You are on page 1of 14

WHEN LINDER MEETS GRAVITY MODEL: THE CASE OF

USA, GERMANY AND JAPAN

Hrvoje JOŠIĆ
University of Zagreb, Faculty of Economics & Business, Kennedy sq 6, Zagreb, Croatia
hjosic@efzg.hr

Maja BAŠIĆ
University of Zagreb, Faculty of Economics & Business, Kennedy sq 6, Zagreb, Croatia
mbasic@efzg.hr

Abstract
This paper brings into conjunction the gravity model of international trade with the Linder
hypothesis. Both trade theories are “new trade” theories of international trade established in
the 60s and 70s of the last century after the Leontief testing of Heckscher-Ohlin theory. The
gravity model of international trade is similar to Isaac Newton's gravity model while Linder
hypothesis is a demand based theory. These two concepts are therefore mutually opposite. In
order to confront two important theories of international trade, bilateral trade data for
imports and manufactured imports specifically for three large World countries (the United
States, Germany and Japan) in the period from 2000 to 2016 are collected. Panel regression
models are constructed for both the gravity model and the Linder variable representing the
Linder effect. The Linder variable is specified as an absolute difference between partner
countries GDP’s per capita. The results of the analysis have shown that trade data for all
three observed countries comport with the gravity model of trade while the Linder effect could
not be confirmed.

Keywords: Linder hypothesis, gravity model of international trade, panel data

JEL classification: C13, F14

Introduction
After the neoclassical theory of international trade, namely Heckscher-Ohlin theory or Factor
proportions model (Heckscher, 1918 and Ohlin, 1931), and the Leontief test of Heckscher-
Ohlin theory in 1950's (Leontief, 1953) new trade theories have emerged. Two important new
trade theories which are subject of this paper are the gravity model of international trade
(Tinbergen, 1962) and the Linder theory of similar preferences also known as the Linder
hypothesis (Linder, 1961). The gravity model of international trade is based on Isaac
Newton's theory of gravity. The trade between two countries is proportional to their size and
reversely proportional to the distance between them. The augmented gravity model takes into
account additional variables such as remoteness, colonial ties, common border, common
language and dummy variables representing, for example, membership in WTO or regional
trade integrations. On the other hand, according to the Linder hypothesis the greater the
similarity between countries' economic structures, the greater the possibility of their mutual
trade. These two concepts are therefore mutually opposite. The goal of the paper is
confronting and bringing into conjunction these two new theories of international trade by
investigating patterns of trade flows (namely imports) for three large world countries (the
United States, Germany and Japan). The reason why these countries have been taken into

194
consideration is the essence of the Linder hypothesis according to which trade occur between
developed countries mostly in manufactured (industrial) products. It is contrary to the pattern
of trade in Heckscher-Ohlin theory where trade happens between capital abundant (developed
countries) and labour abundant (developing countries).

In this paper analysis will be conducted using panel OLS, fixed effects and random effects
regression analysis in the period from 2000 to 2016. An appropriate panel regression model
will be chosen with the help of the Hausman test and the redundant fixed-effect (log
likelihood) test. In order to decide which theory of international trade is suitable to data, the
signs of the regression coefficients for the Linder variable and the GDP of importing country
will be calculated and inspected. The paper is structured in five sections. After the
introduction, literature review presents and elaborates the theoretical and empirical features of
both trade theories. In the third chapter methodology and data are described while in the
fourth chapter the results of the econometric analysis are presented and discussed. The final
chapter is a conclusion.

Literature review
In his 1961 seminal paper Linder (Linder, 1961) coined the demand-oriented theory of
international trade, later named the Linder hypothesis. It was in contrast with supply-oriented
classical and neoclassical theories of international trade. According to Linder a country will
trade with countries of a similar level of economic development and similar demand
structures. The Linder variable catches the difference between countries gross domestic
products, the smaller the difference between them the higher expected trade between them
should occur. The Linder theory predicted patterns of trade between highly developed
countries in manufactured products (North-North trade) as opposed to trade between
developed and developing countries in primary products (North-South trade). The term
gravity model of international trade was first coined by Walter Isard (Isard, 1954) but was
established into practice by virtue of the efforts of Jan Tinbergen (Tinbergen, 1962). The main
critique of gravity model was that it is merely an econometric tool without a proper theoretical
basis. Various economists have nonetheless shown that the gravity model can arise from
various theories of international trade. According to Bergstrand (1985) gravity model is a
direct consequence of the trade model based on monopolistic competition developed by Paul
Krugman, Krugman (1980). Eaton and Kortum have shown that the gravity model can be
derived from a Ricardian type of model, Eaton and Kortum (2002). Helpman et al (2008)
obtained it from the theoretical model of international trade in differentiated goods with firm
heterogeneity (World Trade Organization, 2012).

