You are on page 1of 13

Research Policy 42 (2013) 788–800

Contents lists available at SciVerse ScienceDirect

Research Policy
journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/respol

University effects on regional innovation


Robin Cowan a,b,∗ , Natalia Zinovyeva c
a
BETA, University of Strasbourg, 61 avenue de la Forêt Noire, 67085 Strasbourg, France
b
UNU-MERIT, Maastricht University, Keizer Karelplein 19, 6211 TC Maastricht, The Netherlands
c
Institute of Public Goods and Policies (IPP-CSIC), Calle Albasanz 26-28, Madrid 28037, Spain

a r t i c l e i n f o a b s t r a c t

Article history: This paper analyzes empirically whether expansion of a university system affects local industry innova-
Received 30 June 2011 tion. We examine how the opening of new university schools in Italy during 1985–2000 affected regional
Received in revised form innovation. We find that creation of new schools increased regional innovation activity already within
19 September 2012
five years. On average, an opening of a new school has led to a seven percent change in the number of
Accepted 11 October 2012
patents filed by regional firms. The evidence suggests that the effect is mainly generated by high quality
Available online 24 November 2012
scientific research brought to the region with new schools.
© 2012 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
Keywords:
University research
Regional innovation
Publications
Industry–university interaction

1. Introduction necessary to promote knowledge flows and innovation. These pol-


icy suggestions are often based on the idea that universities have
Between 1960 and 2000, there was a large expansion in univer- within them some of the keys to increasing innovative activity.2
sities in the industrialized countries. Early expansion was to deal The fact that the increase of innovation activity during past
with the baby boom coming of university age; later expansion was decades coincides with the increase in the size of the university sec-
driven by the desire to increase the proportion of the population tor might suggest that the innovation performance of an economy
receiving tertiary education.1 The clearest effect was just that: an is determined in part by the supply of universities in the innovation
increase in the general education level of the labor force. Naturally, system. This hypothesis motivates our analysis.
a rise in student numbers tended to be accompanied by a rise in the There have been many studies of the relationship between
size of the professoriate and an increase in the sizes and numbers universities and industrial innovation, particularly at the regional
of universities. level (see Section 2.1). The vast majority of these studies analyze
University expansion coincided with spectacular rise of innova- cross-sectional data, focusing on either the presence or size of
tion activity in industrialized world. In 1963 the US Patent Office universities and the relationship with local innovation activity.
granted around 45 thousand patents; by the end of the nineties the Generally, they document a strong relationship between university
yearly number of granted patents approached 160 thousand (Hall research activity and industrial innovation. But there are well-
et al., 2001). How to maintain this competitiveness and get more known difficulties in drawing conclusions from cross-sectional
innovation out of a knowledge system has become a hotly debated analysis about phenomena that take place over time, so while the
issue. Following the line taken in the literature on innovation sys- results are suggestive, one must be cautious in drawing the “obvi-
tems, it is often suggested that stimulating academic research and ous” policy conclusions from them, particularly in terms of whether
close interactions between academia, industry and government are opening new universities is a good idea. Additionally, endogene-
ity problems are rife in this kind of work – some of the effects of

∗ Corresponding author at: UNU-MERIT, Keizer Karelplein 19, 6211 TC Maastricht,


The Netherlands. Tel.: +31 0433884408.
2
E-mail addresses: r.cowan@maastrichtuniversity.nl (R. Cowan), An OECD 2007 report “Higher Education and Regions: Globally Competitive,
natalia.zinovyeva@csic.es (N. Zinovyeva). Locally Engaged” estimates that only 10% of UK firms currently interact with uni-
1
According to the Global Education Digest 2009 by UNESCO Institute of Statistics, versities with most university–industry links focusing on big business and a few
the share of students in North America and Western Europe that enroll in tertiary hi-tech fields. The report concludes that “the potential of higher education institu-
education during five years after the end of secondary education increased by 41 tions to contribute to the economic, social and cultural development of their regions
percentage points from 30% in 1970 to 71% in 2007. is far from being fully realized”.

0048-7333/$ – see front matter © 2012 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2012.10.001
R. Cowan, N. Zinovyeva / Research Policy 42 (2013) 788–800 789

university–industry interaction are driven by supply of knowledge, focusing on the short term effects, we can identify direct knowledge
some by demand for it; external factors may drive both public and spillover effects from university faculties to local industries.
private research output simultaneously; the location of universi- Our results suggest that there is indeed a significant effect of
ties and firms is often endogenously determined (Mairesse and the creation of new university schools on regional research and
Mohnen, 2010) – all imply that identifying empirically the effect innovation activity. Industrial patenting increases following the
of universities would ideally rely on exogenous shocks to univer- introduction of a new school to a region: on average, one new
sity supply. Such shocks are rare in real life and most studies rely school has led to about a seven percent increase in the number
on strong assumptions to claim the existence of the supply-side of patents filed by regional firms five years later. But the quality
effects. of patents produced as a consequence of university supply shock
There was, however, a period of several years in the 1980s and is not different from the rest of regional patents. Given that the
1990s in which Italy opened many new university schools in differ- level of development of a region affects its absorptive capacity,
ent regions of the country.3 University expansion was centralized one might expect that more developed regions with more inten-
and, as was acknowledged later by policy makers, the distribu- sive R&D activity benefit more from interactions with universities.
tion of new schools across regions was largely independent of the However, contrary to this hypothesis, we find that less devel-
properties of the regional economy. In fact no significant corre- oped regions benefit more from university–industry interactions.
lation can be observed between the number of new schools in Regarding the second issue, we find that the number of academic
a region and regional characteristics including population, share patents explains essentially none of the effect of universities on
of graduates in the labor force, private and public investment in innovation. Publications corrected for quality explain most of the
research and development, and value added produced by differ- effect of universities on local industrial innovation. This suggests
ent economic sectors. We use this episode to ask directly whether that in order to increase regional innovation the intermediate pol-
expanding university activity by opening new universities has an icy goal should be to increase the amount of high quality academic
identifiable effect on local industrial innovation. This is the first research carried out in the region.
issue we address in this paper. The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 reviews
The second issue has to do with the nature of the relationship the existent empirical findings concerning the role of academic
between universities and industrial innovation. There have been research in innovation systems. Section 3 describes the data. Sec-
several studies on the “channels” of interaction between univer- tion 4.1 introduces the empirical model and comments on the main
sity and industry (see Section 2.2). By and large, these studies are identification assumptions. The results of the empirical analysis are
based on firm surveys, asking firms about their external sources of provided in Sections 4.2 and 4.3. Finally, Section 5 concludes.
knowledge or information. As one might expect, firms use many dif-
ferent channels for accessing university expertise: academic papers
or patents, conferences, seminars, consulting, and so on. But one 2. Background literature
could frame the question in a slightly different way. What measures
of university activity help explain their effects on local innova- 2.1. Identifying the effect of university R&D
tion? Scientific publications are thought to represent advances in
basic knowledge. Patents represent advances in applied knowl- There exists a large literature analyzing the relationship
edge. Both of these activities indicate human capital capable of between academic research and industrial innovation activity. That
producing novel knowledge, basic and applied respectively. We university effects on industrial innovation might be localized stems
construct measures of these activities using data from Thompson ISI from the nature of knowledge. While to a great extent the business
and the European Patent Office. Additionally though, universities of universities is to produce codified knowledge, tacit knowledge
might possess other competences harder to quantify or describe, remains central in the diffusion process (see for example Cowan
for example skills or accumulated knowledge that can be applied et al., 2000). While codified knowledge can be diffused very widely,
to issues other than creating novelty. These too could be of value and now very rapidly, tacit knowledge, by its nature, cannot. Jaffe
in industrial innovation activities. In the latter part of the paper we et al. (1993) showed that diffusion of the knowledge contained in
perform an accounting exercise in an attempt to assess whether patents, which are by definition highly codified, has a strong geo-
the human capital associated with creating new basic knowledge, graphical pattern – diffusion is very much local, and access to the
creating new applied knowledge, or something different is what knowledge spreads geographically over time. Breschi and Lissoni
drives the university effect on industrial innovation. (2009) revisited this issue and showed that in fact it is social rather
For two reasons we focus on the short-term effects of academic than geographic distance over which the diffusion takes place. That
research. First, it is likely that regional collaboration networks grow is, inventors learn about the existence of a patent (and presum-
fastest in the first few years after opening of new university schools. ably the knowledge it contains) through their direct social contacts.
Second, considering the short-run effect of universities allows us Since most social contacts are local, we can expect (geographically)
to identify the direct influence of academic research on innovation localized knowledge diffusion.
activity and to exclude other channels. In particular, it permits us to As early as the 1980s it was suggested that technology clusters
avoid the issue of how graduates contribute to innovation.4 So by such as those in Massachusetts and California would be impossible
without the technology transfer from universities in these areas
(Saxenian, 1985; Dorfman, 1983). It was not long though, before
several case studies questioned the generality of the role of uni-
3
In the Italian system teaching is organized into schools (facoltà) and research versity as an accelerator of regional innovation (Feldman, 1994a;
is organized into departments (dipartimenti). Departments and schools may or may Rogers and Larsen, 1984) and suggested that various character-
not coincide. To simplify presentation, we refer only to “schools”, and our measure of
istics of regional technological infrastructure (business services,
the date of opening of a new school is the year in which the first class was registered
within a newly formed school. This should not be read to imply that university
expansion affected only teaching. A new school in most cases implied creation of a
new department. This conflation of schools and departments, teaching and research
units, is not an issue for our analysis, as both measure university presence in the five years after a school opens: the official duration of most degrees in Italy (in
region. the period analyzed) is five years. But fewer than 20% of graduates complete their
4
The effects of an increased quantity and quality of graduates in a region are education on time and, on average, students take two more years to graduate after
likely to be very diffuse and hard to identify. However, they do not emerge within the end of the official program (Bagues et al., 2008).
790 R. Cowan, N. Zinovyeva / Research Policy 42 (2013) 788–800

