You are on page 1of 47

Journal of Economic Literature

Vol. XXXVII (December 1999), pp. 1661–1707

Clarida, Galí, Gertler: The Science of Monetary Policy

The Science of Monetary Policy:


A New Keynesian Perspective
Richard Clarida, Jordi Galí, and Mark Gertler 1
“Having looked at monetary policy from both sides now, I can testify that
central banking in practice is as much art as science. Nonetheless, while
practicing this dark art, I have always found the science quite useful.”2
Alan S. Blinder

1. Introduction Two main factors underlie this re-


birth of interest. First, after a long pe-
T HERE HAS BEEN a great resurgence
of interest in the issue of how to con-
duct monetary policy. One symptom of
riod of near exclusive focus on the role
of nonmonetary factors in the business
cycle, a stream of empirical work begin-
this phenomenon is the enormous vol- ning in the late 1980s has made the case
ume of recent working papers and con- that monetary policy significantly influ-
ferences on the topic. Another is that ences the short-term course of the real
over the past several years many leading economy. 3 The precise amount remains
macroeconomists have either proposed open to debate. On the other hand,
specific policy rules or have at least there now seems to be broad agreement
staked out a position on what the general that the choice of how to conduct
course of monetary policy should be. monetary policy has important conse-
John Taylor’s recommendation of a sim- quences for aggregate activity. It is no
ple interest rate rule (Taylor 1993a) is a longer an issue to downplay.
well-known example. So too is the recent Second, there has been considerable
widespread endorsement of inflation tar- improvement in the underlying theoret-
geting (e.g., Ben Bernanke and Frederic ical frameworks used for policy analysis.
Mishkin 1997). To provide theoretical underpinnings,
1 Clarida: Columbia University and NBER; Galí: the literature has incorporated the tech-
New York University, Universitat Pompeu Fabra, niques of dynamic general equilibrium
CEPR, and NBER; Gertler: New York University theory pioneered in real business cycle
and NBER. Thanks to Ben Bernanke, Bob King,
Ben McCallum, Albert Marcet, Rick Mishkin,
Athanasios Orphanides, Glenn Rudebusch, Chris 3 Examples include Romer and Romer (1988),
Sims, Lars Svensson, Andres Velasco, and several Bernanke and Blinder (1992), Galí (1992), Ber-
anonymous referees for helpful comments, and to nanke and Mihov (1997a), Christiano, Eichen-
Tommaso Monacelli for excellent research assis- baum, and Evans (1996, 1998) and Leeper, Sims
tance. Authors Galí and Gertler are grateful to the and Zha (1996). Much of the literature has fo-
C.V. Starr Center for Applied Economics, and cused on the effects of monetary policy shocks.
(Galí) to CREI for financial support. e-mail: Bernanke, Gertler, and Watson (1997) present evi-
mark.gertler@econ.nyu.edu dence that suggests that the monetary policy rule
2 Blinder 1997, p. 17. may have important effects on real activity.
1661
1662 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXVII (December 1999)

analysis. A key point of departure from and applied work, as we discuss later. 4
real business cycle theory (as we later There are, however, important strands
make clear) is the explicit incorporation of the literature that either reject the
of frictions such as nominal price rigidi- idea of nominal price rigidities (e.g.,
ties that are needed to make the frame- real business cycle theory) or focus on
work suitable for evaluation of monetary other types of nominal rigidities, such
policy. as frictions in money demand. 5 For this
This paper summarizes what we have reason, we append “New Keynesian
learned from this recent research on Perspective” to the title. In particular,
monetary policy. We review the prog- we wish to make clear that we adopt the
ress that has been made and also iden- Keynesian approach of stressing nomi-
tify the central questions that remain. nal price rigidities, but at the same time
To organize the discussion, we exposit base our analysis on frameworks that in-
the monetary policy design problem in a corporate the recent methodological ad-
simple theoretical model. We start with vances in macroeconomic modeling
a stripped-down baseline model in or- (hence the term “New”).
der to characterize a number of broad Section 2 lays out the formal policy
principles that underlie optimal policy problem. We describe the baseline
management. We then consider the im- theoretical model and the objectives of
plications of adding various real world policy. Because we are interested in
complications. Finally, we assess how characterizing policy rules in terms of
the predictions from theory square with primitive factors, the model we use
policy-making in practice. evolves from first principles. Though it
Throughout, we concentrate on ex- is quite simple, it nonetheless contains
positing results that are robust across a the main ingredients of descriptively
wide variety of macroeconomic frame- richer frameworks that are used for pol-
works. As Ben McCallum (1997b) em- icy analysis. Within the model, as in
phasizes, the key stumbling block for practice (we argue), the instrument of
policy formation is limited knowledge monetary policy is a short-term interest
of the way the macroeconomy works. rate. The policy design problem then is
Results that are highly model-specific to characterize how the interest rate
are of limited use. This literature, how- should adjust to the current state of the
ever, contains a number of useful prin- economy.
ciples about optimal policy that are rea- An important complication is that pri-
sonably general in applicability. In this vate sector behavior depends on the ex-
respect there is a “science of monetary pected course of monetary policy, as
policy,” as Alan Blinder suggests in the well as on current policy. The credibil-
quote above. We provide support for ity of monetary policy thus becomes
this contention in the pages that follow. relevant, as a considerable contemporary
At the same time, we should make literature has emphasized. 6 At issue is
clear that the approach we take is based
on the idea that temporary nominal 4 See, for example, the survey by Goodfriend

price rigidities provide the key friction and King (1997).


5 See, for example, Christiano, Eichenbaum,
that gives rise to nonneutral effects of and Evans (1997). For an analysis of monetary pol-
monetary policy. The propositions we icy rules in these kinds of models—known as “lim-
derive are broadly applicable within this ited participation” frameworks—see Christiano
and Gust (1999).
class of models. This approach has 6 For a recent survey of the credibility litera-
widespread support in both theoretical ture, see Persson and Tabellini (1997).
Clarida, Galí, Gertler: The Science of Monetary Policy 1663

whether there may be gains from en- gain from commitment then is to elimi-
hancing credibility either by formal nate this inflationary bias. How realistic
commitment to a policy rule or by intro- it is to presume that a perceptive cen-
ducing some kind of institutional ar- tral bank will try to inadvisedly reap
rangement that achieves roughly the short-term gains from pushing output
same end. We address the issue by ex- above its natural level is a matter of re-
amining optimal policy for both cases: cent controversy (e.g., Blinder 1997;
with and without commitment. Along McCallum 1997a). We demonstrate,
with expositing traditional results, we however, that there may be gains from
also exposit some new results regarding commitment simply if current price set-
the gains from commitment. ting depends on expectations of the fu-
Section 3 derives the optimal policy ture. In this instance, a credible com-
rule in the absence of commitment. If mitment to fight inflation in the future
for no other reason, this case is of inter- can improve the current output/infla-
est because it captures reality: No ma- tion trade-off that a central bank faces.
jor central bank makes any type of bind- Specifically, it can reduce the effective
ing commitment over the future course cost in terms of current output loss that
of its monetary policy. A number of is required to lower current inflation.
broad implications emerge from this This result, we believe, is new in the
baseline case. Among these: The opti- literature.
mal policy embeds inflation targeting in In practice, however, a binding com-
the sense that it calls for gradual adjust- mitment to a rule may not be feasible
ment to the optimal inflation rate. The simply because not enough is known
implication for the policy rule is that about the structure of the economy or
the central bank should adjust the the disturbances that buffet it. Under
nominal short rate more than one-for- certain circumstances, however, a pol-
one with expected future inflation. That icy rule that yields welfare gains rela-
is, it should adjust the nominal rate suf- tive to the optimum under discretion
ficiently to alter the real rate (and thus may be well approximated by an opti-
aggregate demand) in the direction that mal policy under discretion that is ob-
is offsetting to any movement in ex- tained by assigning a higher relative
pected inflation. Finally, how the cen- cost to inflation than the true social
tral bank should adjust the interest rate cost. A way to pursue this policy opera-
in response to output disturbances de- tionally is simply to appoint a central bank
pends critically on the nature of the dis- chair with a greater distaste for infla-
turbances: It should offset demand tion than society as a whole, as Kenneth
shocks but accommodate supply shocks, Rogoff (1985) originally emphasized.
as we discuss. Section 5 considers a number of prac-
Section 4 turns to the case with com- tical problems that complicate policy-
mitment. Much of the literature has making. These include: imperfect infor-
emphasized that an inefficiently high mation and lags, model uncertainty and
steady state inflation rate may arise in non-smooth preferences over inflation
the absence of commitment, if the cen- and output. A number of pragmatic is-
tral bank’s target for real output ex- sues emerge, such as: whether and how
ceeds the market clearing level. 7 The to make use of intermediate targets, the
7 The potential inflationary bias under discre-
choice of a monetary policy instrument,
tion was originally emphasized by Kydland and and why central banks appear to smooth
Prescott (1977) and Barro and Gordon (1983). interest rate changes. Among other
1664 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXVII (December 1999)

things, the analysis makes clear why that U.S. monetary policy in the fifteen
modern central banks (especially the years or so prior to Paul Volcker did not
Federal Reserve Board) have greatly always follow the principles we have de-
downgraded the role of monetary aggre- scribed. Simply put, interest rate man-
gates in the implementation of policy. agement during this era tended to ac-
The section also shows how the recently commodate inflation. Under Volcker
advocated “opportunistic” approach to and Greenspan, however, U.S. mone-
fighting inflation may emerge under a tary policy adopted the kind of implicit
non-smooth policy objective function. inflation targeting that we argue is
The opportunistic approach boils down consistent with good policy management.
to trying to keep inflation from rising The section also considers some pol-
but allowing it to ratchet down in the icy proposals that focus on target vari-
event of favorable supply shocks. ables, including introducing formal
As we illustrate throughout, the opti- inflation or price-level targets and
mal policy depends on the degree of nominal GDP targeting. There is in ad-
persistence in both inflation and out- dition a brief discussion of the issue of
put. The degree of inflation persistence whether indeterminacy may cause prac-
is critical since this factor governs the tical problems for the implementation of
output/inflation trade-off that the pol- simple interest rate rules. Finally, there
icy-maker faces. In our baseline model, are concluding remarks in section 8.
persistence in inflation and output is
due entirely to serially correlated ex- 2. A Baseline Framework for Analysis
ogenous shocks. In section 6 we con- of Monetary Policy
sider a hybrid model that allows for en-
dogenous persistence in both inflation This section characterizes the formal
and output. The model nests as special monetary policy design problem. It first
cases our forward-looking baseline presents a simple baseline macro-
model and, also, a more traditional economic framework, and then de-
backward-looking Keynesian frame- scribes the policy objective function.
work, similar to the one used by Lars The issue of credibility is taken up next.
Svensson (1997a) and others. In this regard, we describe the distinc-
Section 7 moves from theory to prac- tion between optimal policies with and
tice by considering a number of pro- without credible commitment—what
posed simple rules for monetary policy, the literature refers to as the cases of
including the Taylor rule, and a forward- “rules versus discretion.”
looking variant considered by Clarida, 2.1 A Simple Macroeconomic
Galí, and Gertler (1998; forthcoming). Framework
Attention has centered around simple
rules because of the need for robust- Our baseline framework is a dynamic
ness. A policy rule is robust if it pro- general equilibrium model with money
duces desirable results in a variety of and temporary nominal price rigidities.
competing macroeconomic frameworks. In recent years this paradigm has be-
This is tantamount to having the rule come widely used for theoretical analy-
satisfy the criteria for good policy man- sis of monetary policy. 8 It has much of
agement that sections 2 through 6 es- the empirical appeal of the traditional
tablish. Further, U.S. monetary policy may 8 See, e.g, Goodfriend and King (1997), McCal-
be judged according to this same met- lum and Nelson (1997), Walsh (1998), and the ref-
ric. In particular, the evidence suggests erences therein.
Clarida, Galí, Gertler: The Science of Monetary Policy 1665