The Linder hypothesis and the gravity model of international trade have often been
interconnected and studied simultaneously. In the next section empirical investigations on the
Linder hypothesis will be presented and explained. Kennedy and McHugh (1980) tested the
Linder hypothesis with the help of intertemporal approach with results not supporting the
Linder hypothesis. Limitation of the study refers to the use of total trade data rather than data
on trade in manufactures. Kennedy and McHugh (1983) found no support for the Linder
hypothesis for the United States in the years 1963, 1970 and 1974 using correlations analysis.
Arnon and Weinblatt (1998) tested the Linder effect in trade generally and in trade between
developed and less developed countries. Empirical evidence was provided that the Linder
effect can be found for both developed and less developed countries. McPherson, Redfearn
and Tieslau (2001) examined the Linder theory in the case of OECD countries using panel

195
dataset. The validity of the Linder hypothesis was approved for 18 out of 19 countries. Choi
(2002) presented a favourable result in support of the Linder hypothesis using a modified
gravity model with pooled trade data for 63 countries for various years in the period from
1970 to 1992. It seems that globalization may have strengthened the Linder hypothesis in
1990s as the coefficients of the Linder variable have a tendency to grow over time. The
Linder hypothesis was also supported in the case of India, Pakistan and Bangladesh, Bukhari
et al. (2005). Bohman and Nilsson (2007) introduced new methodology for testing the Linder
effect using the income distribution approach. It identified the common market between
trading partner countries by calculating the income overlap. The next step in the analysis was
to relate the size of the common market to size of the home market forming the new Linder
variable.

Hallak (2010) explained the reason for the failure of the Linder hypothesis in empirical
evidence. Using trade data aggregated across sectors is often an inappropriate theoretical
benchmark. Hallak proposed a theoretical framework in which product quality plays the
central role. Rauh (2010) reaffirmed the Linder hypothesis for Germany in trade with other
European countries using country panel and time fixed effects in the period from 2002 to
2007. Jian (2011) applied the gravity model on China-EU trade on a sample of 25 country-
pairs and 250 observations with panel data used to disentangle the time invariant country-
specific effects. Both the gravity model of trade and the Linder hypothesis seem to hold well
in empirical analysis. Bo (2013) found support for the Linder effect in bilateral trade between
China and its fourteen trading partners using the panel gravity model under fixed effects
estimation. Differential GDP per capita was used as a proxy variable for the Linder effect.
Kahram (2014) examined the Linder hypothesis for bilateral trade of Iran. Along with Linder
effect factors that mostly affected trade pattern of Iran there were political factors, economic
size, distance, common borders and others. Atabay (2015) applied the modified gravity model
using panel data analysis on BRIC’s countries trade in the period from 1996 to 2010.
Countries with smaller GDP per capita difference seem to tend to trade more. Steinbach
(2015) investigated the Linder hypothesis for bilateral export trade in agricultural and food
products on a sample of 152 countries in the period from 1995 to 2012. He formed a
similarity index analysing the estimates of the Linder term. His findings show that the
similarity effect is strongest for processed products and weakest for bulk products. Jošić and
Metelko (2018) tested the validity of the Linder hypothesis for Croatia using panel regression
analysis. The results of the analysis pointed to the rejection of the Linder hypothesis, due to
the fact that the pattern of Croatia's trade is in the line with gravity model of international
trade.

