You are on page 1of 51

Common Institutional Ownership and Stock Price Crash Risk

Shenglan Chen 1 | Hui Ma 2 | Qiang Wu 3 | Hao Zhang 4*

Contemporary Accounting Research, forthcoming

Abstract: This paper presents new evidence on the economic benefits arising from common
institutional ownership. We find a negative and significant effect of common institutional
ownership on stock price crash risk. This effect is robust to a battery of robustness checks and is
causal according to some identification tests, including difference-in-differences (DiD) analyses
on financial institution mergers. We find evidence that the negative effect is attributable to the
monitoring role of common institutional owners—a role that is enabled by common owners’ lower
information processing cost and greater monitoring incentives owing to governance externalities.
We also find that common owners negatively influence crash risk through constraining bad news
hoarding and that common owners are more likely to force chief executive officer (CEO) turnover
when a firm has higher crash risk. Overall, our results suggest that common institutional
shareholders play a unique and effective monitoring role that fends off stock price crashes.

Keywords: Common institutional ownership; Bad news hoarding; Overinvestment; Stock price
crash risk; Monitoring; Governance externalities
JEL Classification Code: G23; G32; M41

1
School of Economics and Institute for Industrial System Modernization, Zhejiang University of Technology, China
2
Institute of Accounting and Finance, Shanghai University of Finance and Economics, China
3
School of Accounting and Finance, Hong Kong Polytechnic University, Hong Kong
4
Saunders College of Business, Rochester Institute of Technology (RIT), USA
*
Acknowledgement: The paper benefitted greatly from valuable comments and suggestions of Linda A. Myers
(editor), Partha S. Mohanram (editor-in-chief), and two anonymous referees. We thank our colleagues at our respective
institutions for their comments. Shenglan Chen acknowledges financial support from the National Social Science Fund
later-funded project (22FJYB014). Hui Ma acknowledges financial support from the National Natural Science
Foundation of China (72102166), the MOE Project of Key Research Institute of Humanities and Social Science in
University (22JJD790094), and 111 Project (B18033). Qiang Wu acknowledges financial support from the start-up
fund at the Hong Kong Polytechnic University (1-BE52). Hao Zhang acknowledges financial support from the
Saunders College of Business at RIT.
0

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3746777


1. Introduction

Common institutional ownership occurs when an institutional investor holds significant

equity stakes in multiple firms within the same industry. It has become an increasingly prevalent

phenomenon as institutional investors expand their dominance in the United States (U.S.) stock

markets. 5 It has also become one of the hottest antitrust topics because common ownership can

promote collusion in a product market and give rise to anticompetitive effects (Jackson 2018).

Although most studies on anticompetitive effects (e.g., Azar et al. 2018) demonstrate substantial

attendant costs of common ownership, some recent studies reveal its beneficial effects on firm

innovation (Anton et al. 2018) and earnings quality (Ramalingegowda et al. 2021). It is therefore

debatable whether common ownership should be strictly regulated (Posner et al. 2017).

Furthermore, prior studies focus predominantly on product market outcomes or firm policies, but

there is a surprising paucity of research on the beneficial capital market consequences of common

ownership. This study aims to contribute to the debate by examining the effect of common

institutional ownership on an important capital market outcome—stock price crash risk.

Crash risk, or the possibility that a stock’s price will suddenly and significantly fall, is an

important consideration for investors. In their seminal work, Jin and Myers (2006) and Hutton et

al. (2009) attribute the importance of crash risk primarily to investor concerns about extreme losses

that arise because they cannot effectively reduce this risk through diversification. Institutional

investors are even more concerned about this risk because they have greater difficulty unwinding

their positions due to price impact (Chiyachantana et al. 2004; Brunnermeier and Pedersen 2005)

and because they are sometimes forced to liquidate positions due to capital withdrawals (Shleifer

and Vishny 2011). A survey by Allianz Global Investors indicates that nearly two-thirds of the 735

5
For example, the proportion of U.S. public companies with common ownership has increased from less than 10%
in 1980 to approximately 60% in the mid 2010s (He and Huang 2017).
1

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3746777


institutional investors surveyed state that tail-risk has become an increasing concern. 6 The fact

that institutional investors often file “stock-drop lawsuits” is a clear indication of their deep

concerns about stock price crashes. Thus, Jin and Myers (2006) and others conclude that firm

characteristics that contribute to the far-left tail of the return distribution warrant thorough

investigation. Although recent studies (e.g., Kim et al. 2011a; Hong et al. 2017; Bauer et al. 2021)

shed significant light on the determinants of stock price crash risk, limited attention has been

devoted to examining the role of common institutional owners in shaping crash risk. Our study

extends the prior literature on the determinants of crash risk to include common institutional

ownership.

We posit that common ownership could mitigate crash risk for two reasons. First, common

institutional owners possess informational advantages in monitoring managerial behaviors that

engender crash risk. Jin and Myers (2006) and Bleck and Liu (2007) argue that in a market with

information asymmetry, managers may suppress bad news or support bad projects for a prolonged

period to benefit themselves at the expense of shareholders. Bad news hoarding conceals negative

information and allows it to accumulate until eventually reaching a tipping point, when the sudden

revelation of the accumulated bad news causes a stock price crash. We predict that common owners

play an integral monitoring role that deters managers from concealing negative information. This

is because when a large shareholder owns equity blocks in multiple firms within the same industry,

this shareholder has economies of scale in acquiring industry-specific information and can thereby

develop industry expertise (Kacperczyk et al. 2005). This expertise consequently enables the

common owner to better identify and constrain bad news hoarding behaviors of firms in their

6
Kim et al. (2011a, 641) state that “unlike the risks stemming from symmetric volatilities, the risk of (extreme) losses
cannot be reduced through diversification.” Some economists (e.g., Bates 2000) and industry practitioners also argue
that investors face challenges in effectively hedging against crash risk even when using derivative securities.
2

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3746777


portfolios, resulting in a lower crash risk.

Second, common owners can benefit from the internalization of externalities and should

therefore have greater incentives to discipline bad news hoarding and overinvestment. Building on

the literature on positive governance externalities (Acharya and Volpin 2010; Dicks 2012), some

recent studies argue that common owners can benefit not only from improved governance at the

focal firm, but also from subsequent governance improvements at peer firms in their portfolios

(He et al. 2019). These studies imply that if a common owner takes action against bad news

hoarding or overinvestment in one firm, then this common owner can benefit from reduced crash

risk in the focal firm and from positive externalities in the peer firms. In addition, a firm’s bad

news hoarding behaviors have negative externalities. When a firm withholds bad news, its inflated

financial performance could distort the reporting choices and the investment decisions of peer

firms (Kravet and Shevlin 2010; Beatty et al. 2013; Li 2016). As an example, Sidak (2003, 209)

points out that WorldCom’s “accounting fraud encouraged [competitors’] overinvestment.”

Furthermore, a stock’s price crash has negative externalities and often leads to stock price crashes

of its industry peers (Brochet et al. 2018), and correlated crashes are especially costly to common

owners of industry peers. To eschew inflicting these negative externalities and to benefit from the

positive externalities, common owners should have stronger incentives to constrain bad news

hoarding and overinvestment by firms in their portfolios, thereby reducing crash risk.

Nevertheless, there are at least two reasons why common ownership may be positively

related to stock price crash risk. First, Dhaliwal et al. (2014) predict that firms may disclose and

recognize bad news more promptly to induce rivals to under-produce, and they find a positive and

significant relation between product market competition and accounting conservatism. To the

extent that product market competition can encourage timely recognition of bad news, common

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3746777


ownership may be positively associated with crash risk through an anticompetitive effect (e.g.,

Azar et al. 2018). Second, research on funding liquidity and commonality in liquidity implies that

common owners with funding liquidity shocks may have to fire-sell portfolio stocks (e.g.,

Brunnermeier and Pedersen 2009; Koch et al. 2016), which increases their industry-peer stocks’

price fragility due to a deterioration in market liquidity and leads to a positive relation between

common ownership and crash risk of these stocks.

We test these competing hypotheses empirically using a sample of U.S. firms from 1980

through 2017. Following He and Huang (2017), we construct three common ownership measures:

an indicator variable for firms with common ownership, the number of a firm’s common owners,

and the number of a firm’s industry peers connected through common owners. Our dependent

variable, stock price crash risk, has two widely used proxies in the literature (e.g., DeFond et al.

2015). Ncskew is the negative skewness of firm-specific weekly returns for a firm during the year,

and Duvol (down-to-up volatility) is the logarithm of the ratio of the standard deviations of firm-

specific returns on down weeks to the standard deviations of firm-specific returns on up weeks

during the year. We regress these crash risk measures on the common ownership proxies,

controlling for a range of firm and institutional investor characteristics, firm fixed effects, and

blockholder fixed effects. The regression results show that the effect of common ownership on

stock price crash risk is negative and statistically significant. The finding is also economically

significant because the presence of common ownership is associated with an 8.0% decrease in

Ncskew. Our main inference holds in robustness tests that use alternate common ownership

measures based on other industry classification methods and alternate model specifications with

additional control variables.

Although the firm fixed effects and blockholder fixed effects in the baseline model should

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3746777


mitigate most endogeneity concerns, we conduct two additional tests to strengthen the causal

interpretation. First, to help rule out reverse causality, we follow Ramalingegowda et al. (2021)

and regress our common ownership measures on lagged crash risk measures and control variables

using a subsample of firms with no common ownership in the prior three years. The results show

no statistically significant relation between lagged crash risk and current common ownership,

mitigating the reverse causality concern. Second, we leverage exogenous variation in common

ownership driven by financial institution mergers and apply a DiD approach. Following He and

Huang (2017), we define treatment firms as those that experienced an increase in common

ownership due to financial institution mergers, and control firms are those blockheld by one merger

partner with no industry rivals blockheld by the other partner. We find that treatment firms, relative

to the control firms, have a significant reduction in crash risk after the mergers. This finding holds

in a regression on a reduced sample that excludes mergers occurring during the 2008–2009

financial crisis. Furthermore, we conduct a placebo test using “pseudo-event” years and find no

statistically significant treatment effect.

Next, we conduct cross-sectional analyses on the mechanisms through which common

ownership influences crash risk. We find that the effect of common ownership on crash risk is less

pronounced in firms followed by industry-specialist analysts. This finding is consistent with the

intuition that industry-specialist analysts diminish the information advantage of common owners,

thereby moderating the impact of common ownership. We also find that the effect of common

ownership is stronger in firms with greater opacity (Hutton et al. 2009). Furthermore, because

firms in industries where managers have more outside options should have greater governance

externalities, we follow He et al. (2019) and use the industry homogeneity index to capture the

extent of externalities. We find that the negative relation between common ownership and crash

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3746777


risk is concentrated in firms with greater externalities, suggesting that the internalization of

externalities motivates common owners to become better monitors. 7

We then investigate whether common owners reduce crash risk by curbing the primary

driver of crash risk—bad news hoarding (Jin and Myers 2006). Prior literature shows that equity

investors demand accounting conservatism as a governance device because it can constrain

management’s ability to overstate accounting numbers and effectively reduce bad news hoarding

(Ramalingegowda and Yu 2012; Kim and Zhang 2016). We therefore conjecture that common

owners are likely to promote accounting conservatism to constrain bad news hoarding and thus

reduce crash risk. To test this conjecture, we perform two-stage regression analyses following Di

Giuli and Laux (2022). We provide evidence that common ownership is positively related to

accounting conservatism, and the conservatism induced by common ownership is significantly and

negatively related to crash risk. In addition, we find that common ownership negatively affects a

firm’s tendency to continue supporting bad projects, leading to a lower crash risk. These two tests

provide tentative evidence that constraining bad news hoarding ex ante is the intermediate step by

which common owners to reduce crash risk. Lastly, we explore the ex-post actions that common

owners take to discipline executives of firms with high crash risk. We find that common ownership

accentuates the positive relation between crash risk and the likelihood of CEO turnover, suggesting

that common owners dismiss CEOs of high crash-risk firms to hold them accountable.

Our study contributes to the extant literature in several ways. First, it extends the

burgeoning stream of research on common ownership by examining its consequences from a stock

market perspective. The six-fold increase in common ownership in the past few decades has ignited

considerable debate on whether common ownership can mitigate firm incentives to compete in

7
Our cross-sectional test results hold in the DiD setting as well.
6

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3746777


product markets (He and Huang 2017; Azar et al. 2018). Despite the rapid expansion of this

literature, existing studies largely focus on the impact of common ownership on product market

outcomes and firm policies (e.g., Azar et al. 2018; Ramalingegowda et al. 2021; DesJardine et al.

2022, 2023; Chen et al. 2023). Our study complements and extends this literature by focusing on

stock market outcomes and shedding light on one more economic benefit of common ownership—

the reduction in stock price crash risk, which is an important consideration for investors.

Additionally, to the best of our knowledge, this study is the first to document that common

ownership reduces crash risk by promoting accounting conservatism and constraining corporate

overinvestment behaviors.

Second, we contribute to the crash risk literature by introducing common ownership as a

new determinant. Prior studies identify various determinants of crash risk. 8 Our findings are most

closely related to research on the role of institutional investors in shaping crash risk (An and Zhang

2013; Callen and Fang 2013; An et al. 2014; Andreou et al. 2016). These studies find a generally

positive, but somewhat mixed, relation between institutional ownership and crash risk. In addition,

they treat institutional investors’ holdings in each firm as separate positions, ignoring

interconnections through institutional cross-holdings. In contrast, our study examines a related but

distinct concept—common ownership. We focus not on the level of institutional ownership per se,

but rather on large blockholders who act as a nexus of industry peer firms through cross-holdings.

Although previous evidence on the effect of common ownership on crash risk is lacking,

two contemporary studies are closely related to our study. First, Cheng et al. (2023) investigates

8
These factors include financial reporting quality (Hutton et al. 2009; Kim et al. 2016a; Kim and Zhang 2016), tax
avoidance (Kim et al. 2011a), executive compensation (Kim et al. 2011b), religiosity (Callen and Fang 2015),
mandatory adoption of International Financial Reporting Standards (DeFond et al. 2015), auditor industry
specialization (Robin and Zhang 2015), CEO overconfidence (Kim et al. 2016b), stock market liquidity (Chang et al.
2017), real earnings management (Khurana et al. 2018), insider share pledging (Dou et al. 2019), and enforcement by
the U.S. Internal Revenue Service (Bauer et al. 2021), among others.
7

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3746777


the role of common ownership in facilitating the contagion of crash risk from one firm to another.

Second, Li et al. (2022, 2) find a negative relation between common ownership and stock price

crash risk; however, their argument is that “industry common owners’ information advantage

allows them to avoid selling on false spillover signals from industry peers, which in turn reduces

stock price crash risk.” They conclude, on page 2, that “our contribution is identifying an

information based spillover story that predicts a stabilizing effect.” Overall, Cheng et al. (2023)

and Li et al. (2022) do not reveal whether common owners influence stock price crash risk that

originates within a focal firm, which is the main focus of the crash risk literature. Differing from

these studies, our study argues and provides evidence that common owners reduce crash risk

because they have an information advantage and governance incentives to constrain the focal

firm’s bad news hoarding. 9

Finally, our findings offer implications for regulators and investors. Recently, common

ownership has come under scrutiny from regulators in the European Union and the U.S. The

Federal Trade Commission (FTC) Commissioner, Noah Phillips, comments that “Some concerned

with common ownership have proposed remedies that are quite dramatic. … I find the common

ownership particularly interesting because it takes place at the intersection of antitrust, corporate,

and securities law and policy.” 10 Whereas law professors including Elhauge (2016) and Posner et

al. (2017) offer several recommendations for regulating common ownership, Rock and Rubinfeld

(2017, 1) argue that these recommendations may be misguided and are likely to have a chilling

9
Another related study, Jiang et al. (2022), finds a negative relation between common ownership and crash risk in a
sample of Chinese firms. But, Jiang et al.’s (2022, 908) main finding only holds in the state-owned enterprises (SOE)
subsample, and they find “no such results in non-state-owned enterprises subsamples.” Thus, whether common
ownership has a significant negative effect on crash risk in public firms in developed markets remains an open and
important question.
10
See page 3 of the opening remarks of Commissioner Noah J. Phillips in FTC Hearing #8: “Competition and
Consumer Protection in the 21st Century Corporate Governance, Institutional Investors, and Common Ownership.”
8

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3746777


effect on “the valuable role of institutional investors in corporate governance.” Against this

backdrop, our study provides evidence that common institutional owners indeed play a unique,

valuable role in monitoring firms and reducing bad news hoarding and crash risk. Thereby, our

study contributes to the ongoing debate by offering a more balanced view of common ownership

and its economic consequences. In addition, stock price crashes are an important concern for

investors, especially following high-profile scandals such as Enron and WorldCom. Our findings

suggest that common ownership is associated with an economically significant reduction in crash

risk. 11 These findings could be useful for investors in assessing investment risk and designing

portfolios with reduced crash risk.

2. Hypothesis development

The classical literature on crash risk proposes that bad news hoarding is the primary cause

of stock price crash risk. These studies argue that self-interested insiders tend to withhold bad news

from outsiders, which may give rise to severe overvaluation of share prices (Jin and Myers 2006;

Hutton et al. 2009). When the stockpiled bad news reaches a tipping point, it usually comes out all

at once and results in a sudden stock price crash. Other studies suggest that insiders have incentives

to retain bad projects for extended periods, resulting in overinvestment (Bleck and Liu 2007;

Benmelech et al. 2010). To derive private benefits, the insiders not only delay taking corrective

actions on poor-performing projects, but may also invest more into these projects to conceal the

poor performance. The negative performance of the bad projects will continue and may eventually

result in a stock price crash. These two explanations of crash risk are not mutually exclusive causes

of stock price crashes because the latter one can be regarded as a specific type of bad news hoarding.

11
Kelly and Jiang (2014) find that stocks with greater tail risk have 5.4% higher required returns than their lower-
risk counterparts. To the extent that a higher required return negatively affects firm value by increasing the discount
rate, our findings imply that common ownership has a beneficial effect on firm value through reducing left-tail risk.
9

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3746777


Prior literature on institutional investors suggests that these investors have two opposing

effects on firm behaviors. On the one hand, institutional investors play a monitoring role in firm

decisions, either through direct intervention (McCahery et al. 2016) or indirectly (Admati and

Pfleiderer 2009; Edmans and Manso 2011; Bharath et al. 2013). On the other hand, some studies

argue that institutional investors have little or even a negative impact on corporate performance

and governance because many institutions are short-term investors or prefer to vote with their feet

rather than engage in costly monitoring (Bushee 1998; 2001). These contrasting views yield

different predictions and mixed evidence on the relation between different types of institutional

investors and crash risk (An and Zhang 2013; Callen and Fang 2013; An et al. 2014; Andreou et

al. 2016). The overall positive relation between total institutional ownership and crash risk

documented in these studies suggests that the majority of institutional investors do not serve as

effective monitors. Nevertheless, we have several reasons to believe that the unique characteristics

of common institutional blockholders should enable them to play an effective monitoring role.

First, unlike investors who only blockhold the shares of one firm in an industry, common

owners of multiple same-industry companies have economies of scale in information acquisition

and processing. Industry peers are subject to similar influences from macroeconomic and industry

factors so common owners can focus on collecting firm-specific information without having to

duplicate the effort of gathering industry-level information. Efficiency gains may also come from

information processing. Industry peer firms provide similar products and services and compete in

the same product markets, so they usually comove in performance (Hoberg and Phillips 2012;

Hameed et al. 2015; De Bodt et al. 2020). Accordingly, common owners can extrapolate findings

from their analysis of one firm to peer firms.

Economies of scale in information acquisition and processing would improve the ability of

10

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3746777


common owners to act as effective monitors. This is because economies of scale would allow them

to acquire superior information and develop industry expertise, enabling them to better identify

irregularities in a firm’s performance and financial reporting. For instance, common owners may

compare financial reporting and other information across industry peers, thereby increasing their

likelihood of detecting bad news hoarding by a particular firm. 12 As another example, common

owners might be better at differentiating firm-specific factors from common shocks to the firms’

product markets (Jayaraman et al. 2021), facilitating more effective monitoring of overinvestment

in inefficient projects and ultimately resulting in lower crash risk.

Second, some scholars including Acharya and Volpin (2010) argue that a firm’s corporate

governance has positive externalities on peer firms. Gao and Zhang (2019) demonstrate that a

firm’s investment in internal controls not only reduces its own managers’ accounting manipulation,

but also alleviates pressure to manipulate for managers at peer firms. Dicks (2012, 1998) argues

that “because firms do not enjoy the full benefit of their governance, there is a positive externality

to governance,” which could be addressed by market-based solutions. Another stream of literature

suggests that a firm’s behaviors may generate negative externalities for its industry peer firms.

Beatty et al. (2013) and Bustamante and Fresard (2021) argue that if a firm conceals bad news or

overinvests, these behaviors will paint a misleading picture of future industry prospects, thereby

leading industry peer firms to overinvest. These studies suggest that both bad news hoarding and

overinvestment by a firm have negative externalities and lead to industry peers’ overinvestment.

Related to the externality literature, some recent studies show that common ownership

provides a market-based mechanism for internalizing the positive externalities (He et al. 2009).

12
If common owners can uncover bad news hoarding, they can also trade on their superior information. That is, in
addition to monitoring insiders to reduce bad news hoarding, common owners can sell their holdings of firms that
conceal bad news. These transactions can impound the hidden bad news into stock prices, reducing future crash risk.
11

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3746777


This occurs because common owners can benefit not only from improved governance of the focal

firm, but also from the spillover effect on the governance of industry peers. Relative to institutions

that blockhold only one firm in an industry, common owners should have greater incentives to

monitor their portfolio firms owing to the benefits of internalizing governance externalities. 13 The

negative externality literature suggests that accounting manipulation problems are particularly

costly to common owners because one portfolio firm’s overstatement may cause overinvestment

and value loss in other industry peer firms in the portfolio (Ramalingegowda et al. 2021). Common

owners also suffer from another type of negative externalities related to crash risk. If a stock has a

crash, then it possibly has a spillover effect, which leads to significant drops of its industry peers’

stocks (Hoberg and Phillips 2012; Brochet et al. 2018). Because common owners have significant

positions across industry peers, this negative externality is costlier for them. Taken together, the

benefits of internalizing positive externalities and the cost of negative externalities incurred by

other firms in the portfolio should provide common owners with stronger incentives to constrain

the focal firm’s bad news hoarding and overinvestment problems, leading to lower crash risk.

The two arguments above lead to the same prediction—a negative relation between

common ownership and crash risk. Nevertheless, we might not observe this negative relation for

two reasons. First, Darrough and Stoughton (1990) and Dhaliwal et al. (2014) show that a firm

may disclose and recognize bad news more quickly to discourage new entry or induce rivals to

under-produce. If product market competition increases timely disclosure of bad news, the anti-

competitive effect (Azar et al. 2018) would suggest a positive relation between common ownership

13
We are not arguing that common owner blockholders have greater influence over firms than non-common owner
blockholders. Instead, our argument hinges on the stronger incentives of common owners to monitor. Even if all
blockholders have the same ability to influence firms’ actions, the one with greater incentives to monitor due to the
benefits of internalizing governance externalities would play a more significant monitoring role.
12

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3746777


and crash risk. However, some studies suggest that whether common ownership affects

anticompetitive behavior remains an ongoing debate (Lewellen and Lowry 2021; Dennis et al.

2022). Therefore, common ownership may not have a significant effect on crash risk. Second, if a

common owner experiences a funding liquidity shock, this investor may have to fire-sell some

stocks to raise money, deteriorating these stocks’ market liquidity (Brunnermeier and Pedersen

2009). Their reduced market liquidity impairs the liquidity of industry peer stocks, especially those

sharing common investors (Chordia et al. 2000; Anton and Polk 2014; Koch et al. 2016). As such,

the deterioration of portfolio stocks’ liquidity would further tighten the funding liquidity of the

investors and force them to sell even more portfolio stocks to meet the liquidity need, exacerbating

the downward liquidity spiral and inducing stock price crashes across industry peer firms. In

summary, these two effects could mitigate the aforementioned negative effects of common

ownership on crash risk, leading to an insignificant relation between common ownership and crash

risk. Accordingly, we follow Lang and Lundholm (1996) and Chang et al. (2016) and state the

hypothesis in the null form:

HYPOTHESIS. Common institutional ownership is unrelated to stock price crash risk.

3. Data, variables, and research design

Data sources and sample selection

Our sample includes U.S. firms with common stocks listed on the New York Stock

Exchange (NYSE), Nasdaq, and American Stock Exchange (AMEX) in 1980-2017. We source

institutional ownership 13-F data from the Thomson Reuters Ownership Database, stock data from

the Center for Research in Security Prices (CRSP) Database, and financial information from the

Compustat Database. 14 Following Kim et al. (2011a) and Chang et al. (2017), we exclude

14
To mitigate the concern that Thomson Reuters’ 13-F data may be stale, we construct alternative common ownership
13

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3746777


observations with negative book values of equity, year-end stock prices less than $1, and

observations with fewer than 26 weeks of stock return data. We further exclude financial and utility

firms and observations with insufficient data for constructing the crash risk measures, common

ownership proxies, or control variables. Our final sample consists of 96,119 firm-year observations.

Variables and the regression model

We follow Hutton et al. (2009) and Kim et al. (2011a) and construct stock price crash risk

measures in two steps. First, we estimate the component of stock returns that is orthogonal to

market and industry returns, firm-specific weekly returns (Wit). Second, we use Wit to construct

two measures. Ncskew is the negative skewness of firm-specific weekly returns for the firm during

a year. Intuitively, Ncskew measures left tail thickness. Our second crash-risk measure, “down-to-

up volatility” (Duvol), is the log of the ratio of the standard deviation of firm-specific returns in

down weeks to that in up weeks during a year. A stock with a higher value of Duvol is likely to be

more crash prone. Compared with Ncskew, this measure may be less influenced by a small number

of extreme returns because it does not involve the third moment (Chen et al. 2001). 15

Common ownership arises when an institution concurrently blockholds more than one firm

in the same industry in a particular period. We follow He and Huang (2017) and define

blockholders as institutional investors with at least 5% ownership in a firm. We focus on

blockholders because they have sufficient influence on managers through private communications

measures using 13-F data from Backus et al. (2021). Backus et al. scraped the data directly from SEC 13-F filings.
We report the results in panel A of Internet Appendix Table IA.1. Our main finding is robust to the use of this alternative
institutional ownership data source.
15
Following Hutton et al. (2009), we also define an indicator variable, Crash, that equals to one if the firm has one
or more weekly returns falling 3.2 or more standard deviations below the mean firm-specific weekly return in a year,
and zero otherwise. We estimate logistic regressions of Crash on the common ownership measures and other controls
in the baseline model. We find negative but statistically insignificant coefficients on common ownership in this
untabulated test. This weak result is likely to be driven by the small variation in the Crash indicator and the fact that
our baseline regression includes firm fixed effects.
14

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3746777


and voting (McCahery et al. 2016). 16 We capture a firm’s common-ownership status in a given

year using three measures proposed by He and Huang (2017). The first measure, Com_Dummy, is

an indicator variable that equals one if at least one of the firm’s institutional blockholders

simultaneously blockholds other firms in the same industry, and zero otherwise. The second

measure, NumInve, is the number of a firm’s institutional blockholders that concurrently hold 5%

ownership or above in at least one other same-industry firm. The third measure, NumFirm, is the

number of same-industry peer firms that share a common institutional blockholder with the focal

firm. We log-transform one plus NumInve and NumFirm to reduce skewness.

Using these variables, we estimate the following baseline regression model:

𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶ℎ 𝑅𝑅𝑅𝑅𝑅𝑅𝑅𝑅𝑖𝑖,𝑡𝑡+1 = 𝛽𝛽0 + 𝛽𝛽1 𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶 𝑂𝑂𝑂𝑂𝑂𝑂𝑂𝑂𝑂𝑂𝑂𝑂ℎ𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖,𝑡𝑡 + 𝛽𝛽2 𝑍𝑍𝑖𝑖,𝑡𝑡 + 𝐹𝐹𝐹𝐹𝐹𝐹𝐹𝐹 𝐹𝐹𝐹𝐹𝐹𝐹𝐹𝐹𝐹𝐹 𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸 +

𝐵𝐵𝐵𝐵𝐵𝐵𝐵𝐵𝐵𝐵ℎ𝑜𝑜𝑜𝑜𝑜𝑜𝑜𝑜𝑜𝑜 𝐹𝐹𝐹𝐹𝐹𝐹𝐹𝐹𝐹𝐹 𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸 + 𝑌𝑌𝑌𝑌𝑌𝑌𝑌𝑌 𝐹𝐹𝐹𝐹𝐹𝐹𝐹𝐹𝐹𝐹 𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸 + 𝜀𝜀𝑖𝑖,𝑡𝑡 (1)

where i and t index firm and year, respectively. The dependent variable is one of the crash risk

measures, Ncskew or Duvol. The key independent variable, Common Ownership, is one of the

three common ownership proxies. Z denotes a vector of control variables, as detailed below. To

partially address concerns about reverse causality, we measure these independent variables with a

one-year lag relative to the dependent variables. Firm Fixed Effects isolate the effects of time-

invariant observable and unobservable firm attributes. Blockholder Fixed Effects address potential

omitted variable bias regarding time-invariant institution characteristics and also help to alleviate

the concern that individual common owners may have idiosyncratic preferences for firms with

16
In untabulated robustness checks, we try using different cutoff levels (e.g., 3.5%) to define common blockholders
and find our main findings remain qualitatively unchanged. Additionally, we use 3-digit SIC codes to identify same-
industry firms in main tests but in robustness checks, we also use alternate common ownership measures based on 4-
digit North American Industry Classification System (NAICS) and 4-digit Standard Industrial Classification (SIC)
codes and find qualitatively identical results. We tabulate these in panels B and C of Internet Appendix Table IA.1.
15

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3746777


lower crash risk. The model also includes Year Fixed Effects. 17

Kim et al. (2011a, 2011b) guide our selection of the control variables. The vector of control

variables, Z, includes total assets (Size), market-to-book ratio (MTB), firm leverage (Leverage),

return on assets (ROA), average firm-specific weekly returns during the year multiplied by 100

(Return), stock return volatility (Sigma), stock turnover change (DTurn), and financial reporting

opacity (Opaque) measured by the moving sum of the absolute value of abnormal accruals in the

prior three years (Hutton et al. 2009). We also control for total institutional ownership (InstiOwn)

and the following institutional ownership factors. CrossDiff is an indicator that equals one if at

least one institutional blockholder of the firm holds equity blocks in firms from other industries

while not blockholding firms in the same industry during the year. We follow Ramalingegowda et

al. (2021) and control for the presence of large shareholders using BlockD, which equals one if the

firm has at least one blockholder, and zero otherwise. We also control the effect of the quasi-index

ownership (IOQix). 18 By explicitly controlling for these institutional ownership factors, we ensure

that the coefficients on Common Ownership capture the incremental effect of common ownership

on crash risk. To minimize the effects of outliers, we winsorize all continuous variables at their 1st

and 99th percentiles. Appendix A presents the detailed variable definitions.

Table 1 presents summary statistics for the variables used in the baseline regression. The

means (standard deviations) of Ncskew and Duvol are −0.250 (0.659) and −0.076 (0.364),

respectively. The mean of Com_Dummy indicates that approximately 54% of the firm-years are

17
In a robustness check, we use industry×year fixed effects to control the effects of time-varying industry
characteristics. Panel D of Internet Appendix Table IA.1 indicates that our main findings are qualitatively unchanged.
18
To ensure our main finding is not driven by passive ownership of quasi-indexers, we control for IOQix in the
baseline regressions and throughout the main tests. However, IOQix is positively correlated with InstiOwn, so
including both IOQix and InstiOwn may lead to multicollinearity problem. To mitigate this concern, we also estimate
a modified version of the baseline model by excluding IOQix and find that our main finding holds in this untabulated
robustness check.
16

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3746777


held by at least one common owner. The means of LnNumInvt and LnNumFirm are 0.591 and

1.105, suggesting that an average firm has approximately two common owners and shares common

owners with approximately three industry peer firms. These values are generally similar to those

reported in the crash risk literature and the common ownership literature (Kim and Zhang 2016;

He and Huang 2017; Kim et al. 2019). The mean value of the average firm-specific weekly returns

multiplied by 100 (Return) and the mean value of Sigma are −0.27 and 0.06, which are comparable

to the corresponding figures (−0.22 and 0.05) in Kim et al. (2011a). The average total institutional

ownership level (41.6%) is slightly higher than the corresponding mean value (36.8%) in He and

Huang (2017), which examines an earlier sample period. The mean value of BlockD suggests that

approximately 65% of the observations have at least one institutional blockholder. 19

4. The relation between common ownership and stock price crash risk

Baseline regression results

In Table 2, columns (1)–(3) and (4)–(6) present the baseline regressions for Ncskew and

Duvol, respectively. The coefficients on the common ownership measures are all negative and

significant across these regressions, which suggests that crash risk is lower in firms held by

common owners. Turning to the control variables, the results indicate that crash risk increases with

the level of institutional ownership (InstiOwn), which is consistent with findings in An and Zhang

(2013) and Callen and Fang (2013). The significantly negative coefficients on quasi-indexer

ownership (IOQix) suggests that quasi-indexer institutions are effective monitors (Hillegeist and

Weng 2021). Taken together, the findings suggest that common ownership has incremental

explanatory power for crash risk that goes beyond the effect of total institutional ownership.

19
To mitigate the concern that Con_Dummy may pick up the effect of blockholders, we conduct a reduced-sample
test where we limit the sample to firm-years with BlockD equal to one and then re-estimate the baseline regressions.
The results in panel E of Internet Appendix Table IA.1 indicate that the coefficients on Con_Dummy remain negative
and significant.
17

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3746777


Our main finding is also economically meaningful. The coefficient on Com_Dummy in the

first column (−0.02) suggests that the presence of common ownership is associated with an 8.0%

(= 0.02/0.25) decrease in negative skewness, where 0.25 is the magnitude of average Ncskew. In

columns (2) and (3), the coefficients on LnNumInve and LnNumFirm are −0.042 and −0.011,

respectively. We gauge the economic significance of these two coefficients by estimating changes

in Ncskew when the common ownership measures shift by one standard deviation. When

LnNumInve (LnNumFirm) increases by one standard deviation, the corresponding decrease in

Ncskew is 0.026 (0.013), which is significant given that the mean value of Ncskew is −0.25. The

coefficients on common ownership in the regressions of Duvol are also economically significant.

We also conduct sensitivity tests to establish the robustness of our main finding. For brevity,

we report these results in the Internet Appendix. First, we estimate alternative model specifications

with additional control variables. To rule out the possibility that our finding is driven by the

contagion of tail risk across industry peers that share common owners with a focal firm (Cheng et

al. 2023; Li et al. 2022), we include the value-weighted average crash risk of these industry peers,

VWNcskew or VWDuvol, as an additional control. Consistent with Cheng et al. (2023), Table IA.2

in the Internet Appendix indicates that a firm’s crash risk is positively correlated with the average

crash risk of its industry peers that share the common blockholders. In addition, we find that the

common ownership proxies continue to be negatively and significantly related to crash risk. To

mitigate the impacts of other factors, we further control for CEO and chief financial officer (CFO)

compensation incentives (Kim et al. 2011a; Anton et al. 2023), financial statement comparability

(Kim et al. 2016a), and bid-ask spread as a proxy for stock liquidity (Chung and Zhang 2014;

Chang et al. 2017) in the baseline regression model. Table IA.3, panels A–C show that the

coefficients on the common ownership measures remain negative and significant.

18

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3746777


Identification strategies

In the baseline model, we bolster causal inference by including key determinants of crash

risk, firm fixed effects, and blockholder fixed effects. All of these should limit the possibility that

cross-sectional variation in firm attributes spuriously drives the negative relation between common

ownership and crash risk. In this section, we aim to further alleviate endogeneity concerns.

First, one may argue that the negative relation between common ownership and crash risk

is driven by the possibility that institutional investors prefer holding good-governance firms that

tend to have lower crash risk (Chung and Zhang 2011; McCahery et al. 2016). We conduct a

falsification test to mitigate this self-selection concern. If common owners self-select into low

crash-risk firms, then crash risk prior to the presence of common ownership should be negatively

associated with future common ownership. To rule out this possibility, we follow Ramalingegowda

et al. (2021) and regress common ownership on lagged crash risk measures and controls using a

subsample of firms with no common ownership in the prior three years. Table 3 indicates an

insignificant relation between lagged crash risk and current common ownership, providing no

evidence that common institutional investors self-select into low-crash firms.

Second, we conduct DiD analyses on financial institution mergers. If two merging

institutions blockhold two different firms in the same industry before a merger, then the merged

institution will become a common owner of these two firms afterward, generating a positive shock

to common ownership. He and Huang (2017) and others argue that institution mergers are likely

to be driven by exogenous reasons such as financial deregulation, rather than characteristics of the

firms held by the institutions (e.g., crash risk). Following these studies, we establish causality by

testing whether a firm’s crash risk significantly decreases after it experiences an exogenous

increase in common ownership due to financial institution mergers.

19

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3746777


We obtain a list of financial institution mergers from He and Huang (2017). To be included

in the treatment group, a firm must satisfy two conditions in the quarter before the merger

announcement: (i) the firm is blockheld by one of the merging institutions, and (ii) the other

merging institution does not blockhold the same firm but blockholds at least one of its industry

peers in the same pre-merger quarter. Because a financial institution merger results in a larger

institution and causes other changes in the institution’s characteristics, we follow He and Huang

(2017) and define control firms as those blockheld by one merger partner with no industry rivals

blockheld by the other partner. As pointed out in He and Huang (2017, 2696), the only difference

between the treatment and control groups is that for the latter, the other party to the merger does

“not simultaneously block-hold same-industry rivals of these firms so that the control firms’ cross-

ownership would not change simply because of the merger.” Lastly, Sun and Abraham (2021)

suggest that for a setting like ours that has variation in treatment timing across treatment firms,

never-treated firms should be used as the control group. Therefore, we exclude firms that are ever

treatment firms from the control sample.

We examine a symmetric seven-year window surrounding the mergers. Our baseline DiD

test sample consists of 7,087 firm-year observations from 225 treatment firms and 1,182 control

firms. The sample size is comparable to those reported in He and Huang (2017) and Lu et al. (2022).

Using the treatment and control firm-year observations, we estimate the following DiD regression:

𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶ℎ 𝑅𝑅𝑅𝑅𝑅𝑅𝑅𝑅 = 𝛽𝛽0 + 𝛽𝛽1 𝑇𝑇𝑇𝑇𝑇𝑇𝑇𝑇𝑇𝑇𝑇𝑇𝑇𝑇 × 𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃 + 𝛽𝛽2 𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃 + 𝑍𝑍 + 𝐹𝐹𝐹𝐹𝐹𝐹𝐹𝐹𝐹𝐹 𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸 + 𝜀𝜀 (2)

where Crash Risk is one of the crash risk measures. Treated is an indicator variable that equals one

for treatment firms and zero for control firms. Post is an indicator variable that equals one for one

of three post-event years, and zero otherwise. Z is a vector of the control variables used in our

baseline regression. The coefficient on Treated × Post identifies changes in crash risk for treatment

20

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3746777


firms, relative to the control firms, following merger-induced common ownership changes. Lastly,

we follow He and Huang (2017) and include firm-merger fixed effects in the regressions. Because

a specific firm in a given merger can only be either a treatment or a control firm, the firm-merger

fixed effects make the Treated indicator unidentified and thus it is not included in model (2).

In panel A of Table 4, columns (1) and (2) present the DiD regressions without control

variables. The negative and significant coefficients on Treated × Post are consistent with our

conjecture that a treatment firm’s increase in common ownership after financial institution mergers

is accompanied by a significant reduction in stock price crash risk. Columns (3) and (4) report

model (2) with control variables. The coefficients on Treated × Post continue to be negative and

significant. These control variables, along with the firm-merger fixed effects, partially mitigate

omitted variable concerns and lend further credence to the argument that our DiD regression

findings can be attributed to the negative causal effect of common ownership on crash risk.

We conduct several supplemental tests to support the causal inference. First, we conduct a

dynamic DiD analysis. We replace the Post indicator with six separate indicator variables including

Pre(−2), Pre(−1), Post(0),Post(1), Post(2), and Post(3). These indicator variables equal one if an

observation is in the specific year relative to the merger event year, and zero otherwise. The

regressions also include the interaction terms between these indicator variables and Treated. Panel

B indicates that five of the six coefficients on the interactions between Treated and the post

indicators are negative and significant, supporting our main DiD regression finding in panel A.

The coefficients on Treated×Pre(−1) and Treated×Pre(−2) are statistically insignificant. This

finding suggests no significant difference in pre-treatment crash risk between the treated and

control firms, thereby validating the parallel trend assumption. Second, we conduct a placebo test

by moving the event year artificially back by five years. We then re-estimate the DiD regressions

21

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3746777


without and with control variables and report the results in columns (1) and (2) and columns (3)

and (4) in panel C, respectively. As expected, we find insignificant coefficients on Treated×Post

across these regressions, suggesting no significant treatment effects surrounding these “pseudo-

event” years. Third, some mergers during a financial crisis may be contaminated by other

concurrent events. As suggested by Lewellen and Lowry (2021), we re-estimate the DiD regression

model (2) using a subsample that consists of observations outside the subprime crisis period. Panel

D, columns (1) and (2) indicate that our finding remains robust in this robustness check.

Lastly, He and Huang (2017) argue that their primary approach of identifying control firms

necessarily implies that treatment and control firms come from different industries. To mitigate the

concern that different industries may have different structural changes surrounding the merger

years, He and Huang (2017) and Lewellen and Lowry (2021) use a matching method to identify

an alternative control sample from the same industry. Following Lewellen and Lowry (2021), we

match each treatment firm with another firm that is in the same 3-digit SIC industry, has the closest

firm size, and is blockheld by a financial institution other than the merging institutions. This

alternative matching-sample procedure results in 210 pairs of treatment firms and control firms

and 2,548 firm-year observations for the DiD tests. Accordingly, we set an indicator variable,

Treated_Alt, to one if it is a treatment observation and zero if it is an observation from this

alternative control sample. We estimate a modified DiD regression model (2) by replacing Treated

with Treated_Alt and report the results in columns (3) and (4) of panel D. We find that the

coefficients on Treated_Alt×Post are negative and significant.

5. Cross-sectional evidence

Cross-sectional evidence: Information advantages of common ownership

22

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3746777


In this section, we evaluate the plausibility of our conceptual framework by examining

whether the negative effect of common owners on crash risk stems from their information

advantages. First, we posit that the presence of industry-specialist analysts diminishes the

information advantage of common owners. Financial analysts collect information through

communications with management and other sources, which parallels the information acquisition

activities of sophisticated investors. Analysts who follow several firms in the same industry

accumulate a wealth of industry knowledge and develop industry expertise (Gilson et al. 2001;

Boni and Womack 2006). 20 The presence of these industry-specialist analysts should diminish the

information advantages of common owners, thereby moderating the disciplinary effect of common

ownership on stock price crash risk.

To test this conjecture, we define financial analysts as industry specialists if they cover at

least four firms within the same industry (Gilson et al. 2001) and construct an indicator variable,

High_Cover, which equals one if the number of industry-specialist analysts following a firm is

above the year-industry median, and zero otherwise. We modify equation (1) by including

High_Cover and its interaction with common ownership. Table 5, panel A, indicates that the

coefficients on the common ownership measures are all significantly negative, whereas the

coefficients on the interaction terms are all positive and five of them are statistically significant.

We also test whether the sum of the coefficients on common ownership and corresponding

interaction term is different from zero. The p values in row (a)+(b) indicate that the sum is

20
Brown et al. (2015, 25) find that industry knowledge is the single most useful input to analysts’ earnings forecasts
and stock recommendations and show that “institutional investors highly value sell-side analysts’ industry knowledge,”
suggesting that research of sell-side analysts can be a source of industry knowledge for many institutional investors.
By producing industry knowledge and leveling the playing field for institutional investors, industry-specialist analysts
should make all institutional investors more informed, reducing the information advantage of common owners.
23

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3746777


insignificantly different from zero in four of the six regressions, suggesting that the disciplinary

effect of common ownership on crash risk is mostly moderated by industry-specialist analysts.

Second, our information advantage argument implies that the negative effect of common

ownership on crash risk should be stronger in more opaque firms. This is because the information

advantages of common owners are likely to be greater, particularly when other market participants

are generally less informed. To test this conjecture, we modify the baseline model (1) by replacing

Opaque with High_Opaque and its interaction with common ownership, where High_Opaque

equals one if a firm’s opaqueness measure proposed by Hutton et al. (2009) is above the year-

industry median, and zero otherwise. 21 Consistent with our expectation, panel B of Table 5

indicates that the coefficients on the interaction terms are all negative and significant. The p values

in the row (a)+(b) are all significant, further confirming that the disciplinary effect of common

ownership is particularly strong in firms with greater opacity.

Third, we examine whether our cross-sectional test results hold in the DiD setting. We

modify the baseline DiD model (2) by including the additional interaction terms with High_Cover

and High_Opaque. 22 Consistent with the baseline DiD finding in panel A of Table 4, we continue

to find significant negative coefficients on Treated×Post. More importantly, the coefficients on

Treated×Post×High_Cover, the variable of interest in columns (1) and (2), are both positive and

significant. This finding is consistent with that in panel A—industry-specialist analysts moderate

the negative effect of common ownership on crash risk. In columns (3) and (4), the coefficients on

21
Research and development (R&D) projects are mostly industry-specific and thus industry expertise is required to
monitor overinvestments in R&D (Aboody and Lev 2000; Faleye et al. 2018). We use R&D as an opacity measure.
We also use reporting readability as an inverse measure of opaqueness (Li 2008; Kim et al. 2019). If the effect of
common owners on crash risk hinges on their information advantages, we should observe a stronger effect in high-
R&D or low-readability firms. We find evidence consistent with both conjectures in the untabulated robustness checks.
22
As discussed in section 4, because a specific firm in a given merger can only be either a treatment or a control firm,
the firm-merger fixed effects make the Treated indicator unidentified so it is not included in our regression. Similarly,
because we define High_Cover and High_Opaque indicators using pre-merger period data, their interactions with
Treated (i.e., Treated×High_Cover and Treated×High_Opaque) are also absorbed by the firm-merger fixed effects.
24

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3746777


Treated×Post×High_Opaque are both negative and significant, confirming the finding in panel B

that the negative effect of common ownership on crash risk is more pronounced in opaque firms.

Cross-sectional evidence: Internalizing governance externalities

This section explores the second mechanism—greater monitoring incentives due to

externalities. We first use the magnitude of governance externalities as a moderator. He et al. (2019)

argue that in an industry with a more competitive managerial labor market, a firm is more likely

to tolerate managerial opportunism (e.g., withholding bad news) because it has greater difficulty

finding a replacement. However, if a firm disciplines bad news hoarding, other firms in the same

industry would be relieved from experiencing this “race to the bottom” game and benefit from

improved governance standards. Thus, the externalities should provide common owners in these

industries with stronger incentives to restrict bad news hoarding. To measure an industry’s labor

market competition, we follow He et al. (2019) and use the industry homogeneity index, which is

the industry average of the partial correlation coefficients between a firm’s stock returns and

industry returns after controlling for market returns (Parrino 1997). We set High_Homo to one

when an industry’s homogeneity index is above the sample median in a year, and zero otherwise.

Panel A of Table 6 reports a modified model (1), in which we add High_Homo and its interaction

with common ownership. The significantly negative coefficients on the interaction suggest that

internalizing governance externalities motivates common owners to curb bad news hoarding.

Prior studies argue that the attention that common owners pay to a firm increases with its

weight in their portfolios (Kempf et al. 2017; Gilje et al. 2020; Iliev et al. 2021). If common owners

are more attentive to a firm, managers have greater incentive to refrain from behaviors that cause

negative externalities, leading to a stronger effect of common ownership. To measure whether a

stock constitutes a larger proportion of common owners’ total portfolio values, High_Atten is set

25

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3746777


to one if the average ratio of a firm’s market value of equity to common owners’ portfolio values

is above the year-industry median, and zero otherwise (Schmidt 2019). Consistent with our

conjecture, panel B of Table 6 shows that the coefficients on the interaction between common

ownership and High_Atten are negative and significant in four regressions. All p values in both

panels A and B suggest that common owners indeed have a stronger disciplinary effect on crash

risk when they are more likely to internalize externalities. Panel C presents cross-sectional tests in

the DiD setting. Similar to panel C of Table 5, we modify the baseline DiD model (2) by including

interactions with High_Homo and High_Atten. The significantly negative coefficients on the triple

interactions suggest that our main findings in panels A and B of Table 6 hold in the DiD setting.

Our hypothesized negative relation between common ownership and crash risk is

conceptually grounded in information advantages and governance incentives of common owners.

The findings in Tables 5 and 6 are consistent with our conjectures and shed light on these two

mechanisms. 23 Furthermore, these tests further alleviate the concern that some omitted variables

drive our results because it is less likely that these omitted variables could drive the cross-sectional

variation in the observed effects (Jiang 2017).

6. Do common owners reduce crash risk through curbing bad news hoarding?

Our theoretical arguments suggest that common owners could take actions to correct

managers’ bad news hoarding and overinvestment behaviors, reducing crash risk as a result. In

this section, we perform exploratory analyses to provide tentative evidence on this conjecture.

Do common owners promote accounting conservatism and consequently reduce crash risk?

Common owners can promote certain financial reporting practices to reduce bad news

23
To test the anticompetitive channel, we examine whether the relation between common ownership and crash risk
is less negative in firms facing higher pressure from product market competition, proxied by Hoberg et al.’s (2014)
market fluidity measure. The results in Table IA.4 of Internet Appendix do not offer significant supporting evidence.
26

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3746777


hoarding behaviors. Prior literature shows that equity investors demand accounting conservatism

as a governance device because it can constrain managerial abilities to overstate accounting

numbers and effectively curb bad news hoarding (Ramalingegowda and Yu 2012; Kim and Zhang

2016). Because common owners may reap benefits of positive externalities from reduced bad news

hoarding of industry peers in their portfolios, they should have stronger incentives to promote

accounting conservatism in their portfolio firms. As such, we predict that common ownership

should have an incremental positive effect on accounting conservatism, which in turn leads to

reduced crash risk. To test our prediction, we follow Cheng et al. (2022) and Di Giuli and Laux

(2022) and estimate the following two-stage regressions:

𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝑖𝑖,𝑡𝑡 = 𝛽𝛽0 + 𝛽𝛽1 𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶 𝑂𝑂𝑂𝑂𝑂𝑂𝑂𝑂𝑂𝑂𝑂𝑂ℎ𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖,𝑡𝑡 + 𝛽𝛽2 𝑍𝑍𝑖𝑖,𝑡𝑡 + 𝐹𝐹𝐹𝐹𝐹𝐹𝐹𝐹𝐹𝐹 𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸 + 𝜀𝜀𝑖𝑖,𝑡𝑡 (3-i)

� 𝑖𝑖,𝑡𝑡 + 𝛽𝛽2 𝑍𝑍𝑖𝑖,𝑡𝑡 + 𝐹𝐹𝐹𝐹𝐹𝐹𝐹𝐹𝐹𝐹 𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸 + 𝜀𝜀𝑖𝑖,𝑡𝑡


𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶ℎ 𝑅𝑅𝑅𝑅𝑅𝑅𝑅𝑅𝑖𝑖,𝑡𝑡+1 = 𝛽𝛽0 + 𝛽𝛽1 𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶 (3-ii)

where CScore in equation (3-i) is the firm-year conservatism measure proposed by Khan and Watts

(2009). In the first stage, we regress CScore on common ownership and the set of control variables

in our baseline model. As shown in panel A of Table 7, the coefficients on the common ownership

proxies are all positive and significant. These results are consistent with our conjecture that higher

common ownership is associated with greater accounting conservatism.

� is the predicted CScore based


In the second stage, the key independent variable 𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶

on the first-stage regression (3-i). It captures the part of CScore that can be explained by common

ownership. If accounting conservatism induced by common ownership is indeed the channel by

� will be negative and


which common ownership reduces crash risk, the coefficients on 𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶

significant. The results in panel B are consistent with this conjecture. Additionally, if we multiply

� in column (1) of panel B by the corresponding coefficient on common


the coefficient on 𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶

27

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3746777


ownership in panel A, the product (= −3.634×0.0056) is the same as the coefficient (−0.02) on

Com_Dummy in column (1) of Table 2. This suggests that the two-stage analysis essentially

decomposes the negative effect of common ownership on crash risk into two steps and enables us

to identify accounting conservatism as a transmission mechanism. Collectively, the findings in

panels A and B support those in prior studies (Ramalingegowda and Yu 2012; Kim and Zhang

2016). They also provide tentative support for the argument that common owners promote greater

accounting conservatism to reduce bad news hoarding and, consequently, reduce crash risk.

Do common owners constrain overinvestment and consequently reduce crash risk?

In section 2, we predict that common owners negatively affect crash risk through

constraining overinvestment—a type of bad news hoarding. To test this, we modify equations (3-

i) and (3-ii) by replacing CScore with an overinvestment measure. We use Biddle et al.’s (2009)

investment model and then sort the observations into quartiles based on the residuals from the

model. We classify observations in the top quartile in a year as over-investing firms and those in

the middle two quartiles as the benchmark group. The dependent variable in the first-stage

regression, OverInv, equals the residual of the investment model if an observation is classified as

over-investing, and zero if it is an observation in the benchmark group. Table 8, panel A shows that

the coefficients on the common ownership proxies are all negative and statistically significant,

supporting our prediction that common ownership is negatively related to overinvestment.

� , is
Panel B presents the second-stage regression. The key independent variable, 𝑂𝑂𝑂𝑂𝑂𝑂𝑂𝑂𝑂𝑂𝑂𝑂𝑂𝑂

the predicted OverInv based on the first-stage regression. It captures the part of OverInv that is

� are all positive and


explained by common ownership. We find that the coefficients on 𝑂𝑂𝑂𝑂𝑂𝑂𝑂𝑂𝑂𝑂𝑂𝑂𝑂𝑂

significant, suggesting that a lower level of overinvestment is associated with less crash risk. In

sum, panels A and B are consistent with the conjecture that common ownership can reduce

28

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3746777


overinvestment and, consequently, lead to lower crash risk. The estimates in Tables 7 and 8 provide

tentative evidence that constraining bad news hoarding (e.g., promoting conservatism or reducing

inefficient investment projects) is the intermediate step for common owners to reduce crash risk.

7. How do common owners discipline managers of firms with high crash risk?

Thus far, we show that common owners alleviate bad news hoarding by promoting

accounting conservatism and curbing overinvestment, suggesting that common owners take ex

ante actions to reduce the likelihood of stock price crashes. It also stands to reason that common

owners take ex post actions to discipline managers responsible for stock price crashes. Firing top

executives is one of the most aggressive governance actions that large shareholders can take (Denis

et al. 1997; Bethel et al. 1998). Plenty of anecdotal and academic evidence shows that disagreement

between management and large shareholders leads to forced CEO turnover (Campbell et al. 2011;

Kang et al. 2018). Therefore, we conjecture that common owners have incentives to internalize

governance externalities by firing CEOs of high-crash-risk firms. By doing so, they can set a

precedent and deter executives of peer firms from increasing crash risk.

We obtain forced CEO turnover data from Peters and Wagner (2014). Forced equals one if

a firm has a forced CEO turnover in a given year, and zero otherwise. We regress Forced on our

common-ownership proxies, High_Crash, and the interactions between common ownership and

High_Crash. To mitigate the concern that our finding is driven by high institutional ownership,

we include an additional interaction term, InstOwn×High_Crash. Table 9 shows that the

coefficients on the interactions between common ownership and High_Crash are positive and

significant in five of the six regressions. 24 These results are consistent with our conjecture that

common owners are more likely to take actions to dismiss CEOs of high crash-risk firms.

24
The combined coefficients on a common ownership measure and the corresponding interaction term are statistically
significant in most regressions, consistent with Kang et al.’s (2018) finding that common owners are more likely to
29

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3746777


8. Conclusion

U.S. public firms are increasingly connected with their industry peers through institutional

cross-blockholding. Common institutional ownership has emerged as a significant anticompetitive

concern among regulators and academics (Phillips 2018). Although recent studies shed

considerable light on the product market consequences of common ownership, there is a surprising

paucity of evidence on whether it has significant economic consequences for the stock market.

Our study proposes that common owners should have greater information advantages and

governance incentives to play a monitoring role in curtailing bad news hoarding and

overinvestment, leading to lower crash risk. Supporting the conjecture, we find a negative and

significant relation between common ownership and crash risk. The identification tests suggest

that the negative effect of common ownership on crash risk is causal. Our cross-sectional tests

support the argument that greater information advantages and stronger monitoring incentives are

the channels through which common owners exert a negative effect on the crash risk of the firms

in their portfolios. Next, we perform two-stage regression analyses and provide tentative evidence

that common owners take measures to mitigate bad news hoarding and overinvestment problems,

which in turn reduces crash risk. Lastly, we show that common owners take actions to penalize

managers who are responsible for stock crashes.

Overall, our findings suggest that unique features of common institutional blockholders

enable them to play an effective monitoring role in curbing crash risk. By identifying common

ownership as a significant determinant of crash risk, this study contributes new evidence to the

crash risk literature and offers valuable insights for investors to improve risk management. Our

findings also shed new light on additional economic benefits of common ownership (e.g.,

force CEO turnover. Our findings here complement their finding by showing that common owners have significantly
stronger incentives to discipline CEOs when a firm’s stock is more prone to crashes.
30

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3746777


promoting conservative reporting and reducing inefficient firm investment), informing the ongoing

debate among scholars and policymakers regarding common ownership.

31

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3746777


References
Aboody, D., and B. Lev. 2000. Information asymmetry, R&D, and insider gains. Journal of
Finance 55(6): 2747–66.
Acharya, V. V., and P. Volpin. 2010. Corporate governance externalities. Review of Finance 14(1):
1–33.
Admati, A. R., and P. Pfleiderer. 2009. The “Wall Street Walk” and shareholder activism: Exit as
a form of voice. Review of Financial Studies 22(7): 2645–85.
An, Z.,G. Huang, D. Li, and S. Xiao. 2014. Foreign institutional ownership, risk–taking, and crash
risk around the world. Working Paper, Monash University and University of New South Wales.
An, H., and T. Zhang. 2013. Stock price synchronicity, crash risk, and institutional investors.
Journal of Corporate Finance 21: 1–15.
Andreou, P. C., C. Antoniou, J. Horton, and C. Louca. 2016. Corporate governance and firm‐
specific stock price crashes. European Financial Management 22(5): 916–56.
Anton, M., F. Ederer, M. Gine, and M. Schmalz. 2018. Innovation: The bright side of common
ownership? Working Paper, University of Navarra, Yale University, and University of Oxford.
Anton, M., F. Ederer, M. Gine, and M. Schmalz. 2023. Common ownership, competition, and top
management incentives. Journal of Political Economy, forthcoming.
Anton, M., and C. Polk. 2014. Connected stocks. Journal of Finance 69(3): 1099–1127.
Azar, J., M. Schmalz, and I. Tecu. 2018. Anti-competitive effects of common ownership. Journal
of Finance 73(4): 1513–65.
Backus, M., C. Conlon, and M. Sinkinson. 2021. Common ownership in America: 1980–2017.
American Economic Journal: Microeconomics 13(3): 273–308.
Bates, D. 2000. Post-'87 crash fears in the S&P 500 futures option market. Journal of Econometrics
94(1-2): 181–238.
Bauer, A. M., X. Fang, and J. Pittman. 2021. The importance of IRS enforcement to stock price
crash risk: The role of CEO power and incentives. The Accounting Review 96(4): 81–109.
Beatty, A., S. Liao, and J. Yu. 2013. The spillover effect of fraudulent financial reporting on peer
firms' investments. Journal of Accounting and Economics 55(2–3): 183–205.
Benmelech, E., E. Kandel, and P. Veronesi. 2010. Stock-based compensation and CEO (dis)
incentives. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 125(4): 1769–820.
Bethel, J., J. Liebeskind, and T. Opler. 1998. Block share purchases and corporate performance.
Journal of Finance 53(2): 605–34.
Bharath, S., S. Jayaraman, and V. Nagar. 2013. Exit as governance: An empirical analysis. Journal
of Finance 68(6): 2515–47.
Biddle, G., G. Hilary, and R. Verdi. 2009. How does financial reporting quality relate to investment
efficiency? Journal of Accounting and Economics 48(2–3): 112–31.
Bleck, A., and X. Liu. 2007. Market transparency and the accounting regime. Journal of
Accounting Research 45(2): 229–56.
Boni, L., and K. Womack. 2006. Analysts, industries, and price momentum. Journal of Financial
and Quantitative Analysis 41(1): 85–109.
Brochet, F., K. Kolev, and A. Lerman. 2018. Information transfer and conference calls. Review of
Accounting Studies 23(3): 907–57.
Brown, L., A. Call, M. Clement, and N. Sharp. 2015. Inside the “black box” of sell‐side
financial analysts. Journal of Accounting Research 53(1): 1–47.

32

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3746777


Brunnermeier, M. K., and L. Pedersen. 2005. Predatory trading. Journal of Finance 60(4): 1825–
63.
Brunnermeier, M. K., and L. Pedersen. 2009. Market liquidity and funding liquidity. Review of
Financial Studies 22(6): 2201–38.
Bushee, B. 1998. The influence of institutional investors on myopic R&D investment behavior.
The Accounting Review 73(3): 305–33.
Bushee, B. 2001. Do institutional investors prefer near‐term earnings over long‐run value?.
Contemporary Accounting Research 18(2): 207–46.
Bustamante, M. C., and L. Frésard. 2021. Does firm investment respond to peers’ investment?.
Management Science 67(8): 4703–24.
Callen, J. L., and X. Fang. 2013. Institutional investor stability and crash risk: Monitoring versus
short-termism?. Journal of Banking and Finance 37(8): 3047–63.
Callen, J. L., and X. Fang. 2015. Religion and stock price crash risk. Journal of Financial and
Quantitative Analysis 50(1-2): 169–95.
Campbell, T. C., M. Gallmeyer, S. Johnson, J. Rutherford, and B. Stanley. 2011. CEO optimism
and forced turnover. Journal of Financial Economics 101(3): 695–712.
Chang, X., Y. Chen
, and L. Zolotoy. 2017. Stock liquidity and stock price crash risk. Journal of Financial and
Quantitative Analysis 52(4): 1605–37.
Chang, H. S., M. Donohoe, and T. Sougiannis. 2016. Do analysts understand the economic and
reporting complexities of derivatives? Journal of Accounting and Economics 61(2-3): 584–
604.
Chen, J., H. Hong, and J. Stein. 2001. Forecasting crashes: Trading volume, past returns, and
conditional skewness in stock prices. Journal of Financial Economics 61(3): 345–81.
Chen, S., Ma, H., Wu, Q., & Zhang, H. 2023. Does common ownership constrain managerial rent
extraction? Evidence from insider trading profitability. Journal of Corporate Finance 80:
102389.
Cheng, S. F., G. De Franco, and P. Lin. 2022. Marijuana liberalization and public finance: A capital
market perspective on the passage of medical use laws. Journal of Accounting and Economics
75(1): 101516.
Cheng, C. A., J. Xie, and Y. Zhong. 2023. Common institutional ownership and tail risk. Journal
of Banking and Finance 148: 106723.
Chiyachantana, C. N., P. K. Jain, C. Jiang, and R. Wood. 2004. International evidence on
institutional trading behavior and price impact. Journal of Finance 59(2): 869–98.
Chordia, T., R. Roll, and A. Subrahmanyam. 2000. Commonality in liquidity. Journal of Financial
Economics 56(1): 3–28.
Chung, K. H., and H. Zhang. 2011. Corporate governance and institutional ownership. Journal of
Financial and Quantitative Analysis 46(1): 247–73.
Chung, K. H., and H. Zhang. 2014. A simple approximation of intraday spreads using daily data.
Journal of Financial Markets 17: 94–120.
Darrough. M., and N. Stoughton. 1990. Financial disclosure policy in an entry game. Journal of
Accounting Economics 12(1–3): 219–43.
De Bodt, E., B. E. Eckbo, and R. Roll. 2020. Competition shocks, rival reactions, and return
comovement. Working Paper, Dartmouth College and California Institute of Technology.
DeFond, M. L., M. Hung, S. Li, and Y. Li. 2015. Does mandatory IFRS adoption affect crash
risk?. The Accounting Review 90(1): 265–99.
33

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3746777


Denis, D. J., D. K. Denis, and A. Sarin. 1997. Ownership structure and top executive turnover.
Journal of Financial Economics 45(2): 193–221.
Dennis, P., K. Gerardi, and C. Schenone. 2022. Common ownership does not have anticompetitive
effects in the airline industry. Journal of Finance 77(5): 2765–98.
DesJardine, M., J. Grewal, and K. Viswanathan. 2022. A rising tide lifts all boats: The effects of
common ownership on corporate social responsibility. Organization Science, forthcoming.
DesJardine, M., M. Zhang, and W. Shi. 2023. How shareholders impact stakeholder interests: A
review and map for future research. Journal of Management 49(1): 400–29.
Dhaliwal, D., S. Huang, I. Khurana, and R. Pereira. 2014. Product market competition and
conditional conservatism. Review of Accounting Studies 19(4): 1309–45.
Di Giuli, A., and P. Laux. 2022. The effect of media-linked directors on financing and external
governance. Journal of Financial Economics 145(2): 103–31.
Dicks, D. L. 2012. Executive compensation and the role for corporate governance regulation.
Review of Financial Studies 25(6): 1971–2004.
Dou, Y., R. Masulis, and J. Zein. 2019. Shareholder wealth consequences of insider pledging of
company stock as collateral for personal loans. Review of Financial Studies 32(12): 4810–54.
Edmans, A., and G. Manso. 2011. Governance through trading and intervention: A theory of
multiple blockholders. Review of Financial Studies 24(7): 2395–428.
Elhauge, E. 2016. Rehabilitating Jefferson Parish: Why ties without a substantial foreclosure share
should not be per se legal. Antitrust Law Journal 80(3): 463–520.
Faleye, O., R. Hoitash, and U. Hoitash. 2018. Industry expertise on corporate boards. Review of
Quantitative Finance and Accounting 50(2): 441–79.
Gao, P., and G. Zhang. 2019. Accounting manipulation, peer pressure, and internal control. The
Accounting Review 94(1): 127–51.
Gilje, E. P., T. Gormley, and D. Levit. 2020. Who's paying attention? Measuring common
ownership and its impact on managerial incentives. Journal of Financial Economics 137(1):
152–78.
Gilson, S. C., P. Healy, C. Noe, and K. Palepu. 2001. Analyst specialization and conglomerate
stock breakups. Journal of Accounting Research 39(3): 565–82.
Hameed, A., R. Morck, J. Shen, and B. Yeung. 2015. Information, analysts, and stock return
comovement. Review of Financial Studies 28(11): 3153–87.
He, J. J., and J. Huang. 2017. Product market competition in a world of cross-ownership: Evidence
from institutional blockholdings. Review of Financial Studies 30(8): 2674–718.
He, J. J., J. Huang, and S. Zhao. 2019. Internalizing governance externalities: The role of
institutional cross–ownership. Journal of Financial Economics 134(2): 400–18
Hillegeist, S. A., and L. Weng. 2021. Quasi‐indexer ownership and insider trading: Evidence from
Russell Index reconstitutions. Contemporary Accounting Research 38(3): 2192–223.
Hoberg, G., and G. Phillips. 2012. The stock market, product uniqueness, and comovement of peer
firms. Working Paper, University of Maryland and University of Southern California.
Hoberg, G., G. Phillips, and N. Prabhala. 2014. Product market threats, payouts, and financial
flexibility. Journal of Finance 69(1): 293–324.
Hong, H. A., J. B. Kim, and M. Welker. 2017. Divergence of cash flow and voting rights, opacity,
and stock price crash risk: International evidence. Journal of Accounting Research 55(5):
1167–212.
Hutton, A. P., A. Marcus, and H. Tehranian. 2009. Opaque financial reports, R2, and crash
risk. Journal of Financial Economics 94(1): 67–86.
34

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3746777


Iliev, P., J. Kalodimos, and M. Lowry. 2021. Investors' attention to corporate governance. Review
of Financial Studies 34(12): 5581–628.
Jackson Jr., R. J. 2018. Common ownership: The investor protection challenge of the 21st century.
https://www.sec.gov/news/testimony/jackson-testimony-ftc-120618.
Jayaraman, S., T. Milbourn, F. Peters, and H. Seo. 2021. Product market peers and relative
performance evaluation. The Accounting Review 96(4): 341–66.
Jiang, W. 2017. Have instrumental variables brought us closer to the truth. Review of Corporate
Finance Studies 6(2): 127–140.
Jiang, P., Y. Ma, and B. Shi. 2022. Common ownership and stock price crash risk: Evidence from
China. Australian Economic Papers 61(4): 876–912.
Jin, L., and S. Myers. 2006. R2 around the world: New theory and new tests. Journal of Financial
Economics 79(2): 257–92.
Kacperczyk, M., C. Sialm, and L. Zheng. 2005. On the industry concentration of actively managed
equity mutual funds. Journal of Finance 60(4): 1983–2011.
Kang, J. K., J. Luo, and H. Na. 2018. Are institutional investors with multiple blockholdings
effective monitors? Journal of Financial Economics 128(3): 576–602.
Kelly, B., and H. Jiang. 2014. Tail risk and asset prices. Review of Financial Studies 27(10): 2841–
71.
Kempf, E., A. Manconi, and O. Spalt. 2017. Distracted shareholders and corporate actions. Review
of Financial Studies 30(5): 1660–95.
Khan, M., and R. Watts. 2009. Estimation and empirical properties of a firm-year measure of
accounting conservatism. Journal of Accounting and Economics 48(2–3): 132–50.
Khurana, I. K., R. Pereira, and E. Zhang. 2018. Is real earnings smoothing harmful? Evidence from
firm‐specific stock price crash risk. Contemporary Accounting Research 35(1): 558–87.
Kim, C., K. Wang, and L. Zhang. 2019. Readability of 10‐K reports and stock price crash risk.
Contemporary Accounting Research 36(2): 1184–216.
Kim, J. B., Y. Li, and L. Zhang. 2011a. Corporate tax avoidance and stock price crash risk: Firm-
level analysis. Journal of Financial Economics 100(3): 639–62.
Kim, J. B., Y. Li, and L. Zhang. 2011b. CFOs versus CEOs: Equity incentives and crashes. Journal
of Financial Economics 101(3): 713–30.
Kim, J. B., L. Li, L. Lu, and Y. Yu. 2016a. Financial statement comparability and expected crash
risk. Journal of Accounting and Economics 61(2–3): 294–312.
Kim, J. B., Z. Wang, and L. Zhang. 2016b. CEO overconfidence and stock price crash risk.
Contemporary Accounting Research 33(4): 1720–49.
Kim, J. B., and L. Zhang. 2016. Accounting conservatism and stock price crash risk: Firm‐level
evidence. Contemporary Accounting Research 33(1): 412–41.
Koch, A., S. Ruenzi, and L. Starks. 2016. Commonality in liquidity: A demand-side explanation.
Review of Financial Studies 29(8): 1943–74.
Kravet, T., and T. Shevlin. 2010. Accounting restatements and information risk. Review of
Accounting Studies 15(2): 264–94.
Lang, M., and R. Lundholm. 1996. Corporate disclosure policy and analyst behavior. The
Accounting Review 71(4): 467–92.
Lewellen, K., and M. Lowry. 2021. Does common ownership really increase firm coordination?
Journal of Financial Economics 141(1): 322–44.
Li, F. 2008. Annual report readability, current earnings, and earnings persistence. Journal of
Accounting and Economics 45(2-3): 221–47.
35

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3746777


Li, V. 2016. Do false financial statements distort peer firms' decisions?. The Accounting Review
91(1): 251–78.
Li, Q., X. Ni, P. E. Yeung, and D. Yin. 2022. The information advantage of industry common
blockholders and its stabilizing effect on stock price crash risk. Working Paper, Wuhan
University, Xiamen University, Cornell University, and Miami University.
Lu, R., Q. Shen, T. Wang, and X. Zhang. 2022. Frenemies: Corporate advertising under common
ownership. Management Science 68(6): 4645–69.
McCahery, J. A., Z. Sautner, and L. Starks. Behind the scenes: The corporate governance
preferences of institutional investors. Journal of Finance 71(6): 2905–32.
Parrino, R., 1997. CEO turnover and outside succession a cross–sectional analysis. Journal of
Financial Economics 46(2): 165–97.
Peters, F., and A. Wagner, 2014. The executive turnover risk premium. Journal of Finance 69(4):
1529–63.
Phillips, N. J. 2018. Taking stock: Assessing common ownership. In US Federal Trade
Commissioner’s speech at Concurrences Review and NYU Stern: The Global Antitrust
Economics Conference, New York.
Posner, E. A., F. Scott Morton, and E. Weyl. 2017. A proposal to limit the anti-competitive power
of institutional investors. Antitrust Law Journal 81: 669–728.
Ramalingegowda, S., S. Utke, and Y. Yu. 2021. Common institutional ownership and earnings
management. Contemporary Accounting Research, 38(1), 208–41.
Ramalingegowda, S., and Y. Yu. 2012. Institutional ownership and conservatism. Journal of
Accounting and Economics 53(1-2): 98–114.
Robin, A. J., and H. Zhang. 2015. Do industry-specialist auditors influence stock price crash risk?.
Auditing: A Journal of Practice & Theory 34(3): 47–79.
Rock, E., and D. Rubinfeld. 2017. Antitrust for institutional investors. Working Paper, New York
University and University of California at Berkeley. Link: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2998296
Schmidt, D. 2019. Distracted institutional investors. Journal of Financial and Quantitative
Analysis 54(6): 2453–91.
Shleifer, A., and R. Vishny. 2011. Fire sales in finance and macroeconomics. Journal of Economic
Perspectives 25(1): 29–48.
Sidak, J. 2003. The failure of good intentions: The WorldCom fraud and the collapse of American
telecommunications after deregulation. Yale Journal on Regulation 20: 207–67.
Sun, L., and S. Abraham. 2021. Estimating dynamic treatment effects in event studies with
heterogeneous treatment effects. Journal of Econometrics 225(2): 175–99.

36

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3746777


APPENDIX A
Variable definitions

Variables Definitions
Dependent Variables of the Baseline Regression
Ncskew The negative skewness of firm-specific weekly returns during a year. Firm-
specific weekly returns are the residuals from the expanded index-model
regression (see, e.g., Hutton et al. 2009).
Duvol The logarithm of the ratio of the standard deviations of firm-specific returns in
down weeks to the standard deviations in up weeks during a year.
Key Independent Variables of the Baseline Regression
Com_Dummy An indicator variable that equals one if the firm shares at least one blockholder
with at least one same-industry firm in at least one of the four quarters within
a year, and zero otherwise. Industry classification is based on 3-digit SIC
industry code.
LnNumInve The natural logarithm of one plus the average number of the firm’s
blockholders that also blockhold at least one same-industry firm over the four
quarters within a year.
LnNumFirm The natural logarithm of one plus the number of same-industry peer firms that
share a common institutional blockholder with the focal firm in a year.
Control Variables in the Baseline Regression
Size The natural logarithm of a firm’s total assets.
MTB The ratio of market value to book value of total assets.
Leverage The ratio of total debt to total assets.
ROA The ratio of earnings before extraordinary items to total assets.
Return 100 times the mean value of firm-specific weekly returns during the year.
Sigma The standard deviation of firm-specific weekly returns during a given year.
Dturn Average monthly stock turnover over the current year minus those over the
previous year.
Opaque The moving sum of the absolute value of abnormal accruals in the prior three
years, where abnormal accruals are estimated using the modified Jones model.
InstiOwn Institutional ownership, defined as the sum of shares held by institutional
investors divided by the total number of shares outstanding.
CrossDiff An indicator variable that equals one if the firm shares at least one blockholder
with at least one different-industry firm in at least one of the four quarters
within a year while not blockholding firms within the same industry during the
year, and zero otherwise.
BlockD An indicator variable that equals one if a firm has at least one blockholder in a
year, and zero otherwise.
IOQix Quasi-indexer ownership, defined as the sum of shares held by quasi-indexers
divided by the total number of shares outstanding.
Key Variables used in Other Tests (sorted in Alphabetical Order)
CScore The accounting conservatism measure proposed by Khan and Watts (2009).
High_Atten An indicator variable that equals one if the average ratio of a firm’s market
value of equity to common owners’ portfolio values is above the year-industry
median, and zero otherwise.
An indicator variable that equals one if the number of industry-specialist
High_Cover
analysts following a firm is above the year-industry median, and zero
otherwise.

37

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3746777


High_Homo An indicator variable that equals one when an industry’s homogeneity index is
above the sample median in a year, and zero otherwise.
High_Opaque An indicator variable that equals one if a firm’s opaqueness measure (Hutton
et al., 2009) is above the year-industry median, and zero otherwise.
Over-investment variable that equals the residuals of investment model if a firm
OverInv
is classified as over-investing, and zero if a firm is classified as in the
benchmark group.
An indicator variable that equals one for the years after the merger, and zero
Post
otherwise.
An indicator variable that equals one for treatment firms and zero for control
Treated
firms.

38

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3746777


TABLE 1
Summary statistics

Variable N Mean SD Q1 Median Q3


Ncskew 96,119 -0.250 0.659 -0.573 -0.246 0.053
Duvol 96,119 -0.076 0.364 -0.317 -0.085 0.151
Com_Dummy 96,119 0.544 0.498 0.000 1.000 1.000
LnNumInve 96,119 0.591 0.609 0.000 0.693 1.099
LnNumFirm 96,119 1.105 1.182 0.000 1.099 1.946
Size 96,119 5.396 2.102 3.841 5.280 6.826
MTB 96,119 2.921 4.063 1.117 1.864 3.230
Leverage 96,119 0.473 0.213 0.310 0.480 0.626
ROA 96,119 0.032 0.204 0.008 0.074 0.126
Return 96,119 -0.271 0.361 -0.317 -0.148 -0.071
Sigma 96,119 0.060 0.034 0.035 0.051 0.075
DTurn 96,119 0.002 0.069 -0.017 0.000 0.018
Opaque 96,119 0.172 0.123 0.084 0.137 0.223
InstiOwn 96,119 0.416 0.309 0.129 0.379 0.675
CrossDiff 96,119 0.555 0.497 0.000 1.000 1.000
BlockD 96,119 0.647 0.478 0.000 1.000 1.000
IOQix 96,119 0.231 0.237 0.000 0.157 0.420
Notes: This table reports the summary statistics of the variables used in the baseline regression. Our sample
is comprised of firms listed on the Nasdaq, NYSE, and AMEX between 1980 and 2017. Appendix A
presents the variable definitions.

39

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3746777


TABLE 2
The effect of common ownership on stock price crash risk

Dep Var= Ncskew Duvol


(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
Com_Dummy -0.020*** -0.013***
(-2.81) (-3.00)
LnNumInve -0.042*** -0.024***
(-5.99) (-5.43)
LnNumFirm -0.011*** -0.006***
(-3.36) (-3.15)
Size 0.070*** 0.069*** 0.070*** 0.036*** 0.036*** 0.036***
(11.59) (11.57) (11.65) (10.66) (10.66) (10.68)
MTB 0.004*** 0.004*** 0.004*** 0.003*** 0.003*** 0.003***
(4.88) (4.87) (4.88) (6.24) (6.25) (6.24)
Leverage -0.153*** -0.151*** -0.152*** -0.045*** -0.045*** -0.045***
(-6.95) (-6.88) (-6.94) (-3.76) (-3.68) (-3.75)
ROA 0.278*** 0.277*** 0.279*** 0.085*** 0.085*** 0.085***
(10.34) (10.26) (10.35) (5.51) (5.44) (5.53)
Return -0.099** -0.097** -0.099** 0.009 0.011 0.009
(-2.54) (-2.50) (-2.55) (0.48) (0.55) (0.47)
Sigma -2.410*** -2.364*** -2.415*** -0.261 -0.236 -0.265
(-4.80) (-4.76) (-4.81) (-1.01) (-0.92) (-1.03)
Dturn 0.263*** 0.264*** 0.263*** 0.157*** 0.158*** 0.157***
(5.64) (5.66) (5.63) (5.81) (5.84) (5.81)
Opaque 0.046** 0.046** 0.046** 0.034*** 0.035*** 0.034***
(2.21) (2.25) (2.21) (3.07) (3.10) (3.07)
InstiOwn 0.277*** 0.302*** 0.277*** 0.171*** 0.185*** 0.171***
(8.01) (8.55) (7.98) (8.13) (8.58) (8.15)
CrossDiff 0.027** 0.026** 0.027** 0.015** 0.014* 0.015**
(2.18) (2.05) (2.16) (1.98) (1.85) (1.96)
BlockD -0.017*** -0.015** -0.017*** -0.008** -0.007* -0.008**
(-2.87) (-2.41) (-2.90) (-2.21) (-1.79) (-2.22)
IOQix -0.073** -0.064* -0.072** -0.049** -0.044** -0.049**
(-2.05) (-1.79) (-2.04) (-2.39) (-2.13) (-2.39)
Constant -0.558*** -0.560*** -0.560*** -0.303*** -0.304*** -0.305***
(-13.05) (-13.16) (-13.24) (-12.42) (-12.54) (-12.59)
Firm Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Blockholder Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Year Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
N 96,119 96,119 96,119 96,119 96,119 96,119
R2 0.132 0.133 0.132 0.087 0.087 0.087
Notes: This table presents the baseline regression of stock price crash risk on common ownership. The
dependent variable is one of the crash risk measures, Ncskew or Duvol. The key independent variable is one
of the common ownership proxies, Com_Dummy, LnNumInve, or LnNumFirm. Control variables include
Size, MTB, Leverage, ROA, Return, Sigma, Dturn, Opaque, InstiOwn, CrossDiff, BlockD, and IOQix.
Appendix A presents the variable definitions. Continuous variables are winsorized at the 1% and 99% levels.
Standard errors are all heteroscedasticity robust, clustered by both firm and year. ∗, ∗∗, and ∗∗∗ represent
significance levels of 10%, 5%, and 1%, respectively.

40

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3746777


TABLE 3
Addressing endogeneity concern: A falsification test

Dep Var= (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)


Com_Dummy LnNumInve LnNumFirm Com_Dummy LnNumInve LnNumFirm
Ncskew -0.001 -0.001 -0.002
(-0.32) (-0.38) (-0.51)
Duvol -0.005 -0.004 -0.011
(-0.81) (-0.81) (-1.08)
Size 0.029*** 0.024*** 0.074*** 0.029*** 0.025*** 0.075***
(4.69) (4.36) (5.71) (4.72) (4.38) (5.73)
MTB -0.000 -0.000 -0.000 -0.000 -0.000 -0.000
(-0.46) (-0.82) (-0.04) (-0.44) (-0.80) (-0.02)
Leverage 0.010 0.003 -0.006 0.010 0.003 -0.006
(0.51) (0.20) (-0.15) (0.51) (0.20) (-0.15)
ROA -0.014 -0.012 -0.020 -0.014 -0.013 -0.022
(-0.93) (-0.94) (-0.65) (-0.99) (-0.98) (-0.70)
Return 0.014 0.015 0.039 0.015 0.015 0.040
(0.66) (0.79) (1.03) (0.69) (0.80) (1.05)
Sigma 0.001 0.035 0.193 0.007 0.039 0.207
(0.00) (0.13) (0.36) (0.02) (0.14) (0.38)
Dturn 0.060* 0.060* 0.184* 0.060* 0.060* 0.182*
(1.75) (1.71) (1.98) (1.73) (1.70) (1.97)
Opaque 0.023 0.023 0.032 0.023 0.023 0.032
(1.07) (1.31) (0.74) (1.07) (1.31) (0.74)
InstiOwn 0.479*** 0.447*** 0.695*** 0.480*** 0.447*** 0.695***
(9.87) (8.62) (7.98) (9.88) (8.62) (7.98)
CrossDiff 0.020 0.020* 0.032 0.020 0.020* 0.031
(1.47) (1.78) (1.28) (1.46) (1.78) (1.27)
BlockD -0.016* -0.016* -0.065*** -0.016* -0.016* -0.065***
(-1.75) (-1.95) (-3.88) (-1.75) (-1.95) (-3.88)
IOQix 0.116** 0.133** 0.164* 0.116** 0.133** 0.164*
(2.10) (2.49) (1.77) (2.11) (2.49) (1.78)
Constant -0.064* -0.074** -0.190*** -0.065* -0.074** -0.192***
(-1.97) (-2.48) (-2.72) (-2.00) (-2.51) (-2.75)
Firm Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Blockholder Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Year Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
N 37,181 37,181 37,181 37,181 37,181 37,181
R2 0.349 0.383 0.384 0.349 0.383 0.384
Notess: This table reports the regressions of common ownership proxies, Com_Dummy, LnNumInve, and
LnNumFirm, on the prior-year crash risk measure (Ncskew or Duvol). The sample consists of firm-year
observations without common institutional ownership in the prior three years. Control variables include
Size, MTB, Leverage, ROA, Return, Sigma, Dturn, Opaque, InstiOwn, CrossDiff, BlockD, and IOQix.
Appendix A presents the variable definitions. Continuous variables are winsorized at the 1% and 99% levels.
Standard errors are all heteroscedasticity robust, clustered by both firm and year. ∗, ∗∗, and ∗∗∗ represent
significance levels of 10%, 5%, and 1%, respectively.

41

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3746777


TABLE 4
Addressing endogeneity concern: DiD analyses on financial institution mergers

Panel A: DiD regression analysis on financial institution merges


Dep Var= (1) Ncskew (2) Duvol (3) Ncskew (4) Duvol
Post 0.044 0.006 -0.002 -0.020**
(1.60) (0.50) (-0.18) (-2.13)
Treated×Post -0.135*** -0.057*** -0.128*** -0.055***
(-4.68) (-2.93) (-4.57) (-3.85)
Controls No No Yes Yes
Firm-Merger FEs Yes Yes Yes Yes
N 7,087 7,087 7,087 7,087
R2 0.044 0.035 0.070 0.067
Panel B: DiD regressions with dynamic effects
Dep Var= (1) Ncskew (2) Duvol
Treated×Pre(-2) -0.121 -0.044
(-0.79) (-0.47)
Treated×Pre(-1) -0.108 -0.055
(-0.94) (-0.89)
Treated×Post(0) -0.016 -0.000
(-0.23) (-0.01)
Treated×Post(1) -0.079* -0.032
(-1.70) (-1.43)
Treated×Post(2) -0.187*** -0.071**
(-3.65) (-2.31)
Treated×Post(3) -0.327** -0.154*
(-2.49) (-1.87)
Controls Yes Yes
Firm-Merger FEs Yes Yes
N 7,087 7,087
R2 0.070 0.068
Panel C: Placebo tests
Dep Var= (1) Ncskew (2) Duvol (3) Ncskew (4) Duvol
Post -0.017 -0.004 -0.089*** -0.042***
(-0.95) (-0.53) (-3.78) (-4.66)
Treated×Post -0.013 -0.009 -0.003 -0.005
(-0.28) (-0.29) (-0.06) (-0.13)
Controls No No Yes Yes
Firm-Merger FEs Yes Yes Yes Yes
N 6,487 6,487 6,487 6,487
R2 0.033 0.024 0.048 0.035
Panel D: Robustness checks
Baseline DiD test using a sample Use an alternative control group
excluding mergers in 2008-2009 that consists of same industry size-
matched control firms
Dep Var= (1) Ncskew (2) Duvol (3) Ncskew (4) Duvol
Post -0.020 -0.001 0.044 0.003
42

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3746777


(-0.67) (-0.04) (0.96) (0.14)
Treated×Post -0.116*** -0.063**
(-2.91) (-2.08)
Treated_Alt×Post -0.115** -0.062**
(-2.70) (-2.21)
Controls Yes Yes Yes Yes
Firm-Merger FEs Yes Yes Yes Yes
N 2,484 2,484 2,548 2,548
R2 0.104 0.110 0.087 0.063
Notes: Panel A presents the DiD regressions that exploit the exogenous increase in common ownership
driven by financial institution mergers. We study a symmetric seven-year window around the event year
(i.e., three years before and three years after the institution merger and the year of the merger). The
dependent variables are the crash risk measures, Ncskew and Duvol. Treated is an indicator variable that
equals one for treatment firms and zero for control firms. The treatment firms are those blockheld by only
one of the merging institutions during the quarter preceding the merger announcement date, whereas the
other merging institution blockholds other firms in the same industry during the same pre-merger quarter.
The control firms are those blockheld by the merger partner with no industry rivals blockheld by the other
partner. Post is an indicator variable that equals one for the post-event period, and zero otherwise. Columns
(1)-(2) present the regressions without control variables, and columns (3)-(4) present the baseline DiD
model with control variables, including Size, MTB, Leverage, ROA, Return, Sigma, Dturn, Opaque,
InstiOwn, CrossDiff, BlockD, and IOQix. Panel B presents the DiD regressions with dynamic effects. Pre
(−1) (Pre (−2)) is an indicator variable that equals one if an observation is in the one year (two years)
before the merger, and zero otherwise. Post (0) (Post (1), Post (2) or Post (3)) is an indicator variable that
equals one if an observation is in the merger year (one year, two years, or three years after the merger), and
zero otherwise. Panel C presents a placebo test, in which we artificially shift the event year back by five
years and rerun the DiD regressions. In columns (1)-(2) of panel D, we rerun the baseline DiD regression
in panel A using a reduced sample that excludes the mergers in 2008-2009. Columns (3)-(4) of panel D
present the results of using an alternative way to define control firms. Specifically, we match each treatment
firm with a control firm that is in the same industry, has the closest firm size, and has at least one institutional
blockholder. Treated_Alt is an indicator variable that equals one for the treatment firms and zero for the
control firms defined in this alternative way. Standard errors are all heteroscedasticity robust, clustered by
financial institution merger levels. ∗, ∗∗, and ∗∗∗ represent significance levels of 10%, 5%, and 1%,
respectively.

43

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3746777


TABLE 5
Cross-sectional evidence: Information advantages

Panel A: Industry-specialist analyst coverage


Dep Var= Ncskew Duvol
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
Com_Dummy (a) -0.027*** -0.018***
(-2.61) (-3.02)
Com_Dummy × High_Cover(b) 0.028** 0.023***
(2.35) (3.49)
LnNumInve(a) -0.043*** -0.026***
(-3.97) (-4.28)
LnNumInve × High_Cover(b) 0.012 0.011*
(1.01) (1.72)
LnNumFirm(a) -0.018*** -0.012***
(-3.05) (-3.30)
LnNumFirm × High_Cover(b) 0.014** 0.010***
(2.16) (2.90)
High_Cover -0.009 0.001 -0.008 -0.007 -0.000 -0.005
(-0.71) (0.09) (-0.61) (-1.08) (-0.01) (-0.74)

(a)+(b) p=0.89 p=0.02 p=0.35 p=0.48 p=0.05 p=0.56


Controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Firm Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Blockhoder Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Year Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
N 55,060 55,060 55,060 55,060 55,060 55,060
R2 0.087 0.087 0.087 0.059 0.060 0.059

Panel B: Opaque information environment


Dep Var= Ncskew Duvol
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
Com_Dummy (a) -0.012 -0.010*
(-1.35) (-1.71)
Com_Dummy × High_Opaque(b) -0.018** -0.008*
(-2.16) (-1.74)
LnNumInve(a) -0.034*** -0.020***
(-4.10) (-3.85)
LnNumInve × High_Opaque (b) -0.018** -0.009**
(-2.54) (-2.12)
LnNumFirm(a) -0.004 -0.003
(-1.15) (-1.28)
LnNumFirm × High_Opaque (b) -0.012*** -0.006***
(-3.18) (-2.72)
High_Opaque 0.020*** 0.021*** 0.023*** 0.011*** 0.011*** 0.013***
(3.28) (3.48) (4.39) (3.00) (3.05) (3.95)

(a)+(b) p=0.00 p=0.00 p=0.00 p=0.00 p=0.00 p=0.00


Controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Firm Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Blockhoder Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Year Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
44

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3746777


N 96,119 96,119 96,119 96,119 96,119 96,119
R2 0.132 0.133 0.132 0.087 0.087 0.087
Panel C: Cross-sectional analysis in DiD setting
Dep Var= (1) Ncskew (2) Duvol (3) Ncskew (4) Duvol
Post -0.006 -0.021* 0.001 -0.017
(-0.47) (-1.78) (0.05) (-1.50)
Treated×Post -0.243*** -0.117*** 0.013 -0.004
(-6.08) (-4.52) (0.28) (-0.14)
High_Cover×Post 0.012 0.002
(0.72) (0.20)
Treated×Post×High_Cover 0.161** 0.090**
(2.24) (2.36)
High_Opaque×Post -0.007 -0.008
(-0.42) (-0.68)
Treated×Post×High_Opaque -0.245*** -0.088**
(-5.54) (-2.20)
Controls Yes Yes Yes Yes
Firm-Merger FEs Yes Yes Yes Yes
N 7,087 7,087 7,087 7,087
R2 0.070 0.067 0.071 0.067
Notes: This table examines whether the relation between common ownership and crash risk varies with
common owners’ information advantages. In panel A, High_Cover is an indicator variable that equals one
if the number of industry-specialist analysts following a firm is above the year-industry median, and zero
otherwise. In panel B, High_Opaque is an indicator variable that equals one if a firm’s opaqueness measure
is above the industry median in a given year, and zero otherwise. The dependent variables are the crash risk
measures, Ncskew and Duvol. The key independent variables are common ownership proxies, Com_Dummy,
LnNumInve, and LnNumFirm. Control variables include Size, MTB, Leverage, ROA, Return, Sigma, Dturn,
Opaque, InstiOwn, CrossDiff, BlockD, and IOQix. Row (a)+(b) reports p values of the tests on whether the
sum of the coefficients in rows (a) and (b) is different from zero. Standard errors are all heteroscedasticity
robust standard errors clustered by both firm and year. In panel C, we conduct the cross-sectional analysis
in DiD setting arising from the financial institution mergers. The dependent variables are the crash risk
measures, Ncskew and Duvol. Treated is an indicator variable that equals one for treatment firms and zero
for control firms. Post is an indicator variable that equals one for the post-event period (the three years after
mergers), and zero otherwise. High_Cover (High_Opaque) is an indicator variable that equals one if the
number of industry-specialist analysts (opaque information environment) of a firm in the pre-merger period
is above the median, and zero otherwise. Control variables include Size, MTB, Leverage, ROA, Return,
Sigma, Dturn, Opaque, InstiOwn, CrossDiff, BlockD, and IOQix. Standard errors are all heteroscedasticity
robust, clustered by financial institution merger levels. Appendix A presents variable definitions.
Continuous variables are winsorized at the 1% and 99% levels. ∗, ∗∗, and ∗∗∗ represent significance levels
of 10%, 5%, and 1%, respectively.

45

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3746777


TABLE 6
Cross-Sectional evidence: Incentives to internalize externalities

Panel A: Industry homogeneity as a proxy for managerial labor market condition


Dep Var= Ncskew Duvol
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
Com_Dummy (a) -0.009 -0.007
(-0.97) (-1.22)
Com_Dummy × High_Homo (b) -0.024** -0.013*
(-2.22) (-2.02)
LnNumInve(a) -0.033*** -0.020***
(-3.72) (-3.47)
LnNumInve × High_Homo (b) -0.020** -0.010*
(-2.18) (-1.72)
LnNumFirm(a) -0.006 -0.004
(-1.52) (-1.45)
-
LnNumFirm × High_Homo (b) -0.013**
0.008***
(-2.55) (-2.58)
High_Homo 0.004 0.003 0.006 0.000 -0.001 0.002
(0.41) (0.28) (0.49) (0.08) (-0.22) (0.38)

(a)+(b) p=0.00 p=0.00 p=0.00 p=0.00 p=0.00 p=0.00


Controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Firm Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Blockhoder Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Year Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
N 96,119 96,119 96,119 96,119 96,119 96,119
R2 0.132 0.132 0.132 0.087 0.087 0.087

Panel B: Importance of a firm in common owners’ portfolios


Dep Var= Ncskew Duvol
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
Com_Dummy (a) -0.009 -0.007
(-0.98) (-1.23)
Com_Dummy × High_Atten (b) -0.021** -0.013**
(-2.52) (-2.69)
LnNumInve(a) -0.039*** -0.022***
(-4.28) (-4.15)
LnNumInve × High_Atten (b) -0.009 -0.006
(-1.05) (-1.24)
LnNumFirm(a) -0.008** -0.004
(-1.98) (-1.67)
LnNumFirm × High_Atten (b) -0.007* -0.006**
(-1.87) (-2.57)
High_Atten 0.000 -0.009 -0.005 0.000 -0.005 -0.001
(0.00) (-1.05) (-0.71) (0.05) (-1.00) (-0.20)

(a)+(b) p=0.00 p=0.00 p=0.00 p=0.00 p=0.00 p=0.00


Controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Firm Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Blockhoder Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
46

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3746777


Year Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
N 96,119 96,119 96,119 96,119 96,119 96,119
R2 0.132 0.133 0.132 0.087 0.087 0.087
Panel C: Cross-sectional analysis in DiD setting
Dep Var= (1) Ncskew (2) Duvol (3) Ncskew (4) Duvol
Post -0.019 -0.030*** -0.030 -0.031*
(-1.14) (-2.72) (-1.15) (-1.78)
Treated×Post -0.101*** -0.036* -0.013 -0.004
(-2.82) (-1.69) (-0.21) (-0.16)
High_Homo×Post 0.039 0.022
(1.42) (1.24)
Treated×Post×High_Homo -0.076* -0.055*
(-1.98) (-1.85)
High_Atten×Post 0.056 0.023
(1.55) (0.92)
Treated×Post×High_Atten -0.200** -0.088*
(-2.36) (-1.91)
Controls Yes Yes Yes Yes
Firm-Merger FEs Yes Yes Yes Yes
N 7,087 7,087 7,087 7,087
R2 0.070 0.067 0.071 0.067
Notes: This table examines whether the relation between common ownership and crash risk varies with the
incentives to internalize externalities. In panel A, High_Homo is an indicator variable that equals one when
an industry’s homogeneity index is above the sample median in a year, and zero otherwise. In panel B, we
compute the average ratio of a firm’s value to common owners’ portfolio values to measure whether a stock
makes up a larger proportion of common owners’ overall portfolios. High_Atten is set to one if this average
ratio is above the year-industry median, and zero otherwise. The dependent variables are the crash risk
measures, Ncskew and Duvol. The key independent variables are common ownership proxies, Com_Dummy,
LnNumInve, and LnNumFirm. Control variables include Size, MTB, Leverage, ROA, Return, Sigma, Dturn,
Opaque, InstiOwn, CrossDiff, BlockD, and IOQix. Row (a)+(b) reports p values of the tests on whether the
sum of the coefficients in rows (a) and (b) is different from zero. Standard errors are all heteroscedasticity
robust standard errors clustered by both firm and year. In panel C, we conduct the cross-sectional analysis
in DiD setting arising from the financial institution mergers. The dependent variables are the crash risk
measures, Ncskew and Duvol. Treated is an indicator variable that equals one for treatment firms and zero
for control firms. Post is an indicator variable that equals one for the post-event period (the three years after
mergers), and zero otherwise. High_Homo (High_Atten) is an indicator variable that equals one if an
industry’s homogeneity index (the average ratio of a firm’s value to common owners’ portfolio values) in
the pre-merger period is above the median, and zero otherwise. Control variables include Size, MTB,
Leverage, ROA, Return, Sigma, Dturn, Opaque, InstiOwn, CrossDiff, BlockD, and IOQix. Standard errors
are all heteroscedasticity robust, clustered by financial institution merger levels. Appendix A presents
variable definitions. Continuous variables are winsorized at the 1% and 99% levels. ∗, ∗∗, and ∗∗∗ represent
significance levels of 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively.

47

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3746777


TABLE 7
Two-stage mechanism analysis: Accounting conservatism

Panel A: The first-stage analysis


Dep Var= CScore
(1) (2) (3)
Com_Dummy 0.0056**
(2.01)
LnNumInve 0.011***
(4.18)
LnNumFirm 0.004**
(2.06)

Controls Yes Yes Yes


Firm Yes Yes Yes
Blockholder Yes Yes Yes
Year Yes Yes Yes
N 96,119 96,119 96,119
Panel B: The second-stage analysis
Dep Var= Ncskew Duvol
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
� 𝑪𝑪𝑪𝑪𝑪𝑪_𝑫𝑫𝑫𝑫𝑫𝑫𝑫𝑫𝑫𝑫 -3.634**
𝑪𝑪𝑪𝑪𝑪𝑪𝑪𝑪𝑪𝑪𝑪𝑪 -2.419*
(-2.04) (-1.97)
� 𝑳𝑳𝑳𝑳𝑳𝑳𝑳𝑳𝑳𝑳𝑳𝑳𝑳𝑳𝑳𝑳𝑳𝑳
𝑪𝑪𝑪𝑪𝑪𝑪𝑪𝑪𝑪𝑪𝑪𝑪 -3.948*** -2.268***
(-4.45) (-4.02)

𝑪𝑪𝑪𝑪𝑪𝑪𝑪𝑪𝑪𝑪𝑪𝑪 𝑳𝑳𝑳𝑳𝑳𝑳𝑳𝑳𝑳𝑳𝑳𝑳𝑳𝑳𝑳𝑳𝑳𝑳 -2.942** -1.748**
(-2.08) (-2.07)

Controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes


Firm Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Blockholder Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Year Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
N 96,119 96,119 96,119 96,119 96,119 96,119
Notes: This table reports two-stage regression analyses on whether common ownership promotes
accounting conservatism and in turn reduces crash risk. Panel A reports the first-stage regression estimates
for the effect of common ownership on accounting conservatism. The dependent variable is the accounting
conservatism measure, CScore, which is proposed by Khan and Watts (2009). The key independent
variables are common ownership proxies, Com_Dummy, LnNumInve, and LnNumFirm. Control variables
include Size, MTB, Leverage, ROA, Return, Sigma, Dturn, Opaque, InstiOwn, CrossDiff, BlockD, and
IOQix. Panel B reports the second-stage regression estimates for the effect of common ownership-related
accounting conservatism on crash risk. The dependent variables are the crash risk measures, Ncskew and
� , is the predicted CScore based on the first-stage regression,
Duvol. The key independent variables, 𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶
capturing the part of CScore that can be explained by common ownership. Control variables are the same
as those in the first-stage regression. For brevity, we do not report the coefficients of the control variables.
Standard errors are all heteroscedasticity robust, clustered by both firm and year. Appendix A presents
variable definitions. Continuous variables are winsorized at the 1% and 99% levels. ∗, ∗∗, and ∗∗∗ represent
significance levels of 10%, 5%, and 1%, respectively.

48

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3746777


TABLE 8
Two-stage mechanism analysis: Overinvestment
Panel A: The first-stage analysis
Dep Var= OverInv
(1) (2) (3)
Com_Dummy -0.002***
(-2.83)
LnNumInve -0.004***
(-5.59)
LnNumFirm -0.002***
(-3.50)

Controls Yes Yes Yes


Firm Yes Yes Yes
Blockholder Yes Yes Yes
Year Yes Yes Yes
N 68,204 68,204 68,204
Panel B: The second-stage analysis
Dep Var= Ncskew Duvol
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

𝑶𝑶𝑶𝑶𝑶𝑶𝑶𝑶𝑶𝑶𝑶𝑶𝑶𝑶 𝑪𝑪𝑪𝑪𝑪𝑪_𝑫𝑫𝑫𝑫𝑫𝑫𝑫𝑫𝑫𝑫 12.764** 8.181**
(2.01) (2.11)

𝑶𝑶𝑶𝑶𝑶𝑶𝑶𝑶𝑶𝑶𝑶𝑶𝑶𝑶 𝑳𝑳𝑳𝑳𝑳𝑳𝑳𝑳𝑳𝑳𝑳𝑳𝑳𝑳𝑳𝑳𝑳𝑳 13.377*** 7.687***
(4.14) (3.90)

𝑶𝑶𝑶𝑶𝑶𝑶𝑶𝑶𝑶𝑶𝑶𝑶𝑶𝑶 𝑳𝑳𝑳𝑳𝑳𝑳𝑳𝑳𝑳𝑳𝑳𝑳𝑳𝑳𝑳𝑳𝑳𝑳 9.341** 5.578**
(2.54) (2.50)

Controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes


Firm Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Blockholder Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Year Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
N 68,204 68,204 68,204 68,204 68,204 68,204
Notes: This table reports two-stage regression analyses on whether common ownership constrains
overinvestment and in turn reduces crash risk. Panel A reports the first-stage regression estimates for the
effect of common ownership on overinvestment. To measure overinvestment, we follow Biddle et al. (2009)
to estimate an investment model, and then group the observations into quartiles based on the residuals from
the investment model. Firm-year observations in the top quartile (in the middle two quartiles) are classified
as over-investing firms (the benchmark group). The dependent variable of the first-stage regression,
OverInv, equals the residuals of investment model if a firm is classified as over-investing, and zero for the
benchmark group. The key independent variables are common ownership proxies, Com_Dummy,
LnNumInve, and LnNumFirm. Control variables include Size, MTB, Leverage, ROA, Return, Sigma, Dturn,
Opaque, InstiOwn, CrossDiff, BlockD, and IOQix. Panel B reports the second-stage regression estimates
for the effect of common ownership-related overinvestment on crash risk. The dependent variables are the
� , is the predicted OverInv
crash risk measures, Ncskew and Duvol. The key independent variables, 𝑂𝑂𝑂𝑂𝑂𝑂𝑂𝑂𝑂𝑂𝑂𝑂𝑂𝑂
based on the first-stage regression, capturing the part of OverInv that can be explained by common
ownership. Control variables are the same as those in the first-stage regression. For brevity, we do not report
the coefficients of the control variables. Standard errors are all heteroscedasticity robust, clustered by both
firm and year. Appendix A presents variable definitions. Continuous variables are winsorized at the 1% and
99% levels. ∗, ∗∗, and ∗∗∗ represent significance levels of 10%, 5%, and 1%, respectively.

49

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3746777


TABLE 9
How do common owners discipline managers of high crash-risk firms?

Dep Var= Forced


(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
Com_Dummy (a) -0.001 0.000
(-0.27) (0.02)
Com_Dummy×High_Crash (b) 0.014*** 0.010**
(2.91) (1.99)
LnNumInve (a) -0.001 0.002
(-0.25) (0.67)
LnNumInve×High_Crash (b) 0.009* 0.002
(1.84) (0.56)
LnNumFirm (a) 0.001 0.001
(0.25) (0.50)
LnNumFirm×High_Crash (b) 0.006** 0.005*
(2.28) (1.85)
High_Crash=High_Ncskew -0.028** -0.024** -0.027**
(-2.54) (-2.22) (-2.42)
High_Crash=High_Duvol -0.006 -0.002 -0.006
(-0.73) (-0.30) (-0.65)
InstOwn×High_Crash 0.026** 0.024** 0.027** 0.004 0.007 0.004
(2.18) (2.16) (2.31) (0.43) (0.74) (0.46)
(a)+(b) p=0.02 p=0.09 p=0.03 p=0.10 p=0.32 p=0.06
Controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Firm Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Blockholder Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Year Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
N 19,767 19,767 19,767 19,767 19,767 19,767
R2 0.053 0.053 0.054 0.053 0.053 0.053
Notes: This table presents the regressions of forced CEO turnover on the interaction between common
ownership and stock price crash risk. The common ownership proxies are Com_Dummy, LnNumInve, and
LnNumFirm. High_Crash is set to one if a firm’s average crash risk, Ncskew in columns (1)-(3) or Duvol
in columns (4)-(6), over the past three years is above the median value, and zero otherwise. Our variable of
interest is the interaction term between a common ownership proxy and High_Crash. In this table, the
dependent variable is Forced, which equals to one if there is a forced CEO turnover in a given firm-year,
and zero otherwise. Following prior studies (e.g., Campbell et al., 2011), control variables include Size,
MTB, Leverage, ROA, Return, Growth, InstOwn, BlockD, CrossDiff, IOQix, SDReturn, CEO_Age,
CEO_Tenure, and CEO_Ownership. We also control for the interaction term between InstOwn and
High_Crash. Growth is the growth from the prior year to the current year. SDReturn is the standard
deviation of monthly returns of a firm during a given year. CEO_Age and CEO_Tenure are the age and
tenure of a firm’s CEO in a year. Other control variables are defined in Appendix A. Continuous variables
are winsorized at the 1% and 99% levels. For brevity, we do not report the coefficients of the control
variables. Row (a)+(b) reports p values of the tests on whether the sum of the coefficients in rows (a) and
(b) is different from zero. Standard errors are all heteroscedasticity robust and clustered at both firm and
year level. ∗, ∗∗, and ∗∗∗ represent significance levels of 10%, 5%, and 1%, respectively.

50

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3746777

You might also like