IS/LM model, yet is grounded in dy- In addition, let πt be the period t infla-
namic general equilibrium theory, in tion rate, defined as the percent change
keeping with the methodological ad- in the price level from t–1 to t; and let i t
vances in modern macroeconomics. be the nominal interest rate. Each vari-
Within the model, monetary policy able is similarly expressed as a deviation
affects the real economy in the short from its long-run level.
run, much as in the traditional Keynes- It is then possible to represent the
ian IS/LM framework. A key difference, baseline model in terms of two equa-
however, is that the aggregate behav- tions: an “IS” curve that relates the out-
ioral equations evolve explicitly from put gap inversely to the real interest
optimization by households and firms. rate; and a Phillips curve that relates
One important implication is that cur- inflation positively to the output gap.
rent economic behavior depends criti- xt = − ϕ[it − Etπt + 1] + Etxt + 1 + gt (2.1)
cally on expectations of the future
course of monetary policy, as well as on πt = λxt + βEtπt + 1 + ut (2.2)
current policy. In addition, the model where gt and ut are disturbances terms
accommodates differing views about that obey, respectively:
how the macroeconomy behaves. In the gt = µgt − 1 + ^
gt (2.3)
limiting case of perfect price flexibility,
for example, the cyclical dynamics re- ut = ρut − 1 + ^
ut (2.4)
semble those of a real business cycle where 0 ≤ µ,ρ ≤ 1 and where both gt and ^
model, with monetary policy affecting ^t are i.i.d. random variables with zero mean
u
only nominal variables. and variances σ2g and σ2u, respectively.
Rather than work through the details Equation (2.1) is obtained by log-
of the derivation, which are readily linearizing the consumption euler equa-
available elsewhere, we instead directly tion that arises from the household’s
introduce the key aggregate relation- optimal saving decision, after imposing
ships. 9 For convenience, we abstract the equilibrium condition that con-
from investment and capital accumula- sumption equals output minus govern-
tion. This abstraction, however, does ment spending. 11 The resulting expres-
not affect any qualitative conclusions, as sion differs from the traditional IS
we discuss. The model is as follows: curve mainly because current output
Let y t and z t be the stochastic compo- depends on expected future output as
nents of output and the natural level of well as the interest rate. Higher ex-
output, respectively, both in logs.10 The pected future output raises current out-
latter is the level of output that would put: Because individuals prefer to
arise if wages and prices were perfectly
11 Using the market clearing condition Y = C + E ,
flexible. The difference between actual t t t
where E t is government consumption, we can re-
and potential output is an important vari- write the log-linearized consumption Euler equa-
able in the model. It is thus convenient tion as:
to define the “output gap” xt: yt − et = − ϕ[it − E tπt + 1 ] + E t{yt + 1 − et + 1 }
xt ≡ yt − zt Et
where et ≡ − log(1 − ) is taken to evolve ex-
Yt
9 See, for example, Yun (1996), Kimball (1995), ogenously. Using xt ≡ yt − zt, it is then possible to
King and Wolman (1995), Woodford (1996), and
derive the demand for output as
Bernanke, Gertler, and Gilchrist (1998) for step-
by-step derivations. xt = − ϕ[it − E tπt + 1 ] + E txt + 1 + g t
10 By stochastic component, we mean the devia-
tion from a deterministic long-run trend. where gt = E t{∆zt + 1 − ∆et + 1}.
1666 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXVII (December 1999)

smooth consumption, expectation of John Taylor (1980). 12 A key difference


higher consumption next period (associ- is that the individual firm price-setting
ated with higher expected output) leads decision, which provides the basis for
them to want to consume more today, the aggregate relation, is derived from
which raises current output demand. an explicit optimization problem. The
The negative effect of the real rate on starting point is an environment with
current output, in turn, reflects in- monopolistically competitive firms: When
tertemporal substitution of consump- it has the opportunity, each firm
tion. In this respect, the interest elastic- chooses its nominal price to maximize
ity in the IS curve, ϕ, corresponds to profits subject to constraints on the
the intertemporal elasticity of substitu- frequency of future price adjustments.
tion. The disturbance g t is a function of Under the standard scenario, each pe-
expected changes in government pur- riod the fraction 1/X of firms set prices
chases relative to expected changes in for X > 1 periods. In general, however,
potential output (see footnote 11). aggregating the decision rules of firms
Since g t shifts the IS curve, it is inter- that are setting prices on a staggered
pretable as a demand shock. Finally, add- basis is cumbersome. For this reason,
ing investment and capital to the model underlying the specific derivation of
changes the details of equation (2.1). equation (2.2) is an assumption due to
But it does not change the fundamental Guillermo Calvo (1983) that greatly
qualitative aspects: output demand still simplifies the problem: In any given pe-
depends inversely on the real rate and riod a firm has a fixed probability θ it
positively on expected future output. must keep its price fixed during that pe-
It is instructive to iterate equation riod and, hence a probability 1 – θ that
(2.1) forward to obtain it may adjust. 13 This probability, fur-
ther, is independent of the time that

has elapsed since the last time the firm
xt = Et∑ { − ϕ[it + i − πt + 1 + i] + gt + i} (2.5) changed price. Accordingly, the average
i=0
time over which a price is fixed is 1 −1 θ .
Equation (2.5) makes transparent the Thus, for example, if θ = .75, prices are
degree to which beliefs about the future fixed on average for a year. The Calvo
affect current aggregate activity within formulation thus captures the spirit of
this framework. The output gap de- staggered setting, but facilitates the ag-
pends not only on the current real rate gregation by making the timing of a
and the demand shock, but also on the firm’s price adjustment independent of
expected future paths of these two its history.
variables. To the extent monetary policy Equation (2.2) is simply a loglinear
has leverage over the short-term real approximation about the steady state of
rate due to nominal rigidities, equation the aggregation of the individual firm
(2.5) suggests that expected as well as pricing decisions. Since the equation re-
current policy actions affect aggregate lates the inflation rate to the output gap
demand. and expected inflation, it has the flavor
The Phillips curve, (2.2), evolves of a traditional expectations-augmented
from staggered nominal price setting, in Phillips curve (see, e.g., Olivier Blanchard
the spirit of Stanley Fischer (1977) and
13 The Calvo formulation has become quite
12 See Galí and Gertler (1998) and Sbordone common in the literature. Work by Yun (1996),
(1998) for some empirical support for this kind of King and Wolman (1995), Woodford (1996) and
Phillips curve relation. others has initiated the revival.
Clarida, Galí, Gertler: The Science of Monetary Policy 1667

1997). A key difference with the stan- We allow for the cost push shock to en-
dard Phillips curve is that expected fu- able the model to generate variation in
ture inflation, Etπt + 1, enters additively, inflation that arises independently of
as opposed to expected current infla- movement in excess demand, as appears
tion, Et − 1πt. 14 The implications of this present in the data (see, e.g., Fuhrer
distinction are critical: To see, iterate and Moore 1995).
(2.2) forward to obtain To close the model, we take the
∞ nominal interest rate as the instrument
πt = Et∑ βi[λxt + i + ut + i] (2.6) of monetary policy, as opposed to a
i=0 money supply aggregate. As Bernanke
and Ilian Mihov (1998) show, this as-
In contrast to the traditional Phillips
sumption provides a reasonable descrip-
curve, there is no arbitrary inertia or
tion of Federal Reserve operating pro-
lagged dependence in inflation. Rather,
cedures since 1965, except for the brief
inflation depends entirely on current
period of non-borrowed reserves target-
and expected future economic condi-
ing (1980–82) under Paul Volcker. 16
tions. Roughly speaking, firms set nomi-
With the nominal rate as the policy in-
nal price based on the expectations of
strument, it is not necessary to specify a
future marginal costs. The variable xt + i
money market equilibrium condition
captures movements in marginal costs
(i.e., an LM curve). 17 In section 5, we
associated with variation in excess de-
discuss the implications of using instead
mand. The shock ut + i, which we refer to
a narrow monetary aggregate as the
as “cost push,” captures anything else that
policy instrument.
might affect expected marginal costs. 15
Though simple, the model has the
same qualitative core features as more
14 Another key difference is that the explicit
derivation restricts the coefficient λ on the output On this latter point, see Erceg, Henderson, and
gap. In particular, λ is decreasing in θ, which mea- Levin (1998). Another interpretation of the ut shock
sures the degree of price rigidity. Thus, the longer (suggested by Mike Woodford) is that it could re-
prices are fixed on average, the less sensitive is flect a shock to the gap between the natural and
inflation to movements in the output gap. potential levels of output (e.g., a markup shock).
15 The relation for inflation that evolves from 16 Roughly speaking, Bernanke and Mihov
the Calvo model takes the form (1998) present formal evidence showing that the
πt = βE t{πt + 1} + δ mct Federal Reserve intervenes in the market for non-
borrowed bank reserves to support its choice for
where mc t denotes the deviation of (real) marginal the level of the Federal Funds rate, the overnight
cost from its steady state value. To then relate in- market for bank reserves. (Christiano, Eichen-
flation to the output gap, the literature typically baum, and Evans 1998, though, take issue with the
makes assumptions on technology, preferences, identifying assumptions in the Bernanke-Mihov
and the structure of labor markets to justify a pro- test). Informally, Federal Reserve policy actions in
portionate relation between real marginal cost and recent years routinely take the form of announcing
the output gap, so that mc t = κ xt holds, where κ is a target for the Federal funds rate (see, e.g, Rude-
the output elasticity of real marginal cost. In this busch 1995). Policy discussions, further, focus on
instance, one can rewrite the relation for inflation whether to adjust that target, and by how much.
in terms of the output gap, as follows: In this context, the view that the Funds rate is the
πt = βE t{πt + 1} + λ xt (see Galí and Gertler (1998) policy instrument is widely held by both practitio-
for details). In this context, the disturbance u t in ners of monetary policy and academic researchers
(2.2) is interpretable as reflecting deviations from (see, e.g., Goodfriend 1991, Taylor 1993, and
the condition mc t = κ x t. (Indeed the evidence in Walsh 1998).
Galí and Gertler 1998 suggests that mc t does not 17 With the interest rate as the policy instru-
vary proportionately with x t). Deviations from this ment, the central bank adjusts the money supply
proportionality condition could be caused, for ex- to hit the interest rate target. In this instance, the
ample, by movements in nominal wages that push condition that money demand equal money supply
real wages away from their “equilibrium” values simply determines the value of the money supply
due to frictions in the wage contracting process. that meets this criteria.
1668 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXVII (December 1999)

complex, empirically based frameworks since inflation is expressed as a percent


that are used for policy analysis. 18 As in deviation from trend. 19
these applied frameworks, temporary While there has been considerable
nominal price rigidities play a critical progress in motivating behavioral mac-
role. With nominal rigidities present, by roeconomic models from first princi-
varying the nominal rate, monetary pol- ples, until very recently, the same has
icy can effectively change the short- not been true about rationalizing the
term real rate. Through this classic objectives of policy. Over the past sev-
mechanism it gains leverage over the eral years, there have been a number of
near term course of the real economy. attempts to be completely coherent in
In contrast to the traditional mecha- formulating the policy problem by
nism, though, beliefs about how the taking as the welfare criterion the util-
central bank will set the interest rate in ity of a representative agent within the
the future also matter, since both model. 20
households and firms are forward look- One limitation of this approach, how-
ing. In this kind of environment, how ever, is that the models that are cur-
monetary policy should respond in the rently available do not seem to capture
short run to disturbances that buffet the what many would argue is a major cost
economy is a nontrivial decision. Re- of inflation, the uncertainty that its vari-
solving this issue is the essence of the ability generates for lifetime financial
contemporary debate over monetary planning and for business planning (see,
policy. e.g., Brad DeLong 1997). 21 Another is-
sue is that, while the widely used repre-
2.2 The Policy Objective sentative agent approach may be a rea-
sonable way to motivate behavioral
The central bank objective function
relationships, it could be highly mis-
translates the behavior of the target
leading as a guide to welfare analysis. If
variables into a welfare measure to
some groups suffer more in recessions
guide the policy choice. We assume,
than others (e.g. steel workers versus
following much of the literature, that
professors) and there are incomplete in-
this objective function is over the tar-
surance and credit markets, then the
get variables x t and π t, and takes the
utility of a hypothetical representative
form:
agent might not provide an accurate
barometer of cyclical fluctuations in
1  ∞ i 
Et∑ β [αxt2 + i + πt2 + i]  (2.7)
 welfare.
max −
2 i = 0  With certain exceptions, much of the
 

where the parameter α is the relative 19 Put differently, under the optimal policy, the
weight on output deviations. Since target inflation rate pins down the trend inflation
xt ≡ yt − zt, the loss function takes poten- rate. The loss function thus penalizes deviations
tial output z t as the target. It also implic- from this trend.
20 Some examples of this approach include Aiya-
itly takes zero as the target inflation, but gari and Braun (1997), King and Wolman (1995),
there is no cost in terms of generality Ireland (1996a), Carlstrom and Fuerst (1995), and
Rotemberg and Woodford (1997).
18 Some prominent examples include the re- 21 Underlying this kind of cost is the observation
cently renovated large scale model used by the that contracts are typically written in nominal
Federal Reserve Board, the FRB-US model (see terms and, for reasons that are difficult to explain,
Brayton, Levin, Tyron, and Williams 1997), and not perfectly indexed to the price level. On this
the medium scale models of Taylor (1979, 1993b) issue, see the discussion in Shiller (1997) and the
and Fuhrer and Moore (1995a,b). associated comment by Hall (1997).
Clarida, Galí, Gertler: The Science of Monetary Policy 1669

literature takes a pragmatic approach to But they define price stability as the in-
this issue by simply assuming that the flation rate at which inflation is no
objective of monetary policy is to mini- longer a public concern. In practice, it
mize the squared deviations of output is argued that an inflation rate between
and inflation from their respective tar- one and three percent seems to meet
get levels. However, Julio Rotemberg this definition (e.g., Bernanke and
and Michael Woodford (1999) and Mishkin 1997). A further justification
Woodford (1998) provide a formal justi- for this criteria is that the official price
fication for this approach. These indices may be overstating the true in-
authors show that an objective function flation rate by a percent or two, as ar-
looking something like equation (2.7) gued recently by the Boskin Commis-
may be obtained as a quadratic approxi- sion. In this regard, interestingly, the
mation of the utility-based welfare Bundesbank has had for a long time an
function. In this instance, the relative official inflation target of two percent. 23
weight, α, is a function of the primitive They similarly argue that this positive
parameters of the model. rate of inflation is consistent with price
In what follows, we simply adopt the stability, and cite measurement error as
quadratic objective given by (2.7), ap- one of the reasons (Clarida and Gertler
pealing loosely to the justification of- 1997).
fered in Rotemberg and Woodford It is clear that the experience of the
(1999). Judging by the number of pa- 1970s awakened policy-makers to the
pers written by Federal Reserve econo- costs of high inflation (DeLong 1997).
mists that follow this lead, this formula- Otherwise, there is no directly observ-
tion does not seem out of sync with the able indicator of the relative weights as-
way monetary policy operates in prac- signed to output and inflation objec-
tice (at least implicitly). 22 The target tives. Nor, argues Blinder (1997), is
level of output is typically taken to be there any obvious consensus among pol-
the natural level of output, based on the icy-makers about what these weights re-
idea that this is the level of output that ally are in practice. It is true that there
would obtain absent any wage and price has been a growing consensus that the
frictions. Yet, if distortions exist in the primary aim of monetary policy should
economy (e.g., imperfect competition be to control inflation (see, e.g., Ber-
or taxes), a case can be made that the nanke and Mishkin 1997). But this dis-
welfare maximizing level of output may cussion in many respects is about what
exceed its natural level. This issue be- kind of policy rule may be best, as op-
comes important in the context of posed to what the underlying welfare
policy credibility, but we defer it for function looks like.
now. For our purposes, however, it is rea-
What should be the target rate of in- sonable to take the inflation target and
flation is perhaps an even more ephem- preference parameters as given and
eral question, as is the issue of what simply explore the implications for
should be the relative weight assigned optimal policy rules.
to output and inflation losses. In the 23 Two percent is also the upper bound of the
U.S., policy-makers argue that “price inflation target range established by the European
stability” should be the ultimate goal. Central Bank. On the other hand, Feldstein (1997)
argues that the tax distortions that arise because
corporate and personal income taxes are not in-
22 See, for example, Williams (1997) and refer- dexed to inflation justify moving from three per-
ences therein. cent to zero inflation.
1670 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXVII (December 1999)

