You are on page 1of 13

Omega 54 (2015) 134–146

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Omega
journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/omega

The comparison between trade-in and leasing of a product


with technology innovations$
Kate J. Li a,n, Susan H. Xu b,†
a
Department of Information Systems and Operations Management, Sawyer Business School, Suffolk University, Boston, MA 02108, USA
b
Department of Supply Chain and Information Systems, Smeal College of Business, The Pennsylvania State University, University Park, PA 16802, USA

art ic l e i nf o a b s t r a c t

Article history: Companies can adopt trade-in and/or leasing to shorten consumers' upgrade cycle and gain control over
Received 12 June 2014 secondary markets. In this paper, we consider a monopolistic manufacturer who offers a technology
Accepted 31 January 2015 product to a market consisting of heterogeneous consumers. We focus on an exogenous, stochastic
Available online 9 February 2015
innovation process that determines the availability of new technology and consequently, residual value
Keywords: of the current product. We derive the optimal pricing strategy of trade-in and leasing, respectively,
Trade-in examine its impact on the manufacturer's expected profit, and compare the performance of the two
Leasing strategies. Trade-in protects the manufacturer against residual value risk and allows the flexibility of
Durable goods offering the option at different innovation states separately. Leasing, on the other hand, provides the
Product reuse
manufacturer an opportunity to circumvent low new product prices and thus increases expected profit
Stationary equilibrium
when product reuse profitability is high. The interplay between the two forces, product reuse profit-
ability and new product price, determines the preference between trade-in and leasing. Our findings
provide monopolistic manufacturers guidance on how to optimally employ the trade-in and leasing
strategies.
& 2015 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

1. Introduction leasing basically did not exist in the early 1980s, but experienced
steady growth in the 1980s and 1990s with reaching a peak in around
Trade-in and leasing are two widely adopted strategies by indivi- 2000 [20]. Recently battery leasing has been introduced by automobile
dual consumers and companies in a variety of industries. Consumers manufacturers and power suppliers in order to reduce the purchase
regularly trade in automobiles, electronics, power tools, video games, cost of electronic vehicles [24].
golf clubs, etc. towards the purchase of new products. In the business- Manufacturers are increasingly offering trade-ins and leasing,
to-business (B2B) markets, many companies trade in large-scale and using the returned products for remanufacturing, recycling,
communication devices, CT scanners, photocopies, computers, etc. and other types of product reuse. Xerox is one of the best-known
when they replace their current equipment. On the leasing side, examples. Its remanufacturing facility is based partly on returns
equipment leasing has a long history and has been adopted by from trade-ins and off-lease products, which has generated cost
companies around the world [41]. It accounts for about $827 billion savings of several hundred million dollars each year [14]. Interface
of business each year in the United States, and will continue to be a Inc., a carpet manufacturer, provides Evergreen Lease with the goal
dynamic and growing business [11]. It has been used by companies of of reducing the environmental impact of its operations and
different sizes to acquire a broad range of assets, such as aircraft, describing it as a “new workable business model for sustainable
automobiles, IT, medical, manufacturing and construction equipment. development” [29]. Other examples include IBM, HP, Herman
According to ELFA, 72 percent of U.S. companies lease some or all of Miller, Bosch, and Eletrolux [33].
their equipment. In recent years, in spite of the challenges posed by a With the ever-increasing rate of technology innovation and
slow economy, low interest rates and falling equipment prices, IT product replacement, trade-in and leasing play a crucial role in
leasing remains a viable and vibrant industry [39]. Leasing has also helping companies to stay competitive, increase consumer satis-
been widely used in business-to-consumer (B2C) markets, mainly for faction by providing more flexible acquisition methods, and be
acquiring automobiles and technology products. For example, new car environmentally responsible. The examples above show that
companies have been implementing trade-in and/or leasing, in

combination with outright selling. Trade-in and leasing enable
This manuscript was processed by Associate Editor Wang.
n
Corresponding author. Tel.: þ 1 6175571586.
companies to achieve two basic goals. First, the two strategies can

Deceased. be used to incentivize consumers to upgrade to products featuring
E-mail addresses: kjli@suffolk.edu (K.J. Li), shx@psu.edu (S.H. Xu). newly introduced technology or simply to replace used products

http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.omega.2015.01.018
0305-0483/& 2015 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
K.J. Li, S.H. Xu / Omega 54 (2015) 134–146 135

with brand-new ones. Second, since trade-in and off-lease pro- asset recovery services are a popular offering from HP Financial
ducts are returned to the companies, they can gain better control Services (HPFS) that take back HP and non-HP equipment from a
over product reuse and secondary market activities in order to wide range of industrial customers. HPFS took in roughly one million
achieve higher profit, fight counterfeits, and engage in sustainable units in 2006 [7]. Remarketing older assets is a key part of HPFS's
operations. business; however, if a piece of equipment is too old (severe
In this paper, we intend to study the implementation of trade-in technology obsolescence), or in such a bad shape that it no longer
and leasing under stochastic technology innovation, examine their has any useful life left (severe functional depreciation), HPFS will mine
impact on consumer behavior and firm profitability, and compare the equipment for any useful parts and then manage the disposition of
the two strategies under different pricing and product reuse the remainder in accordance with applicable environmental regula-
scenarios. Specifically, we consider a setting where a monopolistic tions. These B2B- and B2C-market examples demonstrate that when
manufacturer offers a technology product to a heterogeneous the resell value of trade-in products is higher than the associated costs,
consumer population who differ in their willingness-to-pay (WTP) companies sell refurbished and/or used products in the market;
for the product. The technology product is designed to last for two otherwise, they dispose these products by reusing or recycling
periods functionally, i.e., after it has been used for two periods, it materials or donating to charity.
fully depreciates functionally and has no residual value remained. Note that though operated in the same way, trade-ins offered
We assume that there is an exogenous, stochastic innovation when innovation occurs and when innovation does not occur
process governing the availability of the next-generation technol- serve different purposes to the manufacturer and the consumers.
ogy. Whenever a new technology becomes available, the manufac- When innovation occurs, the manufacturer uses trade-in to buy
turer introduces a new product featuring the latest technology to back technologically obsolete, used products in order to accelerate
the market and stops offering new products featuring the previous- new technology adoption; when innovation does not occur, the
generation technology. A product thus is subject to two types of manufacturer uses trade-in to buy back technologically current,
value decay: functional depreciation (FD), caused by wear and tear, used products and sells them alongside new products featuring
and technological obsolescence (TO) caused by technological inno- the same technology. As such, the manufacturer essentially serves
vation. Trade-in and leasing can be offered by the manufacturer to as an intermediary to facilitate the transaction between consumers
encourage consumers to replace products suffering FD and/or TO to who want to replace their functionally depreciated, one-period-
brand-new products featuring the latest technology. old products with brand-new ones and consumers who demand
In the trade-in model, the manufacturer may offer trade-in credit to used products. The manufacturer decides trade-in credits in
buy back consumers' on-hand products, which can be applied towards anticipation of consumer choice to maximize her expected profit;
the purchase new products. Meanwhile, consumers who have a one- while consumers choose consumption strategy based on their own
period-old product on hand decide whether to take advantage of the willingness-to-pay and trade-in credits offered by the manufac-
trade-in offer or to keep their product for one more period until it fully turer in order to maximize their own utility. From the manufac-
depreciates functionally. If a consumer chooses to trade in when turer's perspective, prices are her enabler to induce consumer
innovation does not occur, he essentially replaces a used, one- behavior that results in her maximum expected profit. Since we
period-old product suffering only FD by a brand-new product with are interested in analyzing the long-run behavior of the manu-
the same technology. This decision is made based on his own facturer and the consumers, we characterize the optimal station-
willingness-to-pay and the trade-in credit provided by the manufac- ary prices.
turer. Since such used products are still technologically current, the The leasing model is set up in a similar way where consumers
manufacturer sells them in the marketplace to consumers with lower may be offered the option of leasing a new product. All leases are
willingness-to-pay. If a consumer chooses to trade in when innovation designed to last for one period and it is assumed that no call
occurs, the consumer is able to upgrade to the new technology option is embedded. If a consumer leases a new product, he
immediately after it becomes available. In essence, the consumer can returns the off-lease product to the manufacturer after one period
enjoy a brand-new product featuring the latest technology instead of a when the lease ends and assumes no further responsibility. Same
used product suffering both FD and TO. However, because now these as in the trade-in model, the manufacturer sells off-lease products
trade-in products are used and obsolete, it is usually not to the best in the marketplace when innovation does not occur, and disposes
economic interest of the manufacturer to resell them given her costs of them outside the primary marketplace otherwise. The manufac-
inspection, remanufacturing, and remarketing; instead, the manufac- turer decides lease prices, given which the consumers choose their
turer is better off disassembling, reusing or recycling materials, or consumption strategy to maximize their own utility.
donating these products to charity. The trade-in and leasing models are solved separately and their
Evidence in practice supports the manufacturer's different dispos- results are compared. We find that the manufacturer's trade-in
ing methods of trade-in products at different innovation states. Apple decision is affected by two factors, namely new product price and
has a “Reuse and Recycling Program”1. Currently, the Reuse Program product reuse profitability. When new product price is low, a relatively
accepts iPhones as old as iPhone 4 and gives customers gift cards low trade-in credit is enough to get consumers interested. Therefore,
based on model number, capacity, and condition of the device. But for the manufacturer can increase her profit by encouraging more
older models (including iPhone, iPhone 3G, and iPhone 3GS), custo- frequent product replacement and upgrade through trade-in. Product
mers can only participate in the Recycling Program which does not reuse profitability is the value that the manufacturer can recover from
provide any monetary compensation, but simply recycles for free for traded-in products. The higher this is, the more likely that the
customers. Besides Apple, other companies, such as Cannon, Best Buy, manufacturer offers trade-in. An important characteristic of the
and Costco, offer programs operated in a similar way. A trade-in value trade-in model is the manufacturer's flexibility to make separate
search conducted in October 2014 using Best Buy's online trade-in decisions of offering trade-in when innovation occurs and when it
calculator shows that the trade-in values of iPhone 3G, iPhone 3GS, does not. This is because consumers participating in trade-in return
iPhone 4, iPhone 4s, iPhone 5, and iPhone 5s (all with 16 GB memory) their used product when they purchase a new one, and the manu-
are: $0, $5, $60, $110, $201, and $300, respectively.2 In the B2B markets, facturer can dispose these used products promptly under observed
innovation condition. Therefore, for example, if selling used products
to lower-valuation consumers is lucrative, but recycling materials is
1
See www.apple.com/recycling/gift-card/for details not, the manufacturer can choose to offer trade-in only when
2
See www.bestbuy.com/site/Electronics-Promotions/Online-Trade-Infor details innovation does not occur.
136 K.J. Li, S.H. Xu / Omega 54 (2015) 134–146