technologically related firms, etc.) are necessary for development those technological areas that require frontier scientific knowledge
of university research outputs. (Hall et al., 2003).
To understand the magnitudes of possible effects of university Once again, even if the empirical evidence suggests that indus-
research on industrial innovation, Jaffe (1989) provided a more trial innovation and university research tend to cluster in the same
aggregate econometric analysis. He used data for 8 years for 29 US locations and university–industry collaborations are more frequent
states to test whether there is an impact of university R&D on indus- in highly innovative firms, it is difficult to claim empirically that
trial patenting, and found a significant positive effect. Several later the intensity of university research influences the innovativeness of
studies confirmed Jaffe’s finding, using firms’ product and process industrial sector, and not vice versa. Typically, one needs to rely on
innovations instead of patents as a measure of innovative activity observable characteristics, which could be used as controls, and to
(Acs et al., 1992; Feldman, 1994b; Feldman and Florida, 1994). assume that they are sufficient to exclude any correlated effect.
The challenge that runs throughout the empirical literature To be policy relevant, it is also important that the observed uni-
on technology transfer is the problem of identifying causation in versity effect is not actually a crowding out effect of private R&D,
a system rife with endogeneity. A positive association between i.e. that university supply does not lead to a substitution of private
academic research and industrial innovation may not necessar- funding for public funding (Mairesse and Mohnen, 2010).
ily imply that universities increase local innovation activity. It is
quite possible that increases in university outputs are “caused 2.2. Transfer of knowledge and expertise
by” increases in industrial R&D and associated with easy access
to industrial inputs such as equipment or materials. A more University research is conducted under a very different sys-
active industrial R&D sector may facilitate and stimulate university tem of incentives than is that in the private sector (Stephan, 1996;
knowledge production. Thus the causation may run in the oppo- Dasgupta and David, 1994). This could easily lead to the accumula-
site direction, and if there is inertia in the variables (industrial tion of very different types of human capital and knowledge in the
R&D and university papers and patents) as seems very likely to two sectors, and thus raises the possibility of synergies between
be the case, then extracting the causal direction is difficult statis- them in innovation activity.
tically. Increases in university research production might also be The most obvious competence associated with university
reinforced by the self-selection of academics able to benefit from researchers is that aimed at expanding the knowledge frontier. This
interaction with industry into highly innovative industrial districts. has been the traditional research function of universities, and is
This will introduce a bias into the types of activities of univer- seen as perhaps the main activity of the professoriate. Publication
sities, changing the types of outputs depending on the nature of is traditionally the activity most highly valued in the univer-
local innovation activities. This would be consistent with results sity setting. More recently, though, academic scientists have been
showing a positive correlation between professors’ scientific out- encouraged to produce applied knowledge. Here again, since the
put (as measured by published papers), and their applied output aim has been to express this knowledge in terms of patents, novelty
as measured by patents (Carayol and Matt, 2004; Stephan et al., is paramount. The types of human capital needed to produce these
2007). Again this causes problems for statistical understanding of types of novelty are likely to be well-proxied by publication and
causation. patenting measures, and indeed, the literature on the channels of
In order to address those endogeneity problems, Jaffe (1989) knowledge communication between industry and university finds
estimated a system of three equations: the first equation charac- that publications and patents, particularly the former, tend to be
terizing the effect of industrial and university R&D on patenting, important channels of communication.
and two equations describing the determinants of, respectively, Academic patents are often discussed, especially by policy mak-
industrial R&D and university R&D. To identify the model, Jaffe ers, as one of the main channels of knowledge and technology
assumed that industry R&D does not depend on the number of transfer from university. In part, this belief motivated the U.S. Bayh-
private and public institutions and that university R&D does not Dole Act (1980), which gave permission for US universities to patent
depend on manufacturing value added, once, respectively, univer- technology developed with federal funds. The underlying rationale
sity and industrial R&D are taken into account. Thus the consistency was that this should speed up technology transfer by bringing new
of Jaffe’s findings depends on the validity of these assumptions. commercialization opportunities to the market.5 In Europe, many
Econometric analysis of university effects on industrial innova- universities have also recently adopted technology transfer poli-
tion at the regional level relies on the assumption that knowledge cies. But at the same time, many academics expressed concerns
diffusion and spillovers are geographically localized. Bottazzi and about potential detrimental effects of incentives to patent on the
Peri (2003) analyze the effect of total regional R&D on innovation type and the quality of the research output produced (Lundvall,
and find that in Europe the effect of R&D is very localized and 1992; Henderson et al., 1998). Contrary to the apparent belief of
exists only within a distance of 300 km. Andersson et al. (2009) policy makers, the empirical evidence tends to suggest that aca-
provide evidence suggesting that spillovers from university invest- demic patenting per se is not a key channel of technology transfer
ment might be even more localized. They analyze the effects of (Agrawal and Henderson, 2002; Arundel and Geuna, 2004; Cohen
changes in the Swedish university system and find that roughly half et al., 2002; D’Este and Patel, 2007).
of the productivity gains from aggregate university investments are It is often argued that the transfer of university knowledge could
manifest within 5–8 km of the community in which they are made. also be spread through the more traditional academic channels
Some authors have claimed that the evidence of firms’ dispropor- such as scientific publications, seminars or face-to-face interac-
tionate location in areas close to universities already suggests that tions. In fact, publications (as well as co-publishing with industry)
the potential positive interactions between industry and university are often found to be among the most important channels of knowl-
are likely to be quite localized (Abramovsky et al., 2007; Audretsch edge transfer from academia, as perceived by survey respondents
and Stephan, 1996). Still, there is also evidence suggesting that uni- (Cohen et al., 2002; Cassiman et al., 2008; Bekkers and Bodas Freitas,
versity R&D might be related to patenting activity much further, 2008). While publication is necessarily strongly correlated with the
away following the collaboration networks of university professors
(Ponds et al., 2010).
Many studies at the firm level have confirmed that those firms 5
Market failure theory suggests that due to the public good nature of knowledge,
that collaborate with universities have higher propensities to inno- private companies have little incentive to invest in developing an invention that is
vate (Loof and Brostrom, 2008; Zucker et al., 1998), especially in not protected by a patent.
R. Cowan, N. Zinovyeva / Research Policy 42 (2013) 788–800 791

ability to produce frontier knowledge, other channels discussed 12

in that literature may be much less so. Conferences, workshops,


consulting and so on may be avenues for transmitting something 10

other than cutting-edge knowledge. Academics may have general

Number of new schools


8
analytic or synthetic skills that can be used for things other than
publishable research; they have (in principle at least) pedagogic
6
skills gathering, synthesizing, codifying and delivering existing
knowledge. All of these could be transferred or facilitate transfer
4
of useful knowledge.
One challenge arising from this literature stems from the sug-
2
gestion that subjectiveness of survey responses can lead to very
different opinions about channels’ importance, depending on who 0
is asked to evaluate it. For instance, Bekkers and Bodas Freitas