Methodology and data

The gravity model is a work-horse of international trade. It was introduced in economics by


Walter Isard in 1954 (Isard, 1954) but was established by Jan Tinbergen after his 1962
seminal paper (Tinbergen, 1962). The gravity model of international trade gives the
relationship between country size and geographical distance. Equation 1 presents a
formulation of the gravity model in multiplicative form:
(
$%& $'
!" =# * (1)
)%'

where !" represents trade flows (imports, exports or total trade), # is a constant, +! and +" are
economic sizes of trade partner countries expressed as GDP, ,!" is the distance between

196
country and country ! while ", # and $ are regression coefficients. The standard procedure
for estimating the gravity model is using natural logarithms of variables:

%&'() = * + "%&,-./( 0 + # ln1-./) 2 + $ ln1.() 2 + 3() (2)

The augmented gravity equation includes other variables such as adjacency, common
language, colonial links, remoteness and dummy variables representing membership in WTO
or regional trade agreements. The Linder variable is expressed as an absolute difference
between trade partner countries and ! GDPs per capita.

( )
4 &567 = 8-./9: ; -./9: 8 (3)

In Equations (5-8) linear relationship between variables is used because there is a problem of
trade zeroes in data due to the absence of trade between some countries.

<>?@7AB()C = * + "-./) + #DEFG + 3() (4)

<>?@7AB()C = * + "4 &567 + #DEFG + 3() (5)

HIJKLI:CKMNO
<>?@7AB()C = * + "4 &567 + #DEFG + 3() (6)

Figure 1 presents the expected theoretical relationship between manufactured imports and the
Linder variable and imports and the GDP variable. The larger the difference between
countries’ GDPs is (the Linder variable), the decrease in manufactured imports should be
larger. Furthermore, the larger the GDP of the exporting country !, the larger the imports from
abroad should be. Obviously, these two concepts can be approached only on higher levels of
GDP per capita while on lower levels of GDP per capita if the gravity model holds well, the
Linder effect should disappear.

Figure 1: Expected relationship Imports vs. P-./) and <>?@7ABHIJKLI:CKMQ vs. Linder
variable

Source: Authors' illustration

Econometric analysis will be conducted using a cross-country panel regression model starting
with the pooled OLS regression model presented in Equation 7.

197
Y ,! = "# + "$ X$, ,! + % + "& X&, ,! + ' ,! (7)

where Y is a dependent variable, X is an independent variable, (# is a constant, ($… () are


regression coefficients, *--and . are indices marking individual entities and time periods while
/ is an error term. In order to take into account heterogeneity in data for different countries
fixed and random effects modells are also constructed. A fixed effects model is presented in
Equation 8.
Y ,! = "# + 0# 123#
4# Dummy + "$ X $, ,! + "& X &, ,! + 5 ,! (8)

A random effects model is shown in Equations (9-11).

Y ,! = "# + "$ X$, ,! + % + "& X&, ,! + 6 ,! (9)

Y ,! = "# + "$ X$, ,! + % + "& X&, ,! + ' ,! + 6 ,! (10)

Y ,! = "# + "$ X$, ,! + % + "& X&, ,! + 7 ,! (11)

The redundant fixed effects test is used in order to differentiate between the pooled OLS and
the fixed effects model while the Hausman test is used to differentiate between the fixed
effects and the random effects model.

Results and discussion


Tables 1, 2 and 3 present the descriptive statistics of variables used in regression analysis.
Imports and Manufactured imports are dependent variables. GDP, Linder and Distance are
independent variables. Regressions are conducted individually for each of three countries, the
United States of America, Germany and Japan, in the period from 2000 to 2016.

Table 1: Descriptive statistics of variables, United States of America, 2000-2016


Imports GDP Linder Manufact. imports Distance
Mean 10470293 2.49E+11 34097.69 7684313 8869.16
Median 394260.2 2.00E+10 36056.53 113686.2 8601.8
Maximum 5.04E+08 1.12E+13 87250.09 4.87E+08 16350.4
Minimum 0 63101272 176.0650 0.000000 742.9
Std. Dev. 40480531 7.64E+11 13291.80 33179668 3582.497
Skewness 7.13 6.891 -0.557423 8.278704 -0.089511
Kurtosis 61.81 69.61 3.034744 89.01290 2.212661
Jarque-Bera 441017.8 557151.0 149.8089 923880.7 78.50590
Sum 3.03E+10 7.19E+14 98542331 2.22E+10 25631893
Sum Sq. Dev. 4.73E+18 1.69E+27 5.10E+11 3.18E+18 3.71E+10
Observations 2890 2890 2890 2890 2890