2.3 The Policy Problem and Discretion From the standpoint of policy design,
versus Rules the issue is to identify whether some
type of credibility-enhancing commit-
The policy problem is to choose a ment may be desirable. Answering this
time path for the instrument i t to engi- question boils down to comparing opti-
neer time paths of the target variables mal policy under discretion versus rules
x t and π t that maximize the objective (using the terminology of the litera-
function (2.7), subject to the constraints ture). In our context, a central bank op-
on behavior implied by (2.1) and (2.2). erating under discretion chooses the
This formulation is in many ways in the current interest rate by reoptimizing
tradition of the classic Jan Tinbergen every period. Any promises made in the
(1952)/Henri Theil (1961) (TT) targets past do not constrain current policy.
and instruments problem. As with TT, Under a rule, it chooses a plan for the
the combination of quadratic loss and path of the interest rates that it sticks to
linear constraints yields a certainty forever. The plan may call for adjusting
equivalent decision rule for the path of the interest rate in response to the state
the instrument. The optimal feedback of the economy, but both the nature
rule, in general, relates the instrument and size of the response are etched in
to the state of the economy. stone.
There is, however, an important dif- Two points need to be emphasized.
ference from the classic problem: The First, the key distinction between dis-
target variables depend not only on the cretion and rules is whether current
current policy but also on expectations commitments constrain the future
about future policy: The output gap de- course of policy in any credible way. In
pends on the future path of the interest each instance, the optimal outcome is a
rate (equation 2.5); and, in turn, inflation feedback policy that relates the policy
depends on the current and expected instrument to the current state of the
future behavior of the output gap economy in a very specific way. The two
(equation 2.6). As Finn Kydland and approaches differ, however, in their im-
Edward Prescott (1977) originally em- plications for the link between policy
phasized, in this kind of environment, intentions and private sector beliefs.
credibility of future policy intentions Under discretion, a perceptive private
becomes a critical issue. For example, a sector forms its expectations taking into
central bank that can credibly signal its account how the central bank adjusts
intent to maintain inflation low in the policy, given that the central bank is
future may be able to reduce current free to reoptimize every period. The ra-
inflation with less cost in terms of out- tional expectations equilibrium thus has
put reduction than might otherwise be the property that the central bank has
required. 24 In section 4, we illustrate no incentive to change its plans in an
this point explicitly. unexpected way, even though it has the
24 In this regard, we stress further that, in discretion to do so. (For this reason, the
contrast to conventional wisdom, the issue of policy that emerges in equilibrium under
credibility in monetary policy is not tied to central discretion is termed “time consistent.”)
bank objectives over output. In the classic,
Barro/Gordon (1983) formulation (and countless In contrast, under a rule, it is simply
papers thereafter), the central bank’s desire to
push output above potential output gives rise to
the credibility problem. However, as we make depends on beliefs about the future, even if cen-
clear in section 4, gains from commitment poten- tral bank objectives over output are perfectly
tially emerge whenever private sector behavior aligned.
Clarida, Galí, Gertler: The Science of Monetary Policy 1671

the binding commitment that makes the possible gains from commitment to a
policy believable in equilibrium. policy rule and other institutional de-
Second, (it should almost go without vices that might enhance credibility, it
saying that) the models we use are no- is necessary to understand what the
where near the point where it is possi- benchmark case of discretion yields.
ble to obtain a tightly specified policy Under discretion, each period the
rule that could be recommended for central bank chooses the triplet {xt,πt,it},
practical use with great confidence. consisting of the two target variables
Nonetheless, it is useful to work and the policy instrument, to maximize
through the cases of discretion and the objective (2.7) subject to the aggre-
rules in order to develop a set of norma- gate supply curve (2.2) and the IS
tive guidelines for policy behavior. As curve, (2.1). It is convenient to divide
Taylor (1993a) argues, common sense the problem into two stages: First, the
application of these guidelines may im- central bank chooses x t and π t to maxi-
prove the performance of monetary pol- mize the objective (2.7), given the infla-
icy. We expand on this point later. In tion equation (2.2). 25 Then, conditional
addition, understanding the qualitative on the optimal values of x t and π t, it de-
differences between outcomes under termines the value of i t implied by the
discretion versus rules can provide les- IS curve (2.1) (i.e., the interest rate
sons for the institutional design of that will support x t and π t).
monetary policy. For example, as we Since it cannot credibly manipulate
discuss, Rogoff’s (1985) insightful beliefs in the absence of commitment,
analysis of the benefits of a conservative the central bank takes private sector
central bank chair is a product of this expectations as given in solving the
type of analysis. Finally, simply under- optimization problem. 26 (Then, condi-
standing the qualitative aspects of opti- tional on the central bank’s optimal
mal policy management under discre- rule, the private sector forms beliefs ra-
tion can provide useful normative tionally.) Because there are no en-
insights, as we show shortly. dogenous state variables, the first stage
We proceed in the next section to de- of the policy problem reduces to the fol-
rive the optimal policy under discretion. lowing sequence of static optimization
In a subsequent section we then evaluate
the implications of commitment. 25 Since all the qualitative results we derive
stem mainly from the first stage problem, what is
critical is the nature of the short run Phillips
3. Optimal Monetary Policy without curve. For our baseline analysis, we use the Phil-
Commitment lips curve implied the New Keynesian model. In
section 6 we consider a very general Phillips curve
that is a hybrid of different approaches and show
We begin with the case without com- that the qualitative results remain intact. It is in
mitment (“discretion”) for two reasons. this sense that our analysis is quite robust.
26 We are ignoring the possibility of reputational
First, at a basic level this scenario ac-
equilibria that could support a more efficient out-
cords best with reality. In practice, no come. That is, in the language of game theory, we
major central bank makes any kind of restrict attention to Markov perfect equilibria.
binding commitment over the course of One issue that arises with reputational equilibria is
that there are multiplicity of possible equilibria.
its future monetary policy. In this re- Rogoff (1987) argues that the fragility of the re-
spect, it seems paramount to under- sulting equilibria is an unsatisfactory feature of
stand the nature of optimal policy in this approach. See also, Ireland (1996b). On the
other hand, Chari, Christiano, and Eichenbaum
this environment. Second, as we have (1998) argue that this indeterminacy could provide
just discussed, to fully comprehend the a source of business fluctuations.
1672 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXVII (December 1999)

problems: 27 Each period, choose x t and πt = αq ut (3.5)


π t to maximize where
1 1
− [αx2t + π2t ] + Ft (3.1) q=
2 λ2 + α(1 − βρ)
subject to The optimal feedback policy for the in-
πt = λxt + ft (3.2) terest rate is then found by simply in-
serting the desired value of xt in the IS
taking as given Ft and ft, where curve (2.1):
1  ∞ i  1
it = γ π E t π t + 1 + g t
Et∑ β [αxt2 + i + πt2 + i]  and
 (3.6)
Ft ≡ − ϕ
2 i = 1 
 
where
ft ≡ βEtπt + 1 + ut. Equations (3.1) and (1−ρ)λ
(3.2) simply reformulate (2.7) and (2.2) γπ = 1 + >1
ρϕα
in a way that makes transparent that, un-
der discretion, (a) future inflation and Etπt + 1 = ρ πt = ραq ut
output are not affected by today’s ac- This completes the formal description of
tions, and (b) the central bank cannot the optimal policy.
directly manipulate expectations. From this relatively parsimonious set
The solution to the first stage prob- of expressions there emerge a number
lem yields the following optimality of key results that are reasonably robust
condition: findings of the literature:
λ Result 1: To the extent cost push in-
xt = − π t (3.3) flation is present, there exists a short
α
run trade-off between inflation and
This condition implies simply that the output variability.
central bank pursue a “lean against the This result was originally emphasized
wind” policy: Whenever inflation is by Taylor (1979) and is an important
above target, contract demand below ca- guiding principle in many applied stud-
pacity (by raising the interest rate); and ies of monetary policy that have fol-
vice-versa when it is below target. How lowed. 28 A useful way to illustrate the
aggressively the central bank should re- trade-off implied by the model is to
duce xt depends positively on the gain in construct the corresponding efficient
reduced inflation per unit of output loss, policy frontier. The device is a locus of
λ, and inversely on the relative weight points that characterize how the uncon-
placed on output losses, α. ditional standard deviations of output
To obtain reduced form expressions and inflation under the optimal policy,
for xt and πt, combine the optimality σx and σπ, vary with central bank prefer-
condition (fonc) with the aggregate sup- ences, as defined by α. Figure 1 por-
ply curve (AS ), and then impose that trays the efficient policy frontier for our
private sector expectations are rational:
xt = − λq ut (3.4) 28 For some recent examples, see Williams
(1997), Fuhrer (1997a) and Orphanides, Small,
27 In section 6, we solve for the optimum under Wilcox and Wieland (1997). An exception, how-
discretion for the case where an endogenous state ever, is Jovanovic and Ueda (1997) who demon-
variable is present. Within the Markov perfect strate that in an environment of incomplete con-
equilibrium, the central bank takes private sector tracting, increased dispersion of prices may reduce
beliefs as a given function of the endogenous output. Stabilizing prices in this environment then
state. raises output.
Clarida, Galí, Gertler: The Science of Monetary Policy 1673

baseline model. 29 In (σx,σπ) space the pends only on current and future de-
locus is downward sloping and convex mand. By adjusting interest rates to set
to the origin. Points to the right of the xt = 0, ∀ t, the central bank is able to hit
frontier are inefficient. Points to the its inflation and output targets simulta-
left are infeasible. Along the frontier neously, all the time. If cost push fac-
there is a trade-off: As α rises (indicat- tors drive inflation, however, it is only
ing relatively greater preference for possible to reduce inflation in the near
output stability), the optimal policy en- term by contracting demand. This
gineers a lower standard deviation of consideration leads to the next result:
output, but at the expense of higher in- Result 2: The optimal policy incorpo-
flation volatility. The limiting cases are rates inflation targeting in the sense
instructive: that it requires to aim for convergence
σu of inflation to its target over time. Ex-
As α → 0: σx = ; σπ = 0 (3.7) treme inflation targeting, however, i.e.,
λ
adjusting policy to immediately reach
σu an inflation target, is optimal under
As α → ∞: σx = 0; σπ = (3.8)
1 − βρ only one of two circumstances: (1) cost
where σu is the standard deviation of the push inflation is absent; or (2) there is
cost push innovation. no concern for output deviations (i.e.,
It is important to emphasize that the α = 0).
trade-off emerges only if cost push in- In the general case, with α > 0 and
flation is present. In the absence of cost σu > 0, there is gradual convergence of
inflation (i.e., with σu = 0), there is no inflation back to target. From equations
trade-off. In this instance, inflation de- (3.5) and (2.4), under the optimal policy
29 Equations (3.4) and (3.5) define the frontier lim Et{πt + i} = lim αqρi ut = 0
for the baseline model. i→∞ i→∞
1674 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXVII (December 1999)