1985

1986

1987

1988

1989

1990

1991

1992

1993

1994

1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000
(2008) compare perceptions of the importance of academic patents Year
(among other things) as a channel of technology transfer among
academics and private sector R&D workers and report that the Fig. 1. Annual number of new university schools (excluding schools in humanities
private sector considers them to be twice as important as does and social sciences), 1985–2000.
academia. In this paper we avoid this problem and do not focus
on channels of transfer, rather we use an accounting procedure to
innovation is affected by the activities and human capital associated
address the issue of different types of knowledge flow.
with professors’ publishing as opposed to those associated with
the more applied activities associated with patenting. The answer
2.3. This study in the literature, and hypotheses to this question can help universities and policy makers to make
judgements about the alignment of existing incentive structures in
The extent to which knowledge flows from university affect academia to the necessities of local industries.
regional innovation and which type of academic expertise matters
in this respect, are important empirical questions. Still, as discussed
above, empirical analysis of these issues faces several methodologi- 3. Data and variables
cal problems related to the identification of the effects of university
research. The presence of those problems often opens a window for The analysis is performed using Italian data at the regional level.
criticism of the recent empirical findings on university effects on The database includes characteristics of the university system, indi-
industry. cators of industrial and academic innovation activity and economic
In what follows we perform a statistical analysis to examine indicators observed for 20 Italian regions between 1984 and 2000.
whether a rapid growth of the university system in Italy had an Our main indicator of the university presence in the region is
effect on local industrial innovation activity. University schools cre- the number of university schools in science, medicine and engineer-
ation in the 1980s and 1990s was part of a plan to expand education ing. We consider the date students were first enrolled in the degree
supply, adopted by the Italian government in the beginning of the program of the school as the date of the creation of this school. Infor-
1980s.6 The plan sought to unburden over-crowded universities mation about the number of first-year students at the school level
and to improve graduation rates.7 We exploit the fact that, as we was obtained from different issues of the Italian National Statistical
show in Section 4.1, the rationale of this rapid university expansion Bureau bulletins (L’università in cifre and Lo Stato dell’Università).8
and consequently the timing of new university openings was inde- According to this definition, 65 schools in science, medicine and
pendent of the demands of local innovation systems. This allows us engineering were opened for enrollment between 1985 and 2000.
to avoid many of the endogeneity problems typically attendant on (Fig. 1 describes the dynamics of university expansion across time
this type of study. and Fig. 2 shows the geographical distribution of new schools.) Out
The focus on Italy is especially relevant since it is one of the of the total of 65 new schools, 29 schools were in civil and industrial
countries that has to catch up with other European countries in the engineering, 12 in sciences, 11 in agriculture and veterinary, and
level of innovation activity in firms. According to the Community 13 in medicine, pharmaceutics and chemistry. The average Italian
Innovation Survey (CIS) 2008, Italy still lags behind the majority of region has nine schools and every fifth region in a given year opened
European countries in the percentage of firms that innovate. a new school (Table 1).
Finally, we explore which type of academic knowledge and The number of schools might seem too aggregate an indica-
expertise is effectively transferred to industry. In particular, we tor of university presence, since schools can vary considerably
are interested in understanding the extent to which industrial by size. However, we have sufficient evidence to believe that the
variation in the number of schools was exogenous to regional
innovation activity and the dynamics of other factors affecting
6
innovation. By contrast, the number of professors hired by these
Some new university openings were already approved in the late 1970s. How-
ever, the substantial reform came with law n. 382 11/7/1980, which provided that
new schools is likely to have been determined by the demand for
any variation in the existing university supply should be included in a development education. This demand could be correlated with the innovation
plan (piani triennali), to be approved by the Minister of Education every three years activity in the region. So the number of professors is unlikely to
(Law no. 590 14/8/1982). Some autonomy was introduced starting from 1995. For be an exogenous shock. Similarly to the case of school size, any
more details see Bratti et al. (2008).
7 indicator of university–industry collaborations (such as the num-
In most cases the new schools were opened within previously existing uni-
versities, but often located in different towns. With time some of these schools ber or size of university technology-transfer offices) would suffer
became independent universities (for example, what is now the University of East-
ern Piedmont was founded in 1998 on the basis of schools of the University of Turin
located in Vercelli, Alessandria and Novara). In a few cases the new units appeared as
8
a result of the split of over-crowded universities in big megalopolises (the University The data are available from 1984 from the printed annual editions of L’università
of Rome III was founded in 1992 simply by taking part of the staff from Univer- in cifre and Lo Stato dell’Università (available in most university libraries in Italy).
sity of Rome La Sapienza). There are very few examples of opening completely new Data for years from 1988 on were accessed at http://ionio.cineca.it, in November
universities from scratch (one such is the University of Teramo, founded in 1993). 2007.
792 R. Cowan, N. Zinovyeva / Research Policy 42 (2013) 788–800

Table 1
Descriptive statistics.

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)

All regions North Center South

Mean Std. dev. Mean Std. dev. Mean Std. dev. Mean Std. dev.

Schools: 9 6 9 7 10 4 8 5
Engineering 2 2 2 2 2 2 3 2
Sciences 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1
Medicine, Chemistry and Pharmacy 3 2 3 3 4 1 2 2
Veterinary and Agriculture 2 1 1 1 2 1 2 1
New schools opened in 1985–2000: 0.20 0.55 0.20 0.53 0.16 0.46 0.24 0.62
Engineering 0.09 0.35 0.08 0.30 0.09 0.33 0.11 0.41
Sciences 0.04 0.19 0.04 0.19 0.04 0.19 0.04 0.19
Medicine, Chemistry and Pharmacy 0.04 0.21 0.05 0.25 0.01 0.11 0.05 0.23
Veterinary and Agriculture 0.03 0.18 0.03 0.17 0.03 0.16 0.04 0.21
Publications 1020 1111 1308 1238 1260 1257 521 527
Citations per publications 17 5 17 5 18 3 15 6
Patents: 142 241 284 327 80 73 22 25
Academic patents 7 12 13 17 8 9 2 3
Industrial patents 134 230 272 311 72 65 20 22
Citations per patent: 0.67 0.46 0.72 0.37 0.67 0.43 0.60 0.56
Academic patents 0.78 1.29 0.97 1.24 1.16 1.66 0.63 0.62
Industrial patents 0.66 0.47 0.72 0.36 0.60 0.36 0.34 0.78
Non-patent literature (NPL) citations per patent 0.66 0.88 0.41 0.33 1.02 1.12 0.70 1.03
Academic patents 2.3 3.34 1.99 2.10 3.67 4.62 1.66 3.04
Industrial patents 0.48 0.69 0.33 0.29 0.68 1.06 0.48 0.63
Private R&D investment, mln euros 229 421 439 582 147 205 48 59
Public Non-University R&D investment, mln euros 90 188 76 71 199 341 27 29
Public University R&D investment, mln euros 150 128 154 125 186 140 119 117
Population, mln 2.4 1.8 2.7 2.3 2.1 1.4 2.1 1.6
Population of 19-olds in total population, % 15.7 4.2 13.3 3.4 15.0 3.7 18.9 3.3
University graduates in the labor force, % 7.6 2.2 6.9 2.1 8.3 2.5 7.9 1.8
VA per capita, thousand euros: 14.8 5.5 18.1 5.5 14.9 4.6 11.0 3.3
Industrial VA in total VA, % 21.9 7.5 25.7 7.7 23.1 6.7 16.7 4.3
Services VA in total VA, % 67.2 6.7 65.2 7.3 67.4 7.3 69.4 4.7
Agriculture VA in total VA, % 4.3 2.0 3.1 1.2 3.6 1.3 6.1 1.6
Construction VA in total VA, % 6.6 2.1 6.1 1.9 5.9 1.7 7.8 2.1

Notes: (*) Total number of regions is 20. Regions classified as “Northern” are Piedmont (PIE), Aosta Valley (AOS), Lombardy (LOM), Friuli-Venezia-Giulia (FVG), Trentino-Alto
Adige (TAA), Veneto (VEN), Emilia-Romagna (EMR), Liguria (LIG); regions classified as “Central” are Tuscany (TUS), Umbria (UMB), Marche (MAR), Lazio (LAZ), Sardinia (SAR);
regions classified as “Southern” are Abruzzo (ABR), Basilicata (BAS), Calabria (CAL), Campania (CAM), Molise (MOL), Apulia (APU), Sicily (SIC). Mean values for the period
1984–2000.

