You are on page 1of 13

Menem and the Governors 89

fiscal crisis of 2001-2. Gone are the days when students of Argentine
politics can attempt to make sense of the country’s political life without
paying serious attention to the provinces and to the governors who control
them. The importance of the roles now played by governors can best be
demonstrated by examining the economic reforms that dominated the pol-
— icy agenda in the 1990s.
According to a growing body of research, provincial governors directly
B
influenced reform outcomes in a variety of dimensions over the course of
— the 1990s. Gibson and Calvo, for example, argue that the interior prov-
inces constituting Peronism’s “peripheral coalition” were able to secure
B e )
advantageous fiscal transfers in exchange for supporting Carlos Menem'’s
Menem and the Governors: market-oriented policies (Gibson 1997; Gibson and Calvo 2000). Remmer
Intergovernmental Relations in the 1990s and Wibbels (2000) show that federal transfers emboldened provincial
officials to flout the preferences of national politicians and to expand dra-
Kent Eaton matically the size of provincial public sector payrolls. In their survey of
policy change during Menem’s two terms as president, Tommasi and
Spiller (2000, 136—40) document the governors’ ability to veto the market-
oriented economic reforms that Menem wanted them to adopt at the pro-
For much of the twentieth century, Argentina was a federal country in vincial level. Jones, Sanguinetti, and Tommasi (2000) find that opposition
name only. By centralizing power in the hands of the national government, governors posed particularly acute problems for the president’s fiscal ad-
most of the leading political and economic developments in that century justment drive, and Eaton (2002) argues that provincial officials used the
were unkind to federalism. In the political realm, chronic coup making legislators rep;%senfing their districts in Congress to acquire preferential
by the armed forces weakened the country’s federal identity by replacing policy treatment from the center.”
democratically elected provincial officials with military appointees and by I contend that the provinces are critical in seeking to explain both Ar-
closing the most important arena for the expression of provincial interests: gentina’s economic successes in the first half of the 1990s and its spectac-
the federal legislature. Meanwhile, in democratic and semidemocratic pe- ular failures later in the decade. To illustrate this argument, I focus on
riods alike, charismatic leaders like Hipélito Yrigoyen and Juan Perén the institution of federal revenue sharing. Given the time and energy that
built political parties that forced rank-and-file politicians to privilege the politicians in Argentina devote to securing access to revenues, this institu-
national party line over the concerns of their home provinces. In the eco- tional arena is a particularly useful window onto the balance of power
nomic realm, Argentina’s particularly radical version of state-led industri- between the federal and provincial governments. In the early 199os, Presi-
alization, together with a crisismanagement style of policymaking dent Menem introduced major changes in the rules governing revenue
necessitated by the country’s repeated stop-and-go cycles, served over time sharing with the provinces through the negotiation of two distinct fiscal
to strengthen the center at the expense of provincial governments. Thus, pacts. According to the logic of each pact, the federal government was
at the time of Argentina’s most recent transition to democracy, in 1983, authorized to remove tax revenues from the revenue-sharing pool and to
the provinces had been at the receiving end of decades of political and
economic change, all of which tended to undermine provincial leverage in
1. The 1990s proved to be a fruitful time for research into provincial actors and institu-
the national political system. tions more broadly. On the incidence of provincial factors in privatization, see Llanos 1998
The return to democracy in 1983, however, marked a sea change in the and 2001. On the importance of provincial parties, see Palanza and Sin 1997. For a study of
relationship between the provincial and federal governments. In the past attempts to strengthen the rule of law in the provinces. see Bill Chivez 2003. On the provin-
dial incentives facing legislators, see Jones et al. 2002. On the role of provincial party leaders
two decades, governors have wrested substantial political and fiscal author- relative to both national and grassroots Peronist actors, see Levitsky 2001, For a study of the
ity from the center, a complex process that culminated in the profound transfer of education to the provinces, see Murillo 1999,
90 Argentine Democracy Menem and the Governors 91
devote these revenues exclusively to national government expenditures in minimo and experienced as a result a real loss of maneuverability in his
exchange for guaranteeing that provincial transfers would not drop below attempt to forestall the country’s catastrophic default on its external debt.
a minimum floor (piso minimo). In other words, provinces were compen- The behavior of the governors in defense of the revenue guarantee was
sated for the percentage reduction in revenue sharing with a new set of thus directly implicated in the fiscal crisis that erupted in 2001 and which
property rights vis-3-vis federal tax revenues. Compensation strategies led to De Ia Riia’s resignation at the end of that year.
proved to be especially important in Argentina, Latin America’s most strik- This chapter is organized in the following manner. In the next section
ing case of market-based reform under democratic auspices, and intergov- I discuss the sources of gubernatorial power that, in periods of democratic
ernmental relations offer yet another example of how compensation was rule, have enabled governors to project a considerable amount of authority
deployed as a reform tool (Etchemendy, this volume; Murillo 2001; Torre into national-level debates and decisions. In order to set the stage for the
1998). struggles over revenue that took place in the 1990s, the second section
In the 1990s, these two fiscal pacts proved to be as momentous for returns to the decision of the provinces in the 19305 to delegate taxing
Argentina’s political economy as the 1991 Convertibility Law, which to date powers to the federal government in exchange for a share of the proceeds.
has received more attention from scholars and policymakers alike. Indeed, All subsequent changes have essentially been reforms of this earlier ar-
as new institutional rules, the fiscal pacts and the Convertibility Law share rangement, and the depth of the current crisis suggests the need to return
several features. Just as convertibility served to bind the hands of politi- to the logic of this initial act of delegation. Considering the significant
cians by tying the peso to the dollar at parity, the pacts instituted a rigid leverage that governors enjoy under democracy, the decision by the prov-
system of minimum revenue guarantees to replace the traditional method inces to depend on fiscal transfers rather than collect their own taxes has
of percentage-based revenue sharing. Like convertibility, the two fiscal emerged as an important source of fiscal strain. The third section focuses
pacts were expressly designed to bolster Menem’s attempt to achieve and on Menem’s unique opportunity to restructure intergovernmental rela-
defend macroeconomic stability at the center, an achievement that led to tions through the fiscal pacts of the early 1990s. Initially these pacts deliv-
his reelection in 1995. The new revenue-sharing rules contributed directly ered short-tern gains to the federal government, but as the fourth section
to the ability of the federal government to control federal budget deficits, shows, over the tourse of Menem’s second administration they generated
fight inflation, and meet the rigors of a new fiscal paradigm in which unanticipated benefits for the provinces. Furthermore, governors success-
money printing was no longer an option. By surrendering their full legal fully increased the level of the piso minimo, demonstrating the weakening
shares of federally collected tax revenues, the provinces contributed to the of Menem’s political authority within the Peronist party. The fifth section
historic stabilization of the macroeconomy in Menem’s first term. Teviews the content and outcome of reform attempts under the aborted De
Also like convertibility, however, the revenue floor proved to be double- la Riia administration and closes with a discussion of how Duhalde built
edged. Undoubtedly, with the surge in tax collection in the first half of the political support for the revoking of revenue guarantees in early 2002. The
1990s, the fiscal pacts delivered important gains to the federal government final section concludes by mining this case for insights into the larger
by no longer requiring it to share with the provinces a set percentage of a questions of institutional design and strength that are at the center of this
dramatically expanding pie. Yet once revenues declined at the end of the volume.
1990s, institutional innovation in the guise of minimum revenue guaran-
tees came back to bite the federal government, now obliged by the pacts to
share a set amount with the provinces regardless of actual tax revenues. THE SOURCES OF GUBERNATORIAL POWER IN ARGENTINA
Rule changes that had represented a revenue grab by the federal govern-
ment and a sacrifice on the part of the provinces in 1992 and 1993 were How did Argentine governors in the last two decades of the twentieth cen-
transformed into a major boon to the provinces and a serious problem for tury achieve greater political prominence? One answer to this question lies
the center after 1996. Though economic decline seriously compromised in a process of redemocratization initiated in 1983, which for all its prob-
the tax collection of the federal government during the two years that Fer- lems and limitations, has been far more successful than the country’s
five
nando De la Ria governed Argentina, he was powerless to remove the piso prior attempts at democratization. In the past, transitions from military
e ————