In this formal sense, the optimal pol- several results regarding the behavior of
icy embeds inflation targeting. 30 With the policy instrument, i t.
exogenous cost push inflation, policy af- Result 3: Under the optimal policy,
fects the gap between inflation and its in response to a rise in expected infla-
target along the convergent path, but tion, nominal rates should rise suffi-
not the rate of convergence. In con- ciently to increase real rates. Put differ-
trast, in the presence of endogenous in- ently, in the optimal rule for the
flation persistence, policy will generally nominal rate, the coefficient on expected
affect the rate of convergence as well, inflation should exceed unity.
as we discuss later. Result 3 is transparent from equation
The conditions for extreme inflation (3.6). It simply reflects the implicit tar-
targeting can be seen immediately from geting feature of optimal policy de-
inspection of equations (3.7) and (3.8). scribed in Result 2. Whenever inflation
When σ u = 0 (no cost push inflation), is above target, the optimal policy re-
adjusting policy to immediately hit the quires raising real rates to contract de-
inflation target is optimal, regardless of mand. Though this principle may seem
preferences. Since there is no trade-off obvious, it provides a very simple crite-
in this case, it is never costly to try to ria for evaluating monetary policy. For
minimize inflation variability. Inflation example, Clarida, Galí, and Gertler (forth-
being the only concern of policy pro- coming) find that U.S. monetary policy
vides the other rationale for extreme in- in the pre-Volcker era of 1960–79 vio-
flation targeting. As equation (3.7) indi- lated this strategy. Federal Reserve pol-
cates, it is optimal to minimize inflation icy tended to accommodate rather than
variance if α = 0, even with cost push fight increases in expected inflation.
inflation present. Nominal rates adjusted, but not suffi-
Result 2 illustrates why some con- ciently to raise real rates. The persis-
flicting views about the optimal transi- tent high inflation during this era may
tion path to the inflation target have have been the end product of the fail-
emerged in the literature. Marvin ure to raise real rates under these cir-
Goodfriend and Robert King (1997), for cumstances. Since 1979, however, the
example, argue in favor of extreme in- Federal Reserve appears to have adopted
flation targeting. Svensson (1997a,b) the kind of implicit inflation targeting
and Laurence Ball (1997) suggest that, strategy that equation (3.6) suggests.
in general, gradual convergence of in- Over this period, the Fed has systemati-
flation is optimal. The difference stems cally raised real rates in response to an-
from the treatment of cost push infla- ticipated increases in inflationary ex-
tion: It is absent in the Goodfriend- pectations. We return to this issue later.
King paradigm, but very much a factor Result 4: The optimal policy calls for
in the Svensson and Ball frameworks. adjusting the interest rate to perfectly off-
Results 1 and 2 pertain to the behav- set demand shocks, g t, but perfectly ac-
ior of the target variables. We now state commodate shocks to potential output, zt,
by keeping the nominal rate constant.
30 Note here that our definition is somewhat
That policy should offset demand
different from Svensson (1997a), who defines shocks is transparent from the policy
inflation targeting in terms of the weights on the rule (3.6). Here the simple idea is that
objective function, i.e., he defines the case with countering demand shocks pushes both
α = 0 as corresponding to strict inflation targeting
and α > 0 as corresponding to flexible inflation output and inflation in the right direc-
targeting. tion. Demand shocks do not force a
Clarida, Galí, Gertler: The Science of Monetary Policy 1675

short run trade-off between output and David Gordon (1983), and Rogoff
inflation. (1985), a voluminous literature has de-
Shocks to potential output also do not veloped on the issue of credibility of
force a short run trade-off. But they re- monetary policy. 34 From the standpoint
quire a quite different policy response. of obtaining practical insights for pol-
Thus, e.g., a permanent rise in produc- icy, we find it useful to divide the pa-
tivity raises potential output, but it also pers into two strands. The first follows
raises output demand in a perfectly off- directly from the seminal papers and
setting manner, due to the impact on has received by far the most attention
permanent income. 31 As a consequence, in academic circles. It emphasizes the
the output gap does not change. In problem of persistent inflationary bias
turn, there is no change in inflation. under discretion. 35 The ultimate source
Thus, there is no reason to raise inter- of this inflationary bias is a central bank
est rates, despite the rise in output. 32 that desires to push output above its
Indeed, this kind of scenario seems to natural level. The second is emphasized
describe well the current behavior of more in applied discussions of policy. It
monetary policy. Output growth was focuses on the idea that disinflating an
substantially above trend in recent times, economy may be more painful than nec-
but with no apparent accompanying in- essary, if monetary policy is perceived
flation. 33 Based on the view that the rise as not devoted to fighting inflation.
in output may mainly reflect productivity Here the source of the problem is
movements, the Federal Reserve has simply that wage and price setting
resisted large interest rate increases. today may depend upon beliefs about
The central message of Result 4 is where prices are headed in the future,
that an important task of monetary pol- which in turn depends on the course of
icy is to distinguish the sources of monetary policy.
business cycle shocks. In the simple These two issues are similar in a
environment here with perfect ob- sense: They both suggest that a central
servability, this task is easy. Later we bank that can establish credibility one
explore some implications of relaxing way or another may be able to reduce
this assumption. inflation at lower cost. But the source
of the problem in each case is different
4. Credibility and the Gains in subtle but important ways. As a
from Commitment consequence the potential empirical
Since the pioneering work of Kydland relevance may differ, as we discuss
and Prescott (1977), Robert Barro and below.
31 In this experiment we are holding constant
We first use our model to exposit the
the IS shock gt. Since gt = [(et − zt) − E t(et + 1 − zt + 1)], famous inflationary bias result. We then
(see footnote 9), this boils down to assuming illustrate formally how credibility can
either that the shock to zt is permanent (so that reduce the cost of maintaining low in-
E tzt + 1 − zt = 0) or that et adjusts in a way to offset
movements in gt. flation, and also discuss mechanisms in
32 That monetary policy should accommodate
movements in potential GDP is a theme of the 34 For recent surveys of the literature, see Fis-
recent literature (e.g., Aiyagari and Braun 1997; cher (1995), McCallum (1997) and Persson and
Carlstrom and Fuerst 1995; Ireland 1996a; and Tabellini (1997).
Rotemberg and Woodford 1997). This view was 35 While the inflationary bias result is best
also stressed in much earlier literature. See Fried- known example, there may also be other costs of
man and Kuttner (1996) for a review. discretion. Svennson (1997c), for example, argues
33 See Lown and Rich (1997) for a discussion of also that discretion may lead to too much inflation
the recent “inflation puzzle.” variability and too little output variability.
1676 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXVII (December 1999)

the literature that have been suggested


1  ∞ i 
Et∑ β [α(xt + i − k)2 + πt2 + i]  (4.1)

to inject this credibility. An important max −
result we wish to stress—and one that 2 i = o 
 
we don’t think is widely understood in
the literature—is that gains from credi- The rationale for having the socially opti-
bility emerge even when the central mal level of output exceed its natural
bank is not trying to push output above level may be the presence of distortions
its natural level. 36 That is, as long as such as imperfect competition or taxes.
price setting depends on expectations of For convenience, we also assume that
the future, as in our baseline model, price setters do not discount the future,
there may be gains from establishing which permits us to fix the parameter β
some form of credibility to curtail infla- in the Phillips curve at unity.38
tion. Further, under certain plausible In this case, the optimality condi-
restrictions on the form of the feedback tion that links the target variables is
rule, the optimal policy under commit- given by:
ment differs from that under discretion λ
xkt = − πkt + k (4.2)
in a very simple and intuitive way. In α
this case, the solution with commitment The superscript k indicates the variable
resembles that obtained under discre- is the solution under discretion for the
tion using a higher effective cost ap- case k > 0. Plugging this condition into
plied to inflation than the social welfare the IS and Phillips curves, (2.1) and
function suggests. 37 In this respect, we (2.2), yields:
think, the credibility literature may have
some broad practical insights to offer. xkt = xt (4.3)
4.1 The Classic Inflationary α
πkt = πt + k (4.4)
Bias Problem λ
As in Kydland and Prescott (1979), where xt and πt are the equilibrium val-
Barro and Gordon (1983), and many ues of the target variables for the base-
other papers, we consider the possibil- line case with k = 0 (see equations 3.4
ity that the target for the output gap and 3.5).
may be k > 0, as opposed to 0. The policy Note that output is no different from
objective function is then given by the baseline case, but that inflation is
systematically higher, by the factor αλ k.
36 A number of papers have shown that a disin-
Thus, we have the familiar result in the
flation will be less painful if the private sector per-
ceives that the central bank will carry it out. But literature:
they do not show formally that, under discretion, Result 5. If the central bank desires
the central bank will be less inclined to do so to push output above potential (i.e.,
(see., e.g. Ball 1995, and Bonfim and Rudebusch
1997). k > 0), then under discretion a subopti-
37 With inflationary bias present, it is also possi- mal equilibrium may emerge with infla-
ble to improve welfare by assigning a higher cost tion persistently above target, and no
to inflation, as Rogoff (1985) originally empha-
sized. But it is not always possible to obtain the gain in output.
optimum under commitment. The point we em- The model we use to illustrate this
phasize is that with inflationary bias absent, it is
possible to replicate the solution under commit- 38 Otherwise, the discounting of the future by
ment (for a restricted family of policy rules) using price-setters introduces a long-run trade-off be-
the algorithm to solve for the optimum under dis- tween inflation and output. Under reasonable pa-
cretion with an appropriately chosen relative cost rameter values this tradeoff is small and its pres-
of inflation. We elaborate on these issues later in ence merely serves to complicate the algebra. See
the text. Goodfriend and King (1997) for a discussion.
Clarida, Galí, Gertler: The Science of Monetary Policy 1677

result differs from the simple expecta- Imposing binding commitments in a


tional Phillips curve framework in model, however, is much easier than do-
which it has been typically studied. But ing so in reality. The issue then becomes
the intuition remains the same. In this whether there may be some simple in-
instance, the central bank has the in- stitutional mechanisms that can approxi-
centive to announce that it will be mate the effect of the idealized policy
tough in the future to lower current in- commitment. Perhaps the most useful
flation (since in this case, current infla- answer to the question comes from Rogoff
tion depends on expected future infla- (1985), who proposed simply the appoint-
tion), but then expand current demand ment of a “conservative” central banker,
to push output above potential. The taken in this context to mean someone
presence of k in the optimality condi- with a greater distaste for inflation (a
tion (4.2) reflects this temptation. A ra- lower α), than society as a whole:
tional private sector, however, recog- Result 6: Appointing a central bank
nizes the central bank’s incentive. In chair who assigns a higher relative cost
mechanical terms, it makes use of equa- to inflation than society as a whole re-
tion (4.2) to forecast inflation, since this duces the inefficient inflationary bias that
condition reflects the central bank’s is obtained under discretion when k > 0.
true intentions. Put simply, equilibrium One can see plainly from equation
inflation rises to the point where the (4.4) that letting someone with prefer-
central bank no longer is tempted to ex- ences given by αR < α run the central
pand output. Because there is no long- bank will reduce the inflationary bias. 39
run trade-off between inflation and out- The Rogoff solution, however, is not a
put (i.e., x t converges to zero in the panacea. We know from the earlier
long run, regardless of the level of infla- analysis that emphasizing greater reduc-
tion), long-run equilibrium inflation is tion in inflation variance may come at
forced systematically above target. the cost of increased output variance.
The analysis has both important posi- Appointing an extremist to the job
tive and normative implications. On the (someone with α at or near zero) could
positive side, the theory provides an ex- wind up reducing overall welfare.
planation for why inflation may remain How important the inflationary bias
persistently high, as was the case from problem emphasized in this literature is
the late 1960s through the early 1980s. in practice, however, is a matter of con-
Indeed, its ability to provide a qualita- troversy. Benjamin Friedman and Ken-
tive account of this inflationary era is a neth Kuttner (1996) point out that in-
major reason for its popularity. flation in the major OECD countries
The widely stressed normative impli- now appears well under control, despite
cation of this analysis is that there may the absence of any obvious institutional
be gains from making binding commit- changes that this literature argues are
ments over the course of monetary pol- needed to enhance credibility. If this
icy or, alternatively, making institu- theory is robust, they argue, it should
tional adjustments that accomplish the account not only for the high inflation
same purpose. A clear example from the of the 1960s and 1970s, but also for the
analysis is that welfare would improve if
the central bank could simply commit 39 See Svensson (1997) and Walsh (1998) for a

to acting as if k were zero. There would description of how incentive contracts for central
bankers may reduce the inflation bias; also, Faust
be no change in the path of output, but and Svensson (1998) for a recent discussion of
inflation would decline. reputational mechanisms.
1678 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXVII (December 1999)

transition to an era of low inflation dur- pend on expectations of the future, as