from endogeneity.9 An additional problem of indicators of formal to the sponsors” (Balconi et al., p. 133). The recent KEINS EP-INV
collaborations is that they unavoidably miss the important com- database on academic patenting (Lissoni et al., 2006) matches the
ponent of informal collaborations (Link et al., 2007).10 All these names of the inventors of the patents with a list of university pro-
arguments justify our focus on the number of university schools as fessors. Thanks to this methodology, the KEINS database includes
an indicator of university presence in the region. not only any patent owned by universities, but also all patents that
We measure regional innovation productivity by the number of involve university scientists, whether the patents are owned by
patents registered in the European Patent Office, using the loca- firms, public research organizations, universities, or the scientists
tion of inventors to determine the region where the patent is themselves. In the following we use the KEINS database to identify
produced.11,12 In order to disentangle the knowledge spillover industrial and academic patents. We observe that an average region
effect of universities from the direct effect of university R&D invest- produced annually 142 patents, seven of which were produced with
ment on patenting and the crowding out effect, we split patents into the participation of academic inventors.
two groups: those that are produced with university participation We measure the quality of innovation by the average num-
(or academic patents), and the rest (industrial patents). Note that ber of citations received by these patents before 2004. Naturally,
until recently it has been difficult to attach patenting activity to series on patent citations are subject to a truncation bias since
university research. In fact, in contrast to the US case, up to the the number of citations any patent receives grows with time, and
present, in Italy universities did not generally retain the property our data include citations received only until 2004.13 We correct
rights on inventions done by their researchers. Often “IPRs over for truncation bias following the method developed by Jaffe and
inventions derived from sponsored research programmes were left Trajtenberg (1996) in the version where the diffusion process is
assumed to have the same shape in all technological sectors.14 Fig. 3
shows the evolution of the number of patents, patent citations and
9
In Italy, there were almost no universities that adopted a patent or technology
corrected citations in industrial and academic sectors. Patents, both
transfer policy until 1996 (see Baldini et al., 2006), so this is not an option for our
analysis.
10
However, it is likely that the intensity of informal collaboration is correlated
with formal collaboration activities due to potential complementarities (Cohen et al.,
2002; Grimpe and Hussinger, 2008).
11 13
Specifically, the database includes all patent applications that passed a prelim- More precisely, citation variables count the number of citations received by
inary examination in the EPO. The assigned date of the patent is the priority date, regional patents from all Italian patents until 2004.
14
which is the date of the first filing world-wide. Results of our analysis are not affected if instead we simply use a 5-year window
12
Patents with inventors from two different regions are counted twice. for patent citations.
R. Cowan, N. Zinovyeva / Research Policy 42 (2013) 788–800 793

times more in R&D than Southern regions. These differences are


also reflected in the number of patent applications made by inven-
tors from these regions. The gap in the innovation activity across
these regions is not due to the size effect: there are no impor-
tant population differences across the regions. There are also no
substantial differences in university presence or in the educational
level of the labor force. Broadly put, the differences in the innova-
tion activity could be attributed to a relatively low income level in
the South and to differences in industrial structure: in the North
manufacturing has a larger weight in the economy than in the
South, whereas in the South the service sector and agriculture are
relatively more important.16

4. Empirical analysis

We start by observing simple correlations between the num-


ber of new schools opened in a region and the variation in various
indicators of research and innovation activity (Table 2). First, we
analyze whether the opening of new schools is associated with
an increase in academic research activity. We find that university
expansion is associated with the growth of university R&D stock
in the region observed about two-five years later (column 1). Sim-
ilarly, higher university presence is associated with the rise of the
number of scientific publications even within the next three years
(column 2). We do not observe any clear (significant at standard
level of 5%) relationship between university expansion and the
growth of academic patenting within first five years (column 3).
Second, we analyze the relationship between university expan-
sion and the growth of industrial innovation activity. We find that
(4,8]
(2,4] there is a positive correlation between university expansion and the
[0,2] growth of industrial patenting a few years later (column 4), even
though new university units are not associated with the growth of
Fig. 2. Location of schools created during 1985–2000 across Italian regions. The
private R&D and income per capita (columns 5 and 6).17
colors indicate numbers of schools opened: dark gray indicates that between 5 and
8 schools were opened in the region over the entire period; light gray, 3 or 4; pale Though suggestive, the results in Table 2 should be considered
gray, between 0 and 2. with caution. In principle, the creation of new schools might be not
independent of regional innovation activity. In addition, the above
correlations could be confounded by characteristics of the economy
industrial and academic, and citations to them grew steadily over
which vary simultaneously with university expansion and regional
the period.15
innovation. In the following we make explicit the assumptions of
Information on professors’ publication records are obtained
our identification strategy and analyze the above findings in more
from ISI Web of Science. We use all publications from 1984 to 2000
detail.
having at least one coauthor with an Italian affiliation. We observe
citations received by these publications up to 2009. An average Ital-
4.1. Empirical model and identification strategy
ian region has produced more than a thousand publications a year;
on average a publication has received about 17 citations.
The main problem we seek to address is the possibility of circular
The extent to which technological innovations rely on scientific
causation between university research and industrial innovation.
knowledge is measured by the propensity of patents to cite non-
In order to address it, we analyze and build upon the standard
patent literature (NPL). Not surprisingly, we observe that patents
reduced-form relationship between industrial innovation output,
with inventors from academia draw more on scientific knowledge
Pi,t , and the number of schools in the region, Ui,t ,
than pure industrial patents (column 1, Table 1).
We use information from the Italian National Statistical Bureau Pi,t = ˛ + ˇUi,t + Xi,t ␥ + ct + ci + i,t (1)
on several regional characteristics including private and public
spending on research and development, value-added produced by The simplest way to avoid potential simultaneity problem in model
different economic sectors (industry, services, agriculture and con- (1) is to consider the right-hand-side variables – including univer-
struction), population, population aged 19, and the proportion of sity presence – with a time lag. The time lag between university
university graduates in the labor force. We apply the depreciation presence and innovation activity could be also justified since the
coefficient used by Gordon (1990) (19.3%) to the time-series of R&D effects of institutional changes could take time to realize (see the
investment in order to construct an indicator of the stock of R&D above findings in Table 2). Below we consider the right-hand-side
facilities available in a region.
Note that the intensity of innovation activity is very heteroge-
neous across Italian regions (columns 3–8, Table 1). Between 1984 16
Evangelista et al. (2001) also observe that, according to the 1995 wave of the
and 2000, regions in the North of Italy were investing almost ten Community Innovation Survey, there are very few science-based firms in the South.
Regionally disaggregated data are not available in later CIS waves.
17
Note that the difference between the effect of new schools on industrial patent-
ing observed in years 3, 4, and 5 is not statistically significant. Throughout the paper,
15
Other ways to treat the truncation bias in citations are discussed in the Appendix we adopt the conventional level of significance – p-value less than 5%. The estimates
A. with p-value between 5% and 10% are considered as marginally significant.
794 R. Cowan, N. Zinovyeva / Research Policy 42 (2013) 788–800

Table 2
Correlation between new school opening and variations in the indicators of private and public research activity.

Number of years after (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)


school opening
University R&D stock Publications Academic patents Industrial patents Private R&D stock VA per capita

−2 n/a −0.074 0.025 −0.036 0.042 0.099


−1 −0.173 0.005 −0.103 −0.058 0.018 0.001
0 0.184 0.031 0.130* 0.021 −0.020 −0.061
1 0.189 0.155** −0.132* −0.056 −0.021 −0.074
2 0.267** 0.226*** −0.072 0.006 −0.034 −0.112
3 0.287*** 0.111* 0.032 0.141** −0.018 −0.039
4 0.250*** 0.016 0.059 0.096 0.006 0.046
5 0.249*** 0.071 0.011 0.142** 0.016 −0.036

n/a: not available.