Table 2: Descriptive statistics of variables, Germany, 2000-2016


Imports GDP Linder Manufact. imports Distance
Mean 5310339 3.15E+11 26245.51 3693909 6177.21
Median 167058.5 2.00E+10 27152.91 32653.50 6152.5
Maximum 1.18E+08 1.86E+13 94804.92 1.07E+08 18122.9
Minimum 0 63101272 24.93981 0 281.2
Std. Dev. 14477199 1.32E+12 12773.76 10779818 3953.18
Skewness 4.06 9.025760 0.12 4.52 0.46
Kurtosis 21.78 97.97 4.10 28.51 2.87

198
Jarque-Bera 50440.21 1125485 154.74 88240.79 104.87
Sum 1.53E+10 9.10E+14 75849518 1.07E+10 17852144
Sum Sq. Dev. 6.06E+17 5.01E+27 4.71E+11 3.36E+17 4.51E+10
Observations 2890 2890 2890 2890 2890
Table 3: Descriptive statistics of variables, Japan, 2000-2016
Imports GDP Linder Manufact. imports Distance
Mean 3411937 3.06E+11 23506.29 1750598 10058.08
Median 60958.71 2.02E+10 25128.32 4716.321 9583.5
Maximum 1.89E+08 1.86E+13 101063 1.71E+08 18555.1
Minimum 0 63101272 10.09 0 1154.8
Std. Dev. 13015388 1.29E+12 11710.93 10213429 3699.87
Skewness 8.30 9.46 0.67 11.63 -0.195060
Kurtosis 91.88 106.42 7.18 160.64 2.48
Jarque-Bera 978834.2 1323270 2311.24 3039884 50.70
Sum 9.80E+09 8.79E+14 67533585 5.03E+09 28896874
Sum Sq. Dev. 4.87E+17 4.78E+27 3.94E+11 3.00E+17 3.93E+10
Observations 2873 2873 2873 2873 2873
Source: Authors' calculations

The number of cross-sections in the analysis for the United States and Germany is 170. San
Marino was excluded from analysis for Japan due to data unavailability so there are 169
cross-sections for Japan. Therefore, the total number of observations in the sample for the
United States of America and Germany is 2890 and 2873 for Japan. Figures 2, 3 and 4 present
scatter plot diagrams illustrating the relationship between dependent and independent
variables.

Figure 2: Scatter plot diagrams for dependent and independent variables, USA, 2000-2016

Source: Authors' illustration

199
Figure 3: Scatter plot diagrams for dependent and independent variables, Germany, 2000-
2016

Source: Authors' illustration

Figure 4: Scatter plot diagrams for imports and independent variables, Japan, 2000-2016

200
Source: Authors' illustration

In the figures 2, 3 and 4 a positive relationship between imports and GDP and a negative
relationship between imports and distance can be noticed as it could be expected from the
previous studies of the gravity model. The fitted regression line is also showing a negative
relationship between imports and the Linder variable suggesting the acceptance of the Linder
effect. In order to finally conclude whether the patterns of trade for three large World
countries are in accordance with the gravity model of trade or they are similar to the Linder
hypothesis, panel regression analysis is conducted.

The results of the cross-country panel regression analysis for the United States of America,
Germany and Japan in the period from 2000 to 2016 are displayed in Tables A1-A3 (in
Appendix). In order to choose between the pooled OLS, fixed effects and random effects
model, the Hausman test and the redundant fixed effects tests are conducted. The redundant
fixed effects test (log likelihood test) is used in order to choose between the pooled OLS and
fixed effects model. Cross-section F and cross-section Chi-Square statistics probabilities for
all models were under 5 percent of probability indicating that the fixed effects model is
preferable over the pooled OLS so there existed a heterogeneity in cross-section data. The
Hausman test is used to choose between the fixed effects and random effects model. The
random effects model is appropriate in all cases for the United States and Germany. The
random effects model is acceptable for Japan under 10 percent of probability while in the case
of imports of manufactures the fixed effects model was appropriate. GDP is statistically
significant independent variable in regression under 1%, 5% and 10% percent of significance
showing a positive relationship with the imports variable. The distance variable is statistically
significant in the pooled OLS and random effects model with a negative relationship to
dependent variable as predicted from the standard gravity model. However, the distance
variable was excluded from the fixed effects model due to time invariant characteristics of
data. The sign of the Linder variable for imports in Table A2 in the random and fixed effects
model is positive indicating refusal of the Linder hypothesis although the pooled OLS model
and scatter plot diagrams were suggesting the opposite. Applying the robustness check in

201
Table A3 by taking only manufactured imports (as suggested in the Linder seminal paper) is
also suggesting the refusal of the Linder hypothesis. It can be concluded that the United
States, Germany and Japan import trade patterns follow the standard gravity model while the
Linder hypothesis cannot be accepted.

Conclusion
The goal of the paper was to investigate trade patterns for three large World countries (the
United States, Germany and Japan). The research question asked was whether trade data
better fit the gravity model of trade or the Linder hypothesis. The method applied in the
analysis was panel regression analysis consisting of pooled OLS, fixed effects and random
effects models. The random effects model was preferable in most cases as most applicable to
data. The results of the analysis have shown that trade patterns of bilateral trade for three large
countries in the World behave according to the gravity model of trade. On the other hand, the
validity of the Linder hypothesis could not be approved because signs of the Linder variable
under the random and fixed effects models were positive leading to rejection of the Linder
hypothesis. The limitations of the paper are related to the observance of only 3 large
countries. Due to the paper length restriction it was optimal to analyse these three countries
because there was a large number of observations on bilateral trade for each observed country.
Also there was a problem of the distance variable which could not be included in the fixed
effects model due to time-invariant characteristics of data. The research conducted can lead to
the need for further research by inclusion of other countries into analysis, especially
developing countries and countries in development. In that case the theory of gravity model
and the Linder hypothesis should be on opposite sides, i.e., the acceptance of one theory
should lead to rejection of other.

References

Arnon, A.,& Weinblatt, J. (1998). Linder's hypothesis revisited: income similarity effects for low income
countries. Applied Economics Letters, 5(10), 607-611. DOI: 10.1080/135048598354267.

Atabay, R. (2015). Validity of Linder Hypothesis in BRIC countries. Journal of International Trade, Logistics
and Law, 1(2) 2, 85-92.

Bergstrand, J. H. (1985). The gravity equation in international trade: some microeconomic foundations and
empirical evidence. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 67(3), 474–481.

Bo, P. (2013). Bilateral trade of China and the Linder hypothesis: A gravity model approach. Bachelor Thesis
within Economics. Retrived from: http://www.diva-portal.org/smash/record.jsf?pid=diva2%3A605666&dswid=-
5886 [4 March 2019].

Bohman, H., & Nilsson, D. (2007). Market overlap and the direction of exports: A new approach of assessing the
Linder hypothesis. Working Paper Series in Economics and Institutions of Innovation 86, Royal Institute of
Technology, CESIS - Centre of Excellence for Science and Innovation Studies. Retrived from:
https://ideas.repec.org/p/hhs/cesisp/0086.html [4 March 2019].

Bukhari, S. et al. (2005). An Empirical Analysis of the Linder Theory of International Trade for South Asian
Countries. The Pakistan Development Review, 44(3), 307-320.

202
Byers, J. A. (2000). Great Circle Distances Between Capital Cities. Retrived from: http://www.chemical-
ecology.net/java/capitals.htm [4 March 2019].

Choi, C. (2002). Linder Hypothesis Revisited. Applied Economics Letters, 9(9), 601-605.

Distance calculator. Retrived from: https://www.distancecalculator.net/ [4 March 2019].

Eaton, J., & Kortum, S. (2002). Technology, geography and trade. Econometrica 70, 1741–1779.

Hallak, J. C. (2010). A product-quality view of the Linder hypothesis. The Review of Economics and Statistics,
92(3), 453-466.

Helpman, E., Melitz, M., & Rubinstein, Y. (2008). Trading partners and trade volumes. Quarterly Journal of
Economics, 123, 441–487.

Isard, W. (1954). Location Theory and Trade Theory: Short-Run Analysis. Quarterly Journal of
Economics, 68(2):305. DOI: 10.2307/1884452.

Jošić, H., & Metelko, M. (2018). Testing the validity of the Linder hypothesis for Croatia. Croatian Review of
Economic, Business and Social Statistics (CREBSS), 4(1), 62-73.

Jian, Z. (2011). Based on gravity trade model and Linder Hypothesis: An Empirical Application to China-EU
Trade Flows. Business Management and Electronic Information (BMEI), 13-15 May 2011, Guangzhou, China.

Kahram, A. (2014). The Comparative Analysis of the Linder Hypothesis:The Bilateral Trade Model between
Iran and Its Trade Partners. Advances in Economics and Business Management (AEBM), 1(1), 1-8.

Kennedy, T., & McHugh R. (1980). An Intertemporal Test and Rejection of the Linder Hypothesis. Southern
Economic Journal, 46(3), 898-903.

Kennedy, T. E., & McHugh, R. (1983). Taste Similarity and Trade Intensity: A Test of the Linder Hypothesis for
U. S. Exports. Weltwirtschaftliches-Archiv, 119(1), 84-96.

Krugman, P. (1980). Scale economies, product differentiation and the pattern of trade. American Economic
Review, 70, 950–959.

Linder, S. B. (1961). An Essay on Trade and Transformation. New York: Wiley and Sons.

McPherson, M. A., Redfearn, M. R., & Tieslau M. A. (2001). International Trade and Developing Countries: An
Empirical Investigation of the Linder Hypothesis. Applied Economics, 33, 649-657.

Niem, L. D. (2016). Linder Hypothesis and Trade of Quality Differentiated Good: A Case of Cosmetic Industry
of China. Modern Economy, 7(3), 307-313.

Ohlin, B. (1933). Interregional and International Trade. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

Rauh, A. (2010). Empirical analysis of the Linder hypothesis: The case of Germany's trade within Europe. The
American Economist, 55(2), 136-141.

Steinbach, S. (2015). Bilateral export trade and income similarity: Does the Linder hypothesis hold for
agricultural and food trade?. AgEcon Search, Research in Agricultural & Applied Economics, Conference Paper
2015-05, 110-114.

Tinbergen, J. (1962). Shaping the World Economy. Suggestion for an International Economic Policy, New York.

World Bank (2018). GDP (Current US$). Retrived from:


https://data.worldbank.org/indicator/NY.GDP.MKTP.CD [4 March 2019].

203
World Bank (2018a). GDP per capita (Current US$). Retrieved from:
https://data.worldbank.org/indicator/NY.GDP.PCAP.CD [4 March 2019].

World Integrated Trade Solution (2018). Imports. Retrived from:


https://wits.worldbank.org/CountryProfile/en/Country/USA/StartYear/2000/EndYear/2016/TradeFlow/Import/Pa
rtner/ALL/Indicator/MPRT-TRD-VL [4 March 2019].

World Integrated Trade Solution (2018a). Manufactured imports. Retrived from:


https://wits.worldbank.org/CountryProfile/en/Country/USA/StartYear/2000/EndYear/2016/TradeFlow/Import/In
dicator/MPRT-TRD-VL/Partner/BY-COUNTRY/Product/manuf [4 March 2019].

World Trade Organization (2012). A Practical Guide to Trade Policy Analysis. Available Retrived from:
https://www.wto.org/english/res_e/publications_e/wto_unctad12_e.pdf [4 March 2019].