92 Argentine Democracy
Menem and the Governors 9
government that reinstated provincial elections temporarily raised the gov- that favors the executive branch relative to the
ernors’ visibility and enabled them to secure gains for their provinces legislature at the national
level is replicated at the provincial level, to the
(Eaton 2001). Sooner or later, however, democracy collapsed in the after- great benefit of the gover-
nors.
math of these earlier transitions, and the reversal to nondemocratic forms The structure of political parties and the content
of government denied provinces the types of channels they could use to of electoral rules are
the final and perhaps most important present-day
defend and build on these gains. [t is important to remember that military sources of gubernatorial
power. As Jones and Hwang show in their contr
coups interrupted democracy not just at the national level but at the subna- ibution to this volume,
partisan and electoral incentives endow governors
tional level as well, and that their frequency in the twentieth century hin- with significant leverage
over the legislators who belong to their parties and
dered the development of stable democratic institutions at both the who represent provin-
cial electoral districts in the federal legislature. With
national and provincial levels. Thanks to the failure of coup attempts after respect to the Senate,
governors wield considerable influence over the
1983, Argentine provinces have now accumulated over two decades of un- selection of the candidate
who will represent his or her party in the genera
interrupted experience with the holding of regularly scheduled elections. l election. In the Chamber
of Deputies, representatives are elected according
These elections endow governors with a degree of democratic legitimacy to closed lists written by
three sets of actors: national party organizations, provin
that has strengthened them in their negotiations with the center. cial party organiza-
tions, and less often, rank-and-file party members.
In combination with the longevity of Argentina’s current experience Despite cross-provincial
variation in the relative importance of these three
with democracy, a number of other factors help explain the newfound im- actors in writing party
lists, provincial party leaders often negotiate a
portance of the provinces and their governors. One is the decreased use of
single list among them-
selves and avoid primary elections entirely (Jones
a constitutional prerogative that enables the federal government to dismiss 1997b, 9-13). In prac-
tice, when the leader of the provincial party is also
the elected government of a given province. Though
governor, that individual
President Menem retains significant power over the voting behavior
used this power of intervention more than President Alfonsin, who de- of federal representa-
tives. However, as Jones notes, when the president
clined to intervene in a single province, the post-1983 period stands in of the national party
organization is gso the president of the nation
, his or her influence over
sharp contrast to the second-longest period of democratic rule (1916-30), the composition of provincial candidate lists tends
during which President Yrigoyen intervened in no fewer than twenty prov-
to increase relative to
provin cial authorities.
inces. Second, not only have federal authorities refrained from using their In the struggle between national and provincial party
full powers over provincial elected officials, but the use of nonconcurrent leaders for influ-
ence over legislators, much depends on the career
prospects of the national
elections has increased the influence of provincial electoral outcomes on a party leadership. Menem’s successful bid to chang
e the Constitution and
range of political phenomena at the national level (Jones 1997a). Specifi- run for reelection enabled him to exert tight contro
cally, the holding of provincial elections in the months leading up to na- l over Peronist leg-
islators in his first administration. Menem used
this power to force the
tional elections has generated a great deal of national leverage for revenue-sharing pacts upon the provinces, the majori
ty of which were gov-
victorious governors. Third, many provinces rewrote their own constitu- erned by fellow Peronists. This type of power
was unavailable to Menem
tions in the 1980s and 1990s to allow the reelection of the governor, simi- once he became a lame duck with his reelection
in 1995, which reduced
lar in spirit to the reform of the federal constitution in 1994 that paved his powers over Peronist legislators relative to Peroni
the way for Menem’s reelection as president the following year. In many st governors and en-
sured that he would have a much more difficult
time imposing losses on
provinces, successful reelection campaigns following the removal of term the provinces. Thus, while the continued playing
of the democratic game
limits have made it easier for governors to dominate politics within their has certainly strengthened governors since 1983,
the degree of their influ-
provinces and to translate this dominance into increased influence in na- ence over legislators still fluctuates in Tesponse
to national phenomena,
tional decision-making arenas.* Partially as a result, the same imbalance including the strength of presidential leadership
and the national electoral
2. Eduardo Duhalde, former governor of Buenos Aires province and president of Argen- calendar.
tina from January 2002 to May 2003, and Néstor Kirchner, former governor of Santa Cruz dynamic, but there are other examples as well, includi
and president of Argentina since May 2003, are the two most important examples of this
Rodriguez Sa of San Luis, Juan Carlos Romero of Salta,ngandformer interim president Adolfo
Ruben Marin of La Pampa.
94 Argentine Democracy Menem and the Governors 95
INSTITUTIONAL INNOVATION: THE CREATION OF the 1853 constitution allowed federal collection of direct taxes in emergen-
CO-PARTICIPACTON cies and for limited periods. Second was the passage of new federal sales
and excise taxes that required the provinces to cease collecting similar
Understanding the significance of how intergovernmental relations taxes in exchange for a share of federal revenues from these tax bases.
changed in the 1990s requires some background. Conflict over revenue Several aspects of this new institutional arrangement, henceforth re-
between the federal and provincial governments has been at the heart of ferred to as coparticipation, deserve emphasis. One is the extent to which
Argentine political history from the very beginning. Nominally a federal revenue sharing initially favored the federal government, which would re-
regime but in practice one that brutally repressed the interior, the govern- ceive 82.5 percent of the proceeds from the new taxes. Over time, the dis-
ment of Juan Manuel de Rosas (1829-53) crystallized support among the tribution of revenues between the two levels of government would
interior provinces for a national government that would be strong enough increasingly favor the provinces relative to the federal government. The
to constrain the province of Buenos Aires and to check its abuses of the apparently disadvantageous terms for the provinces in the 1934 legislation
port Consequently, one of the core features of the 1853 constitution that raise the question of why provincial authorities agreed to this new arrange-
provincial representatives wrote was the exclusive assignment of taxes on ment. According to Pirez (1986) and F1EL (1993), the federal government
external trade to the federal government.+ While the federal government offered debt forgiveness as a means of encouraging governors to agree
was endowed with exclusive control over the most important tax base, the to the coparticipation scheme, essentially playing to the vulnerabilities of
1853 constitution reserved for the provinces exclusive authority over direct provincial authorities. It is also the case that revenue sharing appealed to
taxes and stipulated that hoth levels of government could raise domestic governors, despite the small share of revenues that would come back to
consumption taxes (Pirez 1986, 11).5 Before the 1930s, a pronounced de- the provinces in the form of transfers, because it enabled them in a period
gree of separation characterized revenue collection in Argentina: the fed- of economic turbulence to shift the political and administrative costs of tax
eral government collected most of its revenues from trade taxes, and the collection onto the federal government. Focused on the short term, provin-
provincial governments collected most of their revenues from domestic cial authorities agreed to changes that in effect reduced the institutional
consumption taxes (Macén 1985; Randall 1978). capacity of the provinces as separate units of government.
Just as the international economic crisis of 1930 set in motion deep The introduction of revenue sharing in 1934 proved to be a watershed
changes in the country’s economic policy orientation (Dfaz Alejandro event for the subsequent development of intergovernmental relations in
1970), this same exogenous shock proved to be a critical juncture for inter- Argentina. Even though the 1934 laws were of limited duration, when the
governmental relations. The decline in external trade seriously compro- provinces agreed to surrender responsibility for these tax bases, their deci-
mised the federal government’s fiscal strength at the very moment it was sion had powerful and highly negative consequences for the integrity of
seeking to expand infrastructure projects to keep unemployment rates provincial governments for years to come. Technically, the provinces in
from skyrocketing, In this context, the government of Agustin Justo pro- subsequent decades were free to revoke the right of the federal govern-
posed two important measures. First was the introduction of a direct tax ment to collect their taxes each time they negotiated extensions of the co-
on incomes, formally the exclusive prerogative of the provinces, though participation regulation.® In his time as governor of La Rioja in the 1980s,
3. For a discussion of regional conflicts in the formation of Argentine federalism, see for example, Carlos Menem threatened to do just that by calling on his
Gibson and Falleti 2003. counterparts in other provinces to declare a state of rebellion in the inte-
4. In a response that reflected the interior's overarching goal of restraining the most tior, cutting the supply of energy to the capital, blocking provincial ports,
important province, Buenos Aires refused to sign the 1853 constitution, blockaded the Parani and taking back all powers delegated to the federal government (Pirez
River in an attempt to bring the interior to heel, and subsequently defeated the interior in
the 1861 battle of Pavén. Subsequent to its military victory, Buenos Aires agreed to ratify the 1986, 68). But such threats were less than credible. Once the provinces
x853 constitution, but only after insisting on key amendments, including suppressing lan- delegated taxing authority in the 1930s, provincial tax-raising capacity atro-
guage that would transform the city of Buenos Aires into a national capital and force it to phied in a way that foreclosed this option. In effect, the 1934 decision
share its trade revenues. Only in 1880, with the federalization of the port city, was the central-
ization of trade taxation actually achieved (Ruiz Moreno 198o). shifted the terms of the debate over subnational institutions from a discus-
5+ The Constitution also stipulated that every power not expressly delegated to the federal
government would remain with the provinces. 6. New coparticipation laws were legislated in 1047, 1959, 1964, 1973, and 1988,
96 Argentine Democracy Menem and the Governors 97

