You are on page 1of 10

The Terms of Trade and Equilibrium Growth in the World Economy

Author(s): Ronald Findlay


Source: The American Economic Review , Jun., 1980, Vol. 70, No. 3 (Jun., 1980), pp. 291-
299
Published by: American Economic Association

Stable URL: https://www.jstor.org/stable/1805220

REFERENCES
Linked references are available on JSTOR for this article:
https://www.jstor.org/stable/1805220?seq=1&cid=pdf-
reference#references_tab_contents
You may need to log in to JSTOR to access the linked references.

JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide
range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and
facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at
https://about.jstor.org/terms

is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The American Economic
Review

This content downloaded from


115.187.45.112 on Fri, 08 Dec 2023 06:00:10 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
The Terms of Trade and Equilibrium Growth
in the World Economy

By RONALD FINDLAY*

The extensive discussions that have been technology for manufactures is represented
going on in connection with proposals for a by a neoclassical production function with
New International Economic Order have constant returns to scale and with capital
focused attention on the nature of the eco- and labor as the inputs. Capital consists of a
nomic relations between the advanced and stock of manufactures. The size of the labor
less developed regions of the world econ- force is given at any instant and grows over
omy, or the "North" and "South" as it has time at a constant rate. There is also labor-
become customary to refer to them. Ever augmenting technological progress at a fixed
since the work of Raul Prebisch and Hans rate assumed to be going on. Under these
Singer almost three decades ago the move- assumptions, as is well known, the produc-
ment of the terms of trade between these tion function can be expressed in terms of
regions has been regarded as a key index of capital and "effective" labor, which grows
the distribution of the benefits from the over time at a fixed rate equal to the sum of
international division of labor and the de- the rate of natural increase and the rate of
velopment prospects of the South. Although technological progress. A constant fraction
an extensive and controversial literature has of output is saved and invested. Markets are
developed around these issues, there has perfectly competitive and are cleared in-
been a significant lack of rigorous formal stantaneously so that there is always full
analysis to provide a framework within employment of labor and full utilization of
which the diverse arguments and pieces of capacity.
empirical evidence can be sorted out and These assumptions, of course, correspond
assessed. exactly to the Solow neoclassical growth
The objective of this paper is to present a model. The only change is that the portion
highly stylized dynamic model in which the of output in the North which is not saved is
terms of trade emerge as the mechanism spent either on manufactures or on another
linking the growth rates of output in the homogeneous commodity, representing pri-
North and South. The analysis attempts to mary products, with the proportions de-
forge a synthesis of three famous papers, pending upon the relative price of the two
using the neoclassical growth model of goods. Income elasticities of demand for
Robert Solow for the North, the "labor both goods are unity.
surplus" or "dual economy" model of W. Primary products constitute the sole out-
Arthur Lewis for the South, and the Harry put of the South. There is again a neoclassi-
Johnson (Part 2) treatment of the terms of cal production function with capital and
trade to serve as the link between them. labor as the inputs governing the output of
primary products. Capital consists of a stock
I of manufactures, just as in the North. Labor
is in perfectly elastic supply from a "hinter-
Imagine a world economy consisting of land," which is otherwise outside the model,
two regions, the North and the South. The at a fixed real wage in terms of primary
North produces a single composite com- products. There is perfect competition so
modity, manufactures, which can be used labor is hired up to the point at which its
for either consumption or investment. The marginal productivity is equal to the fixed
real wage. Total employment at any instant
*Columbia University. will depend upon the quantity of capital

291

This content downloaded from


115.187.45.112 on Fri, 08 Dec 2023 06:00:10 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
292 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW JUNE 1980

available. The capital-labor ratio is uniquely notation will be used:


