von chinesischen Hoch-
a globalized world. London: University College technologieunternehmen. Zeitschrift für Wirtschafts-
London Press. geographie, 50(1), 58–71.
Cassiolato, J. E., Lastres, H. M. M., & Maciel, M. L. Hobday, M. (1995). Innovation in East Asia. Chelten-
(Eds.) (2003). Systems of innovation and develop- ham: Elgar.
ment—evidence from Brazil. Cheltenham: Elgar. Humphrey, J., & Schmitz, H. (2002). How does the
Chaturvedi, K., & Chataway, J. (2006). Strategic inte- insertion in global value chains affect upgrading in
gration of knowledge in Indian pharmaceutical firms: industrial clusters. Regional Studies, 36(9), 1017–1027.
Creating competencies for innovation. International Iammarino, S. (2005). An evolutionary integrated view
Journal of Business Innovation and Research, 1(1&2), of regional systems of innovation: Concepts, mea-
27–50. sures and historical perspectives. European Planning
Cimoli, M. et al. (2006). Institutions and policies shaping Studies, 13(4), 497–519.
industrial development. An introductory note. LEM Kasturirangan, K. (2004). Indian space programme.
Working Paper 2006/02. Acta Astronautica, 54, 841–844.
Commander, S., Kangasniemi, M., & Winters, L. A. Kim, S. R., & Tunzelmann, N. (1998). Aligning internal
(2003). The brain drain—Curse or boon? Discussion and external networks: Taiwan’s specialization in IT.
Paper Series, IZA DP 809, Bonn: Institut zur SPRU Electronic Working Paper Series No. 17.
Zukunft der Arbeit, <http://opus.zbw-kiel.de/vollt- Brighton: SPRU, University of Sussex.
exte/2003/1045/pdf/dp809.pdf> (accessed 28 March Krishnan, R. (2007). Can India become an innovation
2006). powerhouse? Paper presented at Workshop on
Dossani, R., & Kenney, M. (2007). The next wave of ‘Asian Drivers: China and India Shaping the Global
globalization: Relocating service provision to India. Political Economy—Challenges for European Devel-
World Development, 35(5), 772–791. opment Policy’, Beijing, 12–13 January.
Economist Intelligence Unit (2006). Driven. Are China’s Kumar, N. (2001). National innovation systems and the
car manufacturers ready to compete in the US and Indian software industry development. Background
Europe?. London: EIU. Paper for Industrial Development Report 2002/2003,
Edquist, C. (Ed.) (1997). Systems of innovation—Tech- Competing through innovation and learning. Geneva:
nologies, institutions and organizations. London: Pin- United Nations Industrial Development Organisation.
ter. Leadbeater, C., & Wilsdon, J. (2007). The atlas of
Enright, M. J., Scott, E. E., & Chang, Ka-mun (2005). ideas—How Asian innovation can benefit us all.
Regional powerhouse: The Greater Pearl River Delta London.
and the rise of China. Singapore: John Wiley & Sons Lee, T.-L., & Tunzelmann, N. (2005). A dynamic
(Asia) Pte Ltd. analytic approach to national innovation systems:
Ernst, D. (2002). Global production networks and the The IC industry in Taiwan. Research Policy, 34,
changing geography of innovation systems. Implica- 425–440.
tions for developing countries. Economics of Innova- Lema, R. (2006). Global value chains, business organi-
tion and New Technology, 11(6), 497–523. sation and structural transformation in the software
Figeuiredo, P. N. (2001). Technological learning and cluster in Bangalore. In D. Fleming, & K. Nordhaug
competitive performance. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar. (Eds.), Global challenges—local responses. An insti-
Forbes, N., & Wield, D. (2002). From followers to tutional perspective on economic transformation in
leaders—Managing technology and innovation. Lon- Asia (pp. 320–340). Roskilde University: Interna-
don: Routledge. tional Development Studies, Roskilde University.
Freeman, C. (1995). The ‘National System of Innova- Lema, R. (2007). Outsourcing and innovation in Indian
tion’, in historical perspective. Cambridge Journal of software industry. Paper presented at the Second
Economics, 19(1), 5–24. International Workshop on The changing knowledge
Freeman, C., & Soete, L. (2007). Developing science, divide in the global economy, 2–5 May 2007. Brigh-
technology and innovation indicators: What we can ton: Institute of Development Studies.
learn from the past. UNU-MERIT Working Papers, Li, Z. (2005). Das chinesische Innovationssystem: Eine
1/2007. Analyse der Informations- und Elektronikindustrie in
Fromhold-Eisebith, M. (2007). Bridging scales in inno- Qingdao. Hamburg: Institut für Asienkunde.
vation policies: How to link regional, national and Long, G. (2005). China’s policies on FDI: Review and
international innovation systems. European Planning evaluation. In T. Moran, E. M. Graham, & M.
Studies, 15(2), 215–231. Blomström (Eds.), Does foreign direct investment pro-
Gao, P. (2004). Supplying auto parts to the world. The mote development? (pp. 315–336). Washington, DC.
McKinsey Quarterly: The Online Journal of McKin- Lundvall, B.-A. (1988). Innovation as an interactive
sey & Co., 2004 Special Edition: China today. process: From user–producer interaction to the
Gereffi, G., Humphrey, J., & Sturgeon, T. (2005). The national system of innovation. In G. Dosi, C.
governance of global value chains. Review of Inter- Freeman, R. Nelson, G. Silverberg, & L. Soete
national Political Economy, 12(1), 78–104. (Eds.), Technical change and economic theory. Lon-
Grace, C. (2005). Update on China and India and access don: Pinter.
to medicines. London: DFID Health Resource Cen- Ma, J., Nguyen, N., & Xu, J. (2006). China’s innovation
trewww.difidhealthrc.org. drive. Hong Kong: Deutsche Bank.
344 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

