You are on page 1of 6

Multivariate Cointegration Analysis and the Long-Run Validity of PPP

Author(s): Peter Kugler and Carlos Lenz


Source: The Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 75, No. 1 (Feb., 1993), pp. 180-184
Published by: The MIT Press
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/2109645 .
Accessed: 25/06/2014 06:45

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at .
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp

.
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of
content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms
of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

The MIT Press is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The Review of
Economics and Statistics.

http://www.jstor.org

This content downloaded from 193.105.154.120 on Wed, 25 Jun 2014 06:45:57 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
180 THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS

MULTIVARIATE COINTEGRATION ANALYSIS


AND THE LONG-RUN VALIDITY OF PPP

Peter Kugler and Carlos Lenz*

Abstract-This papertests the long-runvalidityof PPP using (1990).1 This maximum likelihood approach allows test-
Johansen's multivariatecointegrationmethodologyon ex- ing for PPP in a trivariate framework and avoids some
change rates and domesticand foreignprice levels. Monthly
data coveringthe recent flexibleexchangerate period of the drawbacks of the Engle/Granger regression methodol-
DM vis 'avis 15 currencieslead to the followingconclusion: ogy. Monthly data for DM exchange rates against 15
PPP seems to hold in the long run for six Europeancurren- currencies are considered. The DM was selected as a
cies: the Pound, Lira, NorwegianKrone, Schilling,Escudo base currency as it is clearly the most important cur-
and Peseta. However,PPP has to be rejectedfor the United
States and the CanadianDollar as well as for the Belgian rency in Europe and one of the three most important
Franc and the Danish Krone. Nevertheless,our analysisis currencies in the world.
more favourableto PPP as a long-runpropertyof exchange The contents of this paper are organised as follows:
rates than the recent work applyingthe Engle/Granger re- Section II discusses the general problem of testing
gressionmethodology. PPP. A brief account of the methodology is given in
section III. The empirical results are reported in sec-
I. Introduction tion IV and section V provides concluding remarks.
The post-1973 period of floating exchange rates is
II. Testing PPP in the Long Run
characterized by a high degree of volatility of most
major exchange rates. In particular, the variance of the Consider the following relationship between the
rate of change in exchange rates is much higher than nominal exchange rate Et (domestic currency price of
the variance of international inflation differentials. foreign currency) and the domestic and foreign price
Thus, it is not surprising that the hypothesis of the levels P, and P,*, respectively,
collapse of purchasing power parity (PPP) theory dur-
ing the seventies introduced by Frenkel (1981), became Et = A(P/P,*)exp(q,t), t = 1, 2, ..., n (1)
popular among economists. However, this evidence where mq,is a zero mean stochastic error term captur-
concerns the short-run validity of PPP, whereas most ing all short-run deviations from PPP. Denoting logs by
economists consider PPP to be a long-run property of lower case letters, we arrive at the linear relationship
exchange rates and relative price levels. The recently
developed unit root and cointegration methodology et a= + p-p* + -1tt =1,29 ... ., n. (2)
offers a more appropriate econometric test of the long- The absolute version of PPP states that A is equal to
run validity of PPP. Indeed, some recent papers have one, or equivalently, that (2) holds with the additional
applied univariate unit root tests to real exchange rates restriction a = 0. This absolute version of PPP is a
or Engle/Granger (1987) bivariate cointegration tests very strong hypothesis and is not considered by most
to exchange rates and relative price levels to assess the economists to be the relevant one.2 If we assume that
validity of PPP during the past floating rate period Pt and P,* (as measured by price indices) cover both
(see, e.g., Baillie/Selover (1987); Corbae/Ouliaris traded and non-traded goods, then A is generally
(1988); Huizinga (1987); Lothian (1987); and Taylor different from one and depends on real factors in both
(1988)). In general, the evidence found in these papers countries. This is often called the relative version of
does not support the long-run validity of PPP. PPP. However, (2) remains valid as a relationship be-
However, an Engle/Granger cointegration analysis of tween the level of et, Pt and p* provided that relative
monthly exchange rates and relative price levels in the prices of traded and non-traded goods revert to a
1920s (Taylor/MacMahon (1988)) and of annual data long-run constant mean.
covering 1900-1987 (Kim (1990)) does find evidence The series et, pt and p* are likely to be non-sta-
favouring PPP. tionary, i.e., they have to be differenced once in order
This paper tests the long-run validity of PPP, apply- to become stationary. However, PPP theory tells us
ing the multivariate cointegration methodology pro- that these non-stationary series are connected by a
posed by Johansen (1988) and Johansen and Juselius relationship with a stationary error term. That is, they
1
Received for publication November 8, 1990. Revision ac- Kim (1990) uses Johansen's approach to test for common
cepted for publication November 13, 1991. trends of exchange rates and price levels of several countries,
* Volkswirtschaftliches Institut, Bern. respectively.
2
Helpful comments of two anonymous referees are gratefully In addition, this version of PPP obviously cannot be tested
acknowledged. Of course, all remaining errors are ours. using price indices data.