*
p-Value <0.100.
**
p-Value <0.050.
***
p-Value <0.010.

variables with a 5-year lag. Nevertheless, given the presence of correlated with university presence. Given the panel structure of
strong autocorrelation in the data, lagging independent variables our data, we can account for ci in two ways: using a fixed effect
is likely to be insufficient to avoid endogeneity. estimator (or, equivalently, including the regional dummies among
In order to capture some differences across regions, we include controls) or using a difference estimator. Below we report results
an extensive list of observable regional characteristics among the obtained using the first-difference estimator. We note, though, that
controls, Xi,t . The size of the region – both in terms of population, fixed effect estimation produces results that are statistically simi-
especially younger population, and in terms of economic produc- lar to the ones presented here. We prefer the difference estimator
tion – may reflect inherent local demand for higher education as to the fixed effect specification since the former does not require
well as the propensity to innovate. Therefore we control for popu- strictly exogenous regressors (that is, it does not require that indus-
lation, the proportion of 19 year olds, and aggregate value-added. trial innovation has no impact on future right-hand-side variables
Industrial composition affects the propensity of a region to patent. included in Xi,t , such as value added and R&D) (Wooldridge, 2002).
This in turn may affect the value of certain types of high-skilled With regard to the count nature of our dependent variable, in the
human capital and so the ability of a region to lobby the central following we adopt the traditional approach of modeling regional
government for more university resources. Thus, we control for innovation activity using a log–log relationship between university
proportions of regional value-added in industry, construction, ser- presence and regional patents (Jaffe, 1989; Feldman and Florida,
vices and agriculture. An additional control for industrial structure 1994). We prefer this model to a negative binomial specification
is the share of graduates in the local labor force. Public non- for two reasons. First, given that the mean number of regional
university R&D and private R&D both affect industrial patenting, patents is quite high (134 patents, see Table 1 for more details),
and may reflect a general attitude towards the value of knowl- the negative binomial distribution is essentially normal and the
edge production and training, thus again affecting the ability to log–log model provides a good approximation. Second, the linear
lobby for more university resources. We include both controls in model permits capturing region-specific effects without imposing
our estimations. the strong exogeneity assumption. Performing a negative binomial
University expansion was stronger in the 1990s than in the estimation with predetermined regressors requires a GMM esti-
1980s, coinciding with the rapid growth of innovation activity (see mation for which our sample size is not sufficiently large (Blundell
Figs. 1 and 3). In other words, the timing of university expansion et al., 2002).
generally might be not independent of the time trend affecting Ultimately, our identifying assumption is that the error term,
innovation activity, ct . In order to account for time effects influenc- i,t , is uncorrelated with university presence in the region once
ing all regions simultaneously, we introduce a set of year dummies regional time-invariant effects, time effects and observable time-
among the controls. varying characteristics are taken into account. In other words, we
Notwithstanding the inclusion of the above controls, one might assume that during the analyzed period no variations in regional
suspect that regions differ on other perhaps non-observable dimen- characteristics (apart from the ones included in Xi,t ) affected both
sions, and these differences might explain both the university the variation in the number of university schools and the varia-
presence in the region and the development of innovation activ- tion in the regional innovation 5-years later. Is this assumption
ity. In other words, unobserved regional effects, ci , might be justified?

Fig. 3. Evolution of academic (left panel) and industrial (right panel) innovation outcomes in Italy, 1985–2000.
R. Cowan, N. Zinovyeva / Research Policy 42 (2013) 788–800 795

of the fit of educational supply to local demand for skilled labor


in a region-discipline (measured as the number of new graduates
incorporated in the labor force over the number of new gradua-
tes from local universities) versus the number of new schools in
each region-discipline.18 An economically driven policy might aim
to locate schools in regions that were importing skilled labor, lead-
ing to a positive correlation between university expansion and our
measure of the fit of educational supply. Visually, no positive corre-
lation is apparent, and indeed, the correlation between educational
fit and the number of new schools in a corresponding discipline
and region is on aggregate −0.055. Again, this is consistent with
the MURST analogy between school creation and drops of rain.
Overall, the above evidence implies that exploiting the variation
in the number of schools within regions across time allows con-
sistent estimation of the effect of university presence on regional
innovation.
Fig. 4. Number of new schools opened between 1984 and 2000 by regional demand
for corresponding professions.
4.2. Regional innovation activity

Quantity. The estimation results for model (1) with innovation


To answer this question we need to understand the factors that
activity being measured by the (log) number of industrial patents
influenced university expansion. As was acknowledged by policy
are presented in Table 4. We find that opening a new univer-
makers ex post, the distribution of new units across the regions
sity school significantly increases regional innovation activity. The
was largely independent of regional labor market demands. The
coefficients here are elasticities, so an increase of one percent in the
openings seemed to be associated with an indiscriminate allocation
number of schools in a region increases industrial patenting in that
of funds across the regions. In this regard, the Observatory for the
region by 0.68 percent. The mean number of schools per region
evaluation of the university system in the Ministry of Education
is nine, and the mean number of patent applications per region
and Research (MURST) after analyzing the expansion of university
per year is 134 (Table 1), so on average, one new university school
system in the beginning of 90s concludes:
brings about ten new patent applications by regional non-academic
The rules by which new institutions were created does not seem inventors five years later.19
to have followed any logic tailoring university development to Quality. The number of patents might be an appropriate indi-
territorial specificities. It seems not to have made reference to cator to capture the quantity of innovation, but it might hide
a demand for university education (that is, responding to the important changes in quality. An observed increase in the quantity
potential scope of use of the new initiatives), nor does it seem of patents as a result of a new university school in a region does
to have made reference to the demand for graduates (the for- not guarantee that the overall value of regional innovation activity
mative needs of the country) or to existing infrastructure. In grows. Therefore it is important to analyze the effect of universities
substance, no rigorous evaluations of the initiatives were done, on the quality of the patents produced.
either in absolute terms, or concerning compatibility with the We check for effects on average patent quality, measured as
rest of the system. The criterion actually favored was geograph- the average number of citations received by regional patents. Evi-
ical re-equilibrium, which aimed to bring the offer of university dence exists suggesting that patent citations represent a valid way
education and subjects near to the demand, ignoring not only to capture patent importance. (See Jaffe et al. (2000) for exam-
the “real” size of this demand (which sometimes turned out to ple.) Specifically, we estimate Eq. (1) using the average number of
be less than the minimum requirements for the initiative to be citations to regional industrial patents as the dependent variable.
efficient and effective), but also the importance of the trans- Results are presented in column 2 of Table 4. Opening a new school
portation system, the receptive capacity of the population of has no significant effect on the number of citations per regional
students and students’ financial support in determining access patent.
to university establishments. So, [. . .] at least to a large extent, One might also ask whether not just the quality, but also other
the prevalent logic was the one of incremental expansion and patent characteristics have changed. For instance, one might be
distribution “by drops of rain”, without evaluating other ini- interested to know whether the presence of a university affects the
tiatives that were suppressed [. . .]. (p. 3, Verifica dei piani di rate with which industrial innovation draws information directly
sviluppo dell’universita 1986–90 e 1991–93, Osservatorio per from scientific publications. We use non-patent-literature (NPL)
la valutazione del sistema universitario, MURST, 1997; authors’ citations done by industrial patents to capture this patent char-
translation). acteristic. This is a very noisy measure (not least because many
citations are actually added by patent examiners (Akers, 2000)),
This evaluation of the Italian Ministry of Education and Research
but it can nevertheless reflect any substantial changes in inventors’
supports our identifying assumption. In Table 3 we also analyze the
reliance on scientific publications and basic knowledge. Still, we
contemporaneous correlation between observable regional charac-
do not observe any significant effect of new schools on the nature
teristics included in Xi,t and university expansion. Consistent with
characterization done by the Italian Ministry, observable regional
characteristics in the analyzed period seem to be poorly correlated
with university expansion. Correlation between the number of new 18
New school openings are for the period from 1985 to 2000. The mismatch ratio
schools and the contemporaneous dynamics in observed regional uses data from the triennial Italian National Statistical Bureau (ISTAT) representative
characteristics, including the growth of regional patents, is very survey of graduates, the 1995 edition, which surveys students graduating in 1992.
It covers information concerning graduates’ university-to-work transition, asking,
poor as well. inter alia, where and in what discipline they graduated, and where they work. The
Similarly, the opening of new schools does not seem to be related description of the data could be found in Bagues et al. (2008).
to the demand for particular professions. In Fig. 4 we plot the degree 19
See the Appendix A for robustness checks.
796 R. Cowan, N. Zinovyeva / Research Policy 42 (2013) 788–800

Table 3
Cross-correlation table.

Table 4
The effect of the university expansion on industrial patents.