204
Appendix

Table A1: Cross-country panel regression analysis for imports, GDP and distance
variable, USA, Germany and Japan, 2000-2016
Dependent
variable
United States of America Germany Japan
Total
imports
Independen
Rando
t Pooled Fixed Random Pooled Fixed Random Pooled Fixed
m
variable/M OLS effects effects OLS effects effects OLS effects
effects
odel
2809552 12082766 9974908 2748243 9407126 7844842 1034206 738910
9706496**
*** ** *** *** *** *** *** 8***
Constant *
(15.6742 (2.270519 (26.2533 (29.2111 (6.41213 (15.7464 (12.9037 (3.8485
(7.181151)
7) ) 9) 4) 3) 8) 9) 55)
3.08E- 3.10E- 6.40E- 8.14E- 7.97E- 6.83E- 7.77E- 7.68E-
3.92E-
05*** 05*** 06*** 06*** 06*** 06*** 06*** 06***
GDP 05***
(68.8128 (70.19313 (41.6206 (41.7459 (42.8359 (51.6575 (46.3624 (48.002
(59.69871)
6) ) 0) 7) 2) 9) 7) 48)
- - - -
-
- 1081.62 1069.490 648.5661 629.05
1012.818*
1052.309 3*** *** *** 74***
Distance **
* (- (- (- (- (-
(-
1.891985) 21.1001 5.351585 14.06483 3.5140
7.238431)
4) ) ) 20)
Adjusted R- 0.43425 0.92988 0.4469
0.557232 0.965194 0.629606 0.391700 0.508651 0.935665
squared 8 7 09
S.E. of 1088914 330260
26936061 7552181 7566725 3833385 3838177 9123301 3301276
regression 5 1
Prob. (F- 0.0000
0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000
statistic) 0
Mean dep. 1047029 317401
10470293 5310339 5310339 479403 3411937 3411937
variable 3 738328.3 .6
S.D.
4048053 1447719 1447719 1301538 1301538 444076
dep.variabl 40480531 12433010 4921145
1 9 9 8 8 7
e
Akaike info 35.2454 33.2137
crit. 37.05687 34.56992 7 4 34.89161 32.91486
Durbin - 0.02998 0.25068 0.4034
Watson 0.029163 0.371706 0.349072 2 4 0.235905 0.053089 0.428641 85
Observatio
2890 2890 2890 2890 2890 2890 2873 2873 2873
ns
Hausman Chi-Sq. Statistic (12.129), Prob. Chi-Sq. Statistic (8.222882), Chi-Sq. Statistic (3.304931),
test (0.0005) Prob. (0.0041) Prob. (0.0691)
Cross-section F (205.167), Prob. Cross-section F (143.010854), Cross-section F (123.374346),
Redundant
(0.000) Prob. (0.00) Prob. (0.00)
fixed
Cross-section Chi-Square Cross-section Chi-Square Cross-section Chi-Square
effects test
(7575.263), Prob. (0.000) (6622.174), Prob. (0.00) (6204.6753), Prob. (0.00)
Source: Authors'
calculations
T- statistics in parentheness, *** significant at 1 percent level, ** significant at 5 percent level, * significant at 1
percent level.

Table A2: Cross-country panel regression analysis for imports, Linder and distance

205
variable, USA, Germany and Japan, 2000-2016
Dependent
variable
United States of America Germany Japan
Total
imports
Independent Rando
Pooled Fixed Random Pooled Fixed Random Pooled Fixed
variable/Mo m
OLS effects effects OLS effects effects OLS effects
del effects
10465
367248 4140788 16824556 2065372 3362195 1115678 13343072 2168180
293**
79*** *** ** 1*** *** 6*** *** ***
Constant *
(14.690 (2.78530 (2.153384 (34.0540 (8.09605 (6.59837 (16.17824 (4.85619
(3.874
57) 2) ) 4) 8) 5) ) 5)
575)
- -
-
571.412 185.6285 158.1352* 392.7801 74.22770 53.67004 52.91167 45.793
79.64710
5*** *** ** *** *** *** *** 09***
Linder ***
(- (4.31026 (3.728400 (- (4.80780 (3.53697 (2.83440 (2.511
(-
10.0920 6) ) 20.26503 4) 1) 3) 604)
3.954189)
6) )
- - - -
-
763.401 - 815.0388 1174.485 808.28
801.2388
6*** 1324.398* *** *** 34***
Distance ***
(- (- (- (- (-
(-
3.63400 1.638131) 13.01380 5.181867 3.2461
12.56740)
4) ) ) 46)
Adjusted R- 0.04436 0.0051
0.905226 0.004839 0.207526 0.885919 0.011917 0.056936 0.884846
squared 0 15
S.E. of 395724 1246206 1288774 44183
12489106 4889799 4932882 12639434 4416682
regression 93 3 6 41
Prob. (F- 0.0000
0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000
statistic) 0
Mean dep. 104702 1047029 30522
838828.2 5310339 5310339 539961.6 3411937 3411937
variable 93 3 8.9
S.D. 404805 4048053 1447719 1447719 1301538 44296
12519434 4962539 13015388
dep.variable 31 1 9 9 8 85
Akaike info 37.8262
crit. 0 35.57162 35.58249 33.70055 35.54359 33.49702
Durbin - 0.01666 0.2556
Watson 9 0.168301 0.157774 0.030212 0.192319 0.177998 0.031672 0.271518 08
Observation
2890 2890 2890 2890 2890 2890 2873 2873 2873
s
Hausman Chi-Sq. Statistic (13.543435), Chi-Sq. Statistic (52.096880), Chi-Sq. Statistic (3.156579),
test Prob. (0.0002) Prob. (0.0000) Prob. (0.0756)
Cross-section F (156.952283), Cross-section F (109.540136), Cross-section F (131.515652),
Redundant
Prob. (0.000) Prob. (0.00) Prob. (0.00)
fixed effects
Cross-section Chi-Square Cross-section Chi-Square Cross-section Chi-Square
test
(6864.929), Prob. (0.000) (5939.561), Prob. (0.00) (6367.6764), Prob. (0.00)
Source: Authors'
calculations
T- statistics in parentheness, *** significant at 1 percent level, ** significant at 5 percent level, * significant at
10 percent level.