The manufacturer loses this flexibility when leasing is second period. It is shown that if the monopolist sells rather than
employed. The distinction is that when leasing is offered, off- rents her output, she has an incentive to overinvest. Fudenberg
lease products are returned to the manufacturer a period later and Tirole [16] analyze pricing for sequentially improving products
when the lease term ends. Given the stochastic innovation process, under different market information conditions. Two types of
the manufacturer has to resort to the expected gain of product products are considered: those with an active secondhand market
reuse (considering disposing used products both when innovation and anonymous consumers, and those with no secondhand
occurs and when it does not) to aid her decision. Consequently, the market and identified consumers. In the former case, it is shown
expected gain of product reuse has to be high enough for the that the monopolist may choose to produce, buy back, or keep the
manufacturer to offer leasing. The difference between trade-in and earlier version stock constant once the new version becomes
leasing can also be understood by examining the risk-bearing available. In the latter case, the monopolist chooses to offer
situation. As discussed earlier, a one-period-old, functionally upgrade discounts.
depreciated product may also be technologically obsolete if In the papers discussed above, new product pricing is the key
innovation occurs. We term the risk caused by the uncertain decision made by a monopolist. Besides pricing, there are papers
innovation process as the residual value risk. The ownership of examining the timing of introducing improved products. Levinthal
the one-period-old products determines the party who assumes and Purohot [23] consider a setting where a monopolist may
this risk. It is clear to see that when trade-in is offered, it is the introduce an improved version of the current product. The authors
consumers who bear the residual value risk because they buy the consider various policy measures available to the monopolist and
product outright first and the manufacturer decides later whether identify the optimal sales strategy under different product
she wants to buy back these products; while under leasing, it is the improvement scenarios. The authors find that, for modest levels
manufacturer who carries this risk because off-lease products go of product improvement, the monopolist's optimal policy is to
back to the manufacturer nonetheless. Indeed, Pierce [30] finds phase out sales of the old product; while for large improvements, a
that for automobile leasing, industry-wide failures in effectively buy-back policy is more profitable. Different from using aggregate
managing this residual value risk led to losses of $10–11 billion demand function as in [23,28] considers a monopolist who sells to
between 2000 and 2001, and the average loss per leased returned two groups of consumers with different willingness-to-pay. The
vehicle was $3269 in 2002. Although from the manufacturer's monopolist has a high- and a low-quality version of a product
perspective, leasing is disfavored because of the risk-bearing available simultaneously and needs to decide how to introduce
situation, it may still be preferred when the current new product and price the two versions. The authors find that if the monopolist
prices are too low. Raising prices usually is not a viable option, so decides to introduce the two versions sequentially, the high-
leasing gives the manufacturer an opportunity to offer the product quality version should be introduced first.
in another way to increase her expected profit. The interplay of the This body of literature mainly adopts a two-period model setup
two factors, new product price and product reuse profitability, where innovation occurs with certainty in the second period or is
determines the preference between trade-in and leasing. subject to the monopolist's investment or introduction decision.
The rest of the paper is organized as follows. In Section 2, we Given the complexity of today's business environment, the devel-
review related literature. Section 3 details model setup, solution opment and introduction of new technology usually is not deter-
procedure, and results of the trade-in model. In Section 4, we mined by one company. We are interested in examining how a
present the leasing model with a focus on its difference from the monopolist can use trade-in and leasing to cope with and take
trade-in model. We compare trade-in and leasing strategies and advantage of technology innovation. Therefore, in our study, we
discuss the managerial implications in Section 5, and provide use an infinite-horizon model to consider a case where innovation
concluding remarks and future research opportunities in Section 6. is governed by an exogenous stochastic process. The availability of
a new technology is uncertain and is not determined by the
monopolist. We examine the long-run behavior of a monopolistic
2. Literature review company and consumers maximizing their utilities. Moreover, in
order to focus on the aspect of product improvement, this stream
Our paper is primarily related to the streams of literature in of literature generally ignores physical wear and tear. We, on the
economics studying durable-goods monopolist offering sequen- other hand, are interested in studying the impact of both techno-
tially improving products, and various studies about trade-in and logical obsolescence and functional depreciation on trade-in and
leasing in operations management and marketing. leasing decisions.
Coase [6] famously postulates the time inconsistency problem Trade-in and leasing encourage product replacement, promote
for a durable-goods monopolist of which the monopolist might product reuse, and enable companies to gain control over the
not be able to capture any monopoly profits if she can change secondary markets, which potentially can impact a range of
product price over time. An extensive body of research has been closed-loop supply chain issues that have been extensively studied
built upon [6] and the stream that is most relevant to our paper such as supply chain network design (e.g., [38,15,36,46,25]),
considers monopolists supplying improving durable goods. In the product design (e.g., [5,8,26,12,47]), consumer return process and
two-period model set up by [10] and a followup work by [22], the policy (e.g., [40,21,17,18,34]), and pricing decisions of reusable
authors assume that a low-quality version of a product exists in components and remanufactured products (e.g., [13,44,27,42,31]).
the first period and a high-quality version becomes available in the In operations management and marketing literature, the most
second period. The monopolist chooses first- and second-period relevant stream of literature examining the application of trade-in
prices and second-period quality level to maximize her discounted and leasing. For trade-in, [43] studies quasi-durable goods, i.e.,
profit, while consumers decide whether and when to purchase the products that are infinitely lasting, but with diminishing service,
product to maximize their utility. Silver [37] is concerned with the and therefore consumers do not necessarily leave the market after
pricing of similar goods of different vintages coexisting in a their first purchase. The authors compare two commonly used
market. It examines the differential pricing over the life of the marketing practices: offering discounts to either repeat buyers
update and its effect on the existing vintages as well. No second- (trade-ins) or new buyers (introductory offers). The authors find
hand markets exist in [10,22,37]. Waldman [45] studies a monopo- that trade-ins are optimal for durable products and introductory
list's R&D decision where her investment amount determines the offers are optimal for consumable products when consumers are
probability that an improved product becomes available in the myopic. Ray et al. [33] examine three trade-in pricing schemes
K.J. Li, S.H. Xu / Omega 54 (2015) 134–146 137