(1) (2) (3)


Log patents Citations per patent NPL citations per patent

Log Schools 0.68*** −0.11 −0.27


(0.21) (0.32) (0.41)
Log population 0.15 2.37 −2.41
(2.67) (5.74) (3.95)
Population of 19-olds in total population 0.08 0.25 0.15
(0.16) (0.23) (0.16)
Share of graduates in the work force 0.01 −0.05 −0.06
(0.07) (0.17) (0.21)
Log private RD stock 0.19** 0.31** −1.07**
(0.09) (0.13) (0.41)
Log public (non university) RD stock 0.31 −0.79* −0.88*
(0.23) (0.40) (0.48)
VA per capita −0.04 0.04 −0.08
(0.13) (0.12) (0.19)
Share of VA produced in industrial sector −0.02 0.13* −0.05
(0.04) (0.07) (0.06)
Share of VA produced in agricultural sector 0.08 0.07 −0.23**
(0.05) (0.10) (0.09)
Share of VA produced in construction sector −0.12 0.13** −0.32**
(0.13) (0.05) (0.15)
Constant 0.23 0.74** 0.52
(0.14) (0.30) (0.45)
Year dummies Yes Yes Yes
Adjusted R-squared 0.058 0.020 0.091
Number of observations 220 220 220

Notes: First-difference model estimates. Independent variables are 5-year lagged. In parentheses standard errors clustered by region.
*
p-Value <0.100.
**
p-Value <0.050.
***
p-Value <0.010.

of industrial patenting as measured by NPL citations (column 3, innovation process. Universities can serve as knowledge sources
Table 4). when industry underinvests in private R&D.20
Interestingly, while private R&D tends to increase the quan-
tity and the quality of produced industrial patents, it is negatively
related to the degree to which industrial inventors rely on scientific
publications. One interpretation of the negative effect is that pri- 20
Again this must be treated cautiously since many citations are entered in a patent
vate R&D and local academic research can serve as substitutes in the not by the inventors but by examiners.
R. Cowan, N. Zinovyeva / Research Policy 42 (2013) 788–800 797

Table 5
The effect of the university expansion on the number of regional industrial patents.

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10)

Geographic location Value added per capita R&D stock Graduates in the Industrial
labor force VA/agricultural VA

Center and South North Low High Low High Low High Low High

Log Schools 0.90*** −0.05 1.01*** −0.06 0.79** 0.45 1.04* 0.77** 0.57** 0.86
(0.13) (0.36) (0.29) (0.18) (0.32) (0.35) (0.57) (0.28) (0.25) (0.63)
Number of observations 88 132 110 110 110 110 110 110 110 110

Notes: First-difference model estimates. Regional characteristics and year dummies are included in all regressions. Independent variables are 5-year lagged. In parentheses
standard errors clustered by region. Regions with high level of VA per capita (abbreviations are the same as in Table 1, in parentheses – the year when a region first reaches
the median): ABR (1997), EMR (1991), FVG (1994), LAZ (1991), LIG (1995), LOM, MAR (1995), MOL (2000), PIE (1991), TAA, TUS (1993), UMB (1995), VEN (1995), AOS (1989).
Regions with high level of private R&D: ABR (1992), CAM, EMR, FVG (1990), LAZ, LIG, LOM, PIE, SIC (1998), TUS, VEN. Regions with high ratio of industrial VA to agricultural
VA: ABR (2000), EMR (1989), FVG (1988), LAZ (1986), LIG (1986), LOM, MAR (1991), PIE, TUS, UMB (1988), VEN, AOS.
*
p-Value <0.100.
**
p-Value <0.050.
***
p-Value <0.010.

Regional heterogeneity. A natural question is whether these innovation as innovation done without academic inventors. There-
effects hold uniformly across regions, or whether regions with dif- fore the observed increase in industrial patenting after new school
ferent economic development respond differently. In Table 5 we creation captures a spillover effect of university on industrial sector.
explore whether university spillovers differ by the type of region. In this section we ask whether it is possible to identify the type
The results suggest that the strongest spillover effect occurs in of university expertise that generates this spillover effect on indus-
the center and in the south of Italy (columns 1 and 2). As we have try. Specifically, we are interested in understanding whether firms
mentioned before, southern and central regions differ from the are benefiting from university capability to produce frontier scien-
northern regions in the level of income, private R&D investment tific research, from a more applied inventive potential of academic
and industrial structure. To test whether these characteristics of the researchers or from other types of human capital or endowments.
economy are in fact conditioning the strength of the spillover effect, Understanding the type of expertise that is effectively transferred
we analyze how the effect differs across regions with different load- from university to local industry may be important for the design
ings along these dimensions. Specifically, for each dimension, we of university incentive structures.
split the regions according to the median values of each variable. University capability to produce frontier scientific research
Note that regions can move from one group to another across time. can be measured by the current publication records of profes-
We observe that regions with low per capita income benefit sors employed in a university. A quality-adjusted measure would
from knowledge spillovers from universities, whereas, on average, weight the importance of each publication by its impact in terms
no positive university effect could be observed for high income of received citations. This is a common way to characterize the
regions (columns 3 and 4). Regions that have relatively low levels of quality of academic researchers and there seems to be a trend now
R&D and those with a less educated labor force benefit more from towards making evaluation and incentives for researchers formally
universities (column 5–8). In less industrialized regions universi- related to their (quality-adjusted) publication records. We define
ties have a significant effect on innovation. In more industrialized the quality weighted measure of scientific publications as the total
regions the effect of universities is potentially larger, but is very citations received between date of publication and 2009. Recently,
noisy and not statistically significant (columns 9 and 10).21 in addition, there has been an emphasis on academic patenting:
To summarize, we have observed that an increase in the num- in a variety of ways academic researchers have been encouraged
ber of schools is followed by an increase in industrial innovation to patent their findings, possibly in collaboration with firms. Pro-
activity in the region: the number of industrial patents increases. fessors’ patents (and the number of citations received by these
The effect of new schools depends on the economic characteristics patents) is our measure of academics’ inventive potential. These are
of the region: poorer regions with relatively low human capital and both topical measures, since today publications and especially aca-
low investment in R&D benefit most from university presence. The demic patents are often used to measure university contribution
average characteristics of industrial patents seem not to change to economic activity. In this section we ask to what extent these
with university presence, at least in the very short run. This sug- measures of academic research activity can explain the effects we
gests that in the short run the new industrial patents induced by have found in the previous section.
the creation of new schools are on average not different from the We undertake the following accounting exercise. To the pre-
rest of industrial patents. vious model, we add variables representing our measures of
professors’ expertise, and ask how their inclusion affects the esti-
4.3. Type of knowledge transfer mated coefficient of the number of schools. Specifically we include
in model (1) publications and academic patents as well as their
In the previous section we found that at the regional level, uni- citations, Puni
i,t :
versity presence has a positive influence on the quantity of indus-
trial innovation. Recall that in our analysis we define industrial Pi,t = ˛ + ˇUi,t + Xi,t ␥ + Puni
i,t ␦ + ct + ci + i,t (2)

Note that scientific articles and academic patents might take up


21
The number of new schools is not sufficiently large to perform detailed hetero- to several years to be published or listed in EPO. Additionally, it
geneity analysis of the effect of different types of schools. However, according to might take some time for schools to hire the necessary staff. So to
our data, the strongest effects were generated by schools in medicine, chemistry
and pharmacy, veterinary, and agriculture. Science and engineering schools have
capture correctly the increase in the regional human capital due to
stronger effects only in relatively more industrialized regions. Results are available the opening of new university schools one would need to consider
upon request. the change in publications and academic patents over several years.
798 R. Cowan, N. Zinovyeva / Research Policy 42 (2013) 788–800

Table 6
Explaining the effect of schools on industrial patents.

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7)

Log Schools 0.68*** 0.70*** 0.48** 0.41 0.69*** 0.70*** 0.70***


(0.21) (0.24) (0.19) (0.29) (0.24) (0.23) (0.24)
Publications Yes Yes
Publication citations Yes Yes
Academic patents Yes Yes
Academic patent citations Yes Yes
Adjusted R-squared 0.058 0.093 0.075 0.104 0.050 0.038 0.027
Number of observations 220 220 220 220 220 220 220

Notes: First-difference model estimates. Regional characteristics and year dummies are included in all regressions. Independent variables are 5-year lagged. In parentheses
standard errors clustered by region. All lags of publication and patent indicators are included. In parentheses standard errors clustered by region. The variance inflation factor
(VIF) of Log Schools in column 4 is 1.45.
*
p-Value <0.100.
**
p-Value <0.050.
***
p-Value <0.010.