Malerba, F. (2002). Sectoral systems of innovation and for the global distribution of innovation activities.
production. Research Policy, 31, 247–264. Mimeo: Institute of Development Studies, Sussex
Mitsuhashi, K. (2005). The furniture value chain from and University of Marburg.
Thailand to Japan: Upgrading and the role of Siwek, S. E., & Furchgott-Roth, H. W. (1993). Interna-
buyers. Doctoral thesis. Brighton: Institute of Devel- tional trade in computer software. Portsmouth,
opment Studies, University of Sussex. NH.
Nasscom (2007). Indian IT Industry Factsheet. New Stamm, A. (2005). Perspektiven für Entwicklungsländer?
Delhi: National Association of Software & Service Die Internationalisierung des Dienstleistungsmark-
Companies. tes. In A. Boes, & M. Schwemmle (Eds.), Bangalore
National Bureau of Statistics of China (2005). China statt Böblingen? Offshoring und Internationalisierung
Statistical Yearbook. Beijing. im IT-Sektor. Hamburg.
Navas-Aleman, L. (2006). Opportunities and obstacles Sternberg, R., & Müller, C. (2005). Return migration in
for industrial upgrading of Brazilian footwear and regional innovation systems. Asian Journal of Tech-
furniture firms: A comparison of global and national nology Innovation, 13(2), 71–93.
value chains. Doctoral thesis. Brighton: Institute of Strambach, S. (2004). Wissensökonomie, organisatorischer
Development Studies, University of Sussex. Wandel und wissensbasierte Regionalentwicklung.
Nelson, R. (2004). The challenge of building an effective Herausforderungen für die Wirtschafts geogra-
innovation system for catch-up. Oxford Development phie. Zeitschrift für Wirtschaftsgeographie, 48(1),
Studies, 32(3), 365–374. 1–18.
Nelson, R., & Sampat, B. (2001). Making sense of Sturgeon, T. (2002). Modular production networks: A
institutions as a factor shaping economic perfor- new American model of industrial organisation.
mance. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organiza- Industrial and Corporate Change, 11(3), 351–495.
tion, 44(1), 31–54. Thomas, J. J. (2006). India and China in the knowledge
Noble, G. (2006). The emergence of the Chinese and economy: Rivals or allies? Case studies of pharma-
Indian automobile industries and implications for ceuticals and biotechnology. Paper presented at the
other developing countries. Background Paper for Globelics 2006 Conference, Trivandrum, India,
Dancing with Giants: China, India, and the Global October.
Economy. Institute for Policy Studies and the World Tijssen, R., & Hollanders, H. (2006). Using science and
Bank. Washington, DC. technology indicators to support knowledge-based
OECD (1997). The measurement of scientific and tech- economies. UNU-Merit, Policy Brief 11, Maastricht.
nological activities. Proposed guidelines for collecting UNCTAD (2000). Cross-border M&A and Development:
and interpreting technological innovation data. Oslo World Investment Report 2000. Geneva.
Manual. Paris: OECD. UNCTAD (2005). TNCs and the Internationalization of
OECD (2006). Science, Technology and Industry Out- R&D: World Investment Report 2005. Geneva.
look 2006. Paris. UNCTAD (2006). FDI from Developing and Transition
Pack, H., & Saggi, K. (2006). Is there a case for Economies: Implications for Development: World
industrial policy? A critical survey. The World Bank Investment Report 2006. Geneva.
Research Observer, 21(2), 267–297. Wilsdon, J., & Keeley, J. (2007). China: The next science
Pérez, C. (1989). Technical change, competitive restructur- superpower. London: Demos.
ing and institutional reforms in developing countries. Wilson, D., Puroshothaman, R., & Fiotakis, D. (2004).
World Bank Discussion Paper, No. 4, Washington. The BRICs and global markets: Crude, cars, and
Porter, M. (2001). Regions and the new economics of capital. Goldman Sachs, Global Economics Paper
competition. In A. Scott (Ed.), Global city-regions: No. 118, <http://www.new-frontiers.org/classicdocs/
Trends, theory and policy. Oxford and New York: thebricsreport.pdf> (accessed Mach 2nd, 2007).
Oxford University Press. World Economic Forum (2006). The global competi-
PriceWaterhouseCoopers (2005). China’s impact on the tiveness report 2005–2006. Policies underpinning
semiconductor industry. 2005 update, no place. rising prosperity. Geneva.
Saxenian, A. (2006). The new Argonauts: Regional WTO (2005). International Trade Statistics, 2005.
advantage in a global economy. Cambridge, Massa- Yusuf, S., Nabeshima, K., & Perkins, L. (2006). China
chusetts: Harvard University Press. and India reshape global industrial geography. In A.
Schmitz, H. (2006). Learning and earning in global Winters, & S. Yusuf (Eds.), Dancing with giants:
garment and footwear chains. European Journal of China, India, and the global economy (pp. 27–56).
Development Research, 18(4), 546–571. Washington/Singapore: World Bank, Institute of
Schmitz, H., & Nadvi, K. (1999). Clustering and Policy Studies.
industrialization: Introduction. World Development, Zhou, Y. (2005). The making of an innovative region
27(9), 1503–1514. from a centrally planned economy: Institutional
Schmitz, H., & Strambach, S. (2007). The organizational evolution in Zhongguancun Science Park in Beijing.
decomposition of the innovation process: Implications Environment and Planning A, 37, 1113–1134.

Available online at www.sciencedirect.com

You might also like