Table 41 Vertical fiscal imbalance in Argentina, 1997 federal transfers, it raises important and difficult questions about their
rights to these transfers and the status of these revenues as either provin-
Taxes cial or federal in origin. On the one hand, the claim by provincial authori-
(excluding social (including social ties that they have legal rights to the transfers seems justifiable,
security contributions) security contributions) particularly in the case of the direct taxes that the Constitution reserves
Where Where Where Where for the provinces alone. This view of transfers is clearly reflected in the
the taxes therevenues the taxes the revenues recalcitrance of demands by Peronist governors in 2001 that the De la Riia
are collected arespent are collected are spent administration make good on its past revenue-sharing obligations before
(recaudacién) (recursos) (recaudacién) | recursos)
they would contemplate any changes in the system. Though the press typi-
Federal Government ~ 77.3% 45.4% 81.6% 55% cally understood these transfers as handouts,” they were essentially reve-
Provinces 227% 54.6% 18.4% 44%
nues that came to the federal government at least in part because of the
Sourc: Piffano 1998. ongoing provincial delegation of taxing authority. On the other hand, it
was the federal government that had long paid the administrative and po-
sion over the appropriate division of governing responsibilities to nearly litical costs of collecting taxes that the provinces stopped collecting decades
constant political battles over the division of revenues collected by the fed- ago.
eral government. In this sense, the events of 1934 mark a critical juncture
in the relationship between the provinces and the federal government.
Due to the stickiness of the decision to delegate provincial taxing au- INSTITUTIONAL REDESIGN IN THE FIRST MENEM
thority to the federal government, coupled with the transfer of responsibili- ADMINISTRATION: LOS PACTOS FISCALES
ties to the provinces in the early 1980s and again in the early 199o0s,
Argentina experienced increasing vertical fiscal imbalance. By 1997, as After two harrowing years, President Menem’s attempts at macroeco-
seen in Table 4.1, the country’s fiscal structure reflected a serious disparity nomic stabilizalton finally succeeded in 1991 with the adoption of the Con-
Detween the level of government where taxes are collected and the level of vertibility Law. Success immediately posed serious problems for the
government where tax revenues are spent. president, including the reality that stabilization and the consequent
In order to appreciate the significance of how Menem altered the sys- strengthening of tax collection would automatically generate a sharp in-
tem in the early r9gos, we should also note what did not change in the crease in provincial transfers. Ironically, the chief problem for the presi-
nearly six decades between 1934 and 1992. In these years, the exact size dent was a 1987 coparticipation law pushed by the Peronists themselves
of provincial revenue transfers was determined by applying a fixed percent- that reserved 57 percent of federal tax revenues for the provinces. For Men-
age to a pool of revenues that changed with actual tax collection in any em'’s purposes, the defense of macroeconomic stability would require a
given year (Nufiez Mifiana and Porto 1982; Porto 1990). Taxes were taken revision in the rules governing revenue sharing to benefit the federal gov-
in and out of the revenue pool, and provinces experienced increases and ernment so that it could meet its obligations and eschew its former reli-
decreases in the share they received, but the sharing was consistently per- ance on the inflation tax. Accordingly, in 1992 and 1993, he proposed two
centage based, and therefore highly pro-cyclical (108 1997). In good years, fiscal pacts that would reduce provincial revenue shares by reserving 15
the increase in federal tax collection could translate into sharp real percent of the revenues subject to provincial sharing and dedicating these
increases in the amount of revenues provinces would receive from the revenues to a key expenditure of the federal government: social security.
federal government. In bad years, provinces could likewise experience de- The effect was to reduce the percentage share of the provinces, which
bilitating declines in actual revenue transfers. Nothing was guaranteed in was not a new phenomena in Argentina, since similar centralizing
this period other than the application of an exact percentage to a changing
pool. 7. See “Argentina Says It Will Restructure Debt: Government Hopes to Avoid Defaulting
on Loans as Economic Crisis Deepens,” Washington Posi, October 29, 2001, p. A14, and
Because coparticipation asks the provinces to forgo collecting some of “Argentine Leader in Talks to Avoid Default on $r32 Billion Debt,” New York Times, Novem-
the taxes that the Constitution assigns to them in exchange for receiving ber 1, 2001, p. 6.
98 Argentine Democracy Menem and the Governors 99

