You are on page 1of 11

Japan & The World Economy 50 (2019) 25–35

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Japan & The World Economy


journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/jwe

The impact of financial development on the effectiveness of inflation T


targeting in developing economies
Alice Y. Ouyanga, , Ramkishen S. Rajanb

a
China Academy of Public Finance and Public Policy, Central University of Finance and Economics, #39, S. College Rd., Haidian Dist., Beijing, 100081, China
b
Lee Kuan Yew School of Public Policy, National University of Singapore, Singapore

ARTICLE INFO ABSTRACT

JEL classification: An ever-increasing number of developing economies with varied levels of financial development have adopted
E58 Inflation Targeting (IT) frameworks to guide monetary policy. Using a panel dataset of 54 developing economies
F33 over the period 1980 to 2015 (30 of which have IT frameworks), we re-visit the rather controversial issue of
Keywords: whether adoption of an IT framework leads to superior outcomes in terms of reducing inflation and its varia-
Financial development bility. After controlling for potential endogeneity and self-selection concerns of policy adoption, our main em-
Financial markets pirical finding is that IT frameworks appear to reduce inflation rates in developing economies regardless of the
Financial inclusion level of financial development, while it reduces variability of inflation rates only when we control for levels of
Inflation targeting
financial market development. We further find that the effectiveness of IT framework on inflation is highly
Inflation
dependent on financial inclusion and bank characteristics, while the effect on inflation variability is more as-
Inflation variability
sociated with components of capital market development.

1. Introduction under some criticism following the Global Financial Crisis (GFC) and
the ensuing “Great Recession” due to their seeming narrowness and
The global decline in inflation rates along with the “Great inability to adequately deal with concerns about financial risks and
Moderation” of the business cycles since the 1990s till 2007 was at- imbalances and the breakdown in the interest rate policy transmission
tributed partly to the adoption of inflation targeting (IT) framework as a during that period. As Martin Wolf of the Financial Times has forcefully
monetary policy strategy by many advanced economies (Schmidt- noted: “Over almost three decades policymakers and academics became
Hebbel, 2008). Inspired by this, a number of developing economies ever more confident that they had found, in inflation targeting, the holy
followed suit, choosing to adopt a formal inflation target as a nominal grail of fiat…money...Now we see it was a mirage..” (Wolf, 2009).3
anchor and interest rates as the main monetary policy instrument of More specifically, Svennson, (2010a) has noted that “…financial factors
choice as they move towards greater exchange rate flexibility.1 Having may have a very strong and deteriorating effect on the transmission
been pioneered by New Zealand in 1989 and adopted soon after by a mechanism, making standard interest-rate policy much less effec-
few advanced economies such as Canada and United Kingdom, IT fra- tive…A better theoretical, empirical and operations understanding of
meworks have gained widespread popularity among global central the role of financial factors in the transmission mechanism is urgently
banks over the last few decades. According to the IMF (2016), as of required..” (pp.5 and 8).
October 2016, 38 economies had officially adopted IT framework (10 These concerns should ring particularly true in developing econo-
advanced economies and the rest developing economies). Prominent mies where inflation may, at times, be driven by supply side pressures
recent examples of economies jumping onto the IT bandwagon include (such as domestic food inflation) and the interest rate policy trans-
India in early 2015 and Argentina in 2017.2 mission channel may not work effectively even in normal periods
Despite their undoubted popularity, IT frameworks have come (Agenor and DA Silva, 2013; Walsh, 2009). In particular, at a basic

Corresponding author.

E-mail addresses: Alice.Ouyang@gmail.com (A.Y. Ouyang), spprsraj@nus.edu.sg (R.S. Rajan).


1
There are some exceptions. For instance, Singapore essentially operates an IT regime but uses the trade-weighted exchange rate as the policy instrument (Cavoli
and Rajan, 2007; McCallum, 2007; Parrado, 2004).
2
This excludes Argentina which was still listed as having taken preliminary steps to adopt an IT regime as of October 2016.
3
Some have also argued that strict adherence to an IT framework led to a build-up of financial imbalances that eventually caused the GFC in the first instance
(Wolf, 2009).

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.japwor.2019.03.003
Received 27 February 2019; Received in revised form 19 March 2019; Accepted 19 March 2019
Available online 08 April 2019
0922-1425/ © 2019 Published by Elsevier B.V.
A.Y. Ouyang and R.S. Rajan Japan & The World Economy 50 (2019) 25–35