Consequently, we allow the effect to be distributed in time and ing the 1980s and 1990s in an attempt to identify the effect of
include all lags of our measures in Punii,t . university presence on regional innovation. According to ex post
A positive ˇ in Eq. (1) signals the existence of a causal relation- evaluation of the expansion programmes, university schools were
ship between the opening of a new school and regional innovation created “like rain”, independently of underlying economic features
output. However, if the inclusion of Puni i,t in Eq. (2) reduces of the regions. This experiment permits a nice way out of standard
significantly the size of ˇ relative to its value in Eq. (1), we can endogeneity problems.
claim that the corresponding university research output proxies at Our first result indicates that there is indeed a significant effect
least one type of human capital which is effectively translated into of the creation of new university schools on regional innovation
regional innovation. If, controlling for professors’ publications and activity. Industrial patenting activity in the region increases quite
academic patents, we still observe a significant residual effect of significantly even within five years of a new school opening. Thus
universities on industrial patenting, we might conclude that there the general impression seems to be correct: university activity is
is something beyond the academic human capital captured by positively correlated with local innovation activity, and a policy
publications and academic patents that generates positive effects tool to increase the latter is indeed to increase the former.
on industrial innovation. The effect of new schools depends on the economic character-
Note that university publications and academic patents are istics of the area. Poor regions with low levels of R&D and human
potentially endogenous to industrial patenting. An active indus- capital investment are the ones that benefit most from an increase
trial R&D sector could generate spillover effects inducing university in university presence. This suggests that one role of universities is
activity, perhaps directly as industry seeks partners, or through to fill gaps in missing R&D infrastructure. If this is the case, and if
some less direct, spillover mechanism. On the other hand, for var- there are positive feedbacks in innovation dynamics, then opening
ious cost efficiency reasons, firms might engage in collaboration a university in an innovation-poor region can be an effective part of
with university crowding out their independent research. There- a development strategy for that region. Our results suggest that in
fore we do not interpret the estimated direct effects of publications an initial period when the region is poorly endowed with “innova-
and academic patents here. tion assets”, the university presence can compensate. This, under
The results are presented in Table 6. The first, very clear observa- the proviso that other necessary assets are present, could help to
tion is that academic patenting (columns 5, 6, and 7) captures none push a region onto a higher innovation path.
of the effects of university presence on industrial innovation. Exper- How are these benefits created? Marshall might suggest that it
tise in applied knowledge generation inside a university seems to arises simply from the agglomeration of agents pursuing related
have little effect on local industrial innovativeness. Second, exper- activities; Mike Lazaridis22 asserts that it arises through the pro-
tise measured by a simple count of publications (column 2) also duction of highly trained graduates; supporters of the Bayh-Dole
seems completely ineffective. However, if we include quality in the act assert that it comes from controlled technology transfer through
measure of expertise (column 3) the coefficient on Log Schools falls academic patenting. Given the time frame we examine, namely
by roughly 30 percent. Including both quantity and quality (column effects within 5 years of a school opening, we exclude from the
4) reduces the coefficient by about 40 percent, and it becomes sta- analysis any effects of universities driven by the new graduates
tistically insignificant. This suggests that what matters from the who enter regional labor markets. To address the question of other
point of view of industrial innovation is to have a local univer- channels through which this influence flows, we have performed an
sity producing a significant amount of high-quality research. Strict accounting exercise estimating how the gross effect of increasing
interpretation of statistical significance would imply that high qual- the number of universities is affected when we add to the model
ity research is all that matters, however the size of the coefficient proxies of factors that might be intermediary in the process. The
and its high standard error suggests some caution, and opens the factors that we focus on include professors’ ability to produce scien-
door to the possibility that there is something more, not captured tific research and their ability to produce patentable inventions. We
by standard measures of university output. measure the former by the number of ISI publications and the latter
by the number of patent applications done with the participation
5. Conclusions of academic inventors.
We observe that the human capital associated with traditional
In this paper we focus on the economic effects of universi- university production, as measured by scientific publications and
ties, and in particular on their effects on innovation. It is widely their citations, has a strong effect on innovation, whereas academic
believed that the presence of a university in a region is benefi-
cial for industrial innovation activity. We have taken advantage
of certain unusual features of university expansion in Italy dur- 22
Founder and former CEO of Research in Motion, maker of the Blackberry.
R. Cowan, N. Zinovyeva / Research Policy 42 (2013) 788–800 799

patents cannot explain observed university effects. At the same Appendix A. Robustness and specification checks
time, we do not exclude the possibility that other types of aca-
demic human capital, apart from the ability to produce frontier A.1. Measurement of patent characteristics
research, could be relevant as well. Such competences as collecting,
generalizing and classifying existent knowledge might be relevant In our dataset we observe information on patents only until
for industrial inventors. 2004. There exist several ways to tackle the truncation problem
Universities perform many activities, and contain many vari- in citations for recent patents. Our preferred method is to extrapo-
eties of skill and knowledge. Almost certainly it is a mixture of skills late citations using the method proposed by Jaffe and Trajtenberg
and knowledge that serves the interests of the local economy. How- (1996). Alternatively, one can impose the same truncation bias on
ever, the results presented in this paper suggest that it is possible all observations and count only those citations that were received
to tilt the skill set in directions that are not in fact useful. They sug- within a certain time window after patent filing. Another alter-
gest that forcing universities to change tack towards more applied native would be to normalize citations for patents submitted in
research may not, in fact, provide for the needs of local industry. the same year. In order to account for different propensities to cite
At the very least, introducing patenting activity as a new measure across fields of science and technology, one could also normalize
of university performance may not capture what matters, and, in citations within the same field.
the face of Goodheart’s law, as a policy tool to make universities Table A.1 summarizes estimations for (i) extrapolated patent
more relevant to industry may be self-defeating. The traditional citations, (ii) patent citations received within 5 years after publi-
tool that values high-quality scientific research may remain more cation, and (iii) patent citations normalized by the year of patent
to the point. publication and patent class group. None of these definitions
reveals any effect of new schools on patent quality.
Acknowledgements Given that potentially there might be differences across patent
classes in the propensity to refer to scientific literature, we also redo
We would like to acknowledge the inputs of members of the estimations for non-patent literature citations normalizing them
KEINS project, and particularly Francesco Lissoni and Bulat Sandi- for patents within the same type of patent class and year. Once
tov, for their gracious openness and valuable help with the data. We again, we do not observe any significant effect of new schools on
are also grateful to Francesco Quatraro who provided us with the the propensity to refer to scientific literature.
historic data on Italian regional R&D collected from various issues
of ISTAT. We also acknowledge the helpful comments of Bronwyn A.2. Time clustering of new schools’ opening
Hall, Jacques Mairesse, Joel Baum and all the participants of XXXII
Symposium of Economic Analysis in Granada and DIME Confer- In the paper we hypothesize that the short time span (5-years)
ence “Knowledge Based Entrepreneurship: Innovation, Networks, considered after the opening of new schools allows us to exclude
and System” in Milan. This research was supported by the DYREC the knowledge transfers occurring through graduates. Still, if there
Chaire d’ Excellence of Robin Cowan, funded by the French ANR, exists time clustering in the opening of new schools within a region,
and grants from ESF COST and APE-INV projects. this might affect the interpretation of our results. To avoid this

Table A.1
Measurement of patent characteristics.

Extrapolated citations 5-Year window after publication Normalized for patents of the
same year and patent class

a) Citations per patent


Log Schools −0.11 −0.16 −0.09
(0.32) (0.26) (0.17)
R-squared 0.109 0.147 0.107
Number of observations 220 220 220

Absolute number Normalized for patents of the


same year and patent class

b) NPL citations per patent


Log Schools −0.27 −0.10
(0.41) (0.23)
R-squared 0.174 0.216
Number of observations 220 220

Notes: First-difference model estimates. Regional characteristics and year dummies are included in all regressions. Independent variables are 5-year lagged. In parentheses
standard errors clustered by region. *p-Value <0.100, **p-Value <0.050, ***p-Value <0.010.

Table A.2
Time clustering of new schools’ opening.