determined by the fixed real wage and in q = output per worker of manufac-
turn determines the marginal product of tures in the North
capital and hence the amount of profit per = output per worker of primary pro-
unit of labor. The rate of profit, however, ducts in the South
cannot be determined unless the relative LN, LS= employment in North and South
price of manufactures and primary products YN' YS =total incomes in North and South
is known, since capital consists of a stock of kN, k5= capital-labor ratios in North and
manufactures and profits of a flow of South
primary products. w = fixed wage in the South
It is assumed that a constant fraction of n = fixed growth rate of effective labor
profits are saved and all wages are con- in the North
sumed. Consumption expenditure, whether 9= the terms of trade (manufactures
out of wages or profits, is spent on manufac- per unit of primary products)
tures and primary products with the propor- X=ratio of employment in the South
tions depending upon relative prices. In- to employment in the North
come elasticities of demand for both goods p = rate of profit in the South
are unity. Investment demand is thus purely s = constant fraction of income saved
for manufactures while consumption de- in the North
mand is divided between the two goods. The a= constant fraction of profit saved in
fraction of profits which is saved determines the South
the increase in the stock of capital that IN' IS= total imports in North and South
propels the system forward. m =per capita imports of the North
It is apparent that this depiction of the j=per capita consumption imports of
South corresponds closely to the celebrated the South
Lewis model of economic development with 71N,71=elasticities of m and I with respect
unlimited supplies of labor. The Solow to 9 and 1/9, respectively.
economy of the North and the Lewis econ- Asterisks will denote long-run equilibrium
omy of the South are linked through inter- values of the corresponding variables.
national trade. It is assumed that there is no The constant returns-to-scale production
lending so that trade is always balanced. function for primary products in the South
The demand for imports in each region de- is
pends upon the relative price of the two
(1) = 7(kS)
goods and real income. Johnson obtained a
simple formula for the change in the terms and the profit-maximization condition is
of trade resulting from exogenously given
growth rates of output in the two regions. In (2) 7(ks) - 7'(ks)ks = w
the present model, however, there is a
feedback from the terms of trade to the Under the usual assumptions that i7'(k
growth rate of output in the South. The next > and i7"(ks) < 0, there is a unique k *
section will demonstrate how the terms of satisfies (2). Since capital consists of a stock
trade and the growth rate of the South have of manufactures and output of a flow of
to adjust to the growth rate of the "effec- primary products, the rate of profit in the
tive" labor force in the North that de- South is
termines the steady-state growth of the
whole interdependent dynamic system that (3) p= 07'(ks
constitutes the specification of the world
economy.
while the common growth rate of total
II capital, output, and employment in the
South is
The basic structure of the model will be
presented in this section. The following (4) g= ap

This content downloaded from


115.187.45.112 on Fri, 08 Dec 2023 06:00:10 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
VOL. 70 NO. 3 FINDLA Y: TERMS OF TRADE 293

which is the so-called "Anglo-Italian" equa- where the expression in brackets is the sum
tion. of per capita imports for investment and
A necessary condition for a steady-state consumption, respectively. At any price 1/9
equilibrium in the world economy is that the the demand for capital goods will be
growth rates of North and South should be 9ai7'(ks*)ks* per worker employed, so that
equal. Since the natural growth rate of the investment is always equal to the fraction a
North is the constant n, it follows from (3) of profits in terms of primary products, im-
and (4) that there is a unique value plying that the price elasticity of demand for
capital goods imports is unity. Per capita

(5) O* n import demand for consumption purposes is


L, with t'(1/9)<0 and the elasticity with
respect to per capita consumption w +(1 -
of the terms of trade that is consistent with a)r'(ks*)k.* is equal to unity. Southern em-
balanced growth of the world economy as a ployment Ls is determined by
whole. Notice that 9* depends only on
n,a,w, and the production function for the (10) ks*Ls=Ks
South. It is completely independent of the
production function and propensity to save where the total capital stock at any instant
of the North, and of the demand for imports Ks is given by past history. In the absence
in the two regions. of international capital movements the trade
The terms of trade must also, however, balance must be zero so that
equilibrate the balance of trade. I now turn
to the determination of the terms of trade in (11) SIN= IS
the "short run" by reciprocal supply and
demand for exports and imports in the usual Substituting for IN and IS from (8) and
manner, after which it will be shown how (9) and letting A = LS/LN denote the ratio
the short- and long-run values of the terms of employment in the two regions, (11) can
of trade become reconciled with each other. be solved to obtain
The production function for the North is
A (I ) W+(-'s*)ks*
(6) YN= q(kN)LN
(12) 0=-
where LN depends upon time by the relation m(O, kN) -f X7(k *)ks*

(7) LN =LOent In the short run X and kN are given by


past history so that (12) determines the
and kN at any instant is determined by past value of 9 that equilibrates the trade bal-
history. The import demand function of the ance. On the other hand, if 9 is at its long-
North is run value 9* as determined by (5) then for
each kN there is a value of X such that (12) is
(8) IN= m[ 9, (1 s)q(kN) ] LN satisfied. In particular, if kN is at the
steady-state value kN given by the condition
where it is assumed that m'(0) <0 and that
the elasticity of m with respect to per capita
consumption (1 - s)q(kN) is equal to unity. (13) k* sq(kN)
N n
The import demand function for the South
is then (12) determines the corresponding
unique steady-state value of X as

(9) IS= [a7'(kS*)k* (14)


9*m*(9*, kZ)

I aW + (I - a)T'(ks)k)]LS w ,* ,, Iw (- a) 7'(k *) ks* + nks*

This content downloaded from


115.187.45.112 on Fri, 08 Dec 2023 06:00:10 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
294 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW JUNE 1980

after using (5). It is apparent that X* is equal DkN 0


to the ratio of steady-state per capita im-
ports for the two regions.
The ratio of total incomes in the two DA=O
regions is

(15) Ys 9*r(k*)X*
YN q(kN)

In interpreting (15) it should be noted


that q(kN) is output per unit of "effective
labor." If n includes labor-augmenting tech-
nical progress then the ratio of effective to
actual labor will be continually increasing in
the North. The per capita income of the
actual labor force will be continually rising
in the North while it will be constant in the
South since n is there the rate of growth of * k* N
the actual labor force.
FIGURE 1
III

Having obtained the steady-state solution where D denotes the derivative with respect
of the model, this section examines the to time.
question of convergence towards the steady The properties of this system can be con-
state from arbitrary initial conditions. At veniently seen by means of the phase dia-
any instant LN, KN, and Ks are all given by gram constructed in Figure 1. The DkN=O
past history, and Ls is determined by locus is a vertical line at the value kN ob-
the fixed wage w and the corresponding tained in (13). It is independent of N. The
capital-labor ratio ks*. Dividing KN and Ls condition for DX = 0 is that 9 should be at
by LN, one obtains the normalized variables the value 9* obtained earlier in (5). The
kN and X which are the state variables of the DX=0 locus is therefore one which shows
dynamic system to be studied explicitly in the value of X corresponding to any value of
this section. Capital in the South Ks is not kN
a such that = 9*. The positive slope of
separate state variable since it is always the DX = 0 locus is derived from the relation
strictly proportional to Ls by virtue of the
fixed-wage assumption. Under the assump- d__ ao a9
tions about saving out of profits and wages, (18) dkN * akN ax
the common growth rate of Ks and Ls is
07r'(ks*)(X, kN). The relative rate of change which is obtained by total differentiation of
of X is therefore the difference between this (12) evaluated at 9*, with
rate and the fixed growth rate n of labor
force in the North. The rate of change of(19)
kN
is equal to the difference between per
as ~~~~(I - s) q'(kN) th
a = _
capita saving and the requirements for
maintaining the capital per head of the
growing labor force.
The basic dynamic system can therefore
be formulated as (20)

(16) Dk = q G7'(ks*)-(, kN)k-n]/X __ -XaT'(k 1(-s ["ai(k*)kN*

[m - aT'(ks*)ks I -71s -A _,N)


( 17) DkN = sq(kN) -nkN

This content downloaded from


115.187.45.112 on Fri, 08 Dec 2023 06:00:10 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
VOL. 70 NO. 3 FINDLA Y: TERMS OF TRADE 295

The common denominator of (19) and The "determinant condition" for stability
(20) is the product of two terms, the first of is also fulfilled since
which is the denominator of (12) and is