Copyright ? 1993

This content downloaded from 193.105.154.120 on Wed, 25 Jun 2014 06:45:57 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
NOTES 181

are cointegrated as defined by Engle and Granger. elements of Z, may be I(1). If the series are non-sta-
Thus, we can test the long-run validity of PPP in the tionary, the long-run relationship in levels is given by
sense of (2) by using the recently developed cointegra- (5). Given the I(0) characteristic of qit, it is evident
tion methodology. that the long-run behaviour of the p elements of Zt is
determined by p - r common trends.
III. Johansen's Cointegration Analysis Given the rank property for rk, we may write

Let us define a vector Z, consisting of p = 3 ele- -rk = apt (6)


ments
where ,3 is the p times r matrix of cointegrating
Z'= [ep,pJ*]. vectors and a is a suitable matrix of the same dimen-
sion.
We assume that these variables are integrated of order
one denoted by I(1). That is, they have to be differ- The approach of Johansen is based on maximum
enced once in order to get a series with a stable and likelihood estimation of (4). In this framework, we can
invertible univariate ARMA representation. Long- test hypotheses for the number of cointegrating vectors
run PPP implies that Z',3 is stationary for /3'= r as well as certain linear restrictions on these cointe-
[1 -1 1]. There are different approaches available grating vectors. Note that the matrix of cointegrating
to test this hypothesis. First, we may directly test the vectors ,3 is not identified, but the space spanned by
stationarity of Zf3 by univariate unit root tests. Of the columns of ,3 can be estimated. Thus, we can test
course, this approach does not consider the dynamic whether ,3 can be spanned by at least r known vectors
interrelationship of the variables. Second, we may of dimension p or whether a certain known vector is
regress et on pt and p* and test the I(O) property of contained in the cointegrating space. The latter test is
the residuals. This approach suggested by Engle and of special interest, as it allows us to test the hypothesis
that the real exchange rate e - Pt + P* is stationary.
Granger suffers from several problems. For one, the
direction of the regression, which is arbitrarily se- For details on this approach, the reader is referred
lected, often leads to different results. Furthermore, to Johansen (1988), Johansen and Juselius (1990) and
the approach breaks down when pt and p* are pair- Kunst and Neusser (1990).4
wise cointegrated. Moreover, the approach is static and
does not account for the dynamic interrelationship of IV. Empirical Results
the variables. Finally, the hypothesis that the regres-
The analysis outlined in section III is applied to the
sion coefficients are equal to [1 - 1] cannot be tested
exchange rate of the DM vis 'a vis 15 currencies: the
in a simple way. All these problems can be avoided by
Swiss Franc, French Franc, Lira, Pound Sterling, U.S.
using the approach suggested by Johansen and Juselius
Dollar, Yen, Austrian Schilling, Dutch Guilder, Bel-
(1990).
gian Franc, Spanish Peseta, Swedish Krone, Danish
Consider the following vector autoregressive repre-
Krone, Canadian Dollar, Portuguese Escudo and Nor-
sentation of Z3
wegian Krone. Price levels are measured by the con-
k
sumer price index5 and the monthly data cover the
Zt = + E HTZtT + Et (3) Our sample size of roughly
period 1973/1-1990/11.
T = 1
200 observations may appear rather large, but we note
where Et is N(O, fl) distributed. Now let us consider that the recent floating rate provides us with data for
the following reparameterization of (3): 18 years, which is not very much in order to analyze a
k-1 long-run relationship.6 The application of Dickey-
Azt = E
+r?Azt--Zt,+ rkZt-k +Et (4) Fuller and Phillips-Perron-Stock-Watson univariate
Ti= 1 unit root tests for levels and first differences, which are
where rT =-I + l + +1T. not reported here, indicate that all the series in levels
The rank of rk, the matrix determining the long-run are I(1), i.e., the unit root hypothesis cannot be re-
effects of Et on Z4, is equal to the number of cointe- jected for levels but has to be rejected for first differ-
grating relationships denoted by r. These relationships ences. The results of applying Johansen's approach to
are given by
4This analysis was performed using a RATS procedure
pwzr = nit 1si.t.e.a i = , r (5) kindly provided by Klaus Neusser of the University of Vienna.
5 The data source is IMF International Financial Statistics.
where nqit iS integrated of order zero, although the Consumer Price Indices are seasonally adjusted and the ex-
change rate series are end of period data.
3This is the model considered by Johansen and Juselius 6 The effects of increasing the sample size by the use of
(1990), whereas Johansen (1988) deals with the case without a higher frequency data over a fixed sample period in unit root
constant term. tests are analyzed by Shiller and Perron (1985).