level, the interest rate policy transmission channel works in two stages. stated earlier, for the interest rate channel to work we need a reason-
The first stage of interest rate pass-through (IRPT) refers to changes in ably well-developed government bond markets so that policy rates can
the policy rates to interbank rates to market rates.4 For this stage to pass-through to other short-term paper rates and longer-term bond
work well it is important that: (a) there needs to be a degree of domestic yields. However, greater access to stock and bond markets may also
bank competition (along with interest rate deregulation) so that suggest a higher degree of asset substitutability between loans and se-
changes in policy rates transmit to interbank rates and retail bank curities, indicating a weak interest rate transmission channel through
lending and deposit rates; and (b) there must exist a reasonably well- banks. Therefore, the effects of financial markets components on in-
developed government bond markets such that policy rates impact flation of IT frameworks remain unclear.
other short-term paper rates and longer-term bond yields, thus influ- While one would expect a priori that IT frameworks in more fi-
encing aggregate demand and inflation (see Gopalan and Rajan, 2017).5 nancially developed economies to be successful in managing inflation,
Even if these preconditions – i.e. degree of financial market devel- their impact on inflation variability is ambiguous. On the one hand,
opment – exist for the first stage of interest pass-through to work, in- greater levels of financial sector development allow the central bank to
terest rates may not be an effective policy instrument if a large segment use interest rates more effectively to manage the inflation rate and its
of the population does not have access to the formal financial system variability. In addition, if financial development involves enhanced
and is not impacted directly by bank interest rate changes (Mehrotra access to finance and financial inclusion, this will allow for greater
and Yetman, 2015). Thus, for the second stage of IRPT to operate ef- consumption-smoothing so the central bank can focus more on inflation
fectively it is important that there be a fairly high degree of domestic as opposed to output stabilization, thus facilitating lower and more
financial inclusion. stable inflation rates (Mehrotra and Yetman, 2015).6 On the other hand,
In addition, the interest rate transmission channel can be influenced an IT targeting central bank may be less inclined to manage exchange
by bank characteristics (Kashyap and Stein, 2000; Gambacorta, 2005; rate variability as agents can hedge against such risks, which in turn
Ashcraft, 2006; Brissimis et al., 2014). The related literature has found may impart higher domestic price variability. In addition, greater fi-
that the interest rate channel tends to be weak for banks with higher nancial inclusion could allow agents to hedge against inflation shocks,
liquidity, capitalization and profitability. As Brissimis et al. (2014) thus granting central banks more leeway to operate wider inflation
argue, banks with greater market power tend to have higher profit- target bands to deal with other objectives such as output and financial
ability and easier access to alternative sources of finance. Hence they stability.7
are less reliant on central bank funding and less sensitive to changes in The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. The next section
the marginal cost of loan production when monetary policy changes, as offers a brief review of the literature. Section 2 summarizes the data
is true for foreign banks that can obtain funding from parent company sources and definitions. Section 3 outlines the model and estimation
via cross-border internal funds transfer (Gopalan and Rajan, 2017). The strategy. Section 4 discusses the results. Section 5 concludes the paper.
interest rate channel can also be enhanced by the imperfect substitut-
ability between loans and securities in bank portfolios and the bor-
2. Impact of IT frameworks on inflation: literature review
rowing for firms (Bernanke and Blinder, 1988). Higher degree of asset
substitutability weakens the channels of monetary policy transmission
Early papers by Bernanke et al. (1999) and Mishkin (1999) sug-
through banks.
gested that IT frameworks should reduce inflation rates and macro-
The effects of IT frameworks on inflation and inflation variability
economic variability while enhancing overall policy credibility. Since
conditioned on financial development are therefore the particular focus
then there has been a burgeoning literature that appears to confirm
of this paper using a panel of 54 developing economies over the period
these early insights, at least with regard to the actual rate of inflation
1980 to 2015, 30 of which have adopted an IT framework. Specifically,
(for instance, see Ball and Sheridan, 2005; Batini and Laxton, 2007;
the paper re-examines whether the adoption of an IT framework leads
Calderon and Schmidt-Hebbel, 2010; Goncalves and Salles, 2008;
to attainment of superior macroeconomic outcomes in terms of redu-
Mishkin and Schimdt-Hebbel, 2007; Vega and Winkelreid, 2005).8
cing the rate of inflation as well as its variability after accounting for
However, a problem with much of the earlier empirical works is that
the possibility that a country’s choice of IT regime may be non-random,
they did not adequately deal with the self-selection problems of policy
as well as accounting for the so-called dynamic bias problem a la Brito
adoption, i.e. did economies with better macroeconomic outcomes
and Bystedt (2010). Unlike the existing IT literature, we explicitly take
choose to adopt IT regimes?
into account the role of financial development.
Brito and Bystedt (2010) control for the endogeneity of the IT fra-
We use a new broad-based index of financial development devel-
mework and estimate a dynamic panel estimator (to control for
oped by Svirydzenka (2016) as well as its six components that sum-
common time-varying effects and country fixed effects) for a sample of
marize how developed financial institutions and financial markets are
46 developing economies over the period 1980 and 2006 (13 of which
in terms of their depth, access, and efficiency. While financial markets
had adopted IT frameworks). Their main empirical finding is that there
mainly refer to capital markets (equities and bonds), financial institu-
is “no significant evidence to conclude that IT framework has met its
tions include banks, insurance companies, mutual funds, and pension
main goal of stabilizing inflation and output growth in developing
funds. With regard to the financial institutions components, we expect
economies.” (p.209) They opine that while there has been lower
to find that IT frameworks tend to be more effective if individuals/firms
in an economy have better access to formal financial institutions (i.e.
higher financial institutions access) and more transactions associated 6
Consistent with this, Mehrotra and Yetman (2015) find that the variability
with the formal financial institutions (i.e. higher financial institutions of output relative to inflation is greater with higher levels of financial inclusion,
depth). With regard to financial markets components, their effects on IT suggestive that as households and firms are able to use the financial system to
frameworks effectiveness can be mixed since financial markets include smooth consumption, central banks place more weight on stabilizing inflation
both stock and bond markets in Svirydzenka (2016)’s definition. As volatility relative to stabilizing output volatility.
7
Another possible channel is that the adoption of IT frameworks could lower
sovereign risk (Balima et al., 2017 and Thornton and Vasilakis, 2016) leading to
greater capital flows which in turn could generate greater exchange rate
4
This stage is sometimes divided into sub-stages, viz. from policy rates to variability.
8
interbank rates and interbank rates to market rates (see Gopalan and Rajan, See Svensson (2010b) for a comprehensive review of the earlier literature on
2017). the impact of IT frameworks. Arestis et al. (2014) finds that inflation rates
5
See Ingves (2004) for a discussion of the nexus between monetary policy converge regardless of the monetary policy framework, suggesting that the
and financial market development. reduction of the inflation rates may not be due to the inflation targets per se.

26
A.Y. Ouyang and R.S. Rajan Japan & The World Economy 50 (2019) 25–35

inflation in developing economies which have adopted IT frameworks, 3. Empirical model


this was more due to “window-dressing”, i.e. the countries had lower
inflation rates as they made a conscious decision to do so. Adoption of 3.1. Model specification
an IT framework per se seemed to play no independent role in reducing
inflation rates and was possibly detrimental to output growth. Following Brito and Bystedt (2010) and Alpanda and Honig,
Applying a similar methodology over the same time period but for a 2014we apply a dynamic panel estimator to examine the impact of IT
sample of 66 economies (22 advanced and 44 developing economies, 23 frameworks on inflation rates and variability for a panel of 54 devel-
of which had adopted IT) over the period 1980–2006, Alpanda and oping economies over the period 1980 and 2015. The primary focus of
Honig (2014) find that IT frameworks do not have any significant im- our analysis is on the effects of IT frameworks on inflation rates and
pact on inflation rates in advanced economies and have only small ef- volatility. As with Brito and Bystedt (2010) we take a three-year
fects in developing economies. Further dividing the developing average of the data (not overlapping), resulting in a sample with 12
economies sample into those with low versus high central bank in- periods. Using three-year average of the data has three possible ad-
dependence, the authors find large effects in developing economies vantages as highlighted by Brito and Bystedt (2010, p.199): (1) it can
with low central bank independence. They suggest that the adoption of avoid instrumented variables over-fitting problem in GMM estimation;
IT frameworks in developing economies with low central bank in- (2) it reflects the sluggish responses of macro variables; (3) it can se-
dependence has helped to discipline fiscal policy, hence leading to parate the IT treatment effects from other similar events.
lower inflation rates. We start with a parsimonious model to see if inflation targeting
Even if IT frameworks are successful in managing inflation, their leads to superior macroeconomic outcomes.11
impact on inflation variability remains ambiguous and somewhat
under-studied. The pioneering paper by Ball and Sheridan (2005) find
yi, t = 1 yi, t 1 + 2 ITi, t + 3 Highinfli, t + t + i + r + i, t (1)
that IT framework has no impact either on the level of inflation or its where yi, t is a macroeconomic variable of interest (i.e. inflation and
variability, and any improvements in these variables for the advanced inflation variability in our case) at period t for economy i. To prevent
economies that had adopted IT frameworks was due to mean reversion the empirical results from being biased by high inflation outliers we
as they started with greater and more volatile inflation. In subsequent follow Brito and Bystedt (2010) and transform the inflation to natural
work, Goncalves and Salles (2008) overturned this result using a panel logarithm of inflation based on the formula of yi, t = 100 × ln (1 + 100
Yi, t
).
of 36 developing economies, 13 of which had adopted IT frameworks Following the literature, we also include a high inflation dummy,
between 1980 and 2015. They argue that the lower inflation rates and Highinfli, t as a further control. It equals one if average inflation (in
variability that developing economies with IT frameworks attained was natural logarithm) over a three-year period is greater than 40 percent
due to the regime itself and not because of mean reversion. There have and zero otherwise.12 The lagged value of yi, t is added to account for
been further rejoinders to this debate (see Ball, 2010 and Thornton, mean reversion dynamics that often occur in macroeconomic variables
2016). when they deviate significantly from the long-term trend. ITi, t is an
The study by Brito and Bystedt (2010) noted above did not find any indicator to measure the period that the inflation targeting regime was
obvious reduction in inflation volatility among countries that adopted in place. ITi, t equals one if an IT regime was in place in all three years of
IT frameworks. Lin and Ye (2009) use a propensity score matching the period; two-thirds if an IT regime was in place for only two years of
(PSM) methodology to account for the likelihood that a country’s de- a 3-year period, and so on. Finally, both time effects ( t ) and country
cision to adopt an IT framework may be non-random. In their sample of fixed effects ( i ) are considered in the equation, as are regional dum-
52 developing economies for the period 1985–2005 (13 of which had mies ( r ). i, t is the disturbance.
adopted IT), they find that IT frameworks seem to have large and sig- We then add an array of financial factors relating to financial de-
nificant effects in lowering the rate of inflation and its variability. In a velopment, access and competition to understand the impact of fi-
related earlier study using the same methodology, Lin and Ye (2007) nancial factors on IT effectiveness in managing inflation. The model
examine the impact of IT frameworks on 22 advanced economies (7 of specification is as below:
which adopted IT) over the period 1985–1999 and find they have no
impact on the inflation rate or variability in advanced economies. de yi, t = 1 yi, t 1 + 2 ITi, t + 3 Financei, t + 4 (ITi, t × Financei, t )
Mendonca and de Guimaraes e Souza (2010) also use a PSM metho- + 5 Highinfli, t + t + i + r + i, t (2)
dology on a sample of 180 economies for the period 1990–2007 (29 of
which had adopted IT). Consistent with Lin and Ye (2007) and (2009) Financei, t is a proxy for financial development that may influence the
they find the adoption of IT frameworks appears to reduce inflation impact of IT regime on macroeconomic variables performance. The fi-
rates in developing economies but not in advanced ones.9 nancial factors include not only the index to proxy the overall level of
To our knowledge, the literature to date on the effectiveness of IT financial development but also its components that measure the access,
frameworks on inflation has not incorporated the impact of financial the depth, and the efficiency of financial institutions and financial
development indicators, a gap we aim to fill.10 markets. We further include the interaction term of IT and various fi-
nancial variables, allowing the effectiveness of IT regime to depend on
the level of financial development. The detailed definitions and data
9
There is a related literature using the PSM methodology on the impact of IT sources for all the macroeconomic and financial variables used in the
frameworks on exchange rate variability are Lin (2010) and Ouyang et al. paper are listed in Table 1.
(2016). The former looks at a pooled sample of 23 economies that adopted IT We estimate the model using a two-step System GMM approach
regimes by the end of 2004 and finds strong and robust evidence that IT reduces developed by Arellano and Bover (1995) and Blundell and Bond (1998).
exchange rate variability in developing economies but raises them in industrial
economies. In contrast, Ouyang et al. (2016) use a panel of 62 economies over
the period 2006-2012 and finds that IT regimes seem to have greater real ex- (footnote continued)
change rate variability than other regimes particularly among advanced independence variable (Alpanda and Honig, 2014).
11
economies. Berganza and Broto (2012) find that emerging economies with IT Incorporation of other macro variables such as fiscal balance, public debt,
frameworks experience more nominal exchange rate volatility than non-IT trade/financial openness does not add anything to the results and are therefore
countries, though foreign exchange intervention can help in lowering volatility. excluded for parsimony.
12
For a discussion on using flexible IT and sterilized foreign exchange interven- This threshold has been used in many past literatures. See Alpanda and
tion, see Ghosh et al. (2016). Honig (2014); Lin and Ye (2009) and de Mendonca and de Guimaraes e Souza
10
The closest the literature has come has been to incorporate central bank (2010). Results are robust if the threshold is altered to 30 percent.

27
A.Y. Ouyang and R.S. Rajan Japan & The World Economy 50 (2019) 25–35

Table 1
Variable Definition.
Macro. Variable Definition Source

linfl _cpii, t linfl_cpi = 100*ln(1+infl_cpi/100) WDI


vlinfl _cpii, t Inflation volatility of linfl_cpi (3-year standard deviation)
cvlinfl _cpii, t Coefficients of variation of linfl_cpi (3-year standard deviation divided by 3-year mean)
Financial Variables Definition Source
FD Financial development index (constructed by financial institutions index and financial markets index), 0-1 IMF
FID Financial institutions depth (private-sector credit to GDP + pension fund assets to GDP + mutual fund assets to GDP + Insurance premiums, life IMF
and non-life to GDP), 0-1
FIA Financial institutions access (bank branches per 100,000 adults + ATMs per 100,000 adults), 0-1 IMF
FIE Financial institutions efficiency (net interest margin + lending-deposits spread + non-interest income to total income + overhead costs to total IMF
assets + return on assets + return on equity), 0-1
FMD Financial markets depth (stock market capitalization to GDP + stocks traded to GDP + international debt securities of government to GDP + total IMF
debt securities of financial corporations to GDP + total debt securities of nonfinancial corporations to GDP), 0-1
FMA Financial markets access (percent of market capitalization outside of top 10 largest companies + total number of issuers of debt (domestic and IMF
external, nonfinancial and financial corporations), 0-1
FME Financial markets efficiency (stock market turnover ratio, stocks traded to capitalization), 0-1 IMF

Due to self-selection concerns of policy adoption – i.e. are economies more developed are financial institutions/markets. The summary
with high or low inflation more likely to choose IT regimes – we treat IT statistics of inflation, inflation variability and various financial fac-
adoption as predetermined (S-GMM P) in that it is affected by past tors in different monetary regimes (IT regime versus non-IT regime)
inflation only. As a robustness check we also re-estimate the equation can be found in Table 3.14
by treating IT adoption as endogenous (S-GMM E) in that current in- With regard to inflation, the data suggests that the IT regimes tend
flation may have an influence along with past inflation, or there are to have much lower average inflation rates and volatilities (as measured
omitted variables that influence both inflation and the decision to by standard deviation) compared to the non-IT regimes.15 With regard
choose an IT framework. To avoid the overfitting problem we not only to financial factors, the summary statistics show that the economies
use three-year average of the data, but also reduce the dimensionality of operating IT regimes tend to have more well-developed financial mar-
the instrument matrix by collapsing its columns to fit the “small-T, kets and institutions than their non-IT regime counterparts since the
large-N” panel requirement. We also use the AR(1) and AR(2) tests, average values of financial factors are all higher in IT regimes. This
Hansen J test, and difference-in-Hansen C test to verify whether the conclusion is even more robust in terms of the median value.16
error terms are serially correlated, the instruments are valid, and the
changes in instruments are uncorrelated with the fixed effect, respec- 4.2. Baseline results
tively.
Table 4 presents the estimates of Eq. (1) and summarizes the results
4. Data and methodology on inflation and inflation variability while IT adoption is treated as
predetermined. Focussing on the inflation rate, we see that adoption of
4.1. Data and summary statistics an IT framework lowers the inflation rate and these results are statis-
tically and economically significant. The finding is suggestive of the
There are 30 developing IT economies in our sample, including all possibility that an IT framework acts more as a credible nominal anchor
the 31 developing IT economies as noted in IMF (2016) (except Ka- for inflationary expectations in developing economies and helps depo-
zakhstan since it adopted an to IT regime by late 2015). The sample liticise monetary policies.17 In the case of inflation variability, IT seems
economies and the year of adoption of IT are all listed in Table 2. Most to have a negative though statistically insignificant impact for the de-
developing IT economies are from Europe (11 economies), Latin veloping economies when inflation variability is measured by either
America (9 economies) and Asia (5 economies). Since there are dis- standard deviation or coefficient of variation.18 So overall there is clear
agreements about when an IT regime began, we adopt “the conservative evidence that the adoption of an IT framework has a strongly negative
starting year” of IT regime constructed by de Mendonca and de impact on the inflation rate in developing economies, while its impact
Guimaraes e Souza (2010). More to the point, since the identification of of on inflation variability is less obvious.
starting dates of IT adoption may be ambiguous at times, de Mendonca
and de Guimaraes e Souza (2010) construct two possible starting dates 4.3. Impact of financial development
based on past literatures. While the initial classification of starting dates
of IT regimes refers to the period of soft IT (i.e. the country announces While our finding that the adoption of IT framework lowers
an inflation target but the IT regime is not full-fledged yet), con-
servative classification of starting dates refers to complete adoption of 14
The Financial development index database is accessible here: http://data.
IT. The starting year of new IT economies after 2010 is based on Miller,
imf.org/?sk=F8032E80-B36C-43B1-AC26-493C5B1CD33B
et al (2012) and Schmidt-Hebbel and Carrasco (2016).13 15
However, the results are not all that robust if the coefficient of variation is
For the measure of financial development we use a new broad- used to proxy inflation volatility.
based index of financial development developed by Svirydzenka 16
The standard deviation of financial factors between IT and non-IT regimes
(2016) as well as six indices on annual frequency between 1980 and are quite similar.
2013 that summarize how developed financial institutions and fi- 17
While not shown here, there is no impact of IT frameworks on economic
nancial markets are in terms of their depth, access, and efficiency. All growth in developing economies.
18
the indices are normalized between 0 and 1. The higher the value the The results of AR(1) and AR(2) tests suggest that there is no second-order
autocorrelation of the residuals in any of the models. All the models fail to
reject the Hansen J test and difference in Hansen C test, verifying the overall
13
Their initial and conservative starting dates of IT regimes are the same. validity of the instruments.

28
A.Y. Ouyang and R.S. Rajan Japan & The World Economy 50 (2019) 25–35

Table 2
Sample Developing Economies and Dates of IT adoption.
IT Economies (30) — Initial and Conservative Classifications of Starting Year

Initial Conservative Initial Conservative

Albania 2009 2009 Mexico 1995 2001


Armenia 2006 2006 Moldova 2010 2010
Brazil 1999 1999 Paraguay 2013 2013
Chile 1991 2000 Peru 1994 2002
Colombia 2000 2000 Philippines 2002 2002
Czech Rep. 1998 1998 Poland 1999 1999
Dominican Rep. 2012 2012 Romania 2005 2006
Georgia 2009 2009 Russia 2014 2014
Ghana 2003 2007 Serbia 2006 2006
Guatemala 2005 2006 Slovak Rep.a 2005 2005
Hungary 2001 2001 South Africa 2000 2000
India 2015 2015 Thailand 2000 2000
Indonesia 2005 2006 Turkey 2002 2006
Israel 1992 1997 Uganda 2012 2012
Korea Rep. 1998 2001 Uruguay 2007 2007
Non-IT Economies (24)
Algeria Jordan
Argentina Lebanon
Botswana Malaysia
Bulgaria Nigeria
China Pakistan
Costa Rica Panama
Côte d’Ivoire Saudi Arabia
Croatia Singapore
Ecuador Tanzania
Egypt Tunisia
El Salvador Ukraine
Hong Kong Venezuela

Note: The conservative starting year of IT regime is referred to de Mendonca and de Guimaraes e Souza (2010); Miller, et al. (2012) and Schmidt-Hebbel and Carrasco
(2016). The choice of non-IT economies is referred to Brito and Bystedt (2010).
a. Slovak Republic left the IT regime to adopt the Euro in 2008.

inflation rates in developing economies is consistent with Lin, 2010 and financial development reaches a certain threshold.20 Under the as-
de Mendonca and de Guimaraes e Souza (2010),19 unlike those papers sumption that IT adoption is predetermined (S-GMM P case), IT will not
we do not find significant impact of IT framework on inflation varia- be able to reduce inflation significantly (at the 5 percent significance
bility in developing economies. This may be due to the fact that our level) unless the overall financial development index is greater than
study includes many more developing economies with high degrees of 0.15, which is less than the average for developing economies.21 IT
heterogeneity in financial development that have adopted IT frame- seems to reduce inflation variability no matter which proxy measure is
works over the last decade. For instance, Lin and Ye (2009) listed 13 used, though the negative impact of IT on inflation variability becomes
developing economies that had adopted IT frameworks between 1985 less effective with higher levels of financial development.
and 2005 compared to 30 economies in our sample. Therefore, there is evidence that IT regimes lower inflation, and –
In this section we explore the impact of financial factors on inflation consistent with our hypothesis – this impact is enhanced with greater
and inflation variability in developing economies that have adopted IT levels of financial development. In contrast, while IT decreases inflation
frameworks. To do so we estimate Eq. (2) above using various available variability, the impact is reduced with higher levels of financial de-
measures of financial development. We start with the broadest measures of velopment. This is consistent with the hypothesis that greater levels of
financial development which “is defined as a combination of access financial development allow agents to hedge against exchange rate and
(ability of individuals and companies to access financial services), depth inflation shocks, hence allowing central banks to both accommodate
(size and liquidity of markets), and efficiency (ability of institutions to greater exchange rate flexibility while operating wider inflation target
provide financial services at low cost and with sustainable revenues, and bands to deal with multiple objectives (i.e. flexible IT).
the level of activity of capital markets)” (Svirydzenka, 2016, p. 5). All the
values are bound between zero and one. The higher the value the more
4.4. Impact of financial markets/institutions components
developed financial institutions/markets.
Table 5 summarizes the results. The system GMM estimations show
To further examine which components of financial development
that IT adoption itself cannot reduce inflation effectively unless overall
index affect the effectiveness of IT frameworks on inflation and its
variability, we delve into the components of financial market and fi-
nancial institution variables. The broad-based index of financial de-
19
Alpanda and Honig (2014) also find small negative impact on inflation velopment in Svirydzenka (2016) can be decomposed into six compo-
when IT frameworks are adopted. Brito and Bystedt (2010) is the exception, nents that summarize how developed financial markets and financial
finding no effects of IT framework even on inflation rates in the case of de-
veloping economies. The difference in our results with theirs could be a com-
20
bination of the following: different time periods (ours extends an additional There is a burgeoning literature on the role of financial thresholds in im-
decade and encompasses the GFC) and wider country coverage (54 in ours pact growth, reducing poverty and for a country to positively benefit from
study versus 46 in Brito-Bystedt’s study), inclusion of financial variables in our capital account liberalization.
21
analysis, as well as our use of more conservative start dates to IT regimes in The mean and median values for developing economies are 0.27 and 0.23,
many countries. respectively.

29
A.Y. Ouyang and R.S. Rajan Japan & The World Economy 50 (2019) 25–35

Table 3 Table 4
Summary Statistics. The Effect of IT on Inflation and Inflation Variability.
Variables Obs. Mean Median S.D. Min. Max. S-GMM P Inflation Inflation Variability

All Sample yi, t = linfl _cpii, t yi, t = vlinfl _cpii, t yi, t = cvlinfl _cpii, t
linfl _cpii, t 588 17.48 7.56 36.45 −2.47 354.77
vlinfl _cpii, t 579 6.44 2.24 15.37 0.02 144.32 yi, t 1 0.0794* 0.181*** 0.0180
cvlinfl _cpii, t 579 0.44 0.31 1.15 −8.87 21.79 (0.0456) (0.0366) (0.0453)
FD 648 0.27 0.23 0.17 0.00 0.85 ITi, t −4.936*** −0.126 −0.139
FI 648 0.33 0.30 0.18 0.00 0.80 (1.459) (0.984) (0.205)
FID 648 0.21 0.14 0.20 0.00 0.97 Highinfli, t 75.62*** 34.21*** 0.386*
FIA 648 0.25 0.21 0.20 0.00 1.00 (12.27) (6.226) (0.197)
FIE 648 0.53 0.57 0.21 0.00 0.95 Observations 534 525 525
FM 648 0.20 0.11 0.21 0.00 0.89 Number of Countries 54 53 53
FMD 648 0.16 0.07 0.20 0.00 0.91 Instrument Columns 93 92 92
FMA 648 0.18 0.06 0.22 0.00 0.97 AR(1) test 0.0517 0.00845 0.0293
FME 648 0.25 0.10 0.30 0.00 1.00 AR(2) test 0.734 0.862 0.109
IT regimes Hansen J test 0.982 0.977 0.886
linfl _cpii, t 120 4.83 4.38 2.74 0.05 14.36 Difference-in Hansen 0.946 0.936 0.772
vlinfl _cpii, t 120 1.67 1.29 1.20 0.02 6.79
cvlinfl _cpii, t 120 0.62 0.32 1.99 0.004 21.79 Notes:
FD 120 0.39 0.37 0.17 0.10 0.85
(1) S-GMM P is the two-step system GMM taking the IT dummy as pre-
FI 120 0.46 0.43 0.16 0.16 0.80 determined.
FID 120 0.31 0.24 0.22 0.03 0.89 (2) Regional, time effects and country fixed effects are considered, but not re-
FIA 120 0.42 0.40 0.22 0.05 1.00 ported.
FIE 120 0.58 0.60 0.11 0.29 0.77 (3) AR(1), AR(2), Hansen J tests and Difference in Hansen C test report the
FM 120 0.31 0.33 0.22 0.004 0.89 respective p-value.
FMD 120 0.27 0.22 0.22 0.004 0.88 (4) Standard errors in parentheses. *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.1.
FMA 120 0.32 0.37 0.24 0.00 0.93
FME 120 0.35 0.25 0.32 0.00 1.00
Non-IT regimes Table 5
linfl _cpii, t 468 20.72 9.04 40.21 −2.47 354.77 The Impact of Financial Development on Inflation and Inflation Variability of
vlinfl _cpii, t 459 7.69 2.53 17.03 0.05 144.32 Inflation Targeting Regimes.
cvlinfl _cpii, t 459 0.40 0.31 0.80 −8.87 6.95 S-GMM P Inflation Inflation Variability
FD 528 0.24 0.20 0.16 0.00 0.82
FI 528 0.30 0.28 0.17 0.00 0.77 yi, t = linfl _cpii, t yi, t = vlinfl _cpii, t yi, t = cvlinfl _cpii, t
FID 528 0.18 0.12 0.19 0.00 0.97 Financei, t = FDi, t
FIA 528 0.21 0.16 0.18 0.00 0.96
FIE 528 0.52 0.56 0.22 0.00 0.95 yi, t 0.109*** 0.155*** −0.0104
1
FM 528 0.17 0.08 0.19 0.00 0.89
(0.0181) (0.0199) (0.0270)
FMD 528 0.14 0.06 0.19 0.00 0.91
ITi, t 0.536 −2.142*** −0.590***
FMA 528 0.15 0.04 0.20 0.00 0.97
(1.859) (0.637) (0.168)
FME 528 0.23 0.09 0.30 0.00 1.00
Financei, t −6.638 −9.170** −0.357
(11.27) (3.887) (0.998)
Note: IT regimes indicate the period when the economies conduct inflation
ITi, t × Financei,t −17.62** 5.726** 1.500**
targeting, otherwise non-IT regimes.
(7.515) (2.230) (0.705)
Highinfli, t 79.82*** 30.21*** 0.328***
institutions are in terms of their depth, access, and efficiency. (3.341) (2.734) (0.0893)
We first dissect the financial institution index into its component 2 + 4 × Finance# −2.11**
parts (Table 6): institutional access,22 depth,23 and institutional effi- (FD = 0.15)
ciency.24 The results using S-GMM P indicate that IT frameworks are Observations 534 525 525
Number of Countries 54 53 53
not particularly effective in reducing inflation unless the level of fi-
Instrument Columns 111 110 110
nancial institutional access is greater than or equal to 0.39, higher than AR(1) test 0.0503 0.0279 0.0321
the average for the developing economies of 0.25. The results when AR(2) test 0.968 0.909 0.101
using financial institutional depth lead to similar conclusion, but with Hansen J test 0.819 0.666 0.971
Difference-in Hansen 0.426 0.000 0.753
much lower threshold level to make an IT regime effective. IT lowers
inflation significantly only when the level of financial institutional Notes:
depth has reached a threshold of 0.07. (There are only 3 IT economies (1) S-GMM P is the two-step system GMM taking the IT dummy as pre-
during some certain years where this index is less than 0.07).25,26 In determined.
(2) Regional, time effects and country fixed effects are considered, but not re-
ported.
22
Access consists of bank branches per 100,000 adults and ATMs per 100,000 (3) AR(1), AR(2), Hansen J tests and Difference in Hansen test report the re-
adults. spective p-value.
23
Depth includes private-sector credit to GDP and pension and mutual fund (4) Standard errors in parentheses. *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.1.
assets to GDP. (5) # Table gives 2 + 4 × Finance for the cutoff level of corresponding fi-
24
Efficiency refers to ATMs per 100,000 adults, lending-deposits spread, non- nancial variable at which 2 + 4 × Finance becomes significant negative.
interest income to total income, overhead costs to total assets, return on assets,
and return on equity.
25
In our sample, there are only eight less-developed countries whose average
financial institutional depth is lower than this threshold level. Armenia (2006- contrast, higher levels of financial institutional efficiency appear to
2009), Ghana (2007) and Uganda (2012-2014). reduce the effectiveness of IT on inflation, possibly consistent with the
26
They are Albania, Algeria, Armenia, Georgia, Ghana, Moldova, Tanzania hypothesis that financial institutions with higher market power tend to
and Uganda. be more profitability and less sensitive to interest rate transmission

30
A.Y. Ouyang and R.S. Rajan Japan & The World Economy 50 (2019) 25–35

Table 6
The Impact of Financial Institution Components on Inflation and Inflation Variability of Inflation Targeting Regimes.
S-GMM P Inflation Inflation Variability

yi, t = linfl _cpii, t yi, t = cvlinfl _cpii, t

Financei, t = FIAi, t FIDi, t FIEi, t FIAi, t FIDi, t FIEi, t

yi, t 1 0.134*** 0.111*** 0.113*** 0.00284 0.0180 −0.0210


(0.0241) (0.0205) (0.0184) (0.0217) (0.0248) (0.0245)
ITi, t 3.952** 0.119 −25.20*** −0.843*** −0.268 −1.316**
(1.543) (0.905) (5.479) (0.275) (0.174) (0.597)
Financei, t −4.689 16.61 −10.74 −0.334 0.944 −0.665
(5.615) (10.07) (9.048) (0.519) (1.860) (0.505)
ITi, t × Financei,t −19.62*** −20.90*** 35.97*** 1.776*** 0.0557 2.132**
(3.809) (6.037) (10.96) (0.534) (0.883) (0.997)
Highinfli, t 62.18*** 79.70*** 67.78*** 0.503*** 0.106 0.00294
(4.388) (4.006) (3.827) (0.106) (0.0882) (0.135)
2 + 4 × Finance# −3.70** −1.34**
(FIA = 0.39) (FID = 0.07)
Observations 534 534 534 525 525 525
Number of Countries 54 54 54 53 53 53
Instrument Columns 111 111 111 110 110 110
AR(1) test 0.0635 0.0466 0.0616 0.0305 0.0232 0.0478
AR(2) test 0.965 0.978 0.976 0.115 0.246 0.0978
Hansen J test 0.942 0.889 0.832 0.937 0.939 0.970
Difference-in Hansen 0.637 0.707 0.625 0.681 0.695 0.675

Notes:
(1) S-GMM P is the two-step system GMM taking the IT dummy as predetermined.
(2) Regional, time effects and country fixed effects are considered, but not reported.
(3) AR(1), AR(2), Hansen J tests and Difference in Hansen test report the respective p-value.
(4) Standard errors in parentheses. *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.1.
(5) # Table gives 2 + 4 × Finance for the cutoff level of corresponding financial variable at which 2 + 4 × Finance becomes significantly negative.

channel. With regard to inflation variability,27 we find that IT reduces 4.5. Robustness checks
inflation variability but the negative impact decreases with greater le-
vels of financial institutional access and efficiency. However, financial As a robustness check we re-estimate the equation by assuming IT
institutional depth seems to have insignificant impacts on inflation adoption as endogenous (S-GMM E). Table 8 shows the empirical results
variability in IT regimes. with and without financial development index. Without considering the
We similarly dissect the financial markets into its component parts, financial development index, IT framework tends to lower inflation no
viz. market access,28 market depth,29 and market efficiency.30 The re- matter whether IT adoption is treated as predetermined or endogenous.
sults in Table 7 show that IT regimes reduce inflation rates effectively With the inclusion of the financial development index, IT is effective in
no matter which financial market sub-component is used in the re- reducing inflation as long as the financial development index is at least
gressions. However, the effectiveness of IT regimes on inflation reduc- 0.04. (None of the economies within IT regimes has financial devel-
tion does not seem to be associated with financial markets components opment level less than 0.04).31 IT seems to reduce inflation variability
since the interaction terms of IT dummy and financial market compo- no matter which proxy measure is used, though the negative impact of
nents are statistically insignificant. These could be due to the fact that IT on inflation variability becomes less effective with higher levels of
both of the positive impacts from bond market development and the financial development if coefficient of variation is used. However, the
negative impacts from asset substitutability on the interest rate trans- interaction terms of IT dummy and financial development index are
mission channels co-exist. With respect to inflation variability, we see statistically insignificant in all cases.
that the results go through in all three cases. Regardless of the specific With respect to financial institution components (see Table 9), IT
indicator of financial market development that is included, it appears tends to reduce inflation with higher level of financial institution access
that IT frameworks lower inflation variability, while greater levels of and depth, but the results become statistically insignificant while IT
financial market development reduce this negative impact. adoption is treated as endogenous. The results for financial institution
efficiency remain robust, however, suggesting that financial institution
characteristics, particularly bank profitability (i.e. bank market power),
has negative and statistically significant effects on the effectiveness of
IT regimes on inflation reduction. With regard to inflation variability,
the results are generally robust. We find that IT reduces inflation
27
To save space, we only show results using coefficient of variation as a variability but the negative impact decreases with greater levels of fi-
proxy. nancial institutional access and efficiency. However, the results are
28
Access consists of the percent of market capitalization outside of the top 10
largest companies and total number of issuers of debt (domestic and external,
nonfinancial and financial corporations).
29 31
Depth refers to stock market capitalization to GDP; stocks traded to GDP; There are only 14 economies during some certain periods where this index
international debt securities of government to GDP; total debt securities of fi- is less than 0.04. They are Albania (1980-1991), Armenia (1980-1992),
nancial corporations to GDP; and total debt securities of nonfinancial cor- Bulgaria (1980-1990), China (1980-1981), Croatia (1980-1991), Czech
porations to GDP. Republic (1980-1990), Georgia (1980-1994), Hong Kong (1980-1987),
30
Efficiency refers to stock market turnover ratio (stocks traded to capitali- Hungary (1980-1981), Moldova (1980-1990), Russia (1980-1990), Serbia
zation). (1980-1993), Slovak Republic (1980-1991) and Uganda (1987-1998, 1995).

31
A.Y. Ouyang and R.S. Rajan Japan & The World Economy 50 (2019) 25–35

Table 7
The Impact of Financial Market Components on Inflation and Inflation Variability of Inflation Targeting Regimes.
S-GMM P Inflation Inflation Variability

yi, t = linfl _cpii, t yi, t = cvlinfl _cpii, t

Financei, t = FMAi,t FMDi,t FMEi, t FMAi,t FMDi,t FMEi, t

yi, t 1 0.120*** 0.122*** 0.124*** −0.0271 −0.0402 0.00747


(0.0181) (0.0252) (0.0246) (0.0209) (0.0286) (0.0167)
ITi, t −3.176** −3.987*** −4.137*** −0.544** −0.410* −0.418***
(1.374) (1.037) (1.144) (0.204) (0.220) (0.116)
Financei, t −14.29*** 5.326 3.919 −1.156 −1.607 −0.175
(3.178) (6.021) (2.891) (0.712) (1.434) (0.260)
ITi, t × Financei,t −2.379 −6.773 −1.955 1.714*** 1.418* 0.645***
(5.890) (5.147) (2.673) (0.479) (0.716) (0.236)
Highinfli, t 80.93*** 71.16*** 78.34*** 0.207* 0.279*** 0.345***
(3.537) (5.088) (5.653) (0.104) (0.0942) (0.0958)
Observations 534 534 534 525 525 525
Number of Countries 54 54 54 53 53 53
Instrument Columns 111 111 111 110 110 110
AR(1) test 0.0357 0.0599 0.0474 0.0459 0.0429 0.0385
AR(2) test 0.936 0.979 0.951 0.0927 0.0809 0.119
Hansen J test 0.977 0.965 0.920 0.983 0.995 0.953
Difference-in Hansen 0.879 0.865 0.713 0.718 0.770 0.886

Notes:
(1) S-GMM P is the two-step system GMM taking the IT dummy as predetermined.
(2) Regional, time effects and country fixed effects are considered, but not reported.
(3) AR(1), AR(2), Hansen J tests and Difference in Hansen test report the respective p-value.
(4) Standard errors in parentheses. *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.1.

Table 8
Robustness Check—Taking IT policy as Endogenous.
S-GMM E Inflation Inflation Variability

yi, t = linfl _cpii, t yi, t = vlinfl _cpii, t yi, t = cvlinfl _cpii, t

Financei, t = FDi, t

yi, t 1 0.0908* 0.0720** 0.172*** 0.194*** 0.00775 0.00636


(0.0475) (0.0309) (0.0264) (0.0236) (0.0496) (0.0279)
ITi, t −5.365** −2.671 −1.094 −0.0619 −0.0946 −0.601**
(2.045) (1.880) (0.843) (0.970) (0.206) (0.260)
Financei, t — −26.98** — 14.66** — 1.131
(10.78) (6.237) (2.640)
ITi, t × Financei,t — −18.39* — −6.262 — 1.068
(9.285) (4.652) (1.002)
Highinfli, t 79.44*** 78.52*** 28.71*** 28.74*** 0.368* 0.424***
(14.70) (5.541) (2.906) (3.045) (0.213) (0.155)
2 + 4 × Finance# −3.41**
(FD = 0.04)
Observations 534 534 525 525 525 525
Number of Countries 54 54 53 53 53 53
Instrument Columns 92 108 91 107 91 107
AR(1) test 0.0387 0.0596 0.0251 0.0275 0.0320 0.0260
AR(2) test 0.822 0.903 0.874 0.850 0.0943 0.156
Hansen J test 0.991 0.766 0.242 0.650 0.890 0.820
Difference-in Hansen 0.965 0.549 0.133 0.000 0.849 0.558

Notes:
(1) S-GMM E is the two-step system GMM taking the IT dummy as endogenous (L1.IT is the IV).
(2)Regional, time effects and country fixed effects are considered, but not reported.
(3) AR(1), AR(2), Hansen J tests and Difference in Hansen test report the respective p-value.
(4) Standard errors in parentheses. *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.1.
(5) # Table gives 2 + 4 × Finance for the cutoff level of corresponding financial variable at which 2 + 4 × Finance becomes significant negative.

statistically significant for financial institution access only. Financial enhances the effectiveness of IT frameworks in reducing inflation in a
institutional depth again has insignificant impacts on inflation varia- statistically significance sense. Financial market access has negative but
bility in IT regimes. insignificant impact on the effectiveness of IT regimes. With respect to
Table 10 summarizes the results for financial market components inflation variability, we see that the results go through in all three cases.
and remain generally robust as well. Even though financial market Regardless of the specific indicator of financial market development
depth has similar negative impacts, only financial market efficiency that is included, it appears that IT frameworks lower inflation

32
A.Y. Ouyang and R.S. Rajan Japan & The World Economy 50 (2019) 25–35

Table 9
Robustness Check on the Impact of Financial Institution Components—Taking IT policy as Endogenous.
S-GMM E Inflation Inflation Variability

yi, t = linfl _cpii, t yi, t = cvlinfl _cpii, t

Financei, t = FIAi, t FIDi, t FIEi, t FIAi, t FIDi, t FIEi, t

yi, t 1 0.116*** 0.100*** 0.0922*** 0.00332 0.0120 −0.0124


(0.0212) (0.0295) (0.0262) (0.0215) (0.0220) (0.0259)
ITi, t −2.042 −3.180** −48.91*** −0.785** −0.00881 −0.867
(1.659) (1.504) (6.742) (0.311) (0.214) (0.735)
Financei, t −37.95*** 4.482 −25.83* 0.169 5.748*** −0.625
(5.970) (11.23) (14.86) (0.967) (1.647) (0.715)
ITi, t × Financei,t −0.992 −6.162 79.78*** 1.338* −0.730 1.208
(7.573) (10.94) (14.08) (0.749) (0.746) (1.365)
Highinfli, t 65.22*** 77.09*** 70.22*** 0.577*** 0.103 0.00642
(3.473) (4.857) (4.314) (0.139) (0.124) (0.179)
Observations 534 534 534 525 525 525
Number of Countries 54 54 54 53 53 53
Instrument Columns 108 108 108 107 107 107
AR(1) test 0.0574 0.0505 0.0695 0.0338 0.0378 0.0461
AR(2) test 0.954 0.933 0.875 0.0994 0.165 0.116
Hansen J test 0.840 0.987 0.979 0.891 0.846 0.934
Difference-in Hansen 0.651 0.944 0.921 0.677 0.460 0.659

Notes:
(1) S-GMM E is the two-step system GMM taking the IT dummy as endogenous (L1.IT is the IV).
(2) Regional, time effects and country fixed effects are considered, but not reported.
(3) AR(1), AR(2), Hansen J tests and Difference in Hansen test report the respective p-value.
(4) Standard errors in parentheses. *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.1.

Table 10
Robustness Check on the Impact of Financial Market Components—Taking IT policy as Endogenous.
S-GMM E Inflation Inflation Variability

yi, t = linfl _cpii, t yi, t = cvlinfl _cpii, t

Financei, t = FMAi,t FMDi,t FMEi, t FMAi,t FMDi,t FMEi, t

yi, t 1 0.104*** 0.117*** 0.139*** −0.0291* −0.0186 −0.0243


(0.0202) (0.0232) (0.0257) (0.0150) (0.0299) (0.0180)
ITi, t −4.050*** −6.668*** −3.289** −0.396* −0.397* −0.294*
(1.341) (1.380) (1.502) (0.200) (0.202) (0.162)
Financei, t −40.60*** 1.017 9.734*** −0.469 −1.600 −0.101
(6.029) (6.423) (3.172) (0.761) (1.317) (0.375)
ITi, t × Financei,t 1.093 −0.423 −7.309** 0.983* 0.825 0.683**
(5.284) (6.695) (3.158) (0.517) (0.801) (0.320)
Highinfli, t 83.99*** 71.67*** 71.12*** 0.197* 0.310*** 0.344***
(5.531) (5.167) (5.702) (0.106) (0.104) (0.0928)
Observations 534 534 534 525 525 525
Number of Countries 54 54 54 53 53 53
Instrument Columns 108 108 108 107 107 107
AR(1) test 0.0357 0.0598 0.0514 0.0435 0.0385 0.0450
AR(2) test 0.911 0.979 0.968 0.110 0.111 0.0799
Hansen J test 0.953 0.934 0.956 0.976 0.942 0.923
Difference-in Hansen 0.852 0.813 0.860 0.651 0.784 0.693

Notes:
(1) S-GMM E is the two-step system GMM taking the IT dummy as endogenous (L1.IT is the IV).
(2) Regional, time effects and country fixed effects are considered, but not reported.
(3) AR(1), AR(2), Hansen J tests and Difference in Hansen test report the respective p-value.
(4) Standard errors in parentheses. *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.1.

variability, while greater levels of financial market development reduce financial development it is more likely that the interest rate policy
this negative impact. transmission will work effectively. Two caveats are in order. One, our
Overall, there is evidence that IT frameworks are more effective in empirical results suggest that there may has a threshold effect in fi-
reducing inflation rates with higher levels of financial development in nancial development, i.e. in some cases financial institutions and/or
general, with financial institutional access and depth being particularly overall financial development level need to surpass a certain threshold
significant. This concurs with the thesis that with higher level of before they can contribute positively to lower inflation. Two, the one

33
A.Y. Ouyang and R.S. Rajan Japan & The World Economy 50 (2019) 25–35

exception we find is with regard to financial institutional efficiency References


which seems to deteriorate the effectiveness of IT on inflation. This
likely emphasizes the importance of bank characteristics in impacting Agenor, P., DA Silva, L.A.P., 2013. Inflation Targeting and Financial Stability: a
IT effectiveness. A higher financial institutional efficiency might not Perspective from the Developing World. Working Paper No.324. Banco Central Do
Brasil.
only represent higher bank profitability and market power but may also Alpanda, S., Honig, A., 2014. The impact of central bank independence on the perfor-
indicate a more concentrated banking system.32 Thus, to the extent that mance of inflation targeting regimes. J. Int. Money Finance 44, 118–135.
higher financial institutional efficiency corresponds to either higher Arellano, M., Bover, O., 1995. Another look at the instrumental variable estimation of
error components models. J. Econom. 68, 29–51.
bank profitability and market power or a more concentrated banking Arestis, P., G, Chortareas, Magkonis, G., Moschos, D., 2014. Inflation targeting and in-
system, this may reduce the extent of interest rate pass-through from flation convergence: international evidence. J. Int. Financ. Mark. Inst. Money 31,
policy rates to bank market rates, thus making monetary policy in an IT 285–295.
Ashcraft, A.B., 2006. New evidence on the lending channel. J. Money Credit Bank. 38 (3),
framework somewhat less effective.33 751–775.
All the measures of financial market development seem to be par- Ball, L.M., 2010. The performance of alternative monetary regimes. In: In: Friedman,
ticularly important in influencing the effectiveness of IT on inflation B.M., Woodford, M. (Eds.), Handbook of Monetary Economics, vol. 3B North-Holland
and Elsevier chapter 23.
variability. As noted above, well-developed financial markets allow
Ball, L.M., Sheridan, N., 2005. Does inflation targeting matter? In: Bernanke, B.,
agents to hedge against exchange rate and inflation risks, hence al- Woodford, M. (Eds.), The Inflation Targeting Debate. The University of Chicago
lowing central banks to operate more flexible IT frameworks, as dis- Press, Chicago, USA.
cussed previously. This exchange rate variability could in turn pass- Batini, N., Laxton, D., 2007. Under what conditions can inflation targeting be adopted?
The experience of emerging markets. In: Mishkin, F., Loayza, N., Schmidt-Hebbel, K.
through to domestic prices, causing greater extent of inflation varia- (Eds.), Monetary Policy Under Inflation Targeting. Central Bank of Chile, Santiago,
bility. While the same general story holds when using proxies for fi- Chile.
nancial institutional development, financial access has positive and Berganza, J.C., Broto, C., 2012. Flexible inflation targets, forex interventions and ex-
changes rate volatility in emerging countries. J. Int. Money Finance 31, 428–444.
statistically significant impacts on inflation variability of IT regimes, Bernanke, B.S., Blinder, A.S., 1988. Credit, money, and aggregate demand. American
stressing the importance of financial inclusion in allowing households Economic Review: Papers and Proceedings 78 (2), 435–439.
and firms to manage risks. Bernanke, B.S., Laubach, T., Mishkin, F., Posen, A., 1999. Inflation Targeting: Lessons
from the International Experience. Princeton University Press, Princeton, USA.
Blundell, R., Bond, S., 1998. Initial conditions and moment restrictions in dynamic panel
5. Conclusion data models. J. Econom. 87, 115–143.
Brito, R.D., Bystedt, B., 2010. Inflation targeting in emerging economies: panel evidence.
J. Dev. Econ. 91, 198–2010.
Inflation Targeting remains the predominant monetary approach Calderon, C., Schmidt-Hebbel, K., 2010. What drives inflation in the world? In: Fry, R.,
globally, with interest rates being mostly used as the operating target. Jones, C., Kent, C. (Eds.), Inflation in an Era of Relative Price Shocks. Reserve Bank of
This paper has revisited the issue of the impact of an IT framework on Australia and Centre for Applied Macroeconomic Analysis, The Australia National
University, Sydney, Australia.
inflation, taking into account the role of financial development. We
Cavoli, T., Rajan, R.S., 2007. Managing in the middle: characterizing Singapore’s ex-
follow Brito and Bystedt (2010) by applying a dynamic panel estimator change rate policy. Asian Econ. J. 21, 321–342.
to a comprehensive panel dataset of 54 developing economies over the de Mendonca, H.F., de Guimaraes e Souza, G.J., 2010. Is inflation targeting a good re-
medy to control inflation? J. Dev. Econ. 98, 178–191.
period 1980 and 2015. After controlling for potential endogeneity and
Gambacorta, L., 2005. Inside the bank lending channel. Eur. Econ. Rev. 49 (7),
self-selection concerns of policy adoption, our main empirical finding is 1737–1759.
that IT frameworks appear to have clearly reduced inflation rates in Ghosh, A., Ostry, J., Chamon, M., 2016. Two targets, two instruments: monetary and
developing economies regardless of the level of financial development, exchange rate policies in emerging market economies. J. Int. Money Finance 60,
172–196.
while the framework reduces variability of inflation rates only when we Goncalves, C.E., Salles, J., 2008. Inflation targeting in emerging economies: what do the
control for levels of financial market development. data say? J. Dev. Econ. 85, 312–318.
Once we account for levels of financial development, we find that IT Gopalan, S., Rajan, R.S., 2017. Does foreign bank presence affect interest rate pass-
through in emerging and developing economies? J. Macroecon. 54, 373–392.
frameworks lower both inflation rates and inflation variability. Ingves, S., 2004. Monetary Policy Implementation at Different Stages of Market
However, while greater levels of financial market development Development: Country Cases and Appendices – Supplementary Information. mimeo,
strengthen the diminishing impact of IT on inflation (i.e. lowers it IMF.
International Monetary Fund (IMF), 2016. Annual Report on Exchange Rate
further), they tend to weaken the effect in the case of inflation varia- Arrangements and Exchange Restrictions. IMF, Washington, DC.
bility. This paper further finds that the performance of an IT framework Kashyap, A.K., Stein, J.C., 2000. What do a million observations on banks say about the
in terms of inflation is highly dependent on a country’s level of financial transmission of monetary policy? Am. Econ. Rev. 90 (3), 407–428.
Lin, S., 2010. On the international effects of inflation targeting. Rev. Econ. Stat. 92,
inclusion and specific bank characteristics, while the performance of an
195–199.
IT framework on inflation variability is more associated with financial Lin, S., Ye, H., 2007. Does inflation targeting make a difference? Evaluating the treatment
market components, an issue that has thus far been ignored in the de- effect of inflation targeting in seven countries. J. Monet. Econ. 54, 2521–2533.
Lin, S., Ye, H., 2009. Does inflation targeting make a difference in developing countries. J.
bate on the effectiveness of IT frameworks.
Dev. Econ. 89, 118–123.
McCallum, B.T., 2007. Monetary policy in East Asia: the case of Singapore. Monetary and
Acknowledgements Economic Studies 25. Institute for Monetary and Economic Studies, Bank of Japan,
pp. 13–28.
Mehrotra, A., Yetman, J., 2015. Financial Inclusion – Issues for Central Banks. BIS
The authors are indebted to the anonymous referees of this journal Quarterly Review, March, pp. 83–96.
for their thoughtful and constructive comments on an earlier version of Miller, S.M., Fang, W., Eren, O., 2012. Inflation Targeting: Does It Improve Economic
the paper. Financial support from China National Social Science Fund Performance? mimeo.
Mishkin, F., 1999. International experiences with different monetary policy regimes. J.
(#16BJY167) is greatly acknowledged. Monet. Econ. 43, 579–605.
Mishkin, F., Schimdt-Hebbel, K., 2007. Does Inflation Targeting Make a Difference.
Working Paper No.12876, National Bureau of Economic Research.
32
There is a positive correlation coefficient of 0.34 between financial in- Ouyang, A., Rajan, R.S., Li, J., 2016. Exchange rate regimes and real exchange rate vo-
stitutional efficiency index and bank concentration ratio (the correlation coef- latility: does inflation targeting help or hurt. Japan World Econ. 39, 62–72.
Parrado, E., 2004. Singapore’s Unique Monetary Policy: How Does It Work? MAS Staff
ficient is 0.35 if 5-bank asset concentration ratio is used) within a sample period
Paper No.31, Monetary Authority of Singapore.
of 1996-2014. Due to data deficiency, we do not use a direct measure such as Schmidt-Hebbel, K., 2008. Great Moderation and Inflation Targeting in the World,”
bank concentration ratio or Herfindahl Index, to proxy bank competition. Distinguished Lecture Series 27. The Egyptian Center for Economic Studies.
33
This contrasts with Svirydzenka (2016) who emphasize that their financial Schmidt-Hebbel, K., Carrasco, M., 2016. The Past and Future of Inflation Targeting.
institutional efficiency index does not include banking concentration related mimeo, Bank of Chile.
Svennson, L., 2010a. Inflation targeting after the financial crisis. Speech at the
ratios and claims that there is no clear evidence of whether more concentrated
International Research Conference on “Challenges to Central Banking in the Context
banking systems are more or less efficient.

34
A.Y. Ouyang and R.S. Rajan Japan & The World Economy 50 (2019) 25–35

of Financial Crisis,”. Mumbai, 12 February. Thornton, J., Vasilakis, C., 2016. Does inflation targeting reduce sovereign risk? Further
Svensson, L., 2010b. Inflation targeting, Handbook of Monetary Economics. In: In: evidence. Financ. Res. Lett. 18, 237–241.
Friedman, B.M., Woodford, M. (Eds.), Handbook of Monetary Economics Vol. 3B Vega, M., Winkelreid, D., 2005. Inflation targeting and inflation behavior: a successful
North-Holland and Elsevier chapter 22. story? Int. J. Cent. Bank. 1, 153–175.
Svirydzenka, K., 2016. Introducing a New Broad-based Index of Financial Development. Walsh, C., 2009. Inflation targeting: what have we learned? Int. Financ. 12, 195–233.
Working Paper No. WP/16/5, IMF. Wolf, M., 2009. Central Banks Must Target More Than Just Inflation. Financial Times
Thornton, J., 2016. Inflation targeting in developing countries revisited. Financ. Res. Lett. May 6.
16, 145–153.

35

You might also like