changes had occurred in the wake of military coups in 1966 and 1976 heavily on the use of selective incentives to get a sufficient number of
(Eaton 2004). What was new, however, was that Menem agreed in ex- governors on board. For example, his minister of the economy increased
change to the introduction of a minimum floor for revenue transfers below the pressure on provincial governments to sign by pledging to lift certain
which transfers would not dip, regardless of actual revenue collection. taxes on companies located in provinces that had signed the pact. Menem
Thus in the first fiscal pact of August 1992, the federal government com- also pledged help in a variety of forms for provinces that were inclined not
mitted itself to transfer no less than U.S.$720 million to the provinces to sign (cGE 1993). Governors in Chaco and Formosa, for example, re-
every month, which it raised to $740 million in the second pact one year versed their initially hostile stances after Menem pledged federal help with
later. Neither pact was designed to be permanent; indeed, the terms of the provincial debts (Chaco) and the establishment of a special free-trade zone
second pact were binding only until July 1, 1995. Whereas all governors (Formosa). In other words, that the piso minimo turned out to be such a
signed onto the first pact before it was approved by the legislature, only boon for the provinces should not blind us to fact that the pacts were
sixteen out of twenty-three governors agreed to the second pact before its inspired by the central government and, in the flush times of 1992 and
implementation, which reflects the fact that the second pact made addi- 1993, represented an immediate and huge loss in revenue to the provinces.
tional transfers contingent on a series of federally mandated provincial According to Cetrangolo and Jiménez, the provinces lost approximately
reforms.? US$13 billion between 1992 and 1996 because of the pacts (Fundacién
Significantly, the logic behind these changes was not to benefit the CECE 1997, 43). Nor should the problems later created by revenue guaran-
provinces in an attempt to thereby build support for Menem’s market re- tees prevent us from appreciating the extent to which the fiscal pacts
forms.> Though the revenue guarantee would later prove to be a godsend helped Menem defend macrostability at the center in the first half of the
for the provinces, in 1992 and 1993 the pacts demanded that the governors 1990s.
give up their legal shares of tax revenues at a time when these revenues In addition to financing the generous use of side payments, Argentina’s
were finally becoming more substantial. Percentage cuts for provincial economic successes in the early 199os facilitated the negotiation of the
transfers were difficult for the governors to swallow given the growth in fiscal pacts in another way as well. The increase in tax revenues that fol-
tax revenues and the symbolic quality of the 198y legislation, which had lowed from ecbnomic stabilization and tax reform made it possible for
sought to reverse the prejudicial treatment suffered by the provinces under governors to accept cuts in revenue sharing and still receive more from
the preceding military dictatorship. Several opposition legislators warned the federal government in transfers than they had received during the cha-
in Congress that governors who signed these pacts and thereby agreed to otic years of the late 1980s. Later, when the economy stalled and tax reve-
accept less than their provinces’ full percentage shares of revenue might nues declined, governors were not nearly as willing to consider requests
very well find themselves subject to legal action.= for cuts in transfers, though these continued to emanate from the execu-
Support for my argument that provincial authorities considered the fis- tive branch. The increase in tax revenues in the early 199os, together with
cal pacts to be first and foremost a loss for them can be seen in the months the general euphoria surrounding the end of hyperinflation and renewed
that preceded the signing of the pacts, during which Menem depended economic growth, also mattered because they gave the federal government
less pause about the wisdom of extending a fixed revenue guarantee to the
8. Ultimately, afraid that they would be penalized for not signing the pact, all governors provinces. Not expecting revenue to decline and convinced of the need to
who did not originally agree to the terms of the second pact eventually signed it.
9- See Gibson and Calvo 2000 for the argument that Menem made federal transfers to cut revenue transfers as quickly as possible to produce federal savings,
Argentina's less developed provinces conditional on their support for federal economic re- representatives of the federal government agreed to bind it in a way that
forms. As Gibson and Calvo argue, the increase in discretionary transfers can be attributed to had long-lasting and negative consequences. As for the governors, al-
Menem's attempt to court the “peripheral coalition” of interior provinces. The story is differ-
ent. however, for those tax revenues subject to automatic sharing (coparticipation} as opposed though they were unable to defend the advantageous terms of the 198y
to discretionary disbursement. In the area of automatic revenue sharing, the increase in revenue-sharing law, they were quite savvy in their insistence on a revenue
transfers in the 1990-95 period was not the result of political manipulation by Menem and floor that looked low in 1992-93 but much higher later in the decade.»
would have been even greater if Menem had not acted to limit the transfers through the two
fiscal pacts. Thus we need to distinguish the centralizing logic of the fiscal pacts from the
important argument that discretionary transfers were manipulated to favor peripheral prov- 11 Apart from the question of where the revenue floor was set, governors liked knowing
inces in the interests of economic reform. exactly how much revenuc they would receive each month, which reduced unceriainties in
10. Diario de Sesiones de la Cdmara de Dinutadns de ln Naridn Sveviet va ~n fhm nwewineial hndnstine nencace
100 Argentine Democracy Menem and the Governors 101
Ultimately, however, side payments and differing estimates of reverue about its ability to afford revenue guarantees and led its representatives to
collection in the future cannot explain Menerm'’s ability to secure the fiscal favor their abandonment. When the second fiscal pact expired in July 1995,
pacts politically. Critical is the degree of authority Menem enjoyed over however, the Senate proposed making this extension indefinite “until such
the Peronist governors with whom he negotiated the pacts and over the time as representatives of the federal and provincial governments can de-
Peronists in Congress who provided final legislative support. This author- finitively agree on the way to implement the terms of the second fiscal
ity resulted directly from Menem’s successful stabilization in 1991, an pact.”2 Governors and the legislators over whom they held sway were in-
achievement that had proved elusive in the years since the onset of the creasingly focused on ensuring the continuity of the piso minimo. In de-
debt crisis in 1982 and the return to democracy in 1983. Menem's eco- manding the extension of the revenue guarantee, legislators even proposed
nomic successes led to convincing Peronist victories in the midterm elec- giving the president additional discretion over the budget in order to make
tions of 1991 and 1993, which further bolstered his influence within the the necessary cuts that would enable the federal government to continue
Peronist party. In these years, for a Peronist governor to defy Menem’s to meet its obligations to the provinces.
reform of revenue-sharing institutions would have entailed high political In response to legislators’ efforts on behalf of the revenue guarantee,
costs. A less risky and more effective response for the governors was to the minister of the economy argued that the federal government was not
sign onto the pacts while simultaneously lobbying for side payments to legally bound (no existia disposicion legal) to honor the guarantee beyond
the provinces they governed. July 1, 1995. Senators responded that the federal government then had no
legal right to continue deducting the 15 percent amount from the revenue
pool for social security.® As the conflict between defenders of provincial
INTERGOVERNMENTAL RELATIONS IN MENEM'S SECOND TERM: and federal interests escalated, Peronist and Radical senators proposed ex-
POWER TO THE PROVINCES tending the federal government’s obligations to honor revenue guarantees,
while simultaneously eliminating from the second fiscal pact the obliga-
This section describes and explains the shift in the balance of power back tion that provinces would have to reform their own tax systems.* Though
to the provinces and away from the federal government during Menem'’s Peronist party‘fliscipline prevented this proposal from succeeding, with
second administration (1995-99). While the complexity of the policies the result that both federal and provincial obligations were formally carried
proposed and outcomes legislated make it somewhat difficult to determine over, in practice the provincial implementation of the tax and other re-
the net effect of relevant changes, it is clear that the federal government forms called for in the 1993 pact proved to be very spotty. Among other
was less able to impose losses on the provinces in this period and, in fact, things, the difficult economic situation of the provinces in the 1995/96
that the provinces were increasingly able to impose losses on the center. period bolstered the claims of the governors that they could not afford to
In these years, faced with gubernatorial recalcitrance in defense of revenue do away with taxes simply because they were deemed to be inefficient by
guarantees the federal government was forced to overadjust at the national the minister of the economy. According to Tommasi and Spiller (2000,
level (Remmer and Wibbels 2000}, a solution that ultimately proved to be 140), while provinces made significant headway in the reform of specific
unsustainable. taxes on gas and electricity, they introduced far fewer changes in the turn-
In the wake of the economic turmoil provoked by the Mexican “tequila over tax (ingresos brutos) that had been at the core of the second fiscal pact.
crisis” in 1995 and 1996, the first signs that Menem was losing the politi- In effect, the provinces were the victors in this important showdown with
cal initiative relative to the governors can be seen in congressional at- the federal government.
tempts to extend the federal government’s minimum revenue guarantee In his second administration, Menem also failed to advance two new
over the objections of the federal executive branch. Just as the poor eco- reforms to the revenue-sharing system. First, the Ministry of the Economy
nomic performance of these years depressed tax collection and began to proposed changing the criteria governing the distribution of automatic rev-
render the revenue floor increasingly attractive to all governors, Peronist
governors came to enjoy greater leverage over Peronist legislators relative 12. Diario de Sesiones de la Cdmara de Senadores de la Nacidn, July 3, 1996, p. 3376.
to a president who had just begun his second term. The effect of the crisis 13. Ibid., pp. 3377 and 3380,
14. See the speeches of Senators Cristina Ferndndez de Kirchner (¢, Santa Cruz) and
on tax receipts checked the eatlier optimism of the federal government Luis Leén (uc, Chaco) on pages 3378 and 3379.
T—
102 Argentine Democracy
Menem and the Governors 103
enue transfers to incorporate rewards for provin
cial tax effort. Such a crucial in enabling governors to resist adjustment pressures. This option
change would represent a major departure for
the system of coparticipa- would not have been nearly so available to governors in the absence of
tion. Although the criteria used to alloocate revenu
es have changed sig- guaranteed revenue transfers. Though private banks started refusing to
nificantly over the years, from the initial use of criteria that favored issue new debt to the provinces in 1999 (even loans that would be guaran-
productive capacity and population size toward
increasingly redistributive teed with federal revenue guarantees), in the years leading up to this deci-
criteria that favored poor and sparsely populated
provinces (Nunez Minana sion the provinces incurred significant debts. According to the Economist
and Porto 1983), the effort exerted Dy provincial
authorities has never been Intelligence Unit, provincial debt rose to U.S.$18 billion or 7 percent of
explicitly considered. Indeed, the fact that govern
ors would not have to Goe by 1999, the year private banks cut off further loans (s1u 1999). In
expend political capital and energy on local tax collect
ion was one of the some provinces, debt service payments amounted to nearly half of all reve-
key factors that encouraged them to delegate taxing
authority in the 1930s. nue transfers from the federal government.
While governors signed onto the most important
institutional innovation How were the provinces able to frustrate the reform proposals coming
of Menem’s first term-—the two fiscal pacts—they
simply refused to out of the federal executive in the second half of the 19gos? I emphasize
consider rewards for provincial tax effort, which
was the most important amix of economic, institutional, and partisan factors. With respect to eco-
institutional reform proposal of his second term.
When the federal govern- nomic factors, the country’s declining economic situation toward the end
ment's proposal went nowhere in Congress, Menem
proposed the more of the 1990s gave the governors additional reasons to defend the piso
limited use of provincial tax effort to distribute funds
in excess of the piso minimo. Thanks to the decline in federal tax revenues, rules that favored
minimo, but this more circumscribed proposal also
failed.’s the federal government in 1992 increasingly came to favor the provinces,
In addition to proposing new criteria, Menem also
floated the idea of especially after 1998, Declining revenues from provincial taxes and licens-
direct revenue sharing with the municipalities. Munici
pal revenue sharing ing fees, combined with surging unemployment rates throughout Argen-
was attractive to the president both as a threat that
would force the gover- tina, transformed these revenue guarantees into a vital lifeline for many
nors to contemplate cuts in provincial revenue sharin
g and as a sop to the provincial govegnors. In some provinces, between 80 and 90 percent of
country’s numerous Peronist mayors who could
help Menem in his at- the workforce was employed by provincial governments that were able to
tempt to run for a third term in 1999. Despite its
appeal to the president, meet their payrolls only because of transfers from the Federal Capital. In
governors successfully rejected this proposal.
this context, the loss of certain institutional power resources caused by
Not only did the governors defeat these attempts
to discipline the prov- such changes as the privatization of provincially owned banks in the sec-
inces and control provincial spending, they were
also able to increase the ond half of the 1990s encouraged governors to redouble their energies in