under a single-period model setting: uniform pricing, age- 3.1.2. The manufacturer and the trade-in option
independent trade-in pricing, and age-dependent trade-in pricing. At any time, the monopolistic manufacturer, who faces no
In both [43,33], no technology innovation is considered and trade- production capacity constraint and lead time, sells new products
in is used exclusively to increase purchase frequency. Another featuring the latest technology to consumers. We assume that new
paper related to ours is [32]. Motivated by automobile trade-ins, product prices at states 0 and 1 are fixed, denoted as pN N
0 and p1 ,
lemon problems and adverse selection are major focuses of the respectively, in order to focus on the comparison between trade-in
paper and trade-in is proved to be an intervention by the and leasing for a manufacturer who has already been in the
monopolist to reduce inefficiencies caused by lemon problems. market selling new products outright, but is interested in accel-
Rao et al. [32] assume constant technology as well. On the erating product replacement due to more frequent technology
contrary, Agrawal et al. [1] assume that a product is subject to innovations and gaining control over secondary market.
full technological obsolescence, i.e., consumers need to replace The manufacturer may offer two trade-in opportunities to
their product in every period. Hence, in their model, trade-in is not consumers: state-0 trade-in when a new generation of technology
used as an incentive for consumers to repurchase, but purely a becomes available, and state-1 trade-in otherwise. During periods
mechanism for price discrimination. when innovation does not occur, sold products undergo wear and
On the leasing side, Desai and Purohit [9] analyze the co- tear caused by normal usage while its technology remains the
existence of leasing and selling. The paper shows that the relative latest. We refer to product value decay caused by usage as
profitability of leasing and selling hinges on the rates at which functional depreciation (FD). The manufacturer may allow consu-
leased and sold units depreciate, which results in the different mers to trade in their one-period-old products and will resell
optimal strategy that a firm should implement. Huang et al. [19] these trade-in units in the marketplace because their technology is
construct a dynamic game to simultaneously explain concurrent still current. Consumers who have a one-period-old product on
leasing and selling, active secondary markets for used goods, hand may decide to take the trade-in offer and use the given
heterogeneous consumers, and nontrivial transaction costs. Leas- trade-in credit as a partial payment to purchase a new product, or
ing is considered as a facilitator of price discrimination, which de- keep the unit for one more period until it depreciates fully
bundles a durable good into new and used portions. Instead of functionally.
different rates of depreciation, Huang et al. [19] cite the compara- When innovation occurs, the new technology will be launched
tive advantage of the monopolist disposing used goods as the immediately, and the previous-generation technology will become
explanation of concurrent leasing and selling. Bhaskaran and obsolete and will no longer be adopted by new products. Under
Gilbert [3,4] also study the use of leasing, but extend the scope this situation, besides functional depreciation, one-period-old
to considering complementary products and channel structure. products also suffer technological obsolescence (TO), which refers
Agrawal et al. [2] investigate whether leasing is environmentally to product value decay caused by the innovation process. The
superior to selling. The authors find that leasing can be envir- manufacturer may also offer trade-in, but she will dispose the one-
onmentally worse than selling despite full remarketing, or greener period-old products outside of the marketplace by disassembling
than selling despite the premature disposal of off-lease products, and reusing parts, recovering materials, donating to charity, etc.
depending on firm, product, and consumer characteristics. That is because due to both FD and TO, the value retained by these
The aforementioned papers examine a wide array of questions products may not worth the cost of reselling in the secondary
regarding trade-in and leasing. Our paper complements this body market. Consumers with one-period-old products again may
of literature from the following two aspects. First, all these papers choose to trade in or continue using their products for one more
consider a single product with no technology innovation involved. period. In essence, after a product is sold and used for one period,
In our study, we examine the role that trade-in and leasing play if innovation does not occur, the value of the product is reduced
when product offering depends on a stochastic innovation process. because of functional depreciation; however, if innovation occurs,
Second, we not only study trade-in and leasing separately, but also the value of the product is decreased due to both functional
compare their performance under different new product pricing depreciation and technological obsolescence.
and product reuse profitability scenarios. The manufacturer controls trade-in credits, pTj;t Z 0, where t is
the time period index, to maximize her expected profit. For
convenience, we call a used product a state-j used product when
3. The trade-in model the innovation process is in state j. When the manufacturer resells
one-period-old products in the marketplace, she charges pU1;t ,
3.1. The model setup which is determined endogenously by the market clearance
condition. That is, pU1;t is charged such that available trade-in
We consider an infinite-horizon, discrete-time model in which products are sold out. Selling state-1 used products incurs a per-
a monopolistic manufacturer offers a technology product to unit cost γ to the manufacturer, which includes costs of inspection,
heterogeneous, utility-maximizing consumers, to maximize her repair, refurbishing, and remarketing. Note that this cost applies
profit. Specifically, our model consists of the following constructs. only in state 1 when the manufacturer resells used products, but
does not apply in state 0 when she disposes them outside of the
3.1.1. Innovation process and product lifetime market. We further assume that when the manufacturer disposes
The functional life of each new product is designed to last for state-0 used products, she obtains a per-unit net profit, β. The
two periods, after which the product is fully depreciated function- manufacturer also has a unit production cost, c. We assume that
ally. We assume that there is an exogenous innovation process that γ o c and β o c.
governs the introduction of the next-generation technology of the Though operated in the same way, state-0 and state-1 trade-in
product to the market. The innovation process follows a geometric programs serve different purposes to the manufacturer. At innova-
distribution, with q0 being the probability that a new technology tion state 0, the manufacturer buys back technologically obsolete
becomes available in the next period, and q1 being the probability products in order to accelerate new technology adoption; while at
otherwise, where q1 ¼ 1 q0 . The state of the innovation process in innovation state 1, since new and used products have the same
each period is denoted by a binary variable j, where innovation technology and co-exist in the marketplace, the manufacturer
state 0 means that a new generation of technology just becomes essentially serves as an intermediary who facilitates the transac-
available and innovation state 1 means otherwise. tion between consumers who want to replace their functionally
138 K.J. Li, S.H. Xu / Omega 54 (2015) 134–146

Table 1
Notation summary.

Parameters
q0 Probability that a new technology becomes available in the next period
j Innovation state
c Production cost
γ Remanufacturing and remarketing cost
β Net profit of disposing used products outside of the market
θN N U U
0 , θ1 , θ0 , θ1 H-consumers' valuations of state-0 new, state-1 new, state-0 used,
and state-1 used products, respectively
wH, wL H- and L-consumers' sensitivity measures
nH, nL Sizes of H- and L-consumers
a A consumer's action taken in the current period
a0 A consumer's action taken in the previous period
ilk Consumer states, k ¼ 1; …; 4, l ¼ TI; LS
π il Limiting probability of consumer state ilk
k

us ðpl Þ Consumers' long-run average utility of adopting consumption


strategy s given pl , l ¼ TI; LS
ul ðpl Þ The manufacturer's long-run average profit given pl , l ¼ TI; LS
pU1;l Used product price at state 1, l ¼ TI; LS (endogenously determined)
Decision variables
pTj Stationary trade-in price at state j
pLj Stationary leasing price at state j

in state-1 new products). Therefore, θ0  θ1 can be considered as a


N N
depreciated, one-period-old products with brand-new ones and
consumers who demand used products. measure of technological obsolescence. Moreover, wear and tear
caused by product usage deteriorates the value of state-1 used
products even though their technology is still up-to-date. Hence,
3.1.3. The consumers θN1  θU1 , the valuation of functional difference between a state-1
The population of consumers is constant and a consumer can new and a state-1 used product, measures functional depreciation.
own at most one unit of the product in any period. Consumers
have universally agreed, common attribute values θ~ 0 , θ~ 1 , θ~ 0 , and
N N U

~ U
θ 1 , which represent the one-period utility of consuming a state-0 3.2. Rule of the game and solution characterization
new product, a state-1 new product, a state-0 used product, and a
state-1 used product, respectively. Because of the memoryless The manufacturer and the consumers are assumed to be
property of the innovation process, these attribute values only rational and to maximize their own expected payoff. We study
depend on the innovation state but are independent of the age of an infinitely repeated game with complete information by assum-
the technology. We assume that 0 o θ~ 0 o θ~ 1 o θ~ 1 o θ~ 0 to reflect
U U N N
ing that all payoff-relevant information is common knowledge.
that new technology is valued more than existing technology, and Uncertainty in this repeated game stems from the stochastic
a brand-new product is valued more than a used product featuring innovation process captured by innovation probability q0. At the
the same technology. beginning of each period, the manufacturer announces the trade-
Although consumers agree upon these common attribute in credit, and at innovation state 1, used product price is deter-
values, they differ in their sensitivity to them, which captures mined by the market clearance condition. The utility-maximizing
consumer heterogeneity. We assume that the consumer popula- consumers then choose a consumption strategy based on their
tion consists of two types of consumers: H-consumers, with own type, H or L, the trade-in credit offered by the manufacturer,
sensitivity measure w ~ H , and L-consumers, with sensitivity mea- and used product price determined by the market.
sure w ~ L , where w ~ H Zw ~ L Z 0. Let wL ¼ w ~ L =w
~ H , which is L-consu- Figure 1 illustrates the sequence of events. In this game, the
mers' sensitivity defined as a fraction of that of H-consumers. The consumers play strategically against the manufacturer, but not
value of wL captures the degree of heterogeneity of the consumers. against each other.
A lower wL means that H- and L-consumers are more hetero- In our analysis, we focus on stationary pricing strategies that can
geneous in terms of their willingness-to-pay. Therefore, it can be be deployed by the manufacturer. A stationary pricing strategy
expected that in general, wL is lower for B2C markets than for B2B depends only on the innovation states, but is independent of time
markets. Each consumer's sensitivity type is known only to the and market share [35]. Let the stationary price vector be
consumer himself. A consumer's valuation for a product is his pTI ¼ ðp0;TI ; p1;TI Þ ¼ ðpT0 ; pT1 ; pU1;TI Þ, which are state-0 trade-in credit,
sensitivity measure multiplied by the common attribute value of state-1 trade-in credit, and the price of state-1 used product,
the product. For example, an H-consumer values a state-0 new respectively, where pU1;TI is endogenously determined so is not a
~ H θ~ 0 . For H-consumers, we define θN ~ ~
N N
decision variable of the manufacturer. A consumer's action, a, in
product at w 0 ¼ wHθ0 ,
θN1 ¼ w~ H θ~ 1 , θU0 ¼ w~ H θ~ 0 , and θU1 ¼ w~ H θ~ 1 . Consequently, a L-con-
N U U
each period depends on innovation state j, the corresponding price
sumer's valuations of a state-0 new, state-1 new, state-0 used, and vector pj;TI , and his action in the previous period a0 (because the
state-1 used products can be represented as wL θ0 , wL θ1 , wL θ0 ,
N N U functional lifespan of a new product is two periods, we only need
and wL θ1 , respectively. The sizes of H- and L-consumers are nH and
U

nL, respectively, and we assume that nH r nL . A table of notations is


provided in Table 1. 0,t
T
1,t
T

Note that innovation state affects the universally agreed attri-


bute values and consumer valuations of the products. The differ-
ence, θ0  θ1 , reflects the valuation of technological difference
N N

between the latest technology (i.e., featured in state-0 new


products) and the previous-generation technology (i.e., featured Fig. 1. Sequence of events.
K.J. Li, S.H. Xu / Omega 54 (2015) 134–146 139

to track a consumer's action in the previous period). Therefore, a the previous period, is
consumer's state variable, iTI, can be expressed as ða0 ; pj;TI Þ.
u1 ðpTI Þ ¼ π 1iTI rðN; iTI
1 Þ þ π iTI rðN; i2 Þ þ π iTI rðN; i3 Þ þ π iTI rðN; i4 Þ
1 TI 1 TI 1 TI
1 2 3 4