ing the 1980s and 1990s. A possible equation (2.2) makes clear. 40
counterargument is that in fact a num-
ber of countries, including the U.S., ef- 4.2 Improving the Short-Run
fectively adopted the Rogoff solution by Output/Inflation Trade-off: Gains
appointing central bank chairs with from Commitment with k = 0.
clear distaste for inflation. We now illustrate that there may be
Another strand of criticism focuses gains from commitment to a policy rule,
on the plausibility of the underlying even with k = 0. The first stage problem
story that leads to the inflationary bias. in this case is to choose a state contin-
A number of prominent authors have gent sequence for xt + i and πt + i to maxi-
argued that, in practice, it is unlikely mize the objective (2.7) assuming that
that k > 0 will tempt a central bank to the inflation equation (2.2) holds in
cheat. Any rational central bank, they every period t + i, i ≥ 0. Specifically, the
maintain, will recognize the long-term central bank no longer takes private sec-
costs of misleading the public to pursue tor expectations as given, recognizing
short-term gains from pushing output instead that its policy choice effectively
above its natural level. Simply this rec- determines such expectations.
ognition, they argue, is sufficient to To illustrate the gains from commit-
constrain its behavior (e.g. McCallum ment in a simple way, we first restrict
1997a; Blinder 1997). Indeed, Blinder the form of the policy rule to the gen-
argues, based on his own experience on eral form that arises in equilibrium un-
the Federal Reserve Board, that there der discretion, and solve for the opti-
was no constituency in favor of pursuing mum within this class of rules. We then
output gains above the natural rate. In show that, with commitment, another
formal terms, he maintains that those rule within this class dominates the op-
who run U.S. monetary policy act as if timum under discretion. Hence this ap-
they were instructed to set k = 0, which proach provides a simple way to illus-
eliminates the inflationary bias. trate the gains from commitment.
What is perhaps less understood, Another positive byproduct is that the
however, is that there are gains from restricted optimal rule we derive is sim-
enhancing credibility even when k = 0. ple to interpret and implement, yet still
To the extent that price setting today yields gains relative to the case of dis-
depends on beliefs about future eco- cretion. Because the policy is not a global
nomic conditions, a monetary authority optimum, however, we conclude the
that is able to signal a clear commit- section by solving for the unrestricted
ment to controlling inflation may face optimal rule.
an improved short-run output/inflation
trade-off. Below we illustrate this point. 4.2.1 Monetary Policy under
The reason why this is not emphasized Commitment: The Optimum within
in much of the existing literature on a Simple Family of Policy Rules
this topic is that this work either tends (that includes the optimal rule
to focus on steady states (as opposed to under discretion)
short-run dynamics), or it employs very
simple models of price dynamics, where In the equilibrium without commit-
current prices do not depend on beliefs ment, it is optimal for the central bank
about the future. In our baseline model, 40 This section is based on Galí and Gertler
however, short-run price dynamics de- (1999).
Clarida, Galí, Gertler: The Science of Monetary Policy 1679

to adjust x t solely in response to the discretion, reducing xt by one percent


exogenous cost push shock, u t. We ac- only produces a fall in πt of λ < 1 −λβρ .
cordingly consider a rule for the target The extra kick in the case with commit-
variable xt that is contingent on the ment is due to the impact of the policy
fundamental shock ut, in the following rule on expectations of the future course
way: of the output gap. In particular, the
xct = − ω ut (4.5) choice of ω affects not only xt but also
beliefs about the course of xtc + i, i = 1,2, … ,
for all t, where ω > 0 is the coefficient of since Etxtc + i = − ω ut. A central bank that
the feedback rule, and where xct denotes commits to a tough policy rule (high ω ),
the value of x t conditional on commit- for example, is able to credibly signal
ment to the policy.41 Note that the rule that it will sustain over time an aggres-
includes the optimum under discretion sive response to a persistent supply shock.
as a special case (i.e., the case with ω = λq Since inflation depends on the future
shown in 3.4). course of excess demand, commitment to
Combining equation (4.5) with the the tough policy rule leads to a magni-
Phillips curve (2.2), in turn, implies that fied drop in inflation per unit of output
inflation under the rule, πct , is also a lin- loss, relative to the case of discretion.
ear function of the cost push shock: To find the optimal value of ω , note
πct = λ xct + β Etπct + 1 + ut (4.6) first that since xtc + i and πtc + i are each a
constant multiple of the cost push shock
∞ ut + i, it is possible to express the objec-
= Et∑ βi [λxtc + i + ut + i] (4.7) tive function as a multiple of period t
i=0
loss:

1  ∞ i 
Et∑ β [α (xtc + i)2 + (πct + i)2] 

= Et∑ βi [− λω ut + i + ut + i] (4.8) max −
i=0
2 i = 0 
 

1 − λω 1
= ut (4.9) ←→ max − [α (xct )2 + (πct )2]Lt
1 − βρ 2 (4.11)
The problem for the central bank is  ∞ 
to choose the optimal value of the feed- with Lt ≡ Et∑ βi(ut + i/ut)2 > 0. The prob-
i = 0 
back parameter ω. Relative to the case  
of discretion, the ability to commit to lem then is to choose ω to maximize
a feedback policy provides the central (4.11), subject to (4.10). In this instance,
bank with an improved short-run out- the optimality condition is given by:
put/inflation trade-off. To this end, note λ c
that it is possible to express equation xct = − πt
αc (4.12)
(4.9) as
where
λ 1
πct = xct + ut αc ≡ α(1 − βρ) < α (4.13)
1 − βρ 1 − βρ (4.10)
In this case, a one percent contraction in Since αc < α, relative to the case of dis-
xct reduces πct by the factor 1 −λβρ . Under cretion, commitment to the rule implies
that it is optimal for the central bank to
41 The policy rule only depends on u because
t engineer a greater contraction in output
the central bank can adjust i t to offset any impact in response to inflationary pressures.
of movements in g t on aggregate demand. See
equation (4.16). Intuitively, the more aggressive response
1680 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXVII (December 1999)

to inflation is the product of the im- is compelling from an empirical stand-


proved output/inflation trade-off that point. Because inflation depends on ex-
commitment affords. Specifically, the pected future output gaps, the central
output cost of lowering inflation declines bank would like to convince the private
from α to αc per unit, since reducing in- sector that it will be tough in the fu-
flation a given amount requires, ceteris ture, but at the same time, not to have
paribus, only a fraction (1 − βρ) of the to contract demand much today. As the
output loss required under discretion. future comes to pass, the central bank
The decline in the effective cost of re- has the incentive to renege on its
ducing inflation, in turn, induces the planned toughness and, instead, prom-
more aggressive policy response to infla- ise again to undertake contractionary
tion, as comparing equation (4.12) with policy down the road. To see this, sup-
equation (3.3) makes clear. pose that there is a positive cost push
The equilibrium solutions for xct and shock. If the central bank is free to de-
πt are easily obtained by combining
c
viate from the rule, it will always choose
equations (4.12) and (4.10): the optimal policy under discretion,
xct = − λqc ut (4.14) which calls for a smaller contraction of
output, relative to the case of commit-
π t = − α q ut
c c c
(4.15) ment (again, compare 4.1 and 3.3). A
with rational private sector will recognize
1 that incentive and, unless the central
qc =
+λ2 αc(1
− βρ) bank is able to commit credibly, will not
It is interesting to observe that the expect large contractions in demand in
solution under commitment in this case the future either. As a result, the cost
perfectly resembles the solution ob- push shock generates higher inflation in
tained under discretion that arises when the absence of commitment. We stress
α is replaced with αc < α in the objec- again that, in contrast to the traditional
tive function. It follows that, condi- analysis, this gain from commitment is
tional on the value of the cost push not tied to the desire of the central
shock, u t, inflation is closer to target bank to push output above potential,
and output is further, relative to the but to the forward-looking nature of in-
outcome under discretion. 42 flation (and, thus, the importance of ex-
It is straightforward to verify that pectations about future policy) in our
commitment to the policy rule raises baseline model.
welfare. 43 The tension produced by From a policy standpoint, Rogoff’s ra-
such gains from commitment, we think, tionale for a conservative central banker
carries over perfectly to this case. In-
42 Importantly, with endogenous inflation per- deed with omniscience (i.e. exact
sistence, commitment produces a faster transition knowledge of α c and the true model),
of inflation to target, as we discuss later. an appropriately chosen central banker
43 To verify that commitment raises welfare,
simply substitute the implied values for x t and π t could replicate the outcome under
under the optimal rule for each case into the pol- commitment.
icy objective function. However, it should be obvi- We summarize the findings in Result 7:
ous that commitment raises welfare, since the op-
timal rule under discretion falls within the class of Result 7: If price-setting depends on
rules that we permitted the central bank to choose expectations of future economic condi-
in the case with commitment: Yet we found that tions, then a central bank that can cred-
with commitment it is optimal to choose a differ-
ent parameterization of the rule than arises in the ibly commit to a rule faces an improved
optimum under discretion. short-run trade-off between inflation
Clarida, Galí, Gertler: The Science of Monetary Policy 1681

and output. This gain from commitment xt + i and πt + i to maximize the objective
arises even if the central bank does not (2.7) given that the aggregate supply
prefer to have output above potential curve (2.2) holds in every period
(i.e., even when k = 0). The solution t + i, i ≥ 0. We no longer restrict the
under commitment in this case perfectly choice of xt to depend on the contempo-
resembles the solution that would ob- raneous value of the shock (i.e., ut ), but
tain for a central bank with discretion allow instead for rules that are a func-
that assigned to inflation a higher cost tion of the entire history of shocks. To
than the true social cost. find the globally optimal solution to the
One additional interesting feature of linear quadratic policy problem under
this case with commitment involves the commitment, we follow David Currie
behavior of interest rates. This can be and Paul Levine (1993) and Woodford
seen formally by simply replacing α (1998), and form the Lagrangian: 45
with α c in the interest rate rule under
discretion (given by equation 3.6) to 1  ∞ i
2 i∑
obtain max − Et β [αxt2 + i + πt2 + i
=0

(4.17)
1
it = γπc Etπt + 1 + gt (4.16)
 
ϕ
+ φt + i(πt + i − λxt + i − βπt + i + 1 − ut + i)]
with  
(1 − ρ)λ (1 − ρ)λ 1
γπc ≡ 1 + >1+ ≡ γπ where φt + i is the (state-contingent)
ρϕα c ρϕα 2
multiplier associated with the constraint at
In particular, relative to the case of dis-
t+i. It is straightforward to show that the
cretion, the central bank increases the
first order conditions yield the following
nominal interest rate by a larger amount
optimality conditions
in response to a rise in expected
inflation. λ
xt + i − xt + i − 1 = − π t + i,
4.2.2 Monetary Policy under Commit- α
ment: The Unconstrained Optimum for i = 1,2,3,... (4.18)
We now provide a brief description of and
the general solution for the optimal pol- λ
icy under commitment. 44 Because the xt = − πt (4.19)
α
derivation is more cumbersome than for
the restricted case just described, we Recall that under discretion the opti-
defer most of the details to an appen- mal policy has the central bank adjust
dix. As with the simple fundamental the level of the output gap in response
based policy, however, the general solu- to inflation. The optimal policy under
tion exploits the ability that commit- commitment requires instead adjusting
ment affords to manipulate private the change in the output gap in re-
sector expectations of the future. sponse to inflation. In other words,
The first stage problem remains to commitment changes the level rule for
choose a state-contingent sequence for x t under discretion into a difference
rule for x t, as a comparison of equations
44 We thank Chris Sims and Albert Marcet for
calling to our attention that the globally optimal 45 See also King and Wolman, who analyze the
rule under commitment would likely not fall optimal monetary policy under commitment in a
within the restricted family of rules considered in version of Taylor’s (1980) staggered contracts
the previous sub-section. model.
1682 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXVII (December 1999)

(3.3) and (4.8) indicates. 46 The one ca- tion (given the dependency of π t on fu-
veat is that in the initial period the pol- ture values of x t). Relative to the case of
icy is implemented (i.e., period t) the discretion, accordingly, the cost push
central bank should simply adjust the shock has a smaller impact in current
level of the output gap x t is response to inflation. 48
π t, as if it were following the optimal As with the constrained policy, the
policy under discretion, but for that globally optimal policy under commit-
period only. ment exploits the ability of the central
Because xt + i depends in general on bank to influence π t with expected fu-
xt + i − 1, the (unconstrained) optimal pol- ture values of xt + i as well as current x t.
icy under commitment is in general not It is also easy to see that, as was the
simply a function of the contemporane- case with the more restrictive rule, the
ous state variable ut + i. As Woodford policy is not time consistent. Clearly, if
(1998) emphasizes in a related context, it could reoptimize at t + i, the central
the lagged dependence in the policy bank would choose the same policy it
rule arises as a product of the central implemented at t, the one which mimics
bank’s ability under commitment to di- the rule under discretion for the first
rectly manipulate private sector expec- period only.
tations. 47 To see this for our framework, A disadvantage of the unconstrained
keep in mind that π t depends not only optimal policy under commitment is
on current x t but also on the expected that it appears more complex to imple-
future path of xt + i. Then suppose, for ment than the constrained one (de-
example, that there is a cost push shock scribed by equation 4.12). As we have
that raises inflation above target at time seen, the constrained rule resembles in
t. The optimal response under discre- every dimension the optimal policy un-
tion, as we have seen, is to reduce xt, der discretion, but with relatively more
but then let xt + i revert back to trend weight placed on fighting inflation. Ac-
over time as πt + i falls back to target. cordingly, as we discussed, it is possible
The optimal policy under commitment, to approximate this policy under discre-
however, is to continue to reduce xt + i as tion with an appropriately chosen cen-
long as πt + i remains above target. The tral banker. The same is not true, how-
(credible) threat to continue to contract ever, for the unconstrained optimal
x t in the future, in turn, has the imme- policy. A conservative central banker
diate effect of dampening current infla- operating with discretion has no obvi-
ous incentive to stick to the difference
46 Woodford (1998) makes the connection be- rule for the output gap implied by
tween the lagged dependence in the optimal rule equation (4.18).
under commitment and the lagged dependence
that appears to arise in interest rate behavior un- A further complication, discussed at
der practice (see section 5.2). Roughly speaking, length in Woodford (1998), is that the
since the interest rate affects the output gap, interest rate rule that implements the
lagged dependence in the latter translates into
lagged dependence in the former. optimal policy might have undesirable
47 Woodford (1998) considers a closely related
environment. The difference is that in his frame-
work the policy-maker confronts a trade-off be- 48 On the surface it appears that the difference
tween inflation and the output gap ultimately be- rule for x t might be unstable. However, πt adjusts
cause his objective function includes a target for to ensure that this is not the case. In particular,
the nominal interest rate (along with targets for the optimal response to a positive cost push shock
the output gap and inflation), whereas in our is to contract x t sufficiently to push π t below tar-
framework the trade-off arises due to the cost get. x t then adjusts back up to target over time.
push shock. The appendix provides the details.
Clarida, Galí, Gertler: The Science of Monetary Policy 1683