federal government’s minimum revenue guarantees to U.S.$850 million defense of the piso minimo.
per month in 1998.: The ability to raise the revenue
floor, even as Menem ‘With respect to institutional rules, governors were abetted in their at-
was trying to move in the opposite direction by introd
ucing greater flexi- tempt to deflect reform initiatives in Menem’s second term by changes in
bility into revenue sharing, demonstrates the
governors' growing power the federal constitution that had been introduced in 1994. Specifically, the
in the president’s penultimate year in office. But
the increase in revenue new constitution called for the negotiation of a new revenue-sharing law
guarantees is also significant because of how the
guarantees were used by to replace the 198y legislation, and stipulated that as a result of this new
the governors. In the late 1990s, rather than
attempt to control spending, law, no province could receive less in revenue than it had received in
governors sought to maintain or expand spending
by borrowing from pri- 19947 The Constitution also determined that all legislation affecting the
vate sector banks and by using revenue guaran
tees as collateral in securing Tevenue-sharing system had to originate in the Senate. Though both cham-
these loans. Since most provincial banks had been
privatized in the wake bers are characterized by malapportionment in Argentina, the poorer and
of the 1995 crisis, the ability to contract loans from
private banks was
5. See "La reforma fiscal entra enla etapa del realismo polftico,” I} Economi 17. Initially, the agreement between Menem and former president Alfonsin that gave rise
6,1998. sta, February to the constitutional reform (the so-called nucleo de coincidencias bdsicas) included no mention
6. See “Gobernadores se aseguran $850 millioncs cada mes,” Ambito Financi of provincial or revenue-sharing issues. A provincial coalition among the members of the
ber 10, 1998. cro, Octo- constitutional convention, however, managed to insert language on revenue sharing into the
new constitution.
104 Argentine Democracy
Menem and the Governors 105
less populated provinces that depend so heavily on revenue transfer provinces” (40). Thus, when the center finally did shift its focus onto the
s are
much better represented in the Senate and better able to use
their foothold peripheral provinces, there were sharp limits on how much provincial re-
in that body to veto the types of reforms that Menem propose
d after 1995. form it was able to impose. Ironically, these limits were in large part deter-
In practice, over the course of Menem’s second adminis
tration, these con- mined by the very instrument—revenue guarantees—that Menem had
stitutional rules prevented the negotiation of a new revenue-sharing law used to build support for his centralizing reforms of coparticipation in his
that might have introduced greater flexibility into the transfer system or early years as president.
revoked the rigid guarantees that had been introduced earlier in the
decade.®
With respect to partisan dynamics, growing factionalism within the ) RETURN TO CRISIS: PROVINCIAL-FEDERAL RELATIONS
over the course of the president's second term made it harder for Menem AFTER MENEM
to control the governors within his party. Controlling
the governors and
forcing Peronist legislators to follow the national party line
had never been Conflict between the federal and provincial governments over revenue
easy. As Levitsky shows, few provincial leaders belonged to
the president’s sharing and provincial debt used up a great deal of Fernando De la Rua’s
Menemista faction (Levitsky 2001). But the struggles to succeed
Menem political capital in his two difficult years as president (December 1999—
as the party leader that emerged immediately after his reelecti
on in 1995 December 2001). Although De la Rtia’s alliance of FrEPAsO and the Radi-
complicated his attempts to achieve further policy changes.
That Menem cals won Doth presidential and congressional elections in 1999, it was
could not necessarily count on the support of Peronist governo
rs for such much less successful in provincial elections. As in the Alfonsfn adminis-
measures as criteria that would reward provincial tax effort
illustrates one tration of the 1980s, under De la Rita most provinces were governed by the
of the main findings in Remmer and Wibbels's (2000) study,
which is Peronists. In both periods, this political reality infused center-provincial
that partisan ties do not explain variation in provincial adjustm
ent in Ar- relations with a much greater degree of partisanship that had been the
gentina in the expected direction. In other words, in his
second term case under Mcuem. One salient example is the 2000 attempt by the new
Menem had as much difficulty bringing Peronist governors to
heel as he minister of social development Graciela Fernindez Mejide to increase fed-
did in controlling governors from opposition parties.
eral control over the implementation of provincial social programs. De-
The combined effect of these stalled revenue-sharing reforms
is inter- signed as a measure that would reduce clientelism, the proposal provoked
csting given the argument of Gibson and Calvo about the
sequence of strong opposition in Peronist-controlled provinces.
economic reform “events” in Argentina (Gibson and
Calvo 2000). As they It is also the case, however, that governors from the governing Ali-
argue, it was the country’s metropolitan provinces that bore
the brunt of anza—including Roberto Iglesias in Mendoza, Angel Rozas in Chaco, Al-
the market reforms that Menem was able to adopt in his first
administra- fredo Avelin in San Juan, and Sergio Montiel in Entre Rios—often sided
tion with the support of the peripheral provinces: “Only after
1994, once with Peronist governors against De la Réa. Thus, in contrast to Menem in
the major adjustments in the metropolitan economies had
been made, and his first administration, not only did De la Rtta face a majority of provinces
once the local political dividends of these adjustments began
to be col- that were governed by the opposition, but he enjoyed much less leverage
lected, did the national government tumn its attention to
reform of the over those governors who in fact belonged to one of the two governing
parties. As a result, governors emerged victorious from most of the negoti-
8. To date, no new coparticipation law has been legislated by Congress, and revenue ations that took place with the federal government in this period (see the
sharing in Argentina continues to be governed by a confusing mix of distinct and heavily
amended laws (Saiegh and Tommasi 1999a). time line in Table 4.2).
19 The economic, institutional, and partisan factors highlighted in this chapter explain One of De la Rua’s first attempts to deal with the significant federal
why the governors were able to defend the revenue guarantee past its uscfulness to the budget deficit he had inherited from the outgoing Menem administration
federal government, but it is important to also note that Menem's own interest in revenue
reform certainly waned with the waxing of his drive to win second was to propose the creation of new taxes, the proceeds of which would not
Trying to remove the revenue floor was a sure way of antagonizing the veryreelectio n in 1999
governors whose be shared with the provinces (£1v 1999). On the one hand, by excusing
support Menem would have necded to make this second relection a reality. I am grateful to the federal government from sharing additional revenues with the prov-
an anonymous reviewer for this point. inces, De la Rua’s ability to get this proposal through Congress can be
- S T ————