¼ ðq0 θ0 þ q1 θ1 Þ ðq0 ðpN


N N T N T
0  p0 Þ þ q1 ðp1  p1 ÞÞ:
3.3. Consumer behavior—stationary consumption strategies
and long-run average payoffs Intuitively, the above expression states that, over the long run, an
H-consumer adopting S1TI earns a payoff of ðθ0  pN
N
0 þ p0 Þ in q0 
T

100% of periods and a payoff of ðθ1  p1 þ p1 Þ in q1  100% of


N N T
If an H-consumer took action a0 ¼ N in the previous period,
where N denotes purchasing a new product, he can choose to periods because he consumes a new product in each period by
(i) trade in and purchase a new product at a discounted price of paying the discounted price after trading in.
Taking into account of the clearance condition required at
pNj  pj , also denoted by N, or (ii) keep his on-hand product for one
T

more period, denoted by action K.3 If he took action a0 a N in the innovation state 1, there are four feasible strategy pairs for
previous period, denoted as a0 ¼ N (i.e., he does not have a usable H- and L-consumers: ðS1TI ; S5Þ, ðS2TI ; S5Þ, ðS3TI ; S6Þ, and ðS4; S6Þ,
unit on hand), he purchases a new product. Note that we do not where the first and second entries in a set of parentheses denote
consider the case where an H-consumer does not make a purchase H- and L-consumers' consumption strategies, respectively. The
when he does not have a usable unit on hand because it results in formation of these feasible strategy pairs guarantees that when
the entire market being inactive which is a trivial case. A H-consumers choose to trade in their one-period-old products at
consumer's single-period payoff is denoted by rða; iTI Þ. We have innovation state 1, L-consumers will buy these used products from
four distinct consumer states, labeled as iTI TI the manufacturer. Recall that we assume the size of L-consumers
1 ¼ ðN; p0;TI Þ, i2 ¼ ðN
; p0;TI Þ, iTI ¼ ðN; p Þ, and iTI
¼ ðN ; p Þ. The single-period payoffs exceeds that of H-consumers, so the clearance condition can
3 1;TI 4 1;TI
of an H-consumer are summarized in Table 2. We assume that it is always be satisfied.4 Hence, the resulting price of state-1 used
products determined by the clearance condition is pU1;TI ¼ wL θ1 .
n U
never profitable for the manufacturer to sell new products to L-
consumers. Hence, L-consumers buy used products when they are
available at state 1 (if H-consumers decide to trade in) and obtain 3.4. The manufacturer's optimization problem
payoff wL θ1  pU1;TI , denoted by action U, or remain inactive other-
U

wise, denoted by action I. 3.4.1. Problem setup


Given that we are interested in analyzing the long-run behavior The manufacturer decides the stationary pricing scheme pTI , in
of the manufacturer and the consumers, we choose expected long- anticipation of the consumers' reaction, to maximize her expected
run average payoff as the optimization criterion. In responding to long-run average profit per period. By choosing different pricing
the manufacturer's stationary pricing vector pTI , a consumer schemes, the manufacturer essentially induces the consumers to
chooses a stationary consumption strategy that maximizes his adopt different consumption strategies. Consumers' choices of
long-run average utility per period. A stationary consumption consumption strategies in turn decide the aggregate market shares
strategy of a consumer is a function that maps each possible of new and used products, which determine the manufacturer's
consumer state i to a particular feasible action a. From our earlier overall profit.
discussion, for H-consumers, aiTI ; aiTI A fN; Kg, and aiTI ¼ aiTI ¼ fNg; In essence, the optimal stationary price vector pnTI is the
1 3 2 4
for L-consumers, aiTI ¼ I and aiTI A fU; Ig (note that iTI TI
1 and i3 are
manufacturer's enabler to induce consumer behavior that results
in her maximum long-run average profit. We first formulate the
2 4
unreachable states for L-consumers). Subsequently, there are a
total of four feasible stationary consumption strategies for H- manufacturer's long-run average profit maximization problem for
consumers: AH;TI ¼ fS1TI ; S2TI ; S3TI ; S4g, and two for L-consumers: each of the four feasible strategy pairs: ðS1TI ; S5Þ, ðS2TI ; S5Þ,
AL;TI ¼ fS5; S6g. We label these strategies as S1TI S6 (see Table 3 for ðS3TI ; S6Þ, and ðS4; S6Þ. We define uTI ðpTI Þ as the manufacturer's
details). long-run average profit, which is the sum of the long-run average
The limiting probabilities, denoted by π iTI , k ¼ 1; …; 4, and the payments from the two consumer groups playing different con-
k
long-run average utilities, denoted by us ðpTI Þ, s ¼ 1; …; 6, are shown sumption strategies, subtracted by the manufacturer's long-run
in Table 3. We use S2TI as an example to explain the calculation of average cost of enabling such strategies. We use the strategy pair
the limiting probabilities. When S2TI ¼ ðK; N; N; NÞ is deployed, the ðS1TI ; S5Þ as an example. When the manufacturer induces ðS1TI ; S5Þ,
transition probability matrix is her maximization problem is
2 3 uTI
n
fuTI
0 q0 0 q1 ðS1;S5Þ ¼ maxpTI ðS1;S5Þ ðpTI Þg
6 7
6 q0 0 q1 0 7
0  p0 Þ þ q1 ðp1  p1 Þ  c þ q0 β þq1 ðwL θ 1  γ ÞÞg
U
P¼6 7 ¼ max fnH ðq0 ðpN T N T
6 q 0 0 q 1 0 7: pTI
4 5
q0 0 q1 0 ð1Þ

Limiting probabilities, π iTI , π iTI , π iTI and π iTI , can be obtained by s:t: u1 ðpTI Þ Z u2 ðpTI Þ; ð2Þ
1 2 3 4
solving a system of linear equations. The objective of consumers is
to maximize their long-run average utility per period, which is the u1 ðpTI Þ Zu3 ðpTI Þ; ð3Þ
difference between the reward obtained and the price paid by a
u1 ðpTI Þ Zu4 ðpTI Þ; ð4Þ
consumer. We explain the computation of u1 ðpTI Þ as an example.
The long-run average utility of an H-consumer adopting S1TI where Inequalities (2)–(4) ensure that H-consumers choose S1TI .
ðN; N; N; NÞ, which stipulates the purchase of a new product in The optimization problems based on ðS2TI ; S5Þ and ðS3TI ; S6Þ can be
each period regardless of innovation state and the action taken in formulated in a like manner. We provide only their objective

4
Note that this assumption simplifies exposition, but is not crucial for the
3
We assume that due to high transaction cost, it is not economically plausible for analysis. If the size of H-consumers is greater than that of L-consumers, we can
consumers to sell their used products directly to other consumers or to dispose simply assume that the manufacturer will dispose excess used products outside of
them elsewhere. the market as she does at innovation state 0.
140 K.J. Li, S.H. Xu / Omega 54 (2015) 134–146

functions here: We solve the manufacturer's profit maximization problem in


( !) two steps. First, we examine the constraint set of each of the four
q1 T c  q1 ðwL θ1  γ Þ
U
n q20 N optimization problems to determine whether dominated strategy
uTI
ðS2;S5Þ ¼ max nH p0 þ q1 pN
1  p  ;
pTI 1 þ q0 1 þ q0 1 1 þ q0 pairs exist. If so, we exclude these strategy pairs from further
ð5Þ consideration. Second, we solve for the optimal stationary price
vector pnTI for inducing each strategy pair and calculate the
   manufacturer's maximum expected long-run average profit. We
n q q2 c  q0 β
uTI
ðS3;S6Þ ¼ max nH q0 pN
0  0 pT0 þ 1 pN 1  ; ð6Þ then compare the obtained maximum profits and identify the
pTI 1 þ q1 1 þ q1 1 þq1 optimal strategy pair under different parameter value scenarios.
and the manufacturer's average profit given ðS4; S6Þ is nH ððq0 =
2ÞpN0 þ ðq1 =2Þp1  c=2Þ.
N
3.4.2. Dominant consumption strategies given different new product
Before presenting the solution procedure and the result, we
price regions
discuss two factors, new product price and product reuse profit-
As shown in Table 3, new product prices affect consumers'
ability, which determine the manufacturer's decision. When new
long-run average utility, hence the choice of consumption strate-
product price at an innovation state is low, trade-in at that
gies. We first examine the existence of dominant strategies under
innovation state is favored for two reasons. First, because of the
low price, the manufacturer does not make considerable profit
Table 4
from each sale; therefore she needs to encourage more frequent Two factors driving trade-in decisions.
purchases by offering trade-ins to increase profit. Second, the
manufacturer does not need to offer a high trade-in credit to New product price (pN
j )

incentivize consumers to buy a new unit because its price is


Profitability of product reuse (vj) High Low
already low. Now consider the other factor, product reuse profit-
ability at innovation states 0 and 1, defined as v0 ¼ β  θ0 and
U
High DEPENDS Favors state-j TI
v1 ¼ ðwL θ1  γ Þ  θ1 ¼ ðwL  1Þθ1  γ , respectively. v0 is the value
U U U
Low Disfavors state-j TI DEPENDS
difference between disposing state-0 used products outside of the
market (i.e., β) and letting H-consumers keep them for one more
period (i.e., θU0 ); and v1 is this value difference at state 1. A higher
product reuse profitability implies that the manufacturer can
obtain higher value from disposing used products, therefore
trade-in is more favored; otherwise, trade-in should be discour-
aged. Table 4 summarizes the impact of the two factors on the
manufacturer's trade-in decision. When new product price is low
and product reuse profitability is high, trade-in is clearly favored;
when the conditions are reversed, trade-in is not a preferable
option. When the two factors pull trade-in decision in opposite
directions, the final outcome will depend on their relative
strength.

Table 2
The single-period payoff matrix of an h-consumer in the trade-in model.

Action a Consumer state

iTI
1 ¼ ðN; p0;TI Þ iTI
2 ¼ ðN ; p0;TI Þ iTI
3 ¼ ðN; p1;TI Þ iTI
4 ¼ ðN ; p1;TI Þ

N θN
0  p0 þ p0
N T
θN
0  p0
N
θN
1  p1 þ p1
N T
θN
1  p1
N

K θU
0 a θU
1 
Fig. 2. Dominant consumption strategy pairs under different new product pricing
a
 denotes infeasible actions. scenarios.

Table 3
Consumption strategies, limiting probabilities, and long-run average utilities in the trade-in model.

Strategy Consumer state Limiting probabilities Long-run average utility

iTI
1 iTI
2 iTI
3 iTI
4 π iTI π iTI π iTI π iTI us ðpTI Þ
1 2 3 4

   
S1TI N N N N q0 0 q1 0 q0 θN N
0 þ q1 θ1  q0 ðp0  p0 Þ þ q1 ðp1  p1 Þ
N T N T
!  
S2TI K N N N q0 q20 q1 q0 q1 q20 θN U
0 þ q0 θ 0 q20 q1
1 þ q0 1þ q0 1 þ q0 q1 θN
1 þ  0 þ q1 p1 
pN N
pT1
1 þ q0 1 þ q0 1 þ q0 1 þ q0
!  
S3TI N N K N q0 q0 q1 q1 q21 q21 θN U
N 1 þ q1 θ 1 q0 q2
1 þ q1 1 þ q1 1þ q1 q0 θ0 þ  q0 p0 N
p þ 1 pN
T
1 þ q1 1 þ q1 1 þ q1 0 1 þ q1 1
S4a K N K N q0 q0 q1 q1 q0 θN N U U q
0 þ q1 θ 1 þ q0 θ0 þ q1 θ1 q
2 2 2 2  0 pN þ 1 pN
2 2 0 2 1
S5a – I – U 0 q0 0 q1 U
q1 wL θ1  q1 pU1;TI
S6a – I – I 0 q0 0 q1 0

a
S4–S6 do not have “TI” as subscript because as will be shown later that they are also applicable to the leasing model.
K.J. Li, S.H. Xu / Omega 54 (2015) 134–146 141

different new product pricing scenarios. The result is summarized three regions shown in Fig. 2 and determine their corresponding
by Theorem 1 and Fig. 2. dominant strategies. □

Theorem 1. The existence of dominant consumption strategy pairs Fig. 2 shows the dominant consumption strategy pairs in
depends on the new product prices at both innovation states and the different new product pricing regions. In practice, companies
magnitude of their difference. The dominant strategy pairs in each of usually either keep the price of a product constant throughout
its life cycle (i.e., pN0 ¼ p1 ) or reduce price after the product has
N
the four new product pricing regions, as shown in Fig. 2, are:
been introduced for some time (i.e., pN 0 4p1 ). Hence, we focus on
N

 In Region 1, the Low Price Region, ðS1TI ; S5Þ is the only dominant the area under the 45-degree line. Note that we keep ðS4; S6Þ, the
strategy pair for H- and L-consumers. outright-selling-only strategy pair, available in all four regions
 In Region 2, the Balanced Pricing Region, none of the four strategy because it represents the status quo of the market.
pairs is dominated. In Region 1, the Low Price region, the impact of new product
 In Region 3, the Low Introductory Pricing Region, ðS2TI ; S5Þ is price outweighs that of product reuse profitability; thus ðS1TI ; S5Þ
dominated. is the only dominant strategy pair. In essence, unless the manu-
 In Region 4, the Deep Discounting Region, ðS3TI ; S6Þ is dominated. facturer (or a legislature) can demand a disposal fee, which is
equivalent to a negative trade-in credit, H-consumers always
Proof of Theorem 1. Table 3 contains the long-run average utility prefer trade-in. Region 2 is labeled as the Balanced Pricing region
of the four consumption strategies, S1TI –S4, among which where new product prices at the two innovation states are
H-consumers can choose. We compare the long-run average commensurate with each other. No dominated strategies exist
utilities to determine whether dominant strategies exist under because neither state's trade-in is definitively preferred to the
different new product pricing scenarios. We use the optimization other. We label the region where pN N
1 is relatively close to p0 the

problem defined for ðS1TI ; S5Þ, Eqs. (1)–(4), as an example. It is Low Introductory Pricing region, i.e., Region 3 in Fig. 2. In this
obvious that if (2)–(4) hold, S1TI dominates S2TI , S3TI , and S4. By region, ðS2TI ; S5Þ is dominated. Recall that S2TI is the state-1-trade-
rearranging the three inequalities, we have in-only strategy. When pN 1 is relatively high, state-1 trade-in
becomes less attractive compared to state-0 trade-in; therefore,
1 þq0 T pN  θ0 H-consumers favor S1TI or S3TI . In other words, when state-1
pT1 Z  p þ 0 ; ð7Þ
q1 0 q1 trade-in is worthwhile to H-consumers, state-0 trade-in is at least
as worthwhile. Region 4, the Deep Discounting region where pN 1 is
q0 T pN  θ1 much lower than pN 0 , represents a scenario where the manufac-
pT1 Z  p þ 1 ; ð8Þ
1 þq1 0 1 þ q1 turer discounts heavily once the product is not newly introduced.
Intuitively, contrary to Region 3, ðS3TI ; S6Þ is dominated in this
0 þ q1 p1  ðq0 θ 0 þ q1 θ 1 Þ
q0 T q0 pN N
pT1 Z  p þ ; ð9Þ region.
q1 0 2q1

where θ0 ¼ θ0  θ0 and θ1 ¼ θ1  θ1 . When pN 0 r θ 0 , the right-


N U N U
3.4.3. Optimal consumption strategy given different product reuse
hand side of Inequality (7) is non-positive and therefore (7) holds scenarios
regardless of parameter values. Similar argument can be applied to Now we derive and discuss the optimal consumption strategy
Inequalities (8) and (9). Hence, when pN 0 r θ 0 and p1 r θ 1 , S1TI
N
pair that the manufacturer should induce in each new product
dominates the other three strategies, i.e., it is the only strategy that pricing region. We solve for optimal trade-in credits, pT0n and pT1n ,
should be induced by the manufacturer when new product prices and the resulting maximum expected long-run average profit
fall in Region 1. Following similar analysis, we can define the other given each dominant strategy pair in each region. We then

Fig. 3. The optimal consumption strategy pairs in the trade-in model. (a) the balanced pricing region, (b) the low introductory pricing region and (c) the deep discounting
region.
142 K.J. Li, S.H. Xu / Omega 54 (2015) 134–146

q0 θ0 þ q1 θ1 cÞ=q1 (which is the derivation of Line 3), ðS1TI ; S5Þ


U U
compare the maximum profits and the strategy pair that yields the
maximum profit is the optimal pair. The results are summarized in results in higher maximum average profit; otherwise, ðS2TI ; S5Þ is
Theorem 2 and Fig. 3. preferred. Such pairwise comparisons are conducted and the result is
summarized by Fig. 3(a). The other three regions can be analyzed
Theorem 2. The optimal strategy pair that maximizes the manufac- analogously. □
turer's expected long-run average profit depends on cost parameters,
consumer valuations, and innovation frequency. The stationary The result of Region 2, the Balanced Pricing region (as sum-
equilibrium can be specified as follows. The optimal trade-in credits marized by Fig. 3(a)) demonstrates the flexibility of trade-in.
and the manufacturer's maximum long-run average profit are pro- When pN N
0 and p1 are balanced, i.e., neither is exceedingly high or

vided in Table 5. low compared to the other, product reuse profitability plays the
predominant role in determining the manufacturer's optimal
 In Region 1, the Low Price region, when c r q0 pN0 þq1 pN1 þ trade-in decision. Not surprisingly, when both v0 and v1 are high,
2q0 β þ 2q1 ðwL θ1  γ Þ, ðS1TI ; S5Þ is the optimal strategy pair;
U the manufacturer should induce ðS1TI ; S5Þ to maximize her profit
otherwise, the manufacturer should induce ðS4; S6Þ. because she can recover more value from product reuse; when
 In Region 2, the Balanced Pricing region, the optimal strategy pair both are low, the manufacturer remains to sell outright only.
given different conditions of product reuse profitability is illu- Otherwise, she can exploit different product reuse situation at
strated by Fig. 3(a). When v0 and v1 are both large, ðS1TI ; S5Þ is the different innovation states independently. In essence, when pro-
optimal strategy pair; when v0 is large and v1 is small, ðS3TI ; S6Þ is duct reuse is rather profitable at state 1 but not at state 0 (i.e., v0 is
optimal; when the condition is reversed, ðS2TI ; S5Þ is optimal; small but v1 is large), the manufacturer chooses to induce ðS2TI ; S5Þ
otherwise ðS4; S6Þ is optimal. where H-consumers only trade in at state 1; when the situation is
 In the Low Introductory Pricing region (Region 3), the optimal reversed, she encourages H-consumers to pursue trade-in only at
strategy pair is illustrated by Fig. 3(b). When v0 and v1 are both state 1. Since the manufacturer decides trade-in offer after obser-
large, ðS1TI ; S5Þ is the optimal strategy pair; when v0 is large and ving the innovation state, she can completely shield herself from
v1 is small, ðS3TI ; S6Þ is optimal; otherwise ðS4; S6Þ is optimal. the residual value risk of used products.
 In the Deep Discounting region (Region 4), the optimal strategy Recall that in Region 3, the Low Introductory Pricing region
pair is illustrated by Fig. 3(c). When v0 and v1 are both large, ðS2TI ; S5Þ, the state-1 trade-in only strategy pair, is always domi-
ðS1TI ; S5Þ is the optimal strategy pair; when v0 is small and v1 is nated. Hence, as shown in Fig. 3(b), when v0 is small and v1 is
large, ðS2TI ; S5Þ is optimal; otherwise ðS4; S6Þ is optimal. large, the manufacturer sells outright instead of offering state-1
trade-in as she does in the Balanced Pricing region. This is because
Proof of Theorem 2. It is obvious that the manufacturer's long-run even though the reuse of state-1 used products is profitable, state-
average profit maximization problem of any of the feasible strategy 1 trade-in is disfavored because of the prevailing effect of the
pairs is a linear program and therefore the optimum is always attained relatively high new product price at state 1. This exemplifies the
on one or more vertices of the feasible region, which can be solved by interplay of the two factors driving the trade-in decision, new
standard methods. Here we use Region 2, the Balanced Pricing region product price and product reuse profitability, discussed in Section
as an example. In this region, all four consumption strategy pairs are 3.4.1. Region 4, the Deep Discounting region, is the opposite to
non-dominated, so we first solve for the optimal trade-in credits that Region 3 and can be understood analogously.
maximize the manufacturer's long-run average profit, as defined by
Eqs. (1)–(6). The results are provided in Table 5. Then we compare the
maximum long-run average profit achieved under each strategy pair 4. The leasing model
and determine the optimal strategy pair given different product reuse
profitability scenarios (i.e., different values of v0 and v1). For example, One of the objectives of this paper is to compare trade-in and
by comparing the maximum profits obtained by inducing ðS1TI ; S5Þ, leasing, so we adopt the same basic model setup and solution
and ðS2TI ; S5Þ, we have that when v1 4  ð1 þ q0 Þ=q1 v0  ðθ0 þ
N
concept, as explained in Sections 3.1 and 3.2, for the leasing model.

Table 5
Optimal consumption strategy and maximum average profit in different new product pricing regions.

Region Optimal trade-in credits Optimal strategy & maximum profit

Region 1 pT0n ¼ 0 ðS1TI ; S5Þ : nH ðq0 ðpN U


0 þ βÞþ q1 ðp1 þ wL θ 1  γÞ cÞ
N

(Low price Region) pT1n ¼ 0


 
Region 2 ð1 þ q1 ÞpN
0  q1 p1  ð1þ q1 Þθ 0 þ q1 θ 1
N
0 þ q1 p1 þ q0 θ0 þ q1 θ 1
q0 pN N
pT0n ¼ ðS1TI ; S5Þ : nH þ q0 β þ q1 ðwL θU1  γÞ  c
2 2
(Balanced Pricing Region) Tn  q0 pN
0 þ ð1 þ q0 Þp1 þ q0 θ 0  ð1 þ q0 Þθ1
N
p1 ¼
2
 
q0 pN q pN q q θ0  q1 ð1 þ q0 Þθ1 q1 ðwL θU1  γÞ c
ðS2TI ; S5Þ : nH 0
þ 1 1  0 1 þ 
2 2 2ð1þ q0 Þ 1þ q0 1 þ q0
 
q pN q pN q ð1þ q1 Þθ0  q0 q1 θ1 q β c
ðS3TI ; S6Þ : nH 0 0 þ 1 1 þ 0 þ 0 
2 2 2ð1þ q1 Þ 1 þ q1 1 þ q1
 
0 þ q 1 p1  c
nH q0 pN N
ðS4; S6Þ :
2
 
Region 3 pT0n ¼ 0 q21 q
ðS1TI ; S5Þ : nH q0 pN0 þ pN þ 1 θ1 þ q0 β þ q1 ðwL θU1  γÞ  c
1 þ q1 1 1 þ q1
 
(Low Introductory Pricing Region) 1  θ1
pN q21 1  
pT1n ¼ ðS3TI ; S6Þ : nH q0 pN0 þ pN þ q βc
1þ q1 1 þ q1 1 1 þ q1 0
 2 
Region 4 pN  θ 0 q0 q0
pT0n ¼ 0 ðS1TI ; S5Þ : nH pN0 þ q1 p1 þ
N
θ0 þ q0 β þ q1 ðwL θU1  γÞ  c
1þ q0 1 þ q0 1 þ q0
 2 
(Deep Discounting Region) pT1n ¼ 0 q0 1
ðS2TI ; S5Þ : nH pN þ q1 p N
þ ðq ðwL θU1  γÞ cÞ
1 þ q0 0 1
1 þ q0 1
K.J. Li, S.H. Xu / Omega 54 (2015) 134–146 143

In the leasing model, the manufacturer provides the option of problem is


leasing, along with outright selling, to consumers where all leases n
n o
last for one period and do not have embedded call options. We uLS
ðS3;S5Þ ¼ max uLS
ðS3;S5Þ ðpLS Þ
pLS
present consumer behavior in the leasing model, solve the ( !)
c  q20 β  q0 q1 ðwL θ1  γ Þ
U
q1 N q
manufacturer's long-run average profit maximization problem, ¼ max nH p1 þ 0 pL0 
pLS 1 þ q1 1 þ q1 1 þ q1
and discuss the results in this section.
s:t: u3 ðpLS Þ Zu1 ðpLS Þ;
u ðpLS Þ Z u2 ðpLS Þ;
3

4.1. Consumer behavior—stationary consumption strategies and u3 ðpLS Þ Z u4 ðpLS Þ; ð10Þ


long-run average payoffs
where the constraints ensure that H-consumers choose S3LS from
In the leasing model, the stationary price vector offered by the the choice set. The derivation of the objective function is similar to
manufacturer is: pLS ¼ ðp0;LS ; p1;LS Þ ¼ ðpL0 ; pL1 ; pU1;LS Þ, which consists of that in the trade-in model. The optimization problem of the other
new product leasing prices at states 0 and 1, respectively, and the two strategy pairs can be formulated in the same way. We provide
used product price at state 1. pU1;LS is determined endogenously by their objective functions here:
the market clearance condition. If an H-consumer took action n

ðS1;S5Þ ¼ maxfnH ðq0 p0 þq1 p1  c þ q0 β þ q1 ðwL θ 1  γ ÞÞg;


U
uLS L L
ð11Þ
a0 ¼ N in the previous period, regardless of the current innovation pLS
state, he keeps his one-period-old product for another period, K. If ( !)
c  q0 q1 β  q21 ðwL θ1  γ Þ
U
he took action a0 a N in the previous period, he can choose to n q0 N q
uLS
ðS2;S5Þ ¼ max nH p þ 1 pL  :
(i) purchase a new product, N, or (ii) lease a new product, denoted pLS 1 þ q0 0 1 þ q0 1 1 þq0
by L. Table 6 shows the single-period payoff matrix of an
ð12Þ
H-consumer in the leasing model. There are a total of four feasible
consumption strategies for H-consumers, labeled as S1LS –S3LS and Comparing to the objective functions of the trade-in model,
S4, the outright buying strategy as defined in the trade-in model. given by Eqs. (1), (5), and (6), there is a significant difference: in
the leasing model, the terms β and wL θ1  γ , which reflect the
U
Similarly, we assume that L-consumers' sensitivity measure wL is
so low that it is not profitable for the manufacturer to sell or lease profitability of product reuse at innovation states 0 and 1 respec-
new products to L-consumers. Therefore, they have the same tively, enter all objective functions regardless of the innovation
choice set, fS5; S6g, as that in the trade-in model. The limiting state at which leasing is offered; however, in the trade-in model,
probabilities and long-run average utilities of S1LS –S3LS are pre- β only appears in the objective function of strategies involving
state-0 trade-in, and wL θ1  γ only appears in those involving
U
sented in Table 7.
state-1 trade-in. Essentially, trade-in decision can be made by
considering product reuse profitability at different innovation
states separately; but leasing decision has to be made by jointly
4.2. The manufacturer's optimization problem considering both states. This reflects the inherently different risk-
bearing situation of the two strategies: consumers assume the
The manufacturer uses the stationary price vector pLS to induce
consumer behavior that maximizes her long-run average profit.
Following the same argument, the clearance price of state-1 used
products is pU1;LS ¼ pU1;TI ¼ wL θ1 . There are four feasible strategy
n n U

pairs for H- and L-consumers: ðS1LS ; S5Þ, ðS2LS ; S5Þ, ðS3LS ; S5Þ, and
ðS4; S6Þ. We now formulate the manufacturer's long-run average
profit maximization problems and use ðS3LS ; S5Þ as an example.
When inducing ðS3LS ; S5Þ, the manufacturer's maximization

Table 6
The single-period payoff matrix of an H-consumer in the leasing model.

Action Consumer state

a iLS iLS iLS iLS


1 ¼ ðN; p0;LS Þ 2 ¼ ðN ; p0;LS Þ 3 ¼ ðN; p1;LS Þ 4 ¼ ðN ; p1;LS Þ

N a θN
0  p0
N  θN
1  p1
N

L  θN
0  p0
L  θN
1  p1
L

K θU
0  θU
1 

a
 denotes that the action is infeasible. Fig. 4. The optimal consumption strategy pairs in the leasing model.

Table 7
Consumption strategies, limiting probabilities, and long-run average utilities in the leasing model.

Strategy Consumer state Limiting probabilities Long-run average utility

iLS
1 iLS
2 iLS
3 iLS
4 π iLS π iLS π iLS π iLS us ðpLS Þ
1 2 3 4

S1LS K L K L 0 q0 0 q1 ðq0 θN N
0 þ q1 θ1 Þ  ðq0 p0 þ q1 p1 Þ
L L

q0 q0 q1 q1
S2LS K N K L q20
1 þ q0 1 þ q0 1 þ q0
q0 θ N N 2 U U
0 þ q1 θ 1 þ q0 θ 0 þ q0 q1 θ 1 q pN þ q pL
 0 10 þ q 1 1
1 þ q0 1 þ q0 0
q0 q1 q0 q1
S3LS K L K N 1 þ q1 1 þ q1
q21
1 þ q1
q0 θ N N U 2 U
0 þ q1 θ 1 þ q0 q1 θ 0 þ q1 θ 1 q pN þ q pL
 1 11 þ q 0 0
1 þ q1 1 þ q1 1
144 K.J. Li, S.H. Xu / Omega 54 (2015) 134–146

preference between trade-in and leasing depends on parameter


values.

Proof of Theorem 4. The comparison between trade-in and


leasing can be done by calculating the difference in the manufac-
turer's maximum expected profits obtained under both strategies
(shown in Table 5 and Theorem 3). We use Region 1, the Low Price
region as an example. The manufacturer chooses between
ðS1TI ; S5Þ and ðS4; S6Þ in the trade-in model; and between
ðS1LS ; S5Þ and ðS4; S6Þ in the leasing model. We have

0 þ q1 p1  q0 θ 0  q1 θ 1
q0 pN
n n
N
uTI LS
ðS1;S5Þ  uðS1;S5Þ ¼ r0
2
n
n
ðS1;S5Þ r uðS4;S6Þ in
in Region 1. In addition, ðS4; S6Þ is chosen when uTI
the trade-in model. Hence, leasing yields the same or higher
maximum expected profit than trade-in in this region. The
Fig. 5. The comparison between trade-in and leasing in the balanced pricing region comparison in the other three new product pricing regions can
(Region 2). be performed in the same way. □

The preference of leasing in Region 1 is obvious. When new


residual value risk associated with one-period-old products when product prices are low, leasing enables the manufacturer to
trade-in is adopted; when leasing is employed though, it is the achieve higher profit because it can be priced independently from
manufacturer who bears this risk. the current selling price. The comparison in Region 2 is summar-
The result of the leasing model is summarized by Theorem 3 ized by Fig. 5. The shaded areas are where trade-in is preferred to
and Fig. 4. The proof is similar to that of Theorem 2 and therefore leasing; while the rest is where trade-in and leasing yield the
is omitted. same expected profit. Therefore, trade-in always performs at least
as good as leasing in this region. Line 7, as defined in Fig. 4, divides
Theorem 3. The optimal consumption strategy pair given difference
the optimal choice between ðS1LS ; S5Þ and ðS4; S6Þ in the leasing
product reuse profitability scenarios is shown in Fig. 4. The optimal
model. First consider the area above Line 7, where in the leasing
leasing prices are
model, the manufacturer should offer leasing at both innovation
0  q1 p1 þ q0 θ 0 þ q1 θ 1
ð1 þ q1 ÞpN states (i.e., ðS1LS ; S5Þ). When both v0 and v1 are large, i.e., when
n
N
pL0 ¼ ;
2 product reuse profitability is high at both innovation states, the
n  q0 p0 þ ð1 þ q0 Þp1 þ q0 θ0 þ q1 θ1
N N
manufacturer chooses to offer trade-in at both states (i.e.,
pL1 ¼ ;
2 ðS1TI ; S5Þ) in the trade-in model, and obtains the same expected
and the manufacturer's maximum expected profit given strategy pair profit as leasing. When either v0 or v1 is smaller, trade-in exhibits
ðS1LS ; S5Þ is its advantage over leasing. For instance, when v0 is smaller, the
manufacturer stops offering trade-in at state 0 and switches to
0 þ q1 p1 þq0 θ 0 þ q1 θ 1 þ 2q0 β þ 2q1 ðwL θ 1  γ Þ  2c
U
n q0 pN N
ðS2TI ; S5Þ, the state-1 trade-in only strategy. When leasing is
uLS
ðS1;S5Þ ¼ :
2 considered, it is still more profitable to choose ðS1LS ; S5Þ than
outright selling, but the manufacturer's expected profit is ham-
pered by less lucrative product reuse at state 0. Hence, in the
Line 7 in Fig. 4 delineates two regions: one region where shaded area above Line 7 and below Line 3 (marked as
product reuse profitability is high at both innovation states (i.e., “S2TI 4 S1LS ”), trade-in outperforms leasing. The same explanation
the region above Line 7), and the other region where both are low applies to the shaded area above Line 7 and below Line 4 where v1
compared to how H-consumers value the corresponding used is smaller. In the area below Line 7, when jointly considering v0
products (i.e., the region below Line 7). Recall that both β and and v1, outright selling is preferred to leasing. However, by
wL θ1  γ are in the objective functions of the three strategy pairs
U
offering state-specific trade-ins, the manufacturer can still benefit
(Eqs. (10)–(12)) because off-lease products are returned to the from encouraging product replacement and reuse. In summary,
manufacturer one period later when innovation state is uncertain. the flexibility of acting independently at different innovation
Therefore, it is preferred by the manufacturer to offer leasing only states makes tarde-in a preferred strategy in Region 2, the
when off-lease products can be reused profitably under both Balanced Pricing region.
innovation states; and when this criterion is indeed satisfied, the The comparison between trade-in and leasing in Regions 3 and
manufacturer is better off offering leasing at both innovation 4 is presented in Figs. 6 and 7, respectively, and can be understood
states, instead of offering it at just one of them. Hence, strategy as follows. Recall that in Region 3, the Low Introductory Pricing
pairs ðS2LS ; S5Þ and ðS3LS ; S5Þ are never optimal. region, the current new product price is relatively low when it is
first introduced to the market, i.e., pN0 is not much higher than p1 .
N

As summarized by Table 4, new product price and product reuse


5. The comparison between trade-in and leasing and the
profitability are the two factors driving the manufacturer's trade-
managerial implications
in decision, which in turn affects the preference between trade-in
and leasing. Compared to Region 2, the Balanced Pricing region,
We discuss the comparison between trade-in and leasing given
new product price plays a dominant role in the Low Introductory
the four new product pricing regions defined in Fig. 2. Theorem 4
Pricing region. By comparing Fig. 6 to Fig. 5, two main differences
summarizes strategy preference in the different pricing regions.
are observed. First is the dotted area in Fig. 6 where leasing yields
Theorem 4. Leasing is the preferred strategy in Region 1, the Low higher expected profit than trade-in, which does not exist in Fig. 5.
Price region; in Region 2, the Balanced Pricing region, trade-in is Trade-in is always at least as good as leasing in the Balanced
always at least as good as leasing; in Region 3, the Low Introductory Pricing region; however, in the Low Introductory Pricing region,
Pricing region and Region 4, the Deep Discounting region, the although trade-in is more flexible, leasing may prevail because it
K.J. Li, S.H. Xu / Omega 54 (2015) 134–146 145

