You are on page 1of 112

Free market

In economics, a free market is an


economic system in which the prices of
goods and services are determined by
supply and demand expressed by sellers
and buyers. Such markets, as modeled,
operate without the intervention of
government or any other external authority.
Proponents of the free market as a
normative ideal contrast it with a regulated
market, in which a government intervenes
in supply and demand by means of various
methods such as taxes or regulations. In
an idealized free market economy, prices
for goods and services are set solely by
the bids and offers of the participants.

Scholars contrast the concept of a free


market with the concept of a coordinated
market in fields of study such as political
economy, new institutional economics,
economic sociology, and political science.
All of these fields emphasize the
importance in currently existing market
systems of rule-making institutions
external to the simple forces of supply and
demand which create space for those
forces to operate to control productive
output and distribution. Although free
markets are commonly associated with
capitalism in contemporary usage and
popular culture, free markets have also
been components in some forms of
market socialism.[1]

Historically, free market has also been


used synonymously with other economic
policies. For instance proponents of
laissez-faire capitalism may refer to it as
free market capitalism because they claim
it achieves the most economic freedom.[2]
In practice, governments usually intervene
to reduce externalities such as greenhouse
gas emissions; although they may use
markets to do so, such as carbon
emission trading.[3]

Economic systems

Capitalism

Capitalism is an economic system based


on the private ownership of the means of
production and their operation for
profit.[4][5][6][7] Central characteristics of
capitalism include capital accumulation,
competitive markets, a price system,
private property and the recognition of
property rights, voluntary exchange, and
wage labor.[8][9] In a capitalist market
economy, decision-making and
investments are determined by every
owner of wealth, property or production
ability in capital and financial markets
whereas prices and the distribution of
goods and services are mainly determined
by competition in goods and services
markets.[10]

Economists, historians, political


economists and sociologists have
adopted different perspectives in their
analyses of capitalism and have
recognized various forms of it in practice.
These include laissez-faire or free-market
capitalism, state capitalism and welfare
capitalism. Different forms of capitalism
feature varying degrees of free markets,
public ownership,[11] obstacles to free
competition and state-sanctioned social
policies. The degree of competition in
markets and the role of intervention and
regulation as well as the scope of state
ownership vary across different models of
capitalism.[12][13] The extent to which
different markets are free and the rules
defining private property are matters of
politics and policy. Most of the existing
capitalist economies are mixed economies
that combine elements of free markets
with state intervention and in some cases
economic planning.[14]

Market economies have existed under


many forms of government and in many
different times, places and cultures.
Modern capitalist societies—marked by a
universalization of money-based social
relations, a consistently large and system-
wide class of workers who must work for
wages (the proletariat) and a capitalist
class which owns the means of production
—developed in Western Europe in a
process that led to the Industrial
Revolution. Capitalist systems with varying
degrees of direct government intervention
have since become dominant in the
Western world and continue to spread.
Capitalism has been shown to be strongly
correlated with economic growth.[15]

Georgism

For classical economists such as Adam


Smith, the term free market refers to a
market free from all forms of economic
privilege, monopolies and artificial
scarcities.[2] They say this implies that
economic rents, which they describe as
profits generated from a lack of perfect
competition, must be reduced or
eliminated as much as possible through
free competition.

Economic theory suggests the returns to


land and other natural resources are
economic rents that cannot be reduced in
such a way because of their perfect
inelastic supply.[16] Some economic
thinkers emphasize the need to share
those rents as an essential requirement for
a well functioning market. It is suggested
this would both eliminate the need for
regular taxes that have a negative effect
on trade (see deadweight loss) as well as
release land and resources that are
speculated upon or monopolised, two
features that improve the competition and
free market mechanisms. Winston
Churchill supported this view by the
following statement: "Land is the mother
of all monopoly".[17] The American
economist and social philosopher Henry
George, the most famous proponent of
this thesis, wanted to accomplish this
through a high land value tax that replaces
all other taxes.[18] Followers of his ideas
are often called Georgists or geoists and
geolibertarians.

Léon Walras, one of the founders of the


neoclassical economics who helped
formulate the general equilibrium theory,
had a very similar view. He argued that free
competition could only be realized under
conditions of state ownership of natural
resources and land. Additionally, income
taxes could be eliminated because the
state would receive income to finance
public services through owning such
resources and enterprises.[19]

Laissez-faire

The laissez-faire principle expresses a


preference for an absence of non-market
pressures on prices and wages such as
those from discriminatory government
taxes, subsidies, tariffs, regulations, or
government-granted monopolies. In The
Pure Theory of Capital, Friedrich Hayek
argued that the goal is the preservation of
the unique information contained in the
price itself.[20]

According to Karl Popper, the idea of the


free market is paradoxical, as it requires
interventions towards the goal of
preventing interventions.[2]

Although laissez-faire has been commonly


associated with capitalism, there is a
similar economic theory associated with
socialism called left-wing or socialist
laissez-faire, also known as free-market
anarchism, free-market anti-capitalism and
free-market socialism to distinguish it
from laissez-faire capitalism.[21][22][23]
Critics of laissez-faire as commonly
understood argue that a truly laissez-faire
system would be anti-capitalist and
socialist.[24][25] American individualist
anarchists such as Benjamin Tucker saw
themselves as economic free-market
socialists and political individualists while
arguing that their "anarchistic socialism" or
"individual anarchism" was "consistent
Manchesterism".[26]
Socialism

Various forms of socialism based on free


markets have existed since the 19th
century. Early notable socialist proponents
of free markets include Pierre-Joseph
Proudhon, Benjamin Tucker and the
Ricardian socialists. These economists
believed that genuinely free markets and
voluntary exchange could not exist within
the exploitative conditions of capitalism.
These proposals ranged from various
forms of worker cooperatives operating in
a free-market economy such as the
mutualist system proposed by Proudhon,
to state-owned enterprises operating in
unregulated and open markets. These
models of socialism are not to be
confused with other forms of market
socialism (e.g. the Lange model) where
publicly owned enterprises are
coordinated by various degrees of
economic planning, or where capital good
prices are determined through marginal
cost pricing.

Advocates of free-market socialism such


as Jaroslav Vanek argue that genuinely
free markets are not possible under
conditions of private ownership of
productive property. Instead, he contends
that the class differences and inequalities
in income and power that result from
private ownership enable the interests of
the dominant class to skew the market to
their favor, either in the form of monopoly
and market power, or by utilizing their
wealth and resources to legislate
government policies that benefit their
specific business interests. Additionally,
Vanek states that workers in a socialist
economy based on cooperative and self-
managed enterprises have stronger
incentives to maximize productivity
because they would receive a share of the
profits (based on the overall performance
of their enterprise) in addition to receiving
their fixed wage or salary. The stronger
incentives to maximize productivity that he
conceives as possible in a socialist
economy based on cooperative and self-
managed enterprises might be
accomplished in a free-market economy if
employee-owned companies were the
norm as envisioned by various thinkers
including Louis O. Kelso and James S.
Albus.[27]

Socialists also assert that free-market


capitalism leads to an excessively skewed
distributions of income and economic
instabilities which in turn leads to social
instability. Corrective measures in the form
of social welfare, re-distributive taxation
and regulatory measures and their
associated administrative costs which are
required create agency costs for society.
These costs would not be required in a
self-managed socialist economy.[28]

Criticism of market socialism comes from


two major directions. Economists Friedrich
Hayek and George Stigler argued that
socialism as a theory is not conducive to
democratic systems[29] and even the most
benevolent state would face serious
implementation problems.[30]

More modern criticism of socialism and


market socialism implies that even in a
democratic system, socialism cannot
reach the desired efficient outcome. This
argument holds that democratic majority
rule becomes detrimental to enterprises
and industries, and that the formation of
interest groups distorts the optimal market
outcome.[31]

Concepts

Economic equilibrium

A diagram showing the "effects of


price freedom"
The general equilibrium theory has
demonstrated that, under certain
theoretical conditions of perfect
competition, the law of supply and
demand influences prices toward an
equilibrium that balances the demands for
the products against the supplies.[32] At
these equilibrium prices, the market
distributes the products to the purchasers
according to each purchaser's preference
or utility for each product and within the
relative limits of each buyer's purchasing
power. This result is described as market
efficiency, or more specifically a Pareto
optimum.
Low barriers to entry

A free market does not directly require the


existence of competition; however, it does
require a framework that freely allows new
market entrants. Hence, competition in a
free market is a consequence of the
conditions of a free market, including that
market participants not be obstructed
from following their profit motive.

Perfect competition and market


failure

An absence of any of the conditions of


perfect competition is considered a
market failure. Regulatory intervention may
provide a substitute force to counter a
market failure, which leads some
economists to believe that some forms of
market regulation may be better than an
unregulated market at providing a free
market.[2]

Spontaneous order

Friedrich Hayek popularized the view that


market economies promote spontaneous
order which results in a better "allocation
of societal resources than any design
could achieve".[33] According to this view,
market economies are characterized by
the formation of complex transactional
networks that produce and distribute
goods and services throughout the
economy. These networks are not
designed, but they nevertheless emerge as
a result of decentralized individual
economic decisions.[34] The idea of
spontaneous order is an elaboration on the
invisible hand proposed by Adam Smith in
The Wealth of Nations. About the
individual, Smith wrote:

By preferring the support of


domestic to that of foreign
industry, he intends only his
own security; and by directing
that industry in such a manner
as its produce may be of the
greatest value, he intends only
his own gain, and he is in this,
as in many other cases, led by an
invisible hand to promote an
end which was no part of his
intention. Nor is it always the
worse for society that it was no
part of it. By pursuing his own
interest, he frequently promotes
that of the society more
effectually than when he really
intends to promote it. I have
never known much good done
by those who affected to trade
for the public good.[35]

Smith pointed out that one does not get


one's dinner by appealing to the brother-
love of the butcher, the farmer or the baker.
Rather, one appeals to their self-interest
and pays them for their labor, arguing:

It is not from the benevolence of


the butcher, the brewer or the
baker, that we expect our
dinner, but from their regard to
their own self-interest. We
address ourselves, not to their
humanity but to their self-love,
and never talk to them of our
own necessities but of their
advantages.[36]

Supporters of this view claim that


spontaneous order is superior to any order
that does not allow individuals to make
their own choices of what to produce,
what to buy, what to sell and at what
prices due to the number and complexity
of the factors involved. They further
believe that any attempt to implement
central planning will result in more
disorder, or a less efficient production and
distribution of goods and services.
Critics such as political economist Karl
Polanyi question whether a spontaneously
ordered market can exist, completely free
of distortions of political policy, claiming
that even the ostensibly freest markets
require a state to exercise coercive power
in some areas, namely to enforce
contracts, govern the formation of labor
unions, spell out the rights and obligations
of corporations, shape who has standing
to bring legal actions and define what
constitutes an unacceptable conflict of
interest.[37]
Supply and demand

Demand for an item (such as a good or


service) refers to the economic market
pressure from people trying to buy it.
Buyers have a maximum price they are
willing to pay for an item, and sellers have
a minimum price at which they are willing
to offer their product. The point at which
the supply and demand curves meet is the
equilibrium price of the good and quantity
demanded. Sellers willing to offer their
goods at a lower price than the equilibrium
price receive the difference as producer
surplus. Buyers willing to pay for goods at
a higher price than the equilibrium price
receive the difference as consumer
surplus.[38]

The model is commonly applied to wages


in the market for labor. The typical roles of
supplier and consumer are reversed. The
suppliers are individuals, who try to sell
(supply) their labor for the highest price.
The consumers are businesses, which try
to buy (demand) the type of labor they
need at the lowest price. As more people
offer their labor in that market, the
equilibrium wage decreases and the
equilibrium level of employment increases
as the supply curve shifts to the right. The
opposite happens if fewer people offer
their wages in the market as the supply
curve shifts to the left.[38]

In a free market, individuals and firms


taking part in these transactions have the
liberty to enter, leave and participate in the
market as they so choose. Prices and
quantities are allowed to adjust according
to economic conditions in order to reach
equilibrium and allocate resources.
However, in many countries around the
world governments seek to intervene in the
free market in order to achieve certain
social or political agendas.[39]
Governments may attempt to create social
equality or equality of outcome by
intervening in the market through actions
such as imposing a minimum wage (price
floor) or erecting price controls (price
ceiling).

Other lesser-known goals are also


pursued, such as in the United States,
where the federal government subsidizes
owners of fertile land to not grow crops in
order to prevent the supply curve from
further shifting to the right and decreasing
the equilibrium price. This is done under
the justification of maintaining farmers'
profits; due to the relative inelasticity of
demand for crops, increased supply would
lower the price but not significantly
increase quantity demanded, thus placing
pressure on farmers to exit the market.[40]
Those interventions are often done in the
name of maintaining basic assumptions of
free markets such as the idea that the
costs of production must be included in
the price of goods. Pollution and depletion
costs are sometimes not included in the
cost of production (a manufacturer that
withdraws water at one location then
discharges it polluted downstream,
avoiding the cost of treating the water),
therefore governments may opt to impose
regulations in an attempt to try to
internalize all of the cost of production
and ultimately include them in the price of
the goods.

Advocates of the free market contend that


government intervention hampers
economic growth by disrupting the
efficient allocation of resources according
to supply and demand while critics of the
free market contend that government
intervention is sometimes necessary to
protect a country's economy from better-
developed and more influential economies,
while providing the stability necessary for
wise long-term investment. Milton
Friedman argued against central planning,
price controls and state-owned
corporations, particularly as practiced in
the Soviet Union and China[41] while Ha-
Joon Chang cites the examples of post-
war Japan and the growth of South Korea's
steel industry as positive examples of
government intervention.[42]

Reception

Criticism

Critics of a laissez-faire free market have


argued that in real world situations it has
proven to be susceptible to the
development of price fixing monopolies.[43]
Such reasoning has led to government
intervention, e.g. the United States
antitrust law. Critics of the free market
also argue that it results in significant
market dominance, inequality of bargaining
power, or information asymmetry, in order
to allow markets to function more freely.