side effects. To see this, combine (4.18) 5. Practical Complications


and (2.1) to obtain the implied optimal
interest rate rule In this section we consider a number
of important practical issues that com-
 λ  1
it =  1 −  E tπ t + 1 + g t plicate the implementation of monetary
 αϕ  ϕ policy. While they may not be as exotic
Notice that the coefficient associated as the question of credibility, they are
with expected inflation is less than one. no less important for the day-to-day for-
Under this rule, accordingly, a rise in mulation of policy.
anticipated inflation leads to a decline
in the real interest rate. As we discuss 5.1 Imperfect Information
in section 7, if inflationary pressures Thus far we have assumed that the
vary inversely with the real rate, a rule central bank is able to control perfectly
of this type may permit self-fulfilling the paths of the key target variables. In
fluctuations in output and inflation that practice, of course, this is not the case.
are clearly suboptimal. 49 One important reason is imperfect ob-
Overall, we have: servability. At the time it sets interest
Result 8: The globally optimal policy rates, a central bank may not have all
rule under commitment has the central the relevant information available about
bank partially adjust demand in re- the state of the economy. Certain data
sponse to inflationary pressures. The take time to collect and process. Sam-
idea is to exploit the dependence of cur- pling is imperfect. Even if it has access
rent inflation on expected future de- to data in real time, some key variables
mand. In addition, while appointing a such as the natural level of output are
conservative central banker may raise not directly observable and are likely
welfare under discretion (see Result 7), measured with great error (see, e.g., the
it does not appear that it is possible to discussion in Arturo Estrella and
attain the globally optimal rule with Mishkin 1999 and Orphanides 1998).
this strategy. Finally, there may be some Beyond limiting the efficacy of pol-
practical complications in implementing icy, imperfect information has several
the globally optimal interest rate rule specific implications. First, it is no
that involve potential indeterminacy, as longer possible to specify rules simply
discussed in Woodford (1998). in terms of target variables. With per-
We conclude that, though substantial fect information, a policy may be ex-
progress has been made, our under- pressed equivalently in terms of targets
standing of the full practical implica- or instruments since a one-to-one rela-
tions of commitment for policy-making tionship generally exists between these
is still at a relatively primitive stage, variables. With imperfect information,
with plenty of territory that is worth rules for targets can be expressed only
exploring. in terms of the respective forecasts, as
opposed to the ex-post values. An alter-
49 Indeterminacy does not arise in the case of native is to use an intermediate target
discretion or in the case of the constrained opti- that is directly observable, such as a
mum under commitment, since in each instance
the implied interest rate rule has an inflation coef- broad monetary aggregate.
ficient greater than one. To the extent that such Second, imperfect information makes
coefficient is not too large, implementation of the policy instrument choice non-trivial.
such a rule will result in a unique equilibrium (see
the discussion in section 7 and also in Clarida, With perfect information, for example,
Galí, and Gertler (1998). it does not matter whether the central
1684 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXVII (December 1999)

bank uses the short-term interest rate perfect information) and because the er-
or a monetary aggregate as the policy rors in forecasting the target variables
instrument, so long as the money de- are additive.
mand function yields a monotonic rela- For ease of exposition, assume that
tion between the two variables. 50 With there is no serial correlation in the
imperfect information, the ex post vola- cost push shock; that is, ρ = 0, so that
tility of a variety of key variables hinges ut = ^
ut. The implied equilibrium values
on the instrument choice, as originally of the target variables under imperfect
argued by William Poole (1970). We information, xIt and πIt , are given by
illustrate each of these issues below. 51  λ ^ ^ ^
xIt = xt +  u t + g t = g t (5.2)
λ + α
2
5.1.1 Forecasts as Targets and 
Intermediate Targets
 λ2 
πIt = 1 +  πt + λg
^t = ^
ut + λg^t (5.3)
We now return to the baseline model  α 
with no commitment, and modify it as
where xt and πt are the optimal values of
follows. Suppose that the central bank
the target variables that emerge in case
cannot observe the contemporaneous
of perfect information (when ut is serially
values of output, inflation, or any of the
uncorrelated),53 and where ^ ut and ^
gt are
random shocks. Then let Ω t be the cen-
the unexpected movements in the cost
tral bank’s information set at the time it
push and demand shocks, respectively. Im-
fixes the interest rate that prevails at
perfect information clearly implies greater
time t. 52 The optimality condition for
volatility of inflation, since the central
policy now is expressed in terms of the
bank cannot immediately act to offset
expected as opposed to realized target
the impact of the shocks. The net effect
variables.
on the volatility of the output gap is un-
λ   clear: the inability to offset the demand
E xt | Ω t = − E π t | Ω t
 
  (5.1)
 

α   
shock clearly raises output volatility. On
Equation (5.1) is the certainty equivalent the other hand, the central bank cannot
version of the condition for the case of offset the inflationary impact of the cost
perfect information, given by equation push shock, which works to reduce the
(3.3). Certainty equivalence applies here volatility of the output. There is, however,
because of the linear quadratic setup an unambiguous reduction in welfare. 54
(that gives linear decision rules under One additional result is worth noting.
Since demand shocks now affect the be-
50 To clarify, a money aggregate can serve as an
havior of output, a positive short-run
instrument only if it is directly controllable. A can-
didate aggregate then would be bank reserves. A co-movement between inflation and
broad aggregate such as M3 would not qualify. output can emerge if ^ gt has a variance
51 For a broad survey of the literature on mone-
sufficiently large relative to that of u ^t.
tary policy targets and instruments, see Friedman
(1991). It is straightforward to generalize the
52 Thus, Ω is similarly the private sector’s infor-
t analysis to a setting where the imper-
mation set. Specifically, we let firms observe the fect observability stems from lags in the
current values of their marginal costs, but neither −λ
53
firms nor households can observe contemporane- When u t is serially uncorrelated, xt = 2
ut
ous aggregate variables. In this instance, the IS λ +α
and Phillips curve equations are respectively given α
by and πt = u t.
λ2 + α
54 To prove that imperfect information leads to a
xt = − ϕ[(it | Ω t) − E t − 1 πt+1 ] + E t − 1 xt + 1 + g t
reduction in welfare, evaluate the welfare function
πt = λxt + βE t − 1 πt + 1 + u t with xIt and πIt versus xt and πt.
Clarida, Galí, Gertler: The Science of Monetary Policy 1685

transmission of monetary policy. This reasonable only if the economy has


case is of interest since much of the attained a stationary equilibrium.
available evidence suggests a lag of six A traditional alternative to using the
to nine months in the effect of a shift in target variable forecasts is to focus on
interest rates on output. 55 The lag in the behavior of a variable that is corre-
the effect on inflation is around a year lated with the underlying targets but is
and a half. Suppose, for example, that it instead observable and controllable.
takes j periods for a shift in the current Broad monetary aggregates are the best
interest rate to affect output and an- known examples of intermediate tar-
other k periods for an impact on infla- gets. If demand for a particular aggre-
tion. In the left side of equation (5.1) gate is stable, then this aggregate is
would appear the j period ahead fore- likely to have a stable covariance with
cast of the output gap, and on the right nominal GDP. In practice, however, ex-
would be the (suitably discounted) j + k perience with monetary targeting has
period ahead forecast of inflation. not been successful. The U.S. and the
Svensson (1997a,b) has emphasized U.K., for example, attempted to regu-
the practical importance of this result late the growth of money aggregates in
for the mechanics of inflation targeting the early 1980s and then quickly aban-
(specifically, the kind of inflation tar- doned the policy after the aggregates
geting that the theory implies (see Re- went haywire. 57 Financial innovation in
sult 2 in section 3). A standard criticism each instance was the underlying cul-
of employing an inflation target is that prit. Even in Germany, long considered
information about the impact of current a bastion of money targeting, there have
monetary policy on inflation is only been problems. Unstable movements in
available with a long lag. This informa- money demand have forced a retreat
tion lag, it is argued, makes it impossi- from strict money growth targeting. A
ble to monitor policy performance. It is number of recent papers go further by
possible to circumvent this problem, ac- arguing that in practice Bundesbank
cording to Svensson, by focusing in- policy looks more like inflation target-
stead on the inflation forecast. The ing (as defined in Result 2) than money
forecast is immediately available. It targeting (Clarida and Gertler 1997;
thus provides a quick way to judge the Bernanke and Mihov 1997b).
course of policy. A caveat to this argu- For similar reasons, policies that tar-
ment is that to generate the correct in- get other kinds of simple indicators,
flation forecast, the central bank must such as commodity prices or long term
have a good structural model of the interest rates, have not been widely em-
economy. 56 VAR-based forecasts are ployed. As Woodford (1994a) has em-
phasized, the correlation properties of
55 Galí (1992), Christiano, Eichenbaum, and these simple indicators with output and
Evans (1996), and Bernanke and Mihov (1997a)
document the slow response of GDP to a policy
shock, and the even slower response of prices. cast-based targets, including the possibility of in-
Bernanke and Gertler (1995) show that, while the determinacy under this kind of policy rule. We
overall response of output is sluggish, certain com- discuss this issue in section 7.
ponents of spending do respond quickly, such as 57 See Friedman and Kuttner (1996) for a de-
housing and consumer durables. Inventories ad- tailed accounting of the failure of monetary target-
just to reconcile the gap between spending and ing to take hold in the U.S. See also Estrella and
output. Mishkin (1996). On the other hand, Feldstein and
56 Bernanke and Woodford (1997) emphasize Stock (1997) argue that, with periodic adjustment,
the need to make structural forecasts. They also a broad monetary aggregate can still be a useful
raise some other related criticisms of using fore- intermediate target.
1686 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXVII (December 1999)

inflation is likely to vary with changes where pt is the price level and v t is a
in the policy rule. In the end, there is random disturbance to money demand.
no simple substitute for employing a If v t is perfectly observable then it does
structural model. not matter whether i t or m t is employed
To summarize, we have as the policy instrument. Given the time
Result 9: With imperfect informa- path of i t implied by the optimal policy,
tion, stemming either from data prob- it is possible to back out a time path
lems or lags in the effect of policy, the for m t that supports this policy from
optimal policy rules are the certainty equation (5.4).
equivalent versions of the perfect infor- Matters change if v t is not observ-
mation case. Policy rules must be ex- able. With the interest rate as the in-
pressed in terms of the forecasts of tar- strument, the central bank lets the
get variables as opposed to the ex post money stock adjust to the money de-
behavior. Using observable intermediate mand shock. There is no impact of
targets, such as broad money aggregates is money demand shocks on output or in-
a possibility, but experience suggests that flation because the central bank per-
these indirect indicators are generally fectly accommodates them. With money
too unstable to be used in practice. targeting, the reverse is true: the inter-
est rate and (possibly) output adjust to
5.1.2 The Instrument Choice Problem: clear the money market. Assume for
The Interest Rate versus a Narrow simplicity that demand and cost push
Monetary Aggregate shocks are absent (i.e., g t = 0, u t = 0), so
that the only shock is the innovation to
We now turn to the issue of instru- money demand. Then the interest rate
ment choice. In practice, the interest implied by a money supply instrument
rate that major central banks adjust is im
t , is given by
an overnight rate on interbank lending 1
t = it +
of funds to meet reserve require- im ^
vt (5.5)
η + ϕ(κ + λ)
ments. 58 They control this rate by ma-
nipulating the supply of bank reserves, where it is the rate that would arise un-
i.e., the quantity of high-powered der interest rate targeting and ^ vt is the
money available for meeting bank re- unexpected movement in money demand.
serve requirements. The issue that The key point is that money demand
arises is whether, from an operational shocks can induce volatile behavior of
standpoint, policy should prescribe interest rates. This is particularly true if
paths (or rules) for bank reserves or for money demand is relatively interest in-
interest rates. Suppose that the demand elastic in the short run, as is the case
for bank reserves m t is given by 59 for bank reserves. This short run volatil-
ity in interest rates will then feed into
m t − p t = κ y t − η it + v t (5.4)
output volatility, via the aggregate de-
58 See Bernanke and Mihov (1997a) for a discus- mand relation, equation (2.1). It is for
sion of Federal Reserve operating procedures and this reason that in practice central banks
how they have changed over time. use interbank lending rates as the pol-
59 In the optimizing IS/LM framework of sec-
tion 2, it is possible to motivate this specification icy instrument, an insight due originally
of the money demand function from first princi- to Poole (1970). 60 Recent empirical
ples, assuming that utility is separable in consump-
tion and real money balances and that consump- 60 Poole also argued that if unobservable de-
tion is the only type of good (see, e.g., Woodford mand shocks were large relative to money demand
1996). shocks, then it may be preferable to use a money
Clarida, Galí, Gertler: The Science of Monetary Policy 1687