206
Table A3: Cross-country panel regression analysis for manufactured imports, Linder
and distance variable, USA, Germany and Japan, 2000-2016
Dependent
variable
Manufactu United States of America Germany Japan
red
imports
Independe
Rando Rando
nt Pooled Fixed Pooled Fixed Random Pooled Fixed
m m
variable/M OLS effects OLS effects effects OLS effects
effects effects
odel
236017 912843 9002395* 118204 70273
2558776* 13962846* 2209195** 7231681**
98*** 2 ** 8*** 96***
Constant (1.915951 ** * *
(11.421 (1.4216 (13.84167 (3.3623 (3.297
) (30.17065) (7.157448) (5.559093)
05) 97) ) 98) 673)
-
-
404.301 150.3192 126.293 - 24.1871 19.321
56.57019* 43.01536* 66.76678
2*** *** 8*** 273.4162** 2* 91
Linder ** ** ***
(- (3.885406 (3.3246 * (1.6455 (1.345
(4.929942) (3.809655) (-
8.63809 ) 14) (-18.48682) 37) 778)
4.203423)
4)
- - -
- -
240.354 648.363 - 569.78
755.4755* 564.9543
7 5 500.7099** 90***
Distance ** ***
(- (- * (- (-
(- (-
1.38410 0.97775 10.47737) 2.9002
4.327512) 11.23704)
0) 4) 71)
Adjusted 0.02797 0.00334 0.88406 0.0028
0.886156 0.167756 0.886339 0.009988 0.047639
R-squared 5 8 3 42
S.E. of 327122 112139 347762 34784
11195080 9834145 3634274 3661201 9967184
regression 76 57 6 67
Prob. (F- 0.0000
0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000
statistic) 0
Mean dep. 768431 674381. 175059 15628
7684313 3693909 3693909 362401.9 1750598
variable 3 4 8 5.2
S.D.
331796 112327 102134 34834
dep.variabl 33179668 10779818 10779818 3679623 10213429
68 79 29 20
e
Akaike 37.4454 33.0189
35.35719 35.04166 33.10706 35.06854
info crit. 4 5
Durbin - 0.01285 0.10233 0.12111 0.1140
0.109027 0.024850 0.164442 0.152661 0.014136
Watson 3 1 0 31
Observatio
2890 2890 2890 2890 2890 2890 2873 2873 2873
ns
Hausman Chi-Sq. Statistic (10.744202), Chi-Sq. Statistic (43.939104), Prob. Chi-Sq. Statistic (2.387618),
test Prob. (0.001) (0.000) Prob. (0.1223)
Cross-section F (129.865), Cross-section F (113.75034), Prob. Cross-section F (130.415225),
Redundant
Prob. (0.000) (0.000) Prob. (0.000)
fixed
Cross-section Chi-Square Cross-section Chi-Square Cross-section Chi-Square
effects test
(6372.93873), Prob. (0.000) (6034.826442), Prob. (0.000) (6346.177313), Prob. (0.000)
Source: Authors' calculations
T- statistics in parentheness, *** significant at 1 percent level, ** significant at 5 percent level, * significant at
10 percent level.

207

You might also like