All observations No openings for at least 3 years Rest of observations Excluding Lombardy, Lazio and
before considered period Emilia Romagna

Log Schools 0.68*** 1.13*** 0.80 0.65***


(0.21) (0.44) (0.59) (0.21)
R-squared 0.144 0.229 0.272 0.148
Number of observations 220 94 126 187

Notes: First-difference model estimates. Regional characteristics and year dummies are included in all regressions. Independent variables are 5-year lagged. In parentheses
standard errors clustered by region. *p-Value <0.100, **p-Value <0.050.
***
p-Value <0.010.
800 R. Cowan, N. Zinovyeva / Research Policy 42 (2013) 788–800

problem we have always clustered standard errors for observa- Dorfman, N., 1983. Route 128: the development of a regional high technology econ-
tions belonging to the same region, allowing them to be correlated omy. Research Policy 12, 299–316.
D’Este, P., Patel, P., 2007. University–industry linkages in the UK: what are the fac-
within region across time. We also perform estimations only on the tors underlying the variety of interactions with industry? Research Policy 36,
subsample of observations, for which there were no prior school 1295–1313.
openings during at least 3 years. Results are presented in Table A.2. Evangelista, R., Iammarino, S., Mastrostefano, V., Silvani, A., 2001. Measuring the
regional dimension of innovation. Lessons from the Italian Innovation Survey.
The estimates, if anything, are large on this subsample. Technovation 21, 733–745.
We also perform estimations on the subsample of regions Feldman, M.P., 1994a. The university and economic development: the case of Johns
excluding outliers in terms of university expansion and innovation Hopkins University and Baltimore. Economic Development Quarterly 8, 67–76.
Feldman, M.P., 1994b. Knowledge complementarity and innovation. Small Business
– Piedmont, Lombardy and Emilia-Romagna. 22 of 65 new schools
Economics 6, 363–372.
were opened in these three regions and the average R&D stock Feldman, M.P., Florida, R., 1994. The geographic sources of innovation: technolog-
here is four times bigger than the country average. Once again, our ical infrastructure and product innovation in the United States. Annals of the
Association of American Geographers 84, 210–229.
results are robust to the exclusion of these outliers.
Gordon, R., 1990. Measurement of Durable Goods Prices. University of Chicago Press
(for NBER), Chicago.
References Grimpe, C., Hussinger, K., 2008. Formal and Informal Technology Transfer from
Academia to Industry: Complementarity Effects and Innovation Performance.
ZEW discussion paper 08-080.
Abramovsky, L., Harrison, R., Simpson, H., 2007. University research and the location
Hall, B.H., Jaffe, A., Trajtenberg, M., 2001. The NBER Patent Citations Data File:
of business R&D. The Economic Journal 117, C114–C141.
Lessons, Insights And Methodological Tools. NBER Working Paper Series 8498.
Acs, Z.J., Audretsch, D.B., Feldman, M.P., 1992. Real effects of academic research:
Hall, B.H., Link, A.N., Scott, J.T., 2003. Universities as research partners. The Review
comment. The American Economic Review 92 (1), 363–367.
of Economics and Statistics 85, 485–491.
Agrawal, A., Henderson, R., 2002. Putting patents in context: exploring knowledge
Henderson, R., Jaffe, A.B., Trajtenberg, M., 1998. Universities as a source of com-
transfer from MIT. Management Science 48, 44–60.
mercial technology: a detailed analysis of university patenting 1965–1988.
Akers, N., 2000. The referencing of prior art documents in European patents and
Econometrica 52, 909–938.
applications. World Patent Information 22, 309–315.
Jaffe, A.B., 1989. Real effects of academic research. The American Economic Review
Andersson, R., Quigley, J.M., Wilhelmsson, M., 2009. Urbanization, productivity, and
79 (5), 957–970.
innovation: evidence from investment in higher education. Journal of Urban
Jaffe, A.B., Trajtenberg, M., 1996. Flows of knowledge from universities and federal
Economics 66, 2–15.
labs: modeling the flow of patent citations over time and across institutional
Arundel, A., Geuna, A., 2004. Proximity and the use of public science by innovative
and geographic boundaries. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of
European firms. Economics of Innovation and New Technology 13, 559–580.
the United States of America 93, 12671–12677.
Audretsch, D., Stephan, P., 1996. Company-scientist locational links: the case of
Jaffe, A.B., Trajtenberg, M., Fogarty, M., 2000. The Meaning of Patent Citations: Report
biotechnology. The American Economic Review 86 (3), 641–652.
on the NBER/Case-Western Reserve Survey of Patentees. NBER Working Paper,
Bagues, M., Sylos Labini, M., Zinovyeva, N., 2008. Differential grading standards and
7631.
university funding: evidence from Italy. CESifo Economic Studies 54, 149–176.
Jaffe, A.B., Trajtenberg, M., Henderson, R., 1993. Geographic localization of knowl-
Balconi, M., Breschi, S., Lissoni, F., 2004. Networks of inventors and the role of
edge spillovers as evidenced by patent citations. Quarterly Journal of Economics
academia: an exploration of Italian patent data. Research Policy 33, 127–145.
108, 577–598.
Baldini, N., Grimaldi, R., Sobrero, M., 2006. Institutional changes and the commer-
Link, A.N., Siegel, D.S., Bozeman, B., 2007. An empirical analysis of the propensity of
cialization of academic knowledge: a study of Italian universities’ patenting
academic to engage in informal university technology transfer. Industrial and
activities between 1965 and 2002. Research Policy 35, 518–532.
Corporate Change 16, 641–655.
Bekkers, R., Bodas Freitas, I.M., 2008. Analysing knowledge transfer channels
Lissoni, F., Sanditov, B., Tarasconi, G., 2006. Keins database on academic inventors:
between universities and industry: to what degree do sectors also matter?
methodology and contents. CESPRI Working Paper 181.
Research Policy 37, 1837–1853.
Loof, H., Brostrom, A., 2008. Does knowledge diffusion between university and
Blundell, Richard, Griffith, Rachel, Windmeijer, Frank, 2002. Individual effects and
industry increase innovativeness? Journal of Technology Transfer 33, 73–90.
dynamics in count data models. Journal of Econometrics 108, 113–131.
Lundvall, B., 1992. National Systems of Innovation. Pinter Publishers, London.
Bottazzi, L., Peri, G., 2003. Innovation and spillovers in regions: evidence from Euro-
Mairesse, J., Mohnen, P., 2010. Using innovation surveys for econometric analysis.
pean patent data. European Economic Review 47, 610–687.
In: Hall, B.H., Rosenberg, N. (Eds.), Handbook of the Economics of Innovation.
Bratti, M., Checchi, D., de Blasio, G., 2008. Does the expansion of higher education
Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp. 1130–1155.
increase the equality of educational opportunities? Evidence from Italy. Bank of
Ponds, R., van Oort, F., Frenken, K., 2010. Innovation, spillovers and
Italy Working Paper 679.
university–industry collaboration: an extended knowledge production
Breschi, M.S., Lissoni, F., 2009. Mobility of skilled workers and co-invention
function approach. Journal of Economic Geography 10, 231–255.
networks: an anatomy of localized knowledge flows. Journal of Economic Geog-
Rogers, E., Larsen, J., 1984. Silicon Valley Fever. Basic Books, New York.
raphy 9, 439–468.
Saxenian, A., 1985. Silicon Valley and Route 128: regional prototypes or historic
Carayol, N., Matt, M., 2004. Does research organization influence academic pro-
exceptions? In: Castells, M. (Ed.), High Technology, Space and Society. Sage
duction? Laboratory level evidence from a large European university. Research
Publications, Beverly Hills and London, pp. 81–105.
Policy 33, 1081–1102.
Stephan, P.E., 1996. The economics of science. Journal of Economic Literature 34,
Cassiman, B., Veugelers, R., Zuniga, P., 2008. In search of performance effects
1199–1235.
of (in)direct industry science links. Industrial and Corporate Change 17,
Stephan, P.E., Gurmu, S., Sumell, A.J., Black, G., 2007. Who’s patenting in the univer-
611–646.
sity? Evidence from the survey of doctorate recipients. Economics of Innovation
Cohen, W.M., Nelson, R.R., Walsh, J.P., 2002. Links and impacts: the influence of
and New Technology 16, 71–99.
public research on industrial R&D. Management Science 48, 1–23.
Wooldridge, J.M., 2002. Econometric Analysis of Cross Section and Panel Data. MIT
Cowan, R., David, P.A., Foray, D., 2000. The explicit economics of knowledge codifi-
Press, Cambridge and London.
cation and tacitness. Industrial and Corporate Change 9, 211–253.
Zucker, L.G., Darby, M.R., Armstrong, J., 1998. Geographically localized knowledge
Dasgupta, P., David, P.A., 1994. Toward a new economics of science. Research Policy
spillovers or markets? Economic Inquiry 36, 65–86.
23, 487–521.

You might also like