Menem and the Governors 107


‘ ‘ e a 558 contrasted with Menem’s failure to amend the criteria used to distribute
T
S8
£ ; ) g
g k| Ee L
% w B o excess tax revenue in his second administration
s g a5 g gg= (Bertea and Iturre 2000,
¥
S
SE
=%
EuEFT
Sag
o
&5
&
2
) 24). On the other hand, De la RtaPRpaid handsomely for this: proposal in.
§ By 825
od TREE S i & »
the form of a commitment -
to increase the revenue guarantee to $1.35 bil-:
5 e A = ; X o =
2 my Z5°¢ £5% g o0 lion per month in 2000 and $1.36 billion X
w Z& BLlexg P e in 2001. Given the low rate of
5 B § S5 g] £3% . i
inflation in these years, the increase from a revenue floor of $850 million
< = E 2 . ooy 3
3 3 § 2 é z g8 & =0 g X .
in 1998 to $1.35 billion two years later was indeed a considerable victory
=5 = P 2 a8 .
3 E 5 3“; g 2 Fe EE EXRe for the provinces.
c|T 8% 2% S £ E <t % 25 According to De la Rita’s gamble, if the tax increases succeeded in gen-
g Ry 2888
Ela 28 R43EZ ERE 2 R
§ 2 . .
erating substantial .
new revenues, which L .
was unlikely given the state of the
& = = g2 g F X
3& 3 4 £ i E{—? E =E 58 S . "
g Te &L 28 o X economy, the federal government would enhance its
. . stature relative to the
e L‘é‘ e ‘;‘E ga ‘é g€ g% §oC provinces. But if tax revenues didy not increase
2 3
as the president had hoped,
X EE 55853 § =3 § TE then revenue guarantees would enable the provinces to gain at the expense
) 5 Ea%ga = 2
= e v35 3 = ] = §e & .
of the center. In the end, increases ini tax revenues never materialized,
Fich
5s Ew,2FEHG
5 g g8t R @ g
298 : : )
and the increase in revenue obligations served to hamstring .
the federal
g ESzgasZse £7%F 225 government precisely as it was grappling
SS585
s } s E 2EZE -85 2 £cT% 2%o3 é Sa'g
5
% pling for solutions to the deepenin,
pening
28 economic crisis. Despite the worsening situation over the course
of 2000,
Rylfzlyggfezg % a2 o R the governors were able to increase the revenue floor still further in the
5 SE»-EoR%E8e g5 Ly
T ?: Re3f8:5¢ B .
EEReEEle8HE5 2EE = =3 so-called Federal Pact for Growth and Discipline of November 2000. Ac-
E °8 EESERFE88 8g2 E]
R
S " . N g
cording to this pact, transfers in the 20035 period would be a moving .
a 23 &
Table 4.2 “Time line of events affecting the provinces from 1999 to 2002

average of the
. . 2 e
previous three years, with a minimum floorof $1.45 billion
- S5 per month. As a Tesult of this pact, De la Rfia’s commitments to the prov-
& 2g g S8 o3 : . A
2 2 &5 g53 SOS6s
8]8]%
]3§ BXo inces between 2000 and 2001 experienced an increase despite. the fact that
M g Syy D 3
total federal government revenue declined in this period by 3.5 percent
alw 2
2
5”
F
I
=
:
5 =B
83
29 v
%2 Eg8 i
o848 2
%
§ 5
B
o3 e The2001) : .
5 year 2001 marked the beginning of the end for the rigid system of
< @/ z A< © o0z=zZ
o o . X
Z w federal revenue guarantees initiated in 1992. In the middle of the year,
@ after continued declines in tax revenues,
£ De la Ria managed to push
= = through Congress the Zero Deficit) Law, which .
included a 13 percent cut
2 3 = PR in public sector wages and revenue transfers. Despite growing evidence of
5
g =a H
H 5£ £@ 3
£ 3£ the crisis in public revenues, the provincial governors agreed to lower the
P P! & LR
g . 3 5 s B3 3 tevenue quota, but not to abandon it altogether. Though it is significant
25 = = B g 8 that governors agreed to this reduction, one should not lose sight of the
EE 33 S S 2 ¢s & B
g
£
B g
5
H < 2 85 g T fact that the 13 percent reduction only lowered the monthly revenue g guar-

g - 8 3 : oy : N
5 3 =] E = ) E i3 antee in 2001 to $1.19 biltion, still considerably above the 1998 floor. Fur-
¢ B Ex 5 5 z
£ P35 Il g =8 BEZ2n £ thermore, in exchange for agreeing to the cut, the federal government was
T 5 EER Eg, = 58 2 = g’ forced to renegotiate provincial liabilities with private banks at interest
€8 & 35§ 25285 ELS ; .
£3 4§ 5% 2e3d 285 58 rates no higher than 7 percent (E1v 2001).
e F SCYT gL oom S =
g z =] lg g SESSE % s 8HE i .
In the end, the federal government failed to meet its revenue obliga- .
S S5 83EESE 5 A .
] A & 2o8 3 é, g8- 28 2% EE & tions with the provinces even after the July cut, and arrears began to accu-
& £ S5 BRI Ula = mulate. In August 2001, the De la Rua 8 government created a new
gu
*

108 Argentine Democracy Menem and the Governors 10g


interprovincial bond (bono interprovincial) to be issued by a provincial de- government paid to the provinces for the very last time the monthly guar-
velopment fund (Fondo Fiduciario para el Desarrollo Provincial), which it anteed revenue transfer of $1.185 billion.>
sent to the provinces to pay revenue-sharing arrears. It was conflict over How was Duhalde able to eliminate the piso minimo when this same
these arrears, and demands by the Peronists that De la Rita release $250 institutional change had proved so elusive to his predecessors? First, no
million in overdue transfers, that triggered the breakdown of dialogue be- actual revenues had been transferred to the provinces since August 2001,
tween the president and the governors and the acknowledgement on Octo- which certainly may have complicated the efforts of those who wished to
ber 28, 2001, by the federal government that it would have to restructure defend the continued use of a piso minimo. The reliance on arrears and
its $132 billion debt. De la Rita’s inability to reach a deal with Peronist bonds demonstrated to all concerned that the federal government could
governors over the obligations of the federal government was a key sign of ot guarantee to send revenues it simply did not have. In this sense, one
his inability to govern the country. could argue that the revenue floor had ended months before its formal
It would certainly be a mistake to overstate the importance of the piso removal on February 27, 2002, just as the convertibility era had come to a
minimo in the collapse of the Argentine economy; a more complete expla- close before its official end on January 6, 2002. Second, Duhalde’s negoti-
nation would no doubt pay attention to such factors as the fixed exchange ating position as president was clearly enhanced by his prior and continu-
rate, corruption, and an unfavorable external environment. But the unin- ing position as the leader of the Peronist party in the province of Buenos
tended consequences of the fixed revenue guarantee are crucial, and the Aires. This position gave him extensive control over the largest provincial
easiest way of appreciating the importance of the piso minimo comes from bloc of legislators in Congress, a tremendously useful asset that Menem
the relevant counterfactual. Had Menem not agreed to demands for a piso could not necessarily rely on in his second term and which De la Riia
minimo in 1992 and 1993 in order to grab more revenues for the federal never enjoyed.
government, revenue transfers to the provinces later in the decade would It would be a mistake, however, to conclude that Duhalde’s influence
have declined in step with the country’s faltering tax collection. Instead, as in Congress enabled him to formally withdraw the revenue floor without
it happened, fixed revenue transfers proved to be increasingly expensive making other concessions to the provinces. In fact, considering the conces-
for De la Rita, generating a constraint on his government that was as in- sions he had to make and the damage they did to the economy of Argen-
tractable as the fixed exchange rate system. tina, the end of the governors’ beloved piso minimo did not come cheap to
‘When Congress selected Eduardo Duhalde as the country’s new presi- the president. Duhalde sought to bolster the support of the governors in
dent on January 1, 2002, he targeted for elimination both of the institu- three ways. First, he agreed to share with the provinces the proceeds of a
tions—convertibility and the revenue floor—that had so constrained his new tax on checks, a grossly distorsionary but productive generator of reve-
predecessor. Duhalde declared a formal end to the first institution— nues. Initially the federal government offered 20 percent of this tax to the
convertibility—in less than a week, in effect providing formal recognition provinces, but it was subsequently forced by the governors to increase this
of the fact that convertibility had really come to an end in November 2001 percentage to 25 percent and finally to 30 percent.”” Second, although the
with the debt default and with the imposition of limits on bank account federal government wanted no further provincial bonds to be issued, it
withdrawals (e.g., the so-called corralito). Removing the revenue floor took was forced to let the provinces issue bonds to cover current costs (though
more political skill in that it was not a foregone conclusion and instead not to pay debts with the federal government). Third, Duhalde agreed to
was to require direct and prolonged negotiations with the governors. Ulti- a deal according to which dollar-denominated provincial debts would be
mately, however, Duhalde prevailed and successfully put an end to a dec- converted to pesos (pesificad) at a rate (1.4 pesos to the dollar) that was
ade of fixed revenue transfers through the negotiation of a new pact with advantageous to the provinces. What is striking is that, even after De la
governors signed on February 27, 2002. As Duhalde declared at the sign- Ria's fall, the default on the external debt, and the worst economic crisis
ing ceremony for this pact, “We shall distribute only what we actually col- in Argentine history, governors were still strong enough to demand sig-
lect” (vamos a repartir lo que ingresa).” Thus, on March 20, the federal nificant compensation for the withdrawal of the revenue floor,

20. “Las claves de un acuerdo que todavia guarda algunas dudas,” Clarf, February 26, 21. “Negociacién con el FMI: Aval y reclamos de las provincias,” Clarin, April 12, 3002.
2002. 22. Clarin, February 26, 2000.
110 Argentine Democracy Menem and the Governors m

CONCLUSION: INTERGOVERNMENTAL RELATIONS AND Afier 1992, governors no longer had cause to worry about sudden de-
INSTITUTIONAL DESIGN creases in transfers caused by a drop in federal tax collection. Conse-
quently, the minimum revenue guarantee enabled them to reduce
As this discussion of the establishment, maintenance, and eventual provincial tax effort, expand the size of provincial payrolls, and slough off
abandonment of the revenue guarantee rule demonstrates, questions of demands from the center for provincial adjustment. Furthermore, subse-
institutional volatility and stickiness are central to the study of intergov- quent to the shift from percentage-based sharing to an actual revenue
ernmental relations in Argentina. On the one hand, those who wish to guarantee, provincial authorities used these guarantees as collateral that
draw attention to institutional uncertainty as an underlying cause of Ar- enabled them to run up significant debts with private sector banks. In
gentina’s difficulties can find substantial support in the area of revenue other words, the piso minimo let governors partially circumvent the privati-
sharing. There has been a great deal of volatility in revenue-sharing rules, zation of provincial public banks that the federal government had achieved
with nearly constant political conflict and negotiations between governors at such great effort in the mid-1990s. The revenue floor can thus be under-
and representatives of the federal government since the creation of copar- stood as an institutional rule that directly shaped the behavior of provincial
ticipation in the 1930s. Intergovernmental relations in the last three dec- officials and generated negative consequences at both the provincial and
ades have been subject to a dizzying number of changes, including federal levels. While flexibility in the past often opened up room for the
revenue decentralization in 1973, revenue centralization after the 1976 highly political use of revenue transfers, the experience of the 1990s sug-
coup, the devolution of some education and health-care responsibilities gests that the federal government needs more flexibility than revenue
in the early 1980s, an ad hoc system of revenue transfers in the mid- guarantees allowed. However one comes down on this question, the last
1980s, and the passage of further revenue decentralization in 1987. decade clearly suggests that design considerations, including the appro-
Though the use of the piso minimo remained constant in the 19922002 priate balance between rigidity and flexibility, are hardly superfluous.=
period and was its defining feature, disagreements over where the floor Beyond the fixed nature of the piso minimo in the 199o0s, I argue that
should be set occasioned significant conflicts between the federal and the intergovernmental relations in Argentina have been characterized by a
provincial governments on a yearly (and sometimes even more frequent) deeper form of Mstitutionat rigidity. For all the conflict over the size of
basis. Opposition governors throughout the 1990s complained of lags in revenue transfers and the timing of disbursements, the underlying norm
the distribution of guaranteed transfers from the center, and the lack of of revenue sharing from the federal to the provincial governments has
respect for formal institutional rules was certainly the hallmark of Men- proved to be remarkably sticky. Given some of the pathologies associated
em’s governing style (De Riz 1996; Ferreira Rubio and Goretti 1998). with automatic revenue sharing, one could argue that Argentina would
On the other hand, my analysis demonstrates that some Argentine in- have benefited from more rather than less institutional change in this
stitutions have been too rigid. Attention should be paid to the deeper arena. Revenue sharing was initiated in the 1930s when the fallout from
causes of institutional volatility as an apparently constant feature of the the Great Depression encouraged the provinces to delegate responsibility
country’s political economy, but this attention does not mean that we for the collection of key provincial taxes to the federal government. In the
should ignore questions of institutional design. Despite the general pic- decades that followed, politicians debated which tax bases should be
ture of volatility, one particular institutional rule—the extension of the shared and what the provinces’ shares should be, but not the more funda-
revenue floor or piso minimo—gencrated significant staying power. Once mental rule according to which the federal government continues to collect
granted, the minimum revenue guarantee proved to be quite difficult to provincial taxes. The severing of the connection between tax collection and
rescind as governors rallied repeatedly and aggressively in its defense. expenditure has profoundly compromised the integrity of provincial gov-
Governors were successful in these efforts thanks to the considerable au- emments. Thus, while governors enjoy considerable strength as political
thority they have come to enjoy in Argentina’s current democratic period. actors, the provinces they govern are relatively weak as units of govern-
As I have argued, this authority results both from the structure of Argen- ment. The combination of gubernatorial strength and provincial weakness
tine political parties, which gives governors considerable leverage over fed-
eral legislators, and from the content of the country’s electoral rules, 23. For more on the trade-off between rules and flexibility in the Argentine context, see
including the holding of nonconcurrent national and provincial elections. Saiegh and Tommasi 1999b.
n2 Argentine Democracy
was disastrous for Argentina in the 1990s in that it led to guaranteed
revenue transfers of a magnitude that were neither realistic nor sustain-
able. One can hope that the depth of the recent crisis will generate a sub-
stantive debate that revisits the provinces’ fateful decision in the 1930s to
forgo a more meaningful role in tax collection.

Rethinking Democratic Institutions

24. For specific reform proposals, see the excellent working papers on coparticipation by
scholars at the Centro de Estudios para el Desarrollo Institucional at the Fundacién Gobierno
¥ Sociedad, available at hitp://www.fgys.org/cedi.

You might also like