Critics of a free market often argue that


some market failures require government
intervention.[44] Economists Ronald Coase,
Milton Friedman, Ludwig von Mises, and
Friedrich Hayek have responded by arguing
that markets can internalize or adjust to
supposed market failures.[44]
Two prominent Canadian authors argue
that government at times has to intervene
to ensure competition in large and
important industries. Naomi Klein
illustrates this roughly in her work The
Shock Doctrine and John Ralston Saul
more humorously illustrates this through
various examples in The Collapse of
Globalism and the Reinvention of the
World.[45] While its supporters argue that
only a free market can create healthy
competition and therefore more business
and reasonable prices, opponents say that
a free market in its purest form may result
in the opposite. According to Klein and
Ralston, the merging of companies into
giant corporations or the privatization of
government-run industry and national
assets often result in monopolies or
oligopolies requiring government
intervention to force competition and
reasonable prices.[45]

Another form of market failure is


speculation, where transactions are made
to profit from short term fluctuation, rather
from the intrinsic value of the companies
or products. This criticism has been
challenged by historians such as Lawrence
Reed, who argued that monopolies have
historically failed to form even in the
absence of antitrust law.[46] This is
because monopolies are inherently difficult
to maintain as a company that tries to
maintain its monopoly by buying out new
competitors, for instance, is incentivizing
newcomers to enter the market in hope of
a buy-out. Furthermore, according to writer
Walter Lippman and economist Milton
Friedman, historical analysis of the
formation of monopolies reveals that,
contrary to popular belief, these were the
result not of unfettered market forces, but
of legal privileges granted by
government.[47]

American philosopher and author Cornel


West has derisively termed what he
perceives as dogmatic arguments for
laissez-faire economic policies as free-
market fundamentalism. West has
contended that such mentality "trivializes
the concern for public interest" and "makes
money-driven, poll-obsessed elected
officials deferential to corporate goals of
profit – often at the cost of the common
good".[48] American political philosopher
Michael J. Sandel contends that in the last
thirty years the United States has moved
beyond just having a market economy and
has become a market society where
literally everything is for sale, including
aspects of social and civic life such as
education, access to justice and political
influence.[49] The economic historian Karl
Polanyi was highly critical of the idea of
the market-based society in his book The
Great Transformation, stating that any
attempt at its creation would undermine
human society and the common good:[50]
"Ultimately...the control of the economic
system by the market is of overwhelming
consequence to the whole organization of
society; it means no less than the running
of society as an adjunct to the market.
Instead of economy being embedded in
social relations, social relations are
embedded in the economic system."[51]
David McNally of the University of Houston
argues in the Marxist tradition that the
logic of the market inherently produces
inequitable outcomes and leads to
unequal exchanges, arguing that Adam
Smith's moral intent and moral philosophy
espousing equal exchange was
undermined by the practice of the free
market he championed. According to
McNally, the development of the market
economy involved coercion, exploitation
and violence that Smith's moral philosophy
could not countenance. McNally also
criticizes market socialists for believing in
the possibility of fair markets based on
equal exchanges to be achieved by purging
parasitical elements from the market
economy such as private ownership of the
means of production, arguing that market
socialism is an oxymoron when socialism
is defined as an end to wage labour.[52]

See also

Binary economics
Crony capitalism
Economic liberalism
Freedom of choice
Free price system
Grey market
Left-wing market anarchism
Market economy
Neoliberalism
Participatory economics
Quasi-market
Self-managed economy
Transparency (market)

Notes

1. Bockman, Johanna (2011). Markets in the


name of Socialism: The Left-Wing origins
of Neoliberalism. Stanford University
Press. ISBN 978-0804775663.
2. Popper, Karl (1994). The Open Society and
Its Enemies. Routledge Classics. p. 712.
ISBN 978-0415610216.
3. "Finance & Development" (https://www.im
f.org/external/pubs/ft/fandd/basics/exter
nal.htm) . Finance & Development | F&D.
Archived (https://web.archive.org/web/20
220915183424/https://www.imf.org/exter
nal/pubs/ft/fandd/basics/external.htm)
from the original on 2022-09-15. Retrieved
2022-09-15.
4. Zimbalist, Sherman and Brown, Andrew,
Howard J. and Stuart (1988). Comparing
Economic Systems: A Political-Economic
Approach (https://archive.org/details/com
paringeconomi0000zimb_q8i6/page/6) .
Harcourt College Pub. pp. 6–7 (https://arc
hive.org/details/comparingeconomi0000z
imb_q8i6/page/6) . ISBN 978-
0155124035. "Pure capitalism is defined
as a system wherein all of the means of
production (physical capital) are privately
owned and run by the capitalist class for a
profit, while most other people are
workers who work for a salary or wage
(and who do not own the capital or the
product)."
5. Rosser, Mariana V.; Rosser, J Barkley
(2003). Comparative Economics in a
Transforming World Economy. MIT Press.
p. 7. ISBN 978-0262182348. "In capitalist
economies, land and produced means of
production (the capital stock) are owned
by private individuals or groups of private
individuals organized as firms."
6. Chris Jenks. Core Sociological
Dichotomies. "Capitalism, as a mode of
production, is an economic system of
manufacture and exchange which is
geared toward the production and sale of
commodities within a market for profit,
where the manufacture of commodities
consists of the use of the formally free
labor of workers in exchange for a wage to
create commodities in which the
manufacturer extracts surplus value from
the labor of the workers in terms of the
difference between the wages paid to the
worker and the value of the commodity
produced by him/her to generate that
profit." London; Thousand Oaks, CA; New
Delhi. Sage. p. 383.
7. Gilpin, Robert (2018). The Challenge of
Global Capitalism : The World Economy in
the 21st Century. Princeton University
Press. ISBN 978-0691186474.
OCLC 1076397003 (https://www.worldcat.
org/oclc/1076397003) .
8. Heilbroner, Robert L. "Capitalism" (http://w
ww.dictionaryofeconomics.com/article?id
=pde2008_C000053) Archived (https://w
eb.archive.org/web/20171028232506/htt
p://www.dictionaryofeconomics.com/artic
le?id=pde2008_C000053) 28 October
2017 at the Wayback Machine. Steven N.
Durlauf and Lawrence E. Blume, eds. The
New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics.
2nd ed. (Palgrave Macmillan, 2008)
doi:10.1057/9780230226203.0198 (http
s://doi.org/10.1057%2F9780230226203.0
198) .
9. Louis Hyman and Edward E. Baptist
(2014). American Capitalism: A Reader (ht
tp://books.simonandschuster.com/Americ
an-Capitalism/Louis-Hyman/9781476784
311) Archived (https://web.archive.org/w
eb/20150522065957/http://books.simona
ndschuster.com/American-Capitalism/Lo
uis-Hyman/9781476784311) 22 May
2015 at the Wayback Machine. Simon &
Schuster. ISBN 978-1476784311.
10. Gregory, Paul; Stuart, Robert (2013). The
Global Economy and its Economic
Systems. South-Western College Pub.
p. 41. ISBN 978-1285-05535-0.
"Capitalism is characterized by private
ownership of the factors of production.
Decision making is decentralized and
rests with the owners of the factors of
production. Their decision making is
coordinated by the market, which provides
the necessary information. Material
incentives are used to motivate
participants."
11. Gregory and Stuart, Paul and Robert
(2013). The Global Economy and its
Economic Systems. South-Western
College Pub. p. 107. ISBN 978-1285-
05535-0. "Real-world capitalist systems
are mixed, some having higher shares of
public ownership than others. The mix
changes when privatization or
nationalization occurs. Privatization is
when property that had been state-owned
is transferred to private owners.
Nationalization occurs when privately
owned property becomes publicly owned."
12. Macmillan Dictionary of Modern
Economics, 3rd Ed., 1986, p. 54.
13. Bronk, Richard (Summer 2000). "Which
model of capitalism?" (http://oecdobserve
r.org/news/archivestory.php/aid/345/Whi
ch_model_of_capitalism_.html) . OECD
Observer. Vol. 1999, no. 221–22. OECD.
pp. 12–15. Archived (https://web.archive.
org/web/20180406200423/http://oecdob
server.org/news/archivestory.php/aid/34
5/Which_model_of_capitalism_.html)
from the original on 6 April 2018.
Retrieved 6 April 2018.
14. Stilwell, Frank. "Political Economy: the
Contest of Economic Ideas". First Edition.
Oxford University Press. Melbourne,
Australia. 2002.
15. Sy, Wilson N. (18 September 2016).
"Capitalism and Economic Growth Across
the World". Rochester, NY.
doi:10.2139/ssrn.2840425 (https://doi.or
g/10.2139%2Fssrn.2840425) .
S2CID 157423973 (https://api.semanticsc
holar.org/CorpusID:157423973) .
SSRN 2840425 (https://papers.ssrn.com/
sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2840425) .
"For 40 largest countries in the
International Monetary Fund (IMF)
database, it is shown statistically that
capitalism, between 2003 and 2012, is
positively correlated significantly to
economic growth." {{cite journal}}:
Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
16. Adam Smith, The Wealth of Nations Book
V, Chapter 2, Part 2, Article I: Taxes upon
the Rent of Houses.
17. House Of Commons May 4th; King's
Theatre, Edinburgh, July 17
18. Backhaus, "Henry George's Ingenious Tax,"
pp. 453–458.
19. Bockman, Johanna (2011). Markets in the
name of Socialism: The Left-Wing origins
of Neoliberalism. Stanford University
Press. p. 21. ISBN 978-0804775663. "For
Walras, socialism would provide the
necessary institutions for free competition
and social justice. Socialism, in Walras's
view, entailed state ownership of land and
natural resources and the abolition of
income taxes. As owner of land and
natural resources, the state could then
lease these resources to many individuals
and groups which would eliminate
monopolies and thus enable free
competition. The leasing of land and
natural resources would also provide
enough state revenue to make income
taxes unnecessary, allowing a worker to
invest his savings and become 'an owner
or capitalist at the same time that he
remains a worker."
20. Hayek, Friedrich (1941). The Pure Theory
of Capital.
21. Chartier, Gary; Johnson, Charles W.
(2011). Markets Not Capitalism:
Individualist Anarchism Against Bosses,
Inequality, Corporate Power, and Structural
Poverty. Brooklyn, NY:Minor
Compositions/Autonomedia
22. "It introduces an eye-opening approach to
radical social thought, rooted equally in
libertarian socialism and market
anarchism." Chartier, Gary; Johnson,
Charles W. (2011). Markets Not
Capitalism: Individualist Anarchism
Against Bosses, Inequality, Corporate
Power, and Structural Poverty. Brooklyn,
NY: Minor Compositions/Autonomedia. p.
back cover.
23. "But there has always been a market-
oriented strand of libertarian socialism
that emphasizes voluntary cooperation
between producers. And markets, properly
understood, have always been about
cooperation. As a commenter at Reason
magazine's Hit&Run blog, remarking on
Jesse Walker's link to the Kelly article, put
it: "every trade is a cooperative act." In
fact, it's a fairly common observation
among market anarchists that genuinely
free markets have the most legitimate
claim to the label "socialism." "Socialism:
A Perfectly Good Word Rehabilitated" (htt
p://c4ss.org/content/670) Archived (http
s://web.archive.org/web/2016031011171
6/https://c4ss.org/content/670) 2016-
03-10 at the Wayback Machine by Kevin
Carson at website of Center for a
Stateless Society.
24. Nick Manley, "Brief Introduction To Left-
Wing Laissez Faire Economic Theory: Part
One" (http://c4ss.org/content/27009)
Archived (https://web.archive.org/web/20
210818131348/http://c4ss.org/content/2
7009) 2021-08-18 at the Wayback
Machine.
25. Nick Manley, "Brief Introduction To Left-
Wing Laissez Faire Economic Theory: Part
Two" (https://c4ss.org/content/27062)
Archived (https://web.archive.org/web/20
210516192528/https://c4ss.org/content/
27062) 2021-05-16 at the Wayback
Machine.
26. Tucker, Benjamin (1926). Individual
Liberty: Selections from the Writings of
Benjamin R. Tucker. New York: Vanguard
Press. pp. 1–19.
27. "Cooperative Economics: An Interview
with Jaroslav Vanek" (http://www.ru.org/in
dex.php/30-economics/357-cooperative-e
conomics-an-interview-with-jaroslav-vane
k) Archived (https://web.archive.org/we
b/20210817073532/http://www.ru.org/ind
ex.php/30-economics/357-cooperative-ec
onomics-an-interview-with-jaroslav-vane
k) 2021-08-17 at the Wayback Machine.
Interview by Albert Perkins. Retrieved
March 17, 2011.
28. The Political Economy of Socialism, by
Horvat, Branko (1982), pp. 197–198.
29. Hayek, F. (1949-03-01). "The Intellectuals
and Socialism" (https://chicagounbound.u
chicago.edu/uclrev/vol16/iss3/7) .
University of Chicago Law Review. 16 (3):
417–433. doi:10.2307/1597903 (https://d
oi.org/10.2307%2F1597903) . ISSN 0041-
9494 (https://www.worldcat.org/issn/004
1-9494) . JSTOR 1597903 (https://www.js
tor.org/stable/1597903) . Archived (http
s://web.archive.org/web/2022102705263
3/https://chicagounbound.uchicago.edu/u
clrev/vol16/iss3/7/) from the original on
2022-10-27. Retrieved 2022-10-27.
30. Stigler, George J. (1992). "Law or
Economics?" (https://www.jstor.org/stabl
e/725548) . The Journal of Law &
Economics. 35 (2): 455–468.
doi:10.1086/467262 (https://doi.org/10.1
086%2F467262) . ISSN 0022-2186 (http
s://www.worldcat.org/issn/0022-2186) .
JSTOR 725548 (https://www.jstor.org/sta
ble/725548) . S2CID 154114758 (https://a
pi.semanticscholar.org/CorpusID:1541147
58) . Archived (https://web.archive.org/we
b/20221027052632/https://www.jstor.or
g/stable/725548) from the original on
2022-10-27. Retrieved 2022-10-27.
31. Shleifer, Andrei; Vishny, Robert W (1994).
"Politics of Market Socialism" (https://sch
olar.harvard.edu/files/shleifer/files/politic
s_market_socialism.pdf) (PDF). Journal
of Economic Perspectives. 8 (2): 165–
176. doi:10.1257/jep.8.2.165 (https://doi.o
rg/10.1257%2Fjep.8.2.165) .
S2CID 152437398 (https://api.semanticsc
holar.org/CorpusID:152437398) .
Archived (https://web.archive.org/web/20
140202181443/http://scholar.harvard.ed
u/files/shleifer/files/politics_market_socia
lism.pdf) (PDF) from the original on 2014-
02-02.
32. Theory of Value by Gérard Debreu.
33. Hayek cited. Petsoulas, Christina. Hayek's
Liberalism and Its Origins: His Idea of
Spontaneous Order and the Scottish
Enlightenment. Routledge. 2001. p. 2.
34. Jaffe, Klaus (2014). "Agent Based
Simulations Visualize Adam Smith's
Invisible Hand by Solving Friedrich Hayek's
Economic Calculus" (http://www.ssrn.co
m/abstract=2695557) . SSRN Electronic
Journal. arXiv:1509.04264 (https://arxiv.or
g/abs/1509.04264) .
doi:10.2139/ssrn.2695557 (https://doi.or
g/10.2139%2Fssrn.2695557) . ISSN 1556-
5068 (https://www.worldcat.org/issn/155
6-5068) . S2CID 17075259 (https://api.se
manticscholar.org/CorpusID:17075259) .
35. Smith, Adam (1827). The Wealth of
Nations. Book IV. p. 184 (https://books.go
ogle.com/books?id=rpMuAAAAYAAJ&pg=
PA184) Archived (https://web.archive.or
g/web/20230118144732/https://books.g
oogle.com/books?id=rpMuAAAAYAAJ&pg
=PA184) 2023-01-18 at the Wayback
Machine.
36. Smith, Adam (1776). "2". The Wealth of
Nations. Vol. 1. London: W. Strahan and T.
Cadell.
37. Hacker, Jacob S.; Pierson, Paul (2010).
Winner-Take-All Politics: How Washington
Made the Rich Richer – and Turned Its
Back on the Middle Class. Simon &
Schuster. p. 55.
38. Judd, K. L. (1997). "Computational
economics and economic theory:
Substitutes or complements?" (http://ww
w.nber.org/papers/t0208.pdf) (PDF).
Journal of Economic Dynamics and
Control. 21 (6): 907–942.
doi:10.1016/S0165-1889(97)00010-9 (http
s://doi.org/10.1016%2FS0165-1889%289
7%2900010-9) . S2CID 55347101 (https://
api.semanticscholar.org/CorpusID:553471
01) . Archived (https://web.archive.org/we
b/20200520052928/https://www.nber.or
g/papers/t0208.pdf) (PDF) from the
original on 2020-05-20. Retrieved
2019-08-08.
39. "Chapter 20: Reasons for government
intervention in the market" (https://web.ar
chive.org/web/20140522012501/http://w
ps.pearsoned.co.uk/ema_uk_he_sloman_
econbus_3/18/4748/1215583.cw/) .
Archived from the original (http://wps.pear
soned.co.uk/ema_uk_he_sloman_econbus
_3/18/4748/1215583.cw/) on 2014-05-
22. Retrieved 2014-06-06.
40. "Farm Program Pays $1.3 Billion to People
Who Don't Farm" (https://www.washington
post.com/wp-dyn/content/article/2006/0
7/01/AR2006070100962.html) .
Washington Post. 2 July 2006. Archived (h
ttps://web.archive.org/web/20210904195
617/https://www.washingtonpost.com/w
p-dyn/content/article/2006/07/01/AR200
6070100962.html) from the original on 4
September 2021. Retrieved 3 June 2014.
41. "Ip, Greg and Mark Whitehouse, "How
Milton Friedman Changed Economics,
Policy and Markets", Wall Street Journal
Online (November 17, 2006)" (http://www.
columbia.edu/~esp2/WSJ%20Whitehous
e%20Article.pdf) (PDF). Archived (https://
web.archive.org/web/20100625233550/ht
tp://www.columbia.edu/%7Eesp2/WSJ%2
0Whitehouse%20Article.pdf) (PDF) from
the original on 2010-06-25.
42. "Bad Samaritans: The Myth of Free Trade
and the Secret History of Capitalism", Ha-
Joon Chang, Bloomsbury Press, ISBN 978-
1596915985
43. Tarbell, Ida (1904). The History of the
Standard Oil Company (https://archive.or
g/details/cu31924096224799) . McClure,
Phillips and Co.
44. "Free market" (https://www.britannica.co
m/topic/free-market) . Encyclopædia
Britannica. Archived (https://web.archive.o
rg/web/20221020092442/https://www.bri
tannica.com/topic/free-market) from the
original on 2022-10-20. Retrieved
2022-10-15.
45. Saul, John The End of Globalism.
46. "Cliche #41: "Rockefeller’s Standard Oil
Company Proved That We Needed Anti-
Trust Laws to Fight Such Market
Monopolies" (https://fee.org/articles/41-r
ockefellers-standard-oil-company-proved-t
hat-we-needed-anti-trust-laws-to-fight-suc
h-market-monopolies/) Archived (https://
web.archive.org/web/20170216010448/ht
tps://fee.org/articles/41-rockefellers-stan
dard-oil-company-proved-that-we-needed-
anti-trust-laws-to-fight-such-market-mono
polies/) 2017-02-16 at the Wayback
Machine, The Freeman, January 23, 2015.
Retrieved December 20, 2016.
47. "Why We Need To Re-think Friedman's
Ideas About Monopolies" (https://promark
et.org/2021/04/25/milton-friedman-mono
poly-self-interest/) . ProMarket. 2021-04-
25. Archived (https://web.archive.org/we
b/20210927191628/https://promarket.or
g/2021/04/25/milton-friedman-monopoly-
self-interest/) from the original on 2021-
09-27. Retrieved 2021-09-27.
48. "Cornel West: Democracy Matters" (http://
www.theglobalist.com/cornel-west-democ
racy-matters/) Archived (https://web.arch
ive.org/web/20141015220208/http://ww
w.theglobalist.com/cornel-west-democrac
y-matters/) 2014-10-15 at the Wayback
Machine, The Globalist, January 24, 2005.
Retrieved October 9, 2014.
49. Michael J. Sandel (June 2013). Why we
shouldn't trust markets with our civic life
(http://www.ted.com/talks/michael_sande
l_why_we_shouldn_t_trust_markets_with_
our_civic_life) Archived (https://web.archi
ve.org/web/20150521110607/http://www.
ted.com/talks/michael_sandel_why_we_s
houldn_t_trust_markets_with_our_civic_lif
e) 2015-05-21 at the Wayback Machine.
TED. Retrieved January 11, 2015.
50. Henry Farrell (July 18, 2014). The free
market is an impossible utopia (https://w
ww.washingtonpost.com/blogs/monkey-c
age/wp/2014/07/18/the-free-market-is-an
-impossible-utopia/) Archived (https://we
b.archive.org/web/20150915010202/htt
p://www.washingtonpost.com/blogs/mon
key-cage/wp/2014/07/18/the-free-market
-is-an-impossible-utopia/) 2015-09-15 at
the Wayback Machine. The Washington
Post. Retrieved January 11, 2015.
51. Polanyi, Karl (2001-03-28). The Great
Transformation: The Political and
Economic Origins of Our Time (https://boo
ks.google.com/books?id=YfpIs1Z6B2s
C) . Beacon Press. p. 60. ISBN 978-0-
8070-5642-4. Archived (https://web.archiv
e.org/web/20230104145109/https://book
s.google.com/books?id=YfpIs1Z6B2sC&n
ewbks=0&hl=en) from the original on
2023-01-04. Retrieved 2023-01-04.
52. McNally, David (1993). Against the Market:
Political Economy, Market Socialism and
the Marxist Critique. Verso. ISBN 978-
0860916062.

Further reading

Adler, Jonathan H. “Excerpts from ‘About


Free-Market Environmentalism.’” In
Environment and Society: A Reader, edited by
Christopher Schlottmann, Dale Jamieson,
Colin Jerolmack, Anne Rademacher, and
Maria Damon, 259–264. New York University
Press, 2017. doi:10.2307/j.ctt1ht4vw6.38 (htt
ps://doi.org/10.2307%2Fj.ctt1ht4vw6.38) .
Althammer, Jörg. “Economic Efficiency and
Solidarity: The Idea of a Social Market
Economy.” Free Markets with Sustainability
and Solidarity, edited by Martin Schlag and
Juan A. Mercaso, Catholic University of
America Press, 2016, pp. 199–216,
doi:10.2307/j.ctt1d2dp8t.14 (https://doi.org/
10.2307%2Fj.ctt1d2dp8t.14) .
Baradaran, Mehrsa. “The Free Market
Confronts Black Poverty.” The Color of
Money: Black Banks and the Racial Wealth
Gap, Harvard University Press, 2017,
pp. 215–246, JSTOR j.ctv24w649g.10 (http
s://www.jstor.org/stable/j.ctv24w649g.10) .
Barro, R.J. (2003). Nothing is Sacred:
Economic Ideas for the New Millennium (http
s://books.google.com/books?id=TmLyGCJE-r
IC) . The MIT Press. MIT Press. ISBN 978-
0262250511. Archived (https://web.archive.or
g/web/20230118144733/https://books.googl
e.com/books?id=TmLyGCJE-rIC) from the
original on 2023-01-18. Retrieved 2022-03-11.
Basu, K. (2016). Beyond the Invisible Hand:
Groundwork for a New Economics (https://bo
oks.google.com/books?id=n3CYDwAAQBA
J) . Princeton University Press. ISBN 978-
0691173696. LCCN 2010012135 (https://lcc
n.loc.gov/2010012135) . Archived (https://we
b.archive.org/web/20230118144733/https://
books.google.com/books?id=n3CYDwAAQBA
J) from the original on 2023-01-18. Retrieved
2022-03-11.
Baumol, William J. (2014). The Free-Market
Innovation Machine: Analyzing the Growth
Miracle of Capitalism (https://books.google.c
om/books?id=tloXAwAAQBAJ) . Princeton
University Press. ISBN 978-1400851638.
Archived (https://web.archive.org/web/20230
118144734/https://books.google.com/book
s?id=tloXAwAAQBAJ) from the original on
2023-01-18. Retrieved 2022-03-11.
Block, Fred and Somers, Margaret R. (2014).
The Power of Market Fundamentalism: Karl
Polanyi's Critique (http://www.hup.harvard.ed
u/catalog.php?isbn=9780674050716)
Archived (https://web.archive.org/web/2021
0429085412/https://www.hup.harvard.edu/c
atalog.php?isbn=9780674050716) 2021-04-
29 at the Wayback Machine. Harvard
University Press. ISBN 0674050711.
JSTOR j.ctt6wpr3f.7 (https://www.jstor.org/st
able/j.ctt6wpr3f.7) .
Boettke, Peter J. "What Went Wrong with
Economics?", Critical Review Vol. 11, No. 1,
pp. 35, 58 (http://www.the-dissident.com/Boe
ttke_CR.pdf) Archived (https://web.archive.o
rg/web/20071201024600/http://www.the-dis
sident.com/Boettke_CR.pdf) 2007-12-01 at
the Wayback Machine.
Boudreaux, Donald (2008). "Free-Market
Economy" (https://sk.sagepub.com/referenc
e/libertarianism/n114.xml) . In Hamowy,
Ronald (ed.). Archived copy (https://books.go
ogle.com/books?id=yxNgXs3TkJYC) . The
Encyclopedia of Libertarianism. Thousand
Oaks, CA: Sage; Cato Institute. pp. 187–189.
ISBN 978-1412965804. LCCN 2008009151 (h
ttps://lccn.loc.gov/2008009151) .
OCLC 750831024 (https://www.worldcat.org/
oclc/750831024) . Archived (https://web.arch
ive.org/web/20230109234738/https://books.
google.com/books?id=yxNgXs3TkJYC) from
the original on 2023-01-09. Retrieved
2022-03-20.
Burgin, A. (2012). The Great Persuasion:
Reinventing Free Markets since the
Depression (https://books.google.com/book
s?id=BnZ1qKdXojoC) . Harvard University
Press. ISBN 978-0674067431.
LCCN 2012015061 (https://lccn.loc.gov/2012
015061) . Archived (https://web.archive.org/
web/20230118144735/https://books.google.
com/books?id=BnZ1qKdXojoC) from the
original on 2023-01-18. Retrieved 2022-03-11.
Chua, Beng Huat. “Disrupting Free Market:
State Capitalism and Social Distribution.”
Liberalism Disavowed: Communitarianism
and State Capitalism in Singapore, Cornell
University Press, 2017, pp. 98–122,
JSTOR 10.7591/j.ctt1zkjz35.7 (https://www.j
stor.org/stable/10.7591/j.ctt1zkjz35.7) .
Cox, Harvey (2016). The Market as God (htt
p://www.hup.harvard.edu/catalog.php?isbn=
9780674659681) Archived (https://web.arch
ive.org/web/20161111195435/http://www.h
up.harvard.edu/catalog.php?isbn=97806746
59681) 2016-11-11 at the Wayback
Machine. Harvard University Press.
ISBN 978-0674659681.
Cremers, Jan and Ronald Dekker. “Labour
Arbitrage on European Labour Markets: Free
Movement and the Role of Intermediaries.”
Towards a Decent Labour Market for Low
Waged Migrant Workers, edited by Conny
Rijken and Tesseltje de Lange, Amsterdam
University Press, 2018, pp. 109–128,
JSTOR j.ctv6hp34j.7 (https://www.jstor.org/st
able/j.ctv6hp34j.7) .
de La Pradelle, M. and Jacobs, A. and Katz, J.
(2006). Market Day in Provence (https://book
s.google.com/books?id=HHMlUcjfXPIC) .
Fieldwork Encounters And Discoveries, Ed.
Robert Emerson And Jack Katz. University of
Chicago Press. ISBN 978-0226141848.
LCCN 2005014063 (https://lccn.loc.gov/2005
014063) . Archived (https://web.archive.org/
web/20230118144736/https://books.google.
com/books?id=HHMlUcjfXPIC) from the
original on 2023-01-18. Retrieved 2022-03-11.
Eichner, M. (2019). The Free-Market Family:
How the Market Crushed the American
Dream (and How It Can Be Restored) (https://
books.google.com/books?id=9NjBDwAAQBA
J) . Oxford University Press. ISBN 978-
0190055486. Archived (https://web.archive.or
g/web/20230118144740/https://books.googl
e.com/books?id=9NjBDwAAQBAJ) from the
original on 2023-01-18. Retrieved 2022-03-11.
Ferber, M.A. and Nelson, J.A. (2009). Beyond
Economic Man: Feminist Theory and
Economics (https://books.google.com/book
s?id=BFg6lK48EX0C) . University of Chicago
Press. ISBN 978-0226242088. Archived (http
s://web.archive.org/web/20230118144742/ht
tps://books.google.com/books?id=BFg6lK48
EX0C) from the original on 2023-01-18.
Retrieved 2022-03-11.
Fox, M.B. and Glosten, L. and Rauterberg, G.
(2019). The New Stock Market: Law,
Economics, and Policy (https://books.google.
com/books?id=_oFbDwAAQBAJ) . Columbia
University Press. ISBN 978-0231543934.
LCCN 2018037234 (https://lccn.loc.gov/2018
037234) . Archived (https://web.archive.org/
web/20221024235604/https://books.google.
com/books?id=_oFbDwAAQBAJ) from the
original on 2022-10-24. Retrieved 2022-10-24.
Friedman, M. and Friedman, R.D. (1962).
Capitalism and Freedom (https://books.googl
e.com/books?id=CE49HAiRugAC) . Phoenix
Book : business/economics. University of
Chicago Press. ISBN 978-0226264011.
LCCN 62019619 (https://lccn.loc.gov/620196
19) . Archived (https://web.archive.org/web/2
0230118144746/https://books.google.com/b
ooks?id=CE49HAiRugAC) from the original
on 2023-01-18. Retrieved 2022-03-11.
Garrett, G. and Bates, R.H. and Comisso, E.
and Migdal, J. and Lange, P. and Milner, H.
(1998). Partisan Politics in the Global
Economy (https://books.google.com/books?i
d=RoePU0zM7t4C) . Cambridge Studies in
Comparative Politics. Cambridge University
Press. ISBN 978-0521446907.
LCCN 97016731 (https://lccn.loc.gov/970167
31) . Archived (https://web.archive.org/web/2
0230118145248/https://books.google.com/b
ooks?id=RoePU0zM7t4C) from the original
on 2023-01-18. Retrieved 2022-03-11.
Group of Lisbon Staff and Cara, J. (1995).
Limits to Competition (https://books.google.c
om/books?id=2OT8IsbJubsC) . MIT Press.
ISBN 978-0262071642. LCCN 95021461 (htt
ps://lccn.loc.gov/95021461) . Archived (http
s://web.archive.org/web/20230118145247/ht
tps://books.google.com/books?id=2OT8IsbJ
ubsC) from the original on 2023-01-18.
Retrieved 2022-03-11.
Harcourt, Bernard E. (2011). The Illusion of
Free Markets: Punishment and the Myth of
Natural Order (https://books.google.com/boo
ks?id=-nYLSvgP2ekC) . Harvard University
Press. ISBN 978-0674059368. Archived (http
s://web.archive.org/web/20230118145248/ht
tps://books.google.com/books?id=-nYLSvgP2
ekC) from the original on 2023-01-18.
Retrieved 2022-03-11.
Hayek, Friedrich A. (1948). Individualism and
Economic Order. Chicago: University of
Chicago Press. vii, 271, [1].
Helleiner, Eric; Pickel, Andreas (2005).
Economic Nationalism in a Globalizing World
(https://books.google.com/books?id=oCpor-
DkFwwC) . Cornell studies in political
economy. Cornell University Press. ISBN 978-
0801489662. LCCN 2004015590 (https://lcc
n.loc.gov/2004015590) . Archived (https://we
b.archive.org/web/20230118145248/https://
books.google.com/books?id=oCpor-DkFww
C) from the original on 2023-01-18. Retrieved
2022-03-11.
Higgs, Kerryn. “The Rise of Free Market
Fundamentalism.” Collision Course: Endless
Growth on a Finite Planet, The MIT Press,
2014, pp. 79–104, JSTOR j.ctt9qf93v.11 (http
s://www.jstor.org/stable/j.ctt9qf93v.11) .
Holland, Eugene W. “Free-Market
Communism.” Nomad Citizenship: Free-
Market Communism and the Slow-Motion
General Strike, NED-New edition, University of
Minnesota Press, 2011, pp. 99–140,
JSTOR 10.5749/j.ctttsw4g.8 (https://www.jst
or.org/stable/10.5749/j.ctttsw4g.8) .
Hoopes, James. “Corporations as Enemies of
the Free Market.” Corporate Dreams: Big
Business in American Democracy from the
Great Depression to the Great Recession,
Rutgers University Press, 2011, pp. 27–32,
JSTOR j.ctt5hjgkf.8 (https://www.jstor.org/st
able/j.ctt5hjgkf.8) .
Howell, D.R. (2005). Fighting Unemployment:
The Limits of Free Market Orthodoxy (https://
books.google.com/books?id=PHs8DwAAQB
AJ) . Oxford University Press. ISBN 978-
0195165852. LCCN 2004049283 (https://lcc
n.loc.gov/2004049283) . Archived (https://we
b.archive.org/web/20230118145249/https://
books.google.com/books?id=PHs8DwAAQB
AJ) from the original on 2023-01-18.
Retrieved 2022-03-11.
Jónsson, Örn D., and Rögnvaldur J.
Sæmundsson. “Free Market Ideology, Crony
Capitalism, and Social Resilience.” Gambling
Debt: Iceland's Rise and Fall in the Global
Economy, edited by E. Paul Durrenberger and
Gisli Palsson, University Press of Colorado,
2015, pp. 23–32, JSTOR j.ctt169wdcd.8 (http
s://www.jstor.org/stable/j.ctt169wdcd.8) .
Kuhner, T.K. (2014). Capitalism v. Democracy:
Money in Politics and the Free Market
Constitution (https://books.google.com/book
s?id=ljaOAwAAQBAJ) . Stanford University
Press. ISBN 978-0804791588. Archived (http
s://web.archive.org/web/20230118145252/ht
tps://books.google.com/books?id=ljaOAwAA
QBAJ) from the original on 2023-01-18.
Retrieved 2022-03-11.
Kuttner, Robert, "The Man from Red Vienna"
(review of Gareth Dale, Karl Polanyi: A Life on
the Left, Columbia University Press, 381 pp.),
The New York Review of Books, vol. LXIV, no.
20 (21 December 2017), pp. 55–57. "In sum,
Polanyi got some details wrong, but he got
the big picture right. Democracy cannot
survive an excessively free market; and
containing the market is the task of politics.
To ignore that is to court fascism." (Robert
Kuttner, p. 57).
Lowe, A. and Adolph, L. and Pulrang, S. and
Nell, E.J. (1976). The Path of Economic
Growth (https://books.google.com/books?id=
lTUAGqp7PRQC) . Cambridge University
Press. ISBN 978-0521208888.
LCCN 75038186 (https://lccn.loc.gov/750381
86) . Archived (https://web.archive.org/web/2
0230118145253/https://books.google.com/b
ooks?id=lTUAGqp7PRQC) from the original
on 2023-01-18. Retrieved 2022-03-11.
McGowan, T. (2016). Capitalism and Desire:
The Psychic Cost of Free Markets (https://bo
oks.google.com/books?id=MMGlDAAAQBA
J) . Columbia University Press. ISBN 978-
0231542210. LCCN 2016005309 (https://lcc
n.loc.gov/2016005309) . Archived (https://we
b.archive.org/web/20230118145254/https://
books.google.com/books?id=MMGlDAAAQB
AJ) from the original on 2023-01-18.
Retrieved 2022-03-11.
Mittermaier, Karl and Isabella Mittermaier.
“Free-Market Dogmatism and Pragmatism.”
In The Hand Behind the Invisible Hand:
Dogmatic and Pragmatic Views on Free
Markets and the State of Economic Theory,
1st ed., 23–26. Bristol University Press, 2020.
doi:10.2307/j.ctv186grks.10 (https://doi.org/
10.2307%2Fj.ctv186grks.10) .
Newland, Carlos. “Is Support for Capitalism
Declining around the World? A Free-Market
Mentality Index, 1990–2012.” The
Independent Review, vol. 22, no. 4,
Independent Institute, 2018, pp. 569–583,
JSTOR 26591762 (https://www.jstor.org/stab
le/26591762) .
Noriega, Roger F., and Andrés Martínez-
Fernández. "The Free-Market Moment:
Making Grassroots Capitalism Succeed
Where Populism Has Failed". American
Enterprise Institute, 2016,
JSTOR resrep03243 (https://www.jstor.org/st
able/resrep03243) .
Orłowska, Agnieszka. “Toward Mutual
Understanding, Respect, and Trust: On Past
and Present Dog Training in Poland.” Free
Market Dogs: The Human-Canine Bond in
Post-Communist Poland, edited by Michał
Piotr Pręgowski and Justyna Włodarczyk,
Purdue University Press, 2016, pp. 35–60,
doi:10.2307/j.ctt16314wm.7 (https://doi.org/
10.2307%2Fj.ctt16314wm.7) .
Ott, Julia C. “The ‘Free and Open Market’
Responds.” When Wall Street Met Main
Street, Harvard University Press, 2011, pp.
36–54, JSTOR j.ctt2jbtz3.5 (https://www.jsto
r.org/stable/j.ctt2jbtz3.5) .
Palda, Filip (2011) Pareto's Republic and the
New Science of Peace 2011 Home (http://ww
w.paretorepublic.com) Archived (https://web.
archive.org/web/20220127013934/https://w
ww.paretorepublic.com/) 2022-01-27 at the
Wayback Machine chapters online. Published
by Cooper-Wolfling. ISBN 978-0987788009.
Philippon, Thomas. “The Rise in Market
Power.” The Great Reversal: How America
Gave Up on Free Markets, Harvard University
Press, 2019, pp. 45–61,
JSTOR j.ctv24w62m5.7 (https://www.jstor.or
g/stable/j.ctv24w62m5.7) .
Quiggin, John (2019). Economics in Two
Lessons: Why Markets Work So Well, and
Why They Can Fail So Badly (https://books.go
ogle.com/books?id=qjwDEAAAQBAJ) .
Princeton University Press. ISBN 978-
0691217420. Archived (https://web.archive.or
g/web/20230118145256/https://books.googl
e.com/books?id=qjwDEAAAQBAJ) from the
original on 2023-01-18. Retrieved 2022-03-11.
Roberts, Alasdair. “The Market Comes Back.”
The End of Protest: How Free-Market
Capitalism Learned to Control Dissent,
Cornell University Press, 2013, pp. 41–57,
JSTOR 10.7591/j.ctt20d88nv.6 (https://www.j
stor.org/stable/10.7591/j.ctt20d88nv.6) .
Robin, Ron. “Castrophobia and the Free
Market: The Wohlstetters’ Moral Economy.”
The Cold World They Made: The Strategic
Legacy of Roberta and Albert Wohlstetter,
Harvard University Press, 2016, pp. 118–138,
JSTOR j.ctv253f7gh.8 (https://www.jstor.org/
stable/j.ctv253f7gh.8) .
Sandel, Michael J. (2013). What Money Can't
Buy: The Moral Limits of Markets. Farrar,
Straus and Giroux. ISBN 0374533652.
Sim, Stuart. “Neoliberalism, Financial Crisis,
and Profit.” Addicted to Profit: Reclaiming Our
Lives from the Free Market, Edinburgh
University Press, 2012, pp. 70–95,
JSTOR 10.3366/j.ctt1g0b72g.9 (https://www.
jstor.org/stable/10.3366/j.ctt1g0b72g.9) .
Singer, Joseph W. “Why Consumer Protection
Promotes the Free Market.” No Freedom
without Regulation: The Hidden Lesson of
the Subprime Crisis, Yale University Press,
2015, pp. 58–94, JSTOR j.ctt175729r.5 (http
s://www.jstor.org/stable/j.ctt175729r.5) .
Sloman, Peter. “Welfare in a Neoliberal Age:
The Politics of Redistributive Market
Liberalism.” In The Neoliberal Age?: Britain
since the 1970s, edited by Aled Davies, Ben
Jackson, and Florence Sutcliffe-Braithwaite,
75–93. UCL Press, 2021.
JSTOR j.ctv1smjwgq.11 (https://www.jstor.or
g/stable/j.ctv1smjwgq.11) .
Starrett, D.A. and Hahn, F.H. (1988).
Foundations in Public Economics (https://bo
oks.google.com/books?id=R35yljdyyIkC) .
Cambridge Economic Handbooks. Cambridge
University Press. ISBN 978-0521348010.
LCCN 87027892 (https://lccn.loc.gov/870278
92) .
Stiglitz, Joseph. (1994). Whither Socialism?
Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press.
Symons, Michael. “Free The Market! (It's Been
Captured by Capitalism).” Meals Matter: A
Radical Economics Through Gastronomy,
Columbia University Press, 2020, pp. 225–
246, JSTOR 10.7312/symo19602.15 (https://
www.jstor.org/stable/10.7312/symo19602.1
5) .
Sunstein, C.R. (1999). Free Markets and
Social Justice (https://books.google.com/bo
oks?id=Y2cFPSEn4xMC) . Oxford University
Press. ISBN 978-0195356175.
Tanzi, V. (2011). Government versus Markets:
The Changing Economic Role of the State (ht
tps://books.google.com/books?id=0) .
Cambridge University Press. ISBN 978-
1139499736.
Taylor, Lance (2011). Maynard's Revenge: The
Collapse of Free Market Macroeconomics (ht
tps://books.google.com/books?id=ZEE9B2yU
-kYC) . Harvard University Press.
doi:10.2307/j.ctv1m592k8.12 (https://doi.or
g/10.2307%2Fj.ctv1m592k8.12) . ISBN 978-
0674059535.
Tomasi, J. (2013). Free Market Fairness (http
s://books.google.com/books?id=LmmYDwAA
QBAJ) . Princeton University Press.
ISBN 978-0691158143. LCCN 2011037125 (h
ttps://lccn.loc.gov/2011037125) . pp. 226–
266, JSTOR j.ctt7stpz.12 (https://www.jstor.o
rg/stable/j.ctt7stpz.12) .
Turner, A. (2012). Economics After the Crisis:
Objectives and Means (https://books.google.
com/books?id=l6ZbiqFND2IC) . Lionel
Robbins Lectures. MIT Press. ISBN 978-
0262300995.
Verhaeghe, Paul (2014). What About Me? The
Struggle for Identity in a Market-Based
Society. Scribe Publications.
ISBN 1922247375.
Vogel, S.K. (1998). Freer Markets, More
Rules: Regulatory Reform in Advanced
Industrial Countries (https://books.google.co
m/books?id=2uasvzh5paMC) . Cornell
paperbacks. Cornell University Press.
ISBN 978-0801485343. LCCN 96005054 (htt
ps://lccn.loc.gov/96005054) .
Zeitlin, Steve, and Bob Holman. “Free Market
Flavor: Poetry of the Palate.” The Poetry of
Everyday Life: Storytelling and the Art of
Awareness, 1st ed., Cornell University Press,
2016, pp. 127–131,
JSTOR 10.7591/j.ctt1d2dmnj.17 (https://ww
w.jstor.org/stable/10.7591/j.ctt1d2dmnj.17) .

External links

Media related to Free Wikiquote


has
market at Wikimedia
quotations
Commons related to
Free
"Free market" (https://w market.
ww.britannica.com/topi
c/free-market) at Encyclopædia
Britannica
"Free Enterprise: The Economics of
Cooperation" (https://web.archive.org/w
eb/20070113041320/http://www.dallasf
ed.org/educate/free/index.html) looks
at how communication, coordination
and cooperation interact to make free
markets work

Retrieved from
"https://en.wikipedia.org/w/index.php?
title=Free_market&oldid=1196291966"

This page was last edited on 17 January 2024, at


01:31 (UTC). •
Content is available under CC BY-SA 4.0 unless
otherwise noted.

You might also like