This content downloaded from 193.105.154.120 on Wed, 25 Jun 2014 06:45:57 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
182 THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS

TABLE l.-MULTIVARIATE COINTEGRATION TESTS OF PPP, DM


vis A vis 15 CURRENCIES1977-1989

k-1
z= t+ FAZt-,+FkZt-k+et

- rk = H = a;8 1: Matrix of cointegrating vectors


[/11 1812 1313 all ... alr

=
. a = a21 *2r a
K= [1 -1 1]
Prl 18r2 /3r3 [a31 ... a3r

Z, [et,P P p, t *]

Ho: H = a/' Ho: Kcsp(/3) Ho: H = a13' Ho: Kcsp(/3)


Johansenb Johansenb
DM /... r kHQa Statistic X2rC kAa Statistic X2rC

US$ <2 2 1.34 14.5' 6 2.29


< 1 18.26e 11.93 21.9'
= 0 59.52f 36.57e
BF <2 2 3.32 6 5.23 15.8'
< 1 10.00 4l.5' 26.31
= 0 75.7l1 53.14'
DKr < 2 1 3.65 6 6.10
< 1 11.43 5. ld 13.59 7.08e
0 = 1 45.54f 31.12d
SFr < 2 2 0.016 10.lf 6 0.16
< 1 19.09e 9.19
= 0 50.19' 27.56
? < 2 2 5.00 1.84 6 4.52 0.11
< 1 25.23f 16.84d
= 0 64.33' 43.1 1i
FF < 2 2 6.91d 1.24 6 4.48
< 1 19.62e 14.16 9.89f
= 0 39.19f 28.97 d
Lit < 2 2 4.53 0.66 6 6.46 1.32
< 1 21.22e 16.20d
= 0 50.02' 39.23'
Y < 2 1 3.21 0.71 6 4.77 4.15e
< 1 16.9ld 17.49d
= 0 92.15' 57.37'
CAN$ < 2 2 1.81 9.82f 4 2.87
< 1 21.02e 14.57 25.5f
= 0 48.09' 50.0o
NLfl < 2 7 1.41 1.47 2 0.85 4.19e
< 1 16.23d 21.1e
= 0 53.68' 56.82'
NKr < 2 2 4.57 3 4.57
< 1 14.28 0.58 14.24 1.55
= 0 34.50e 29.24d
OSch <2 8 3.90 0.07 2 2.26
< 1 18.65e 11.94 0.45
= 0 39.67' 44.04'
PEsc <2 1 3.78 0.25 2 3.76
< 1 16.01d 13.35 4.30
= 0 57.53' 41.13'
SKr < 2 1 1.62 6 0.81
< 1 8.65 9.67' 8.14
= 0 45.35' 21.23
Pts < 2 2 5.29 0.35 6 7.01 2.01
< 1 23.83' 22.44'
= 0 63.l4' 71.88'

Lag length selected by using the Hannan-Quinn (kHQ) and the Akaike (kA) criterion, respectively.
b Under the Ho, this statistic has a (non-standard) distribution which is tabulated in Johansen and Juselius
(1990). The 5% critical values (without drift) are 8.08 (r < 2), 17.84 (r < 1), and 31.27 (r = 0), respectively.
c Under the Ho, this statistic is x2 distributed with 3- r degrees of freedom.
d Significant at the 10% level.
e Significant at the 5% level.
f Significant at the 1% level.

This content downloaded from 193.105.154.120 on Wed, 25 Jun 2014 06:45:57 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
NOTES 183

our data, taking into account constant terms (A o 0), V. Conclusion


are reported in table 1. In order to check the robust-
ness of the results with respect to the lag length, we The application of Johansen's multivariate cointe-
used two approaches. The results given in the first gration methodology for 15 DM exchange rates and the
columns are obtained by choosing the value of k that corresponding price levels using recent monthly data
minimizes the multivariate Hannan-Quinn criterion, lead us to the following conclusion: PPP seems to hold
whereas the second set of results is obtained using the in the long run for six European currencies, namely the
multivariate Akaike criterion.7 For 10 currencies (US$, Pound, Lira, Norwegian Krone, Schilling, Portuguese
BF, DKr, ?, Lit, Can$, NKr, OSch, PEsc, Pts) the Escudo and the Spanish Peseta. However, PPP has to
results are essentially the same for both VAR-systems be clearly rejected for four currencies: the U.S. Dollar
considered. All of them seem to be cointegrated (r = 2 and the Canadian Dollar, as well as for the Belgian
or r = 1), but only in the case of six currencies (?C,Lit, Franc and the Danish Krone. For the remaining five
NKr, OSch, FEsc, Pts) can the hypothesis that the currencies (Swiss Franc, French Franc, Yen, Dutch
PPP-vector is an element of the cointegrating space not Guilder, Swedish Krone), we obtained mixed results
be rejected. For the remaining five currencies the re- depending on the VAR lag length adopted. Neverthe-
sults are mixed: For two of them (SFr, SKr) no evi- less, our analysis is more favourable to PPP as a
dence of cointegration is found when the larger Akaike long-run property of exchange rates than the recent
lag length is adopted, whereas the FF, Yen and NlFl work applying the Engle/Granger regression method-
pass the PPP test with the shorter Hannan-Quinn lag ology. Our results are also in line with the findings of
length, but this hypothesis is rejected for the Akaike Abuaf and Jouron (1990) who apply Dickey-Fuller unit
lag length. Thus we have clear-cut results for 10 out of root tests to real exchange rates in a seemingly unre-
15 currencies considered. For six European currencies lated regression framework.
PPP seems to be a long-run property of the exchange Given these results we may ask whether membership
rate against the DM. The corresponding countries are in the European Monetary System is of importance for
United Kingdom, Italy, Norway, Austria, Portugal and the non-rejection of PPP. Five currencies have been
Spain. However, PPP clearly does not seem to hold for linked to the DM by the EMS since 1979, namely, the
the exchange rate of the U.S. and the Canadian Dollar, Danish Krone, the Belgian and the French Franc, the
the Belgian Franc and the Danish Krone vis 'a vis the Lira and the Dutch Guilder. The Austrian Schilling
DM, although exchange rates and price levels are was de facto linked to the DM, whereas the Peseta
cointegrated. In this context it is worthwhile to men- entered the EMS only in the late eighties. The Swiss
tion the paper of Taylor (1988), which argues that Franc was only linked to the DM during one year by
measurement errors and transportation costs may im- the exchange rate targeting policy followed by the
ply that PPP leads to cointegration with a cointegrating Swiss National Bank (1979). With these facts, we note
vector ,3' O [1 -1 1]. Therefore, our findings sup- that the empirical evidence for PPP within the EMS is
port such a weaker variant of the PPP hypothesis for not stronger than for the European Countries outside
the U.S. and the Canadian Dollar, the Belgian Franc this systems.8 This should not come as a surprise as the
and the Danish Krone. For the exchange rates of the EMS links nominal, not real, exchange rates.
Swiss Franc, the French Franc, the Yen, the Dutch How can we explain the failure of PPP to explain the
Guilder, and the Swedish Krone the results are mixed. long-run development of the Dollar? Of course, we
In these cases the results depend essentially on the may argue that the shocks, in particular fiscal policy
VAR lag length. Thus, a larger sample is needed in shocks, that hit the United States in the eighties re-
order to get more accurate results for these currencies. sulted in permanent changes of the relative price of
Finally, one may wonder whether PPP holds between traded goods in the United States. If this conjecture is
the U.S. and the Canadian Dollar. Therefore, we ana- true, PPP only holds in the sense of a long-run rela-
lyzed the corresponding exchange rate and price levels tionship for rates of change in the exchange rate, the
using Johansen's approach. Here again we found one domestic price level and the foreign price level.
cointegrating relationship between the variables, but
the PPP vector is not contained in the cointegrating REFERENCES
space. Abuaf, Niso, and Philippe Jouron, "Purchasing Power Parity
in the Long Run," The Journal of Finance 45 (1990),
157-174.
7 In addition, we carried out the analysis using quadratically Artis, Michael J., and Mark P. Taylor, "Some Issues Concern-
detrended log time series. This procedure is motivated by ing the Long-Run Credibility of the European Mone-
some evidence of a linear deterministic time trend in first
8
differences, which, of course, points to a quadratic determinis- For a univariate unit root analysis of pre- and post-EMS
tic time trend in levels. However, the results obtained are not real DM exchange rates the reader is referred to Artis and
essentially different from those reported in table 1. Taylor (1989).

This content downloaded from 193.105.154.120 on Wed, 25 Jun 2014 06:45:57 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
184 THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS

tary System," in R. MacDonald and M. P. Taylor (1988), 231-254.


(eds.), Exchange Rates and Open Economy Macroeco- Johansen, Soren, and Katerina Juselius, "Maximum Likeli-
nomics (Oxford: Basil Blackwell, 1989), 295-306. hood Estimation and Inference on Cointegration-with
Baillie, Richard, and David Selover, "Cointegration and Mod- Applications for the Demand for Money," Oxford Bul-
els of Exchange Rate Determination," International letin of Economics and Statistics 52 (1990), 169-210.
Journal of Forecasting 3 (1987), 43-53. Kim, Yoonbai, "Purchasing Power Parity in the Long Run: A
Corbae, Dean, and Sam Ouliaris, "Cointegration and Tests of Cointegration Approach," Journal of Money, Credit,
Purchasing Power Parity," this REVIEW 70 (1988), and Banking 12 (1990), 491-503.
508-511. Kunst, Robert M., and Klaus Neusser, "Cointegration in a
Engle, Robert F., and Clive W. J. Granger, "Cointegration Macro-Economic System," Journal of Applied Econo-
and Error Correction: Representation, Estimation and metrics 5 (1990), 351-366.
Testing," Econometrica 55 (1987), 251-276. Lothian, James R., "The Behaviour of Real Exchange Rates,"
Frenkel, Jeffrey A., "The Collapse of Purchasing Power Pari- International Journal of Forecasting 3 (1987), 17-42.
ties During the 1970's," European Economic Review 16 Shiller, Robert J., and Pierre Perron, "Testing the Random
(1981), 145-165. Walk Hypothesis: Power versus Frequency of Observa-
Huizinga, John "An Empirical Investigation of the Long Run tion," Economics Letters 18 (1985), 381-386.
Behaviour of Real Exchange Rates," in K. Brunner Taylor, Mark P., "An Empirical Analysis of Long-Run Pur-
and A. Meltzer (eds.), Carnegie Rochester Conference chasing Power Parity Using Cointegration Techniques,"
Series on Public Policy, 27 (Amsterdam: North-Holland, Applied Econometrics 20 (1988), 1369-1381.
1987), 149-214. Taylor, Mark P., and Patrick C. McMahon, "Long-Run Pur-
Johansen, Soren, "Statistical Analysis of Cointegration Vec- chasing Power Parity in the 1920's," European Eco-
tors," Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 12 nomic Review 32 (1988), 179-197.

EFFICIENT ESTIMATION OF THE COSTS OF RENT CONTROLS: A COMMENT

Choon-Geol Moon and Janet G. Stotsky*

Abstract-Caudill, Ault, and Saba (1989) introduce an ap- using only the observations from the uncontrolled mar-
proachto estimatinga hedonic price equationthat accounts ket.
for censoringdue to rent controlin a rental housingmarket.
This paperextendsand clarifiestheir assertionon the consis- Caudill et al. use maximum likelihood estimation,
tencyof the ordinaryleast squaresestimates(OLS) and their recognizing the following data generation process:
estimates.We indicatehow the natureof the rent controllaw
affectsthe consistencypropertiesof the two estimationmeth- p1 = a + 3'z + Ei, i = 1,.. .,n (1)
ods. (= Pi*, if the ith observation is
from the uncontrolled market (8- 1);
I. Introduction
{i <P*, if the ith observationis
Caudill, Ault, and Saba (1989) present a method for from the controlled market (5i 0);
hedonic price equation estimation that accounts for (2)
censoring due to rent control. The traditional approach
to the estimation of the market rent equation in a where zi denotes a vector of the ith apartment charac-
rental housing market with rent control has been OLS teristics, 5i indicates rent control status, pi denotes
the latent market rent, and pi denotes the observed
Received for publication-October 9, 1990. Revision accepted
apartment rent. The triples of (pi, 8i, zi) for i =
for publication October 10, 1991. 1, .. ., n are observables while pi are unobservables.
* Rutgers University and United States Treasury Depart- They assume that Ej are normally distributed and inde-
ment, respectively. pendent over i, and derive the log-likelihood function
The authors would like to thank Denton Marks and Steven which is the same as that of the Tobit model with
B. Caudill for helpful comments on an earlier version. Special
thanks go to an anonymous referee who suggested we focus known, variable left censoring.1
on the main issue in this and earlier revisions. We gratefully
1
acknowledge the support of the Center for Urban Policy Observationally, rent control places an upper bound on
Research and the Research Council of Rutgers University. observed rent. However, since the latent market rent has a
The views expressed here are those of the authors, and do not structure relating regressors, error term and parameters, in
necessarily reflect those of the United States Treasury De- econometric terminology the latent market rent is censored by
partment. the observed rent from the left.

Copyright ?) 1993

This content downloaded from 193.105.154.120 on Wed, 25 Jun 2014 06:45:57 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

You might also like