You are on page 1of 6

ECONOMY

How Competition Is Driving AI’s


Rapid Adoption
by Jacques Bughin and Jeongmin Seong
OCTOBER 17, 2018

TOMOHIRO OHSUMI /GETTY IMAGES

Artificial intelligence (AI) is engendering all kinds of breathless headlines, from being able to play
Go to spotting rare cancer tumors. But how will AI impact the economy in broad terms? The
answer hinges on both on what AI can be used for and the dynamics of a competitive race to
adopt AI that’s set to unfold between firms.

New research from the McKinsey Global Institute simulates the potential global macroeconomic
impact of five powerful technologies (computer vision, natural language, virtual assistants,
robotic process automation, and advanced machine learning). It finds that AI could (in aggregate
and netting out competition effects and transition costs) deliver an additional $13 trillion to
global GDP by 2030, averaging about 1.2% GDP growth a year across the period. This would
compare well with the impact of steam during the 1800s, robots in manufacturing in the 1900s,
and IT during the 2000s.

The average effect on GDP depends on multiple factors. At the industry level they include (a) the
extent of AI diffusion in economies; (b) the build-up of corporate profit; and (c) labor market
dynamics.

The modeling and simulation relies on two important features. The first is high-quality data from
two corporate surveys conducted by MGI and McKinsey in 2007, one of around 1,600
executives across industries globally on digital technologies and AI to ascertain the causes of
economic impact and the likely pace of that impact, and one of more than 3,000 corporations in
14 sectors in ten countries. The second feature of the simulation is micro-estimates of the pace of
adoption and absorption of AI technologies.

A faster pace of adoption

We know that technologies often take a long time to diffuse and to deliver benefits. It took more
than 30 years for electricity to diffuse and enable industrial plant design that could generate
significant productivity growth. It took several decades for steam to drive the rollout of railways
services and create a large market of exchanges in the United States. Amazon, born 24 years ago,
had captured about 45% of online retail commerce in the United States by 2017, but still stood
for just about 5% of total US retail gross merchandise volume in that year.

How does AI diffusion compare with the absorption of the early set of digital technologies such as
web, mobile, cloud, and big data? Those technologies started to be used about ten to 25 years
ago, and the average level of absorption of these technologies was about 37% in 2017. Our
simulation suggests that it may reach 70% by 2035. In comparison, absorption of AI might reach
today’s level of digital absorption by 2027—in roughly ten years.

There are two stand-out reasons why AI adoption and absorption could be more rapid this time.
One is the breadth of ways in which AI is used, including in areas where digitization is still under-
penetrated, such as the automation of services and smart automation of manufacturing
processes. Second is that returns for front-runners tend to be large. They will benefit from
innovations enabling them to serve (and perhaps create) new markets and, at the same time, gain
share from non-AI adopters in existing markets. Perception of cannibalization is high among
firms surveyed, in line with their experience of early digitization and the emergence of many new
business models.

We simulate that about 70% of companies might adopt some AI technologies by 2030, up from
today’s 33%, and about 35% of companies might have fully absorbed AI, compared with only 3%
today. The econometrics demonstrate that peer competitive pressure is the largest influencer of
the decision to adopt AI and make it work across all enterprise functions. The peer pressure effect
on adoption incentive is an order of magnitude larger than the expected profitability impact of
AI, or perception of the impact it has had in recent years.

A race between firms

Even if a technology race develops, some companies will adopt rapidly, but others less so—and
the benefits of AI will vary accordingly. The pace could be enhanced by sector dynamics and by
characteristics of firms such as the size and extent of their globalization, but could also be held
back by constraints such as early capabilities in digitization, or by organizational rigidities.

We simulated the economic impact of AI for three groups of companies: “front-runners,”


“followers,” and “laggards.” The first group experiences the largest benefits from AI, and the
second benefits but only by a fraction of the general AI productivity uplift. Laggards (many of
them nonadopters) may witness a shrinking market share, and may have no choice but exit the
market in the long term.

Regarding front-runners, our average simulation suggests that about 30% of companies might
have absorbed the full set of AI technologies in their operations by 2030. About half of those will
do so in half the time, and may more than double their operating cash flows by 2030. This is
equivalent to sustaining a long-term growth rate of 6% per year through AI. These companies
would typically be growing at the rate of high-growth performing firms. Cash generation is not
linear as the impact of AI scales up over time—it might be negative in the early years and only
becomes positive and accelerates after a period of five to seven years. In this initial period, front-
runners could experience cash outflows as they invest in, and scale up, AI. Over time, however,
front-runners will tend to slowly concentrate the profit pool of their industry in a winner-takes-
most phenomenon.
Followers are firms that are cautiously starting to adopt and absorb AI technologies, having seen
the tangible impact enjoyed by front-runners and having realized the competitive threat of not
adopting and absorbing. We simulated that 20% to 30% of firms would be in this group by 2030.
For these companies, the pace and degree of change in cash flow are likely to be more moderate,
and typically below the average productivity uplift witnessed by their economy. On the one
hand, front-runners have already triggered some spillovers that spread some benefits to
followers; on the other hand, followers lose market share to front-runners.

Laggards are companies that are not investing in AI seriously, or not at all. Why do laggards not
jump into AI? The answer is that they may face short-term constraints and may bet—wrongly—
that time is on their side. The cost of investment in and implementation of AI means that the
divergence among firms on their stance toward AI adoption may only affect their economics after
a few years. This may dissuade them from acting. These companies could lose around 20% of
cash flow by 2030 compared with today. Laggards may have major capability issues that prevent
them from joining the AI race, and therefore they may need to respond in other ways such as
limiting costs and cutting investment. The drop in cash flow arrives last, but it is a major slide
when it comes.

A fierce competitive race among companies appears to be in prospect with a widening gap
between those investing in AI and those that are not. This divide can facilitate “creative
destruction” and competition among firms so that the reallocation of resources toward higher-
performing companies improves the vibrancy of overall economies. But there is no doubt that the
transition may cause disruption and shock in the economy. These tradeoffs need to be
understood and managed appropriately in order to capture the potential of AI for the world
economy.

Jacques Bughin is a director of the McKinsey Global Institute based in Brussels.

Jeongmin Seong is a senior fellow at the McKinsey Global Institute, based in Shanghai.

This article is about ECONOMY


FOLLOW THIS TOPIC

Related Topics: ANALYTICS | TECHNOLOGY

Comments
Leave a Comment

POST

0 COMMENTS

JOIN THE CONVERSATION

POSTING GUIDELINES
We hope the conversations that take place on HBR.org will be energetic, constructive, and thought-provoking. To comment, readers must sign in or
register. And to ensure the quality of the discussion, our moderating team will review all comments and may edit them for clarity, length, and
relevance. Comments that are overly promotional, mean-spirited, or off-topic may be deleted per the moderators' judgment. All postings become
the property of Harvard Business Publishing.
Harvard Business Review Notice of Use Restrictions, May 2009

Harvard Business Review and Harvard Business Publishing Newsletter content on


EBSCOhost is licensed for the private individual use of authorized EBSCOhost users. It is not
intended for use as assigned course material in academic institutions nor as corporate learning
or training materials in businesses. Academic licensees may not use this content in electronic
reserves, electronic course packs, persistent linking from syllabi or by any other means of
incorporating the content into course resources. Business licensees may not host this content
on learning management systems or use persistent linking or other means to incorporate the
content into learning management systems. Harvard Business Publishing will be pleased to
grant permission to make this content available through such means. For rates and permission,
contact permissions@harvardbusiness.org.

You might also like