enables the manufacturer to circumvent the relatively low new manufacturer and the optimal consumption strategies that hetero-
product price pN 0 by offering leasing at an independent price when geneous consumers should choose to maximize their own utility
product reuse profitability is high at both innovation states. under both the trade-in and leasing models. We then compare trade-
Second is that under Balanced Pricing, when v0 is small and v1 in and leasing in terms of the manufacturer's profitability.
is large, the state-1 trade-in only strategy S2TI is the most Several key insights gained from our analysis are summarized
preferred. Nonetheless, under Low Introductory Pricing, S2TI is as follows. First, a main difference between trade-in and leasing is
always dominated because of the relatively high pN 1 . Consequently, the timing of the return of used products. Used products are
when v0 is small, the manufacturer can no longer exploits the returned to the manufacturer immediately after consumers choose
flexibility of trade-in by resorting to the state-1 trade-in only to trade in. However, for leasing, consumers return their off-lease
strategy, but has to sell outright. Analogous to that in the Low products one period later when their leases end. Therefore when
Introductory Pricing region, reversing the situation at states 0 and trade-in is considered, the manufacturer has the flexibility to make
1 is true in Region 4, the Deep Discounting region and the result is trade-in decision at different innovation states independently. The
presented by Fig. 7. In short, when new product prices at the two manufacturer loses this flexibility when leasing is offered, which
innovation states are disproportional, the flexibility of trade-in is exposes her to residual value risk caused by the stochastic
restrained and leasing may be favored because it can be priced innovation process. Second, when current new product prices
separately to better capture consumer valuation. are low, leasing may enable the manufacturer to increase profit
by charging a separate leasing price, as opposed to trade-in where
consumers still purchase at the current selling price. Third, a
6. Conclusions and future research manufacturer who considers using trade-in or leasing to promote
product upgrading and replacement can use our models to assist
In this paper, we study the problem of a monopolistic manufac- her decision. As a first step, she should determine the new product
turer offering a technology product to a heterogeneous consumer pricing region that she belongs to. If her current pricing scheme is
population where trade-in or leasing can be provided either as an in the Low Price or the Balanced Pricing region, she knows
incentive to accelerate innovation adoption or as a means to facilitate immediately that leasing or trade-in is her optimal strategy,
replacing physically depreciated used products with brand-new ones. respectively. If her current pricing scheme is in the Low Introduc-
We characterize the optimal stationary pricing strategy for the tory Pricing or the Deep Discounting region, she needs to further

Fig. 6. The comparison between trade-in and leasing in the low introductory pricing region (Region 3).

Fig. 7. The comparison between trade-in and leasing in the deep discounting region (Region 4).
146 K.J. Li, S.H. Xu / Omega 54 (2015) 134–146

examine the profitability of product reuse at different innovation [19] Huang S, Yang Y, Anderson K. A theory of finitely durable goods monopoly
states. When new product price is relatively low at an innovation with used-goods market and transaction costs. Management Science 2001;47
(11):1515–32.
state and product reuse profitability at that state is much higher [20] Johnson J, Schneider HS, Waldman M. The role and growth of new-car leasing:
than that at the other state, trade-in is the preferred strategy theory and evidence. Journal of Law and Economics 2014;57(3):140–54.
because of its flexibility and risk-free nature to the manufacturer. [21] Ketzenberg M, Zuidwijk R. Optimal pricing, ordering and return policies for
Otherwise, leasing is the optimal strategy because it enables the consumer goods. Production and Operations Management 2009;18(3):344–60.
[22] Kornish LJ. Pricing for a durable-goods monopolist under rapid sequential
manufacturer to charge a higher price by introducing a new innovation. Management Science 2001;47(11):1552–61.
buying option. [23] Levinthal DA, Purohit D. Durable goods and product obsolescence. Marketing
For future research, it is interesting to consider an endogenous, Science 1989;8(1):35–56.
[24] Li Z, Ouyang M. A win-win marginal rent analysis for operator and consumer
stochastic innovation process where the manufacturer's invest-
under battery leasing mode in China electric vehicle market. Energy Policy
ment and effort level can affect the success of innovation. It will 2011;39(6):3222–37.
also be useful to examine how this endogenous innovation process [25] Longinidis P, Georgiadis MC. Integration of sale and leaseback in the optimal
interplays with the manufacturer's pricing decision. Instead of the design of supply chain networks. Omega 2014;47:73–89.
[26] Maukhopadhyay SK, Setoputro R. Optimal return policy and modular design for
two groups of consumers characterized in this paper, one can
build-to-order products. Journal of Operations Management 2005;23:496–506.
study a continuous spectrum of consumers to better capture the [27] Mitra S. Revenue management for remanufactured products. Omega 2007;35
interaction between consumers and consequently, between the (5):553–62.
primary and secondary markets. Moreover, we observe in practice [28] Moorthy KS, Png IPL. Market segmentation, cannibalization, and the timing of
product introductions. Management Science 1992;38(3):345–59.
the coexistence of trade-in and leasing offered by the same [29] Olivia R, Quinn J. Interface's evergreen services agreement. HBS Case 9-603-
manufacturer. Our modeling framework can be adapted to study 112. Cambridge MA: Harvard Business School; 2003.
the phenomenon. [30] Pierce L. Organizational structure and the limits of knowledge sharing:
incentive conflict and agency in car leasing. Management Science 2012;58
(6):1106–21.
References [31] Qiang Q, Ke K, Anderson T, Dong J. The closed-loop supply chain network with
competition, distribution channel investment, and uncertainties. Omega
[1] Agrawal V, Ferguson M, Souza G. Trade-in rebates for price discrimination and 2013;41(2):186–94.
product recovery. Working paper, 2014. [32] Rao RS, Narasimhan O, John G. Understanding the role of trade-ins and
[2] Agrawal V, Ferguson M, Toktay LB, Thomas V. Is leasing greener than selling? durable goods markets: theory and evidence. Marketing Science 2009;28
Management Science 2012;58(3):523–33. (5):950–67.
[3] Bhaskaran SR, Gilbert SM. Selling and leasing strategies for durable goods with [33] Ray S, Boyaci T, Aras N. Optimal prices and trade-in rebates for durable,
complementary products. Management Science 2005;51(8):1278–90. remanufacturable products. Manufacturing & Service Operations Management
[4] Bhaskaran SR, Gilbert SM. Implications of channel structure for leasing or 2005;7(3):208–28.
selling durable goods. Marketing Science 2009;28(5):918–34. [34] Ruiz-Benitez R, Ketzenberg M, van der Laan EA. Managing consume returns in
[5] Chen C. Design for the environment: a quality-based model for green product a high clockspeed industries. Omega 2014;43:54–63.
development. Management Science 2001;47(2):250–63. [35] Rust J. Stationary equilibrium in a market for durable assets. Econometrica
[6] Coase R. Durability and monopoly. Journal of Law and Economics 1972;15 1985;53(4):783–805.
(1):143–9. [36] Salema MIG, Barbosa-Povoa APFD, Novais AQ. Simultaneous design and
[7] Correa M. Treasure hunters. 〈www.hp.com〉; 2007. planning of supply chains with reverse flows: a generic modelling framework.
[8] Debo LG, Toktay LB, van Wassenhove LN. Market segmentation and product European Journal of Operational Research 2010;203:336–49.
technology selection for remanufacturerable products. Management Science [37] Silver M. Disparities in the prices of new and old models when they coexist in
2005;51(8):1193–205. the market: some econometric estimates. Omega 1999;27(1):13–24.
[9] Desai P, Purohit D. Leasing and selling: optimal marketing strategies for a [38] Network design for reverse logistics, Omega 36:535–48.
durable goods firm. Management Science 1998;44(11):S19–34. [39] Steinback K. Maintaining a vibrant presence: independents continue to evolve
[10] Dhebar A. Durable-goods monopolists, rational consumers, and improving in IT leasing. Monitor 2005;32(7):1–2.
products. Marketing Science 1994;13(1):100–20. [40] Su X. Consumer returns policies and supply chain performance. Manufactur-
[11] Equipment Leasing and Finance Association. 〈www.elfaonline.org〉. ing and Service Operations Management 2009;11:595–612.
[12] The compatibility of durable goods with contingent generic consumables. [41] Ta HP, Gn HL. Singapore leasing industry: an empirical study. Omega 1987;15
Omega 41;2013:574–85.
(4):301–11.
[13] Ferguson ME, Toktay LB. The effect of competition on recovery strategies.
[42] Vadde S, Zeid A, Kamarthi SV. Pricing decisions in a multi-criteria setting for
Production and Operations Management 2006;15(3):351–68.
product recovery facilities. Omega 2011;39(2):186–93.
[14] Fishbein BK, McGarry LS, Dillon PS. Leasing: a step toward producer respon-
[43] van Ackere A, Reyniers DJ. Trade-ins and introductory offers in a monopoly.
sibility. Report from INFORM Inc., New York; 2000. 〈www.informinc.org〉.
Rand Journal of Economics 1995;26(1):58–74.
[15] Francas, Minner DS. Manufacturing network configuration in supply chains
[44] Vorasayan J, Ryan SM. Optimal price and quantity of refurbished products.
with product recovery. Omega 2009;37(4):757–69.
[16] Fudenberg D, Tirole J. Upgrades, tradeins, and buybacks. The RAND Journal of Production and Operations Management 2006;15(3):369–83.
Economics 1998;29(2):235–58. [45] Waldman M. Planned obsolescence and the R&D decision. The RAND Journal
[17] Hu W, Li Y, Govindan K. The impact of consumer returns policies on consign- of Economics 1996;27(3):583–95.
ment contracts with inventory control. European Journal of Operational [46] Wang F, Lai X, Shi N. A multi-objective optimization for green supply chain
Research 2014;233(2):398–407. network design. Decision Support Systems 2011;51:262–9.
[18] Huang X, Gu J, Ching W, Siu T. Impact of secondary market on consumer [47] Wu C. OEM product design in a price competition with remanufactured
return policies and supply chain coordination. Omega 2014;45:57–70. products. Omega 2013;41:287–98.

You might also like