work by Bernanke and Mihov (1997a) This finding is not uncommon. The
confirms that except for the brief pe- FRB-US model also generates high in-
riod of non-borrowed reserve targeting terest rate volatility under an optimal
under Volcker (1979:10–1982:10), the rule. Because this degree of volatility
Federal Reserve Board has indeed seems greater than monetary policy
treated the Funds rate as the policy in- makers seem willing to tolerate in prac-
strument. In summary, we have tice, optimal rules are also computed
Result 10: Large unobservable with constraints on the volatility of
shocks to money demand produce high interest rate changes (see, e.g., John
volatility of interest rates when a mone- Williams 1997). 61
tary aggregate is used as the policy in- The tendency of the Federal Reserve
strument. It is largely for this reason to adjust rates cautiously is generally re-
that an interest rate instrument may be ferred to as “interest rate smoothing.”
preferable. To be precise, as a number of authors
The analysis thus makes clear why the have shown, a monetary policy rule of
new Federal Reserve Board model does the following form captures the last
not even bother to include a money ag- twenty or so years of data fairly well:
gregate of any form (see Flint Brayton
et al. 1997). Narrow aggregates are not it = (1 − ρ)[α + β πt + γ xt] + ρ it − 1 + εt (5.6)
good policy instruments due to the im- where α is a constant interpretable as
plied interest rate volatility. Broad ag- the steady state nominal interest rate62
gregates are not good intermediate tar- and where ρ ∈[0,1] is a parameter that
gets because of their unstable relation reflects the degree of lagged depen-
with aggregate activity. dence in the interest rate.63 Interest rate
smoothing is present in distinct respects.
5.2 Policy Conservatism: Model First, the estimated slope coefficients on
Uncertainty vs. Exploitation of inflation and the output gap, β and γ, are
Forward-Looking Behavior typically smaller than what the optimal
In practice, central banks adjust in- rule would suggest. Second, there is typi-
terest rates more cautiously than stan- cally partial adjustment to movements in
dard models predict. Put differently, πt and xt, reflected by the presence of the
optimal policies derived in a certainty lagged interest in the fitted rule. That is,
equivalent environment generally pre- i t is a weighted average of some desired
dict a much more variable path of inter- value that depends on the state economy
est rates than is observed in practice. (given by the term [ α + βπt + γ xt] ) and the
An interesting illustration of this point lagged interest rate, where the relative
is Rotemberg and Woodford (1997) who weights depend on the smoothing pa-
estimate a model very similar to our rameter ρ. Estimates of ρ for quarterly
baseline model, and then compute an data are typically on the order of 0.8 or
optimal interest rate policy. The histori- 0.9, which suggests very slow adjustment
cal interest rate displays much less vola- 61 An alternative is to penalize large changes in
tility than the optimal interest rate. the nominal interest rate by including the squared
deviations of the change in the interest rate (i.e,
( it − it − 1)2) in the function, as in Rudebusch and
supply instrument. With a money supply instru- Svensson (1998).
ment, interest rates will naturally move in an off- 62 Recall that π represents deviations of infla-
t
setting direction in response to unobserved de- tion from its average (target) level.
mand shocks (see Result 4). In practice, the high 63 See Rudebusch (1995), for example, for a dis-
variability of money demand shocks seems to cussion of the persistence in short term interest
dominate the instrument choice, however. rates.
1688 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXVII (December 1999)

in practice. The existing theory, by and To be concrete, suppose that the two
large, does not readily account for why parameters of the model, the interest
the central bank should adjust rates in elasticity in the IS equation and the
such a sluggish fashion. slope coefficient on the output gap are
~
Indeed, understanding why central random variables, now given by ϕt = ϕ + εt
~
banks choose a smooth path of interest and by λt = λ + ηt. 65 Assume further that
rates than theory would predict is an εt and ηt are i.i.d random variables with
important unresolved issue. One impli- zero means. The optimality condition
cation is that the standard certainty for policy then becomes:
equivalence models may not adequately
capture the constraints policy-makers λ
E{xt | Ω t} = E{πt | Ω t}
face in practice. A natural possibility is α + λ2σ2η
that policy-makers know far less about σ2ε
+ (α + λ2) rt (5.7)
the way the world works than is ϕ
presumed in simple policy experiments. where rt ≡ it − E{πt + 1 | Ω t} is the ex ante
In general, model uncertainty is a real interest rate. This condition leads to
formidable problem. Ideally, one would the following result:
like to take into account that the central Result 11: Parameter uncertainty
bank is continually learning about the may reduce the response of the policy
economy as it adjusts its policy. Per- instrument to disturbances in the econ-
forming this exercise in a clean way is omy. It can thus motivate a smoother
beyond the frontier of current knowl- path of the interest rate than the cer-
edge. Though, advances in computa- tainty equivalent policy implies.
tional methodology have allowed some Comparing equations (5.1) and (5.7)
progress to be made with relatively reveals how parameter uncertainty re-
simple frameworks. 64 duces policy activism. Under certainty
It is possible to illustrate how model equivalence, a rise in inflation above
uncertainty could in principle introduce target requires the central bank to raise
at least some degree of policy caution. interest rates to contract demand. 66
Suppose the values of several parame- With an uncertain slope coefficient
ters in the model are random. The cen- on the output gap in the AS curve, how-
tral bank knows the distribution of ever, contraction of output below po-
these parameters but not the realiza- tential raises the variability of inflation.
tion. When it adjusts policy, accord- This induces the central bank to moder-
ingly, it cannot be sure of the impact on ate the contraction in demand, as re-
the economy. As originally demon- flected by the presence of the term λ2σ2η
strated by William Brainard (1969), this in the coefficient on E{πt | Ω t}. Similarly,
kind of uncertainty can introduce cau- 65 We are assuming that the policy-maker knows
tion in policy responses. In contrast to the first two moments of the random parameters.
the case of certainty-equivalence, policy It may be more plausible to argue that the policy-
maker in fact has little idea what the true distri-
actions now affect the conditional vari- bution looks like. See Onatski and Stock (1999)
ance of inflation and output, as well as who analyze the policy problem in this kind of en-
the conditional mean. vironment using robust control methods.
66 It should also be clear from equation (5.7)
that with parameter uncertainty the interest rate
64 Wieland (1997) analyzes policy in a frame- no longer adjusts to perfectly offset demand
work where the central bank has to learn the value shocks. Suppose, for example, that there is a posi-
of the natural rate of unemployment (which, in tive demand shock. The interest rate goes up, but
our analysis, corresponds to having to learn about the parameter uncertainty moderates the extent of
potential GDP.) the rise, relative to the certainty equivalence case.
Clarida, Galí, Gertler: The Science of Monetary Policy 1689

uncertainty about the impact of an in- may care about avoiding excessive vola-
crease in the interest rate on the output tility in the short term interest rate in
gap moderates the extent of adjustment pursuing its stabilization goals.
in it. The second term on the right side To illustrate, consider the special
of equation (5.7) captures this latter case of equation (5.6) with ρ = 1. In this
dampening effect. instance, the difference in the interest
This simple form of model uncertainty rate (it − it − 1), as opposed to the level, is
thus may help explain the relatively low a linear function of πt and xt. Under the
variability of interest rates in the data. difference rule, the expected future
One feature of interest rate smoothing short rate at t + i, Et{it + i}, is given by
it does not appear to capture, however,
 k 
is the strong lagged dependence in the
Et{it + k} = Et∑ (it + j − it + j − 1) + it
interest rate. Put differently, the kind j=1 
of parameter uncertainty we have dis-   (5.8)
cussed may explain why the slope coef-  k 
= Et∑ [α + βπt + j + γxt + j] + it
 
ficients on inflation and the output gap,
j=1 
α and β, are small relative to the case of  
certainty equivalence. But it does not Assume that the long-term rate depends
explain the partial adjustment, given by on the sum of expected short rates over
the dependence of it on it − 1.67 the same horizon, in keeping with the ex-
Rotemberg and Woodford (1997) of- pectations hypothesis of the term struc-
fer a novel explanation for the lagged ture. Then, in comparison with the level
dependence that is based on the lever- rule, the difference rule increases the re-
age that this kind of adjustment rule sponsiveness of the long term rate under
may provide the central bank over the the feedback policy. Suppose for example
long term interest rate. The idea is that that, in reaction to a rise in inflation above
lagged dependence in it permits the target at time t, the central bank raises it
central bank to manipulate long term above its steady state value. Under the
rates, and hence aggregate demand, difference rule the increase in the inter-
with more modest movements in the est rate has a persistent effect on the path
short term rate than would be otherwise of the expected short rate, since Et it + i 



 
be required. This kind of rule is thus depends additively on it. Further, if changes
desirable to the extent the central bank in inflation and output are persistent,
67 Sack (1997a,b) argues, nonetheless, that pa- then the path of expected short rates will
rameter uncertainty can explain this phenomenon actually be rising, as equation (5.8) makes
if the uncertainty of the impact of the interest rate clear. 68 The difference rule thus en-
on the economy is based on the change in the in-
terest rate (it − it − 1) as opposed to the deviation hances the countercyclical movement of
from trend it. In the former instance, changes in it the long rate relative to the movement of
raise the conditional variability of output, which short rate. Given that aggregate demand
induces the central bank to keep it close to it − 1.
On the other hand, it is not well understood how depends on the long rate, this kind of
the link between model uncertainty and policy rule thus enables the central bank to
conservatism is affected when there is active
learning about the economy. Some results suggest
that learning should induce active adjustments of 68 On the surface it appears that the interest
the policy instrument to facilitate estimating the rate might explode under the difference rule,
true model. See the discussion in Wieland (1997), since it will continue to increase so long as infla-
for example. Also, it is possible to construct exam- tion is above target. However, the rise in the inter-
ples where parameter uncertainty leads to in- est rate will dampen demand and inflation. In the
creased activism. See, for example, Thomas Sar- context of our model, it does so sufficiently to pre-
gent (1998). clude explosive behavior.
1690 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXVII (December 1999)

stabilize the economy with relatively it is always optimal to tighten monetary


modest movements in the short rate. 69 policy to gradually bring inflation back
Overall, Rotemberg and Woodford to the optimum (see Result 2 in Section
provide a plausible explanation for why 3). During his tenure at the Federal Re-
central banks may want to introduce serve Board, however, Blinder proposed
lagged dependence in the interest rate. the following alternative: If inflation is
Whether this story can also account for above but near the optimum, policy
the empirically observed modest re- should not contract demand. Rather, it
sponse of the short rate to inflation and should take an “opportunistic” ap-
the output gap (i.e., the low values of β proach. Roughly speaking, being oppor-
and γ, the slope coefficients on πt and xt) tunistic boils down to waiting until
remains to be seen. achieving the inflation target could be
Another explanation for policy con- done at the least cost in terms of incre-
servatism and the associated interest mental output reduction. Blinder’s
rate smoothing includes fear of disrupt- original concept was vague as to the de-
ing financial markets (see, e.g., Good- tails. Recent work by researchers at the
friend 1991). Sharp unanticipated in- Federal Reserve Board has filled in a
creases in interest rates can generate number of the missing pieces.
capital losses, particularly for commer- Athanasios Orphanides and David
cial banks and other financial institu- Wilcox (1996) show that it is possible to
tions that may be exposed to interest rationalize something like opportunistic
rate risk. This consideration might ex- policy by making a small adjustment of
plain why the Federal Reserve chose to the policy objective function. In par-
raise rates only very gradually during ticular, suppose that policy-makers care
1994, the tail end of a period of consid- quite a lot about small departures of
erable financial distress (see, e.g., the output from target, at least relative to
discussion in John Campbell 1995). Dis- small departures of inflation. An exam-
agreement among policy-makers is an- ple of an objective function that capture
other explanation for slow adjustment this phenomenon is given by
of rates. Neither of these alternative
stories have been well developed, 1  ∞ i 
Et∑ β (α | xt + i | + πt2 + i)

however. In general, understanding max − (5.9)
2 i = 0 
why interest rate smoothing occurs in  
practice is an important unresolved With this objective function, the opti-
issue. mality condition for policy becomes:
α
5.3 Non-Smooth Preferences xt = 0, if | πt | <
λ (5.10)
and Opportunism
α
| πt | = , otherwise
Another aspect of policy that has re- λ
ceived considerable attention involves Thus, if inflation is within αλ units of
the process of disinflation. In the base- the target, the optimal policy is to sim-
line model, if inflation is above target, ply stabilize output. Otherwise, policy
69 The idea that the central bank should pursue should keep inflation at most αλ units
a partial adjustment rule to exploit the depen- from target and then wait for favorable
dence of demand on future policy is reminiscent supply shocks that move it closer to tar-
of the globally optimal policy under commitment
(see section 4.2.2). Indeed, Woodford (1998) get (e.g., favorable movements in the
makes this connection formally. cost push shock ut). In this respect the
Clarida, Galí, Gertler: The Science of Monetary Policy 1691