(24) a2~
ak,V (DX) _ ao
positive. The second is negative if
X a7T'(ks*) ak >0

(21) Om >1
(25) a(DkN)
ax
where s and fN are the elasticities of con-
sumer import demand with respect to the The conditions imply that X falls at any
terms of trade in the two regions. This is point above the D A = 0 locus and rises at
what corresponds to the familiar Marshall- any point below it, while kN increases at any
Lerner stability condition in the present point to the left of the DkN= 0 locus and
model, since the elasticity of demand for decreases at any point to the right. The
investment imports in the South is unity. It motion of X and kN is indicated by the
is apparent that (21) and the Marshall- arrows in each of the quadrants. A possible
Lerner condition are equivalent since (21) trajectory from an arbitrary initial condition
implies that qN plus a weighted average of
is indicated by the dashed curve in Figure 1.
qs and the unit elasticity of investment At im-
the initial point 9 is below 9* so that the
ports with k,u/Om as the weight of qs ex- rate of the South is below n which
growth
ceeds unity. The symbol mh in the numerator means that X falls and 9 increases. When the
of (19) is the partial derivative of m with DX = 0 locus is reached 9 = 9*. The increase
respect to per capita consumption expendi- in kN raises the terms of trade above 9*
ture (1 - s)q(kN) in (8). It follows that which means that A must now start to in-
crease together with kN towards the steady-
ao > 0, ao <> state values A* and kN while 9 approaches
*akN 'ax 9* from above. The terms of trade therefore
overshoot the long-run value 9* but then are
if (21) holds, which establishes the positive pulled towards it. The intersection of the
slope of the D X = 0 locus from (18). The trajectory with the DX=O locus divides the
reason for this slope is clear since an in- approach towards the steady state into two
crease in kN improves the terms of phases,
trade of the first in which the South grows
the South above 9* so that an increase in X more slowly than the North and the terms
is required to restore this value. The inter- of trade continually improve, and the sec-
section of the D X = 0 and DkN= 0 loci de- ond in which the South grows faster than
termines the steady-state value X* of X, the North and the terms of trade converge
already obtained in (14). toward 9* from above.
Examining the dynamic system (16) and
(17) the "trace condition" for stability is IV
seen to be satisfied since
This section investigates the impact and
long-run effects of variations in the parame-

(22) (DX) =* '(ks*) ao <O ters. The initial position will in all cases be
taken as the steady-state point (X*, kN).
First, suppose that there is a shift of de-
mand in the North towards primary prod-
(23)(2)(DNa)
akN = sq'(kN*)-n(<O ucts, so that m is larger for any given 9. The
impact effect on 9 is given by partial dif-
ferentiation of (12) with respect to a shift
at the steady-state point (X*, kN). The condi- parameter which reveals that 9 would in-
tion (23) is the same as the familiar stability crease if the stability condition (21) holds.
condition for the Solow model of a closed This raises the rate of profit in the South
economy. which causes X to increase and 9 to fall. It is

This content downloaded from


115.187.45.112 on Fri, 08 Dec 2023 06:00:10 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
296 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW JUNE 1980

clear from (5) that the long-run value of 9*


is independent of the import demand func-
tion of the North, so that 9 converges back
towards the original 9*, while (14) indicates
\ B
that X* increases in the same proportion as
the increase in m. In terms of Figure 1 the
B~~~~~~~~
effect is to shift the D X = O schedule up-
wards, while leaving the DkN= 0 schedule
unchanged, so that A* rises and kN remains B~~~~~~~~~
constant.
The impact and long-run effects of the
shift in import demand can be conveniently * A*
0-
seen in terms of Figure 2. The BB curve lI B -
shows the combinations of 9 and X that
maintain equilibrium in the trade balance
when the capital-labor ratio of the North is
at its steady-state value kN. The negative
slope follows from the assumption that
the Marshall-Lerner stability condition (21) FIGURE 2
holds. An increase in the propensity to im-
port of the North shifts BB to the right to
B'B', since X has to increase at constant 9 that X must fall if there is to be equilibrium
for (12) to still hold. In the short run X in the balance of trade with everything else
cannot change so it remains at the original held constant. The fact that the D = O
value of A* while 9 increases to the corre- locus shifts down while the DkN= 0 locus
sponding point on B'B'. This raises the rate shifts to the right might appear to render the
of growth of the South so X increases gradu- effect of a rise in s on A* ambiguous. If the
ally while 9 falls and the economy of the North is to the left of the Golden Rule point
South moves down B'B', approaching the where q'(kN) =n, however, a rise in s must
point on it corresponding to the original raise total consumption per capita (1-
terms of trade 9*. The same line of reason- s)q(kN*). It follows from (14) that A* must
ing indicates that a shift in the South's con- increase in the same proportion as steady-
sumption demand towards manufactures state per capita consumption in the North,
eventually leaves 9* unchanged but reduces since the elasticity of demand for primary
X* by a proportion equal to the product of products with respect to consumption ex-
the increase in consumption demand and penditure is unity. It is interesting to note,
the share of imports for consumption to therefore, that A* is maximized, for given
total imports in the South. The effects on values of all other parameters, when the
relative income shares of these shifts in propensity to save in the North is at the
import demands are proportional to the level required by the Golden Rule. The dis-
changes in X*, as (15) indicates. parity in per capita consumption and in-
An increase in the propensity to save of come levels between North and South is of
course widened by the increase in s since
the North raises kN by virtue of (13) so that
the DkN=O schedule is shifted to the right, the levels of these variables in the South are
while (5) shows that 9* is not affected by not affected by s. The ratio of total incomes
this change. An increase in s, for given shown in (15) worsens for the South in spite
values of 9 and kN, must lead by (12) to of a the increase in A*, since the proportion-
reduction in X, so that the DA= 0 schedule ate increase of this variable is equal to
is shifted downwards as a result. This is (1-s)q(kN) which is less than that of
because a rise in s means a shift towards q(kN*) because of the rise in s. An increase in
manufactures and away from primary prod- the North's propensity to save therefore
ucts in the demand pattern of the North, so raises relative employment in the South but

This content downloaded from


115.187.45.112 on Fri, 08 Dec 2023 06:00:10 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
VOL. 70 NO.3 FINDLA Y: TERMS OF TRADE 297

it lowers its relative per capita income. The parameter shifts through their effects on
favorable effect on relative total income of the terms of trade. An increase in the fixed
the South of the improvement in relative real wage iw raises the capital-labor ratio ks*
employment is not sufficient to offset the in the South and so reduces 7'(ks*), the
decline in relative per capita incomes. marginal productivity of capital. This results
Technological change in the North can be by (5) in a rise in 9* proportionately equal
introduced in the form of a once and for all to the fall in ff'(ks*). The South is therefore
Hicks-neutral shift in the production func- able to improve its terms of trade in the
tion q(kN), or in the form of an increase in long run by an exogenous increase in the
the rate of labor-augmenting Harrod-neutral fixed real wage. The price for this, however,
progress that results in an increase in n, the will be a reduction in the relative employ-
growth rate of the effective labor force. ment ratio X*. This can be proved by show-
Taking the case of the Hicks-neutral shift ing that an increase in w must reduce X* if
first, it is evident that the DkN= 0 locus is the terms of trade are held constant, so that
shifted to the right and that kN increases. the improvement in the South's terms of
For given values of 9 and kN (12) implies trade must reduce it even further by virtue
that X must increase if q(kN) rises. Theof the fact that a/a/ <O. The rise in ks*
D X
=0 locus is therefore shifted upward and so induced by the rise in w, combined with
X* increases. The immediate impact of the the fact that the South is to the left of
Hicks-neutral shift in the production func- the Golden Rule since a < 1 means that
tion of the North is for 9 to increase with X* total consumption expenditure w +(1 - a)
and kN at their original steady-state values. 7r'(ks*)ks* and investment nks* both rise on
The initial rise of 0 raises the growth rate of a per capita basis. At constant terms of
the South above n, which causes A to in- trade this means an increase in the demand
crease towards its new steady-state value, for imports for both consumption and in-
while kN also increases because savings in vestment purposes. Exports will however be
the North now exceed the steady-state re- constant, since the North's income is not
quirement. The fact that the South grows affected, so that X* must fall as a result of
faster than the North means that 9 falls the rise in W with 9* held constant. But 9* in
after the initial jump in its level, and it fact rises, so that X* must fall even further
eventually approaches its original level 9* since ax/ao O.
which, as may be seen from (5), is not An increase in a, the propensity to save
affected by the shift in q(kN). It can out be of profits in the South, leads by (5) to a
seen
from (14) and (15) that the shift in q(kN) fallhas
in 9* in the same proportion. The effect
no effect on the relative total incomes of the on X* is obtained by logarithmic differentia-
North and South since X* increases in the tion of (14) with respect to a, using the fact
that the elasticitiy of 9* with respect to a is
same proportion as q(kN) while 9* remains
unchanged. Relative per capita incomes of minus unity. This establishes that
course move in favor of the North.
An increase in n shifts the DkN = 0 locus
(26) a dA 0
to the left and reduces kN. From (5) it is
clear that 9* must rise in the same propor-
tion as n, so that there is a permanent im- depending upon whether
provement in terms of trade of the South.
For any given kN it follows from (12) that a
higher 9* requires a lower X to equilibrate
(27) N+r qs Z_ I +
the trade balance, so that the DX= 0 sched-
ule is shifted downward and A* falls. where f is the additional import of manu-
A change in any of the South's parame- factures for consumption resulting from an
ters does not affect the DkN = 0 locus and so increase in total consumption expenditure
leaves kN unchanged. The welfare of the in terms of primary products w- + (1-a) -
North, however, can be altered by these I'(ks*)ks*. The condition (27) on the sum

This content downloaded from


115.187.45.112 on Fri, 08 Dec 2023 06:00:10 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
298 THE A MERICAN ECONOMIC RE VIEW JUNE 1980

of the elasticities of import demands is more technical progress on X* is obtained by loga-


stringent than the stability condition (21), rithmic differentiation of (14) with respect
since the marginal propensity to import to r, using the fact that the elasticity of 9*
when income in the South is measured in with respect to r is minus unity. This yields
terms of manufactures is A/IO*, the result
which is that
between zero and unity, making (a*-A)
positive. r d/X*
The effect of a rise in a on A* at constant (28) A* dr 0
terms of trade is for it to be reduced, since
all of the increase in saving out of profits is depending on whether
spent on imports while only part of what
was formerly being consumed was spent on 9*m + , [O* -(1- )fj] rks*
imports, requiring X* to fall to equilibrate (29) A qN
the trade balance. The terms of trade wor-
sen, however, which, if (21) holds, leads to a The interpretation of (29) is analogous to
rise in X*. The necessary and sufficient con- that of (27). The impact and long-run effects
dition for the induced increase in X* to on 9 and X can also be shown in terms of
more than offset the fall at constant terms Figure 2 in a manner corresponding exactly
of trade is provided by (27). to the preceding analysis of the increase in
In terms of Figure 2 the increase in a the propensity to save, since the increase in
shifts the BB curve to the left to B "B ". In the South's income at constant terms of
the short run X* remains fixed so 0 falls to trade requires X to be reduced, thus shifting
the corresponding point on B"B". This de- BB to the left.
cline, however, may be smaller or greater The effect of this type of technological
than the long-run decline in 9* which must change is to reduce the relative per capita
be in the same proportion as the increase in income of the South. The reason is that 9*
a. The new steady-state value of X* will be deteriorates in the same proportion as r
at the point on B "B" corresponding to this increases while r(ks*) increases only by the
long-run decline in 0* and the economy of share of profit times this amount. Thus the
the South moves along B"B" in whichever relative total income of the South would
direction is required to get to this point also decline unless the total elasticity of X*
since DX will be positive or negative de- with respect to r, obtained in connection
pending upon whether the impact effect on with (29), were to exceed the share of wages
0 is less or more than the long-run effect. times the proportionate increase in r result-
The effect of the increase in a is to worsen ing from the technological change.
the relative per capita income of the South
since 9* falls while 7(ks*) and q(kN) are V
unchanged. The effect on relative total in-
comes depends in addition upon what "An engine of growth" was the famous
happens to X*. So long as the total elasticity phrase that Dennis Robertson used to de-
of X* with respect to a, obtained earlier in scribe the role of international trade in the
connection with (27), does not exceed unity expansion of the world economy from the
the relative total income of the South must mid-nineteenth century to World War I, a
also decline. process that has continued in the last three
A simple way in which a once and for all decades after the disruptions of the interwar
technological change in the South can be years. In the model that has been presented
introduced is by an increase in the marginal here, trade is indeed an engine of growth for
productivity of capital with the capital-labor the economy of the South, but the power
ratio and the marginal productivity of labor that drives that engine is generated by the
unchanged. This will lower 9* in the same exogenously determined natural growth rate
proportion as the rise in the marginal pro- of the North. The South does not have a
ductivity of capital, as implied by (5). De- given natural growth rate but an endoge-
noting 7r'(k*) by r, the effect of this type of nous one, depending upon the value of the

This content downloaded from


115.187.45.112 on Fri, 08 Dec 2023 06:00:10 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
VOL. 70 NO. 3 FINDLA Y: TERMS OF TRADE 299

terms of trade since this is what determines the context of either constant terms of trade
the rate of profit in the Anglo-Italian equa- or an exogenously shifting demand curve
tion. The steady-state level of the terms of for the exportable primary product. Once
trade must be whatever is necessary to make again, an extension of the analysis to ac-
the endogenous growth rate of the South commodate this feature is quite feasible but
equal to the fixed natural growth rate of the would require too much space to attempt
North. here.
The structural differences in the de- The most basic assumption of all, of
termination of the growth rate of the course, has been that the South enjoys un-
two regions produces asymmetrical con- limited supplies of labor at a fixed real
sequences on the terms of trade of changes wage. This is not intended as a permanent
in technology and the propensity to save. As state of affairs, since if the growth rate of
demonstrated in the previous section, once employment in the "modern" or com-
and for all improvements in the production mercialized sector exceeds the rate of popu-
function of the North and increases in its lation growth, the unlimited supplies of
propensity to save leave the terms of trade labor must become exhausted and growth
unchanged in the long run and increase its will eventually produce a rise in the real
real per capita income. In the South, on the wage. Structural differences between North
other hand, these shifts lead to a pro- and South would then no longer exist and
portionate fall in the long-run terms of trade the neoclassical model would come into its
and a decline in real per capita income own the world over. Hopefully that day will
measured in terms of manufactures. These come, but it has not as yet.
unfavorable effects, however, are compen-
sated by an increase in the relative employ- REFERENCES
ment ratio if the elasticities of import de-
mand are sufficiently high. This asymmetry Ronald Findlay, International Trade and De-
is a prominent feature in the writings of velopment Theory, New York 1973.
Raul Prebisch and Hans Singer. The argu- Harry G. Johnson, International Trade and Eco-
ments put forward for this asymmetry by nomic Growth, Cambridge, Mass. 1967.
these writers, however, usually involve the W. A. Lewis, "Economic Development with
role of monopolies and trade unions in the Unlimited Supplies of Labour," Man-
North and generally have not been very chester Sch. Econ. Soc. Stud., May 1954,
convincing. The present analysis obtains 22, 139-91.
similar conclusions in spite of assuming per- Raul Prebisch, The Economic Development of
fectly competitive markets everywhere. Latin America and its Principal Problems,
In conclusion some of the major limita- New York 1950.
tions of the model may be noted. One of D. H. Robertson, "The Future of Interna-
these is the absence of international capital tional Trade," Econ. J., Mar. 1938, 48,
mobility in response to differences in the 1-14.
rate of profit between North and South. H. W. Singer, "The Distribution of Gains
This can readily be handled but an ade- between Borrowing and Investing Coun-
quate treatment requires a separate paper. tries," Amer. Econ. Rev. Proc., May 1950,
Another is the assumption of complete spe- 40, 473-85.
cialization in both regions. Two-sector open R. M. Solow, "A Contribution to the Theory
dual economics have been studied, for ex- of Economic Growth," Quart. J. Econ.,
ample in my book, Part 2, though only in Feb. 1956, 70, 65-94.

This content downloaded from


115.187.45.112 on Fri, 08 Dec 2023 06:00:10 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms

You might also like