You are on page 1of 3

Consociationalism Colombia, the Lebanon, and Malaysia.

The
concept has also been applied to the political
(Consociational system of the European Union.
Democracy) A consociational democracy is character-
ized by government by grand coalition, a high
RUDY B. ANDEWEG
degree of autonomy for the subcultural seg-
Leiden University, Netherlands
ments, proportionality in the electoral system
and in the distribution of state resources, and
Consociationalism refers to power sharing by minority veto. A more recent and broader
political elites in deeply divided societies as a version, called “consensus democracy,” lists
means to achieve or maintain a stable democ- ten institutional features (also including
racy. The theory is employed both to explain federalism and corporatism) to distinguish
the existence of a stable democracy in soci- power sharing from concentrating power in
eties with deep social cleavages of a religious, the hands of the winning party in a “majori-
linguistic, ethnic, or ideological nature and to tarian democracy” (Lijphart 2012). Although
prescribe elite cooperation as a solution for consociational democracy is also defined
societies where peace and democracy are at by the existence of deep social cleavages,
risk because of subcultural conflict. whereas consensus democracy is not, the two
Although the Latin term consociatio was concepts clearly overlap and most consocia-
already used in 1603 by the German scholar tional democracies also classify as consensus
and statesman Johannes Althusius to denote democracies.
a polity comprising several distinct societies, Reforming the political system to con-
Dutch-born political scientist Arend Lijphart form to such consociational characteristics
is generally recognized as the leading theorist is recommended by consociationalists and
of contemporary consociationalism (Lijphart embraced by international organizations
1977). He used the term to generalize from such as the United Nations and the European
the simultaneous but independent discov- Union as the only viable option for deeply
eries in the late 1960s and early 1970s that divided societies to avoid or resolve sub-
democratic stability in Austria, Belgium, the cultural conflict and to rule the country
Netherlands, and Switzerland was not safe- democratically. There have been several
guarded at the mass level by social cleavages attempts at consociational engineering, for
cross-cutting each other—in fact the social instance the 1995 Dayton Accords in Bosnia
cleavages in these countries to a considerable and Herzegovina, the 1998 Good Friday
extent coincided and reinforced each other. Agreement in Northern Ireland, and the 2003
Instead democratic stability was achieved at Pretoria Protocol in Burundi. Such attempts
the level of the political elites, who shared have reinforced the debate on the favorable
rather than competed for power. The number and unfavorable conditions for consocia-
of countries that are claimed to be or to have tional success (Bogaards 1998; Pappalardo
been consociational democracies gradually 1981). In general, it is more likely that elites
expanded beyond the four classic Euro- will refrain from subcultural competition if
pean cases to include, for example, Canada, they perceive the costs of such competition

The Wiley Blackwell Encyclopedia of Race, Ethnicity, and Nationalism, First Edition.
Edited by John Stone, Rutledge M. Dennis, Polly S. Rizova, Anthony D. Smith, and Xiaoshuo Hou.
© 2016 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Published 2016 by John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.
DOI: 10.1002/9781118663202.wberen517
2 C ON S O CIAT IONA L I SM (C ON S O CIAT IONA L DEMO C R ACY )

as outweighing the benefits. This is the case conflicts may be more difficult to resolve
when no social segment has a majority or through power sharing, but cases such as
when a minority can credibly threaten to South Africa and Burundi show that it is not
harm the majority militarily or economi- impossible.
cally. A consociational solution is also more Consociationalism has also been criticized
likely to succeed when the leaders are rel- for insufficient conceptual clarity (Halpern
atively immune from competition within 1986; Lustick 1997). Recently, attention has
their own subculture through control of the been drawn to the fact that the four main
mass media and subcultural organizations characteristics of consociationalism refer
and patronage networks. The role of third to two very different conceptualizations of
parties (other states or international orga- power sharing. Sharing power by joining in a
nizations) is of crucial importance either in grand coalition involves actual cooperation,
exacerbating subcultural conflict or in facili- whereas sharing power by granting autonomy
tating, or even imposing, power sharing—in to the various subcultural segments involves
which case the result is called “coercive separation rather than cooperation. Lijphart
consociationalism.” also found that the ten institutional features
One of the most fiercely debated ques- of consensus democracy fall across two dif-
tions is the extent to which the nature of ferent and unrelated dimensions: joint power
divisions in society affects the viability of a and divided power. This raises the question
consociational solution. In particular, it has which of these two forms of power sharing
been argued that power sharing may not be has better prospects to produce a stable
able to resolve ethnic conflict (Barry 1975; democracy. Critics have warned that giving
Horowitz 1985). Critics argue that ethnic segmental autonomy to geographically con-
conflicts tend to be more intense and violent centrated subcultures may merely aggravate
than religious or class conflicts: they are the conflict and act as a first step to secession
often less about policy than about national (Nordlinger 1972). Others have pointed out
unity, especially where ethnic groups are that even this recognition of two types of
geographically concentrated. In addition, power sharing is restricted to political institu-
moderate leaders of ethnic groups are more tions and that power sharing arrangements in
easily outflanked by radical rivals: other the media and in the military may be crucial
than in the case of religious or ideological to the success or failure of consociationalism
dogma, ethnic interests are easily recognized in bringing peace or democracy (or both) to
by ordinary group members, and no orga- conflict-ridden countries (Binningsbø 2013).
nization is needed to mobilize the rank and
file. It is perhaps no accident that the African SEE ALSO: Accommodation; Ethnic Politics;
continent, where social divisions are often Lebanon; Netherlands; Pillarization;
Switzerland
of an ethnic nature, has been likened to “a
graveyard of consociational experiments”
REFERENCES
(Lemarchand 2007: 2). On the other hand,
the ascriptive nature of ethnicity renders Barry, Brian. 1975. “Review Article: Political
Accommodation and Consociational Democ-
attempts to “convert” members of opposing
racy.” British Journal of Political Science 5:
social groups pointless, and thus removes a 477–505.
cause of intergroup conflict that may exac- Binningsbø, Helga M. 2013. “Power Sharing, Peace
erbate religious or ideological conflicts. This and Democracy: Any Obvious Relationships?”
does not negate the conclusion that ethnic International Area Studies Review 16: 89–112.
C ON S O CIAT IONA L I SM (C ON S O CIAT IONA L DEMO C R ACY ) 3

Bogaards, Matthijs. 1998. “The Favourable Factors Lustick, Ian S. 1997. “Lijphart, Lakatos, and Conso-
for Consociational Democracy: A Review.” ciationalism.” World Politics 50: 88–117.
European Journal of Political Research 33: Nordlinger, Eric A. 1972. Conflict Regulation in
475–96. Divided Societies. Cambridge, MA: Harvard
Halpern, Sue M. 1986. “The Disorderly Universe Center for International Affairs.
of Consociational Democracy.” West European Pappalardo, Adriano. 1981. “The Conditions
Politics 9: 181–97. for Consociational Democracy: A Logical
Horowitz, Donald L. 1985. Ethnic Groups in Con- and Empirical Critique.” European Journal of
flict. Berkeley: University of California Press. Political Research 9: 365–90.
Lemarchand, René. 2007. “Consociationalism and
Power Sharing in Africa: Rwanda, Burundi and FURTHER READING
the Democratic Republic of the Congo.” African Andeweg, Rudy B. 2000. “Consociational Democ-
Affairs 106: 1–20. racy.” Annual Review of Political Science 3:
Lijphart, Arend. 1977. Democracy in Plural Soci- 509–36.
eties: A Comparative Explanation. New Haven: O’Leary, Brendan. 2005. “Debating Consociational
Yale University Press. Politics: Normative and Explanatory Argu-
Lijphart, Arend. 2012. Patterns of Democracy: Gov- ments.” In From Power Sharing to Democracy,
ernment Forms and Performance in Thirty-Six edited by Sidney J. R. Noel, 3–43. Montreal:
Countries, 2nd ed. New Haven: Yale University McGill University Press.
Press.

You might also like