policy is opportunistic. A better term We now consider an alternative frame-


for it, however, might be “inflation zone work that allows for endogenous persis-
targeting” (Bernanke and Mishkin tence in output and inflation. Our pur-
1997). What the policy really amounts pose is to show that the results derived
to is keeping inflation with a certain in the baseline framework extend to this
range, as opposed to trying to move it more general setting. In this regard, we
to an exact target. show that our results are not specific to
Variations on this theme allow for the particular benchmark model we em-
preferences that generate an inflation ployed, but instead hold across a rea-
zone target, but then has policy trade off sonably broad class of models that are
between inflation and output goals when used for applied macroeconomic analy-
inflation is outside the target zone. Or- sis. The major difference is that with
phanides, David Small, Volcker Wieland endogenous persistence in inflation, the
and Wilcox (1997) (OSWW) provide an equilibrium feedback monetary policy now
example of this more general setup. influences the speed of convergence of
It is important to emphasize, though, inflation to its target.
that opportunistic policy behavior that Consider the following generaliza-
is distinct from the gradualism of the tions of the IS and aggregate supply
baseline model only arises if cost push curves:
factors are present in inflation. This is
true because only with cost push infla- x t = − ϕ [ it − E t π t + 1 ] + θ x t − 1
tion present does a trade-off between + (1 − θ)Etxt + 1 + gt (6.1)
output and inflation emerge (see Result
π t = λ xt + φ π t − 1
1). Indeed, OSWW show that opportun-
+ (1 − φ)βEtπt + 1 + ut (6.2)
istic policy rules are equivalent to con-
ventional gradualist rules in the pres- Equation (6.1) incorporates the lagged
ence of demand shocks, but differ when output gap in the IS curve. Equation
there are supply shocks. 70 (6.2) adds lagged inflation to the aggre-
In summary, we have gate supply curve. The parameters θ and
Result 12: If there is more cost asso- φ index the influence of lagged versus ex-
ciated with small departures of output pected future variables. As a result the
from target than with small departures model nests some important special
of inflation, then an opportunistic ap- cases. With θ = 0 and φ = 0, we recover
proach to disinflation may be optimal. the baseline model. Conversely, with
This policy, further, is equivalent to θ = 1 and φ = 1, the model becomes
targeting inflation around a zone as (approximately) the backward-looking
opposed to a particular value. framework that Svensson (1997a,b) and
Ball (1997) have used to analyze mone-
6. Implications of Endogenous Inflation tary policy. For simplicity we assume that
and Output Persistence the disturbances gt and ut are serially
uncorrelated (i.e., we set µ and ρ in
Within our baseline model, the dy-
equation (2.3) and (2.4) equal to zero).
namics of output and inflation are due
This simple formulation does not allow
entirely to exogenous force processes.
for delays in the effect of policy, but we
70 For an alternative description of the oppor- show later that it is easy to amend the
tunistic approach, see Bomfin and Rudebusch analysis to incorporate delayed policy
(1997). These authors emphasize the ratcheting
down of inflation and, in particular, explore the effects.
role of imperfect credibility. As we noted earlier, virtually all the
1692 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXVII (December 1999)

major applied macroeconomic models analytical solution is not available, ex-


allow for some form of lagged depen- cept in the polar cases of φ = 0 and φ = 1.
dence in output and inflation. The pri- It is, however, possible to provide an in-
mary justification is empirical. 71 By ap- tuitive description of the optimum. Let
pealing to some form of adjustment aπ be a parameter that measures the se-
costs, it may be feasible to explicitly rial dependence of inflation in the
motivate the appearance of xt − 1 within reduced form. Then the optimality
the IS curve. Motivating the appearance condition that governs policy is given
of lagged inflation in the aggregate sup- by:
ply curve, however, is a more formida- ∞
λ
ble challenge. 72 Some frameworks do so xt = −  π t + ∑ β k E tπ t + k  (6.3)
by effectively appealing to costs of α k=1 
changing the rate of inflation. 73 This as-
λ
sumption, though, is clearly unattrac- = − πt (6.4)
tive. In the spirit of robustness, how- α(1 − βaπ)
ever, it is important to understand the with
implications of lagged dependence. This π t = aπ πt − 1 + au ut (6.5)
is particularly true given the empirical and
appeal of this formulation.
We begin with the case of discretion, 0 ≤ aπ < 1
and then later describe briefly how the With inertia present, adjustments in
results are affected when the central current monetary policy affect future
bank can make credible promises. 74 An time path of inflation. As consequence,
policy now responds not only to current
71 For an empirical justification for including
inflation but also to forecasts of infla-
lagged dependent variables, see Fuhrer (1996).
72 It is possible to motivate a dependency of cur- tion into the indefinite future. How
rent inflation on lagged inflation by appealing to much depends positively on aπ, which
adaptive expectations (e.g., suppose E t − 1πt = measures the degree of inflationary
κπt − 1 ). Indeed, this is the traditional approach
(see the discussion in Blanchard 1997). The issue
persistence.
then becomes motivating the assumption of adap- The coefficients aπ and au are func-
tive expectations. tions of the underlying parameters
73 See, for example, Fuhrer and Moore
(1995a,b) and Brayton, Levin, Tyron, and Williams
(α,λ,β,φ). 75 The former, aπ, is key, since
(1997). Galí and Gertler (forthcoming) criticize it measures the speed of convergence to
the existing empirical literature on inflation dy- inflation under the optimal policy. It is
namics, and provide new evidence which suggests
that (2.2) is a good first approximation to the data.
possible to show that this parameter lies
74 As in section 3, we restrict attention to between zero and unity, implying con-
Markov perfect equilibria. In this case, however, vergence. The magnitude of aπ depends
we must take into account that inflation is an en-
dogenous state variable. In any stationary equilib-
positively on the degree of inflation in-
rium, therefore, expected inflation will depend on ertia φ. In the baseline case of no infla-
lagged inflation. What the policy maker takes as tion inertia, φ = 0, implying aπ = 0. aπ
given, accordingly, is not the level of expected in-
flation, but rather how private sector expectations 75
To obtain solutions for aπ and au , substitute
of inflation tomorrow respond to movements in in-
λ
flation today. Simply put, to solve for the equilib- the optimality condition xt = − πt and
rium under discretion, we assume that private sec- α(1 − βa π )
tor forecast of πt + 1 takes the form νππt + νu u t, the conjectured solution for πt, (6.5), into the ag-
where νπ and νu are arbitrary constants that the gregate supply curve. Then use the methods of
policy-maker takes as given. In the rational expec- undetermined coefficients to solve for aπ and au .
tations equilibrium νπ and νu equal the true funda- The equation for aπ is a cubic. The solution is the
mental parameters in the reduced form inflation, unique value between zero and unity, which corre-
a π and a u . sponds to the unique stable root.
Clarida, Galí, Gertler: The Science of Monetary Policy 1693

also depends negatively on the relative Most of the qualitative results ob-
cost of inflation, measured by 1/α. As in tained in the baseline case extend to
the baseline case, if the distaste for in- this more general setting. As in the
flation is high (α is low), the optimal baseline case, the policy-maker faces a
policy aggressively contracts demand short-run trade-off between output and
whenever inflation is above target: With inflation (Result 1). The effect of infla-
endogenous persistence, this contrac- tion inertia is to make this trade-off less
tion not only reduces inflation but also favorable. Equation (6.3) shows that
increases the speed of convergence to relative to the baseline case of φ = 0, the
target. Figure 2 illustrates the relation optimal policy requires a more aggres-
between aπ and α for three different sive response to any burst of inflation.
values of φ: φ = 0.01 (low inertia), φ = 0.5 The problem is that any inflation not
(medium) and φ = 0.99 (high). eliminated today persists into the fu-
Combining (6.3) with (6.1) yields the ture, potentially requiring more output
implied optimal interest rate rule: contraction. Figure 3 illustrates how the
1 trade-off becomes less favorable in this
it = γ π E t π t + 1 + γ x x t − 1 + g t (6.6) case by plotting the efficient policy
ϕ
frontier for the three benchmark values
with of φ. In addition, since 0 ≤ aπ < 1, the op-
λ(1 − aπ) timal policy calls for gradual adjustment
γπ = 1 +
ϕαaπ(1 − βaπ) of inflation to target (Result 2). With
θ φ > 0, further, extreme inflation target-
γx = ing is only optimal if α = 0, as equation
ϕ
(6.3) and Figure 2 suggest.
E tπ t + 1 = a π π t From the interest rate rule given by
1694 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXVII (December 1999)

equation (6.6) it is apparent that the co-


efficient on expected inflation exceeds
unity, implying that the ex ante real
rate must rise in response to higher ex-
pected inflation (Result 3). Finally, the
interest rate should also adjust to per-
fectly offset demand shocks, but should
not respond to movements in potential
output (Result 4.) One interesting dif-
ference in this case is that the interest
rate responds to the lagged output gap,
since this variable now enters the IS
curve. Thus, the optimal interest rate
rule now resembles the simple gap rules
that have been discussed in the litera-
ture. We return to this point later. In
summary, we have
Result 13: Results 1 through 4 that
describe optimal monetary policy under
discretion within the baseline model
also apply in the case with endogenous
output and inflation persistence.
In addition to allowing for lagged de-
pendence in output and inflation, there
is also strong empirical justification for
incorporating delays in the effect of
policy. It is straightforward to extend
the analysis to include this real world
feature. Suppose, following Svensson
(1997a,b) and Ball (1997), that there is
a one-period delay in the effect of the
real interest rate on the output gap and,
in turn, a one-period delay in the effect
of the output gap on inflation. Then the
optimality condition becomes 76
λ
Et{xt + 1} = − Et{πt + 2} (6.7)
α(1 − βaπl )
where the parameter alπ measures the se-
rial dependence in inflation for this case.
It has qualitatively similar properties to
aπ in equation (6.5), with 0 ≤ alπ < 1. The
left side of (6.7) reflects the one-period
delay in the impact of policy on output,
76 In this case, the IS curve is given by x =
t
− ϕ [it − 1 − E t − 1 πt] + θxt − 1 + (1 − θ)E t − 1 xt + 1 + g t and
the aggregate supply curve is given by πt =
λxt − 1 + φπt − 1 + (1 − φ)βE tπt + 1 + u t.
Clarida, Galí, Gertler: The Science of Monetary Policy 1695

and the right side reflects the two-period installing a conservative central bank
delay on inflation. chair.
Due to the delayed impact of policy,
the central bank takes both the output 7. Simple Rules for Monetary Policy
gap at t, xt, and the forecast of inflation
We next discuss some normative and
at t + 1, Et{πt + 1}, as predetermined from
positive aspects of simple feedback
the vantage of time t. The rest of the
rules for the interest rate that have
solution may thus be expressed in terms
been discussed in the literature. We then
of these predetermined variables:
discuss how these instrument-based
Et{πt + 2} = alπ Et{πt + 1} (6.8) rules are related to simple rules for tar-
it = γ π E t π t + 1 + γ x x t
l
(6.9) gets that have been recently proposed,
with including inflation targeting and nomi-
nal GDP targeting. Finally, we conclude
(γπ − 1)β
γπl = 1 + >1 with a brief discussion of the issue of
alπ possible indeterminacy of interest rate
The solution closely resembles the rules.
case without delay. Any differences just
7.1 Simple Interest Rate Rules
reflect the lagged influence of policy in
this environment. The nominal rate still Taylor (1993a) ignited the discussion
adjusts more than one-for-one with ex- of simple interest rate rules. 78 He pro-
pected inflation. Due to the lag struc- posed a feedback policy of the following
ture, though, it adjusts to the current form:
output gap, as opposed to one from the –) + γ x
i∗ = α + γ (π − π
t π t (7.1)
x t
previous period.
We conclude this section with brief with
discussion of the gains from commit- α = –r + π –
ment. It is possible to show that, as in γπ > 1, γx > 0
the baseline model, the policy rule un- ∗
der commitment resembles the rule un- where it is the target interest rate the
feedback rule defines, π – is the target in-
der discretion that would obtain if the –
policy-maker assigned a higher relative flation rate, and r is the long-run equi-
cost to inflation (lower value of α ) than librium real interest rate.79 Also, we now
the true social cost. Because inflation express all variables in levels, as opposed
inertia is endogenous in this case, the to deviations from trend.
optimal policy with commitment im- A number of other researchers have
plies a faster transition of inflation to considered rules like (7.1) (see, e.g.,
the optimum relative to what occurs un- Henderson and Mckibbon 1993). Tay-
der discretion. This can be seen by not- lor’s contribution is to spell out the nor-
ing that the parameter which governs mative and positive implications. On
the speed of convergence of inflation,
78 McCallum (1988) proposed a simple rule for
aπ, is decreasing in the relative cost of
the monetary base. The rule is less popular in pol-
inflation 1/α (see Figure 4). 77 Simply icy circles due to the implied interest rate volatil-
put, disinflations will be swifter than ity (see Result 9). McCallum (1997) argues, how-
otherwise if credible commitment is ever, that the concern about interest rate volatility
is not well understood, a point with which we
possible either directly or indirectly by agree.
79 The inflation rate Taylor uses is actually the
77 Note that the speed of convergence of infla- rate over the previous year (as opposed to the pre-
tion is decreasing in aπ. vious quarter).
1696 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXVII (December 1999)

the normative side, the rule is consis- rule provides a reasonably good descrip-
tent with the main principles for opti- tion of policy over the period 1987–92.
mal policy that we have described. It These are: γπ = 1.5, γx = 0.5, π– = 2, and
calls for gradual adjustment of inflation –r = 2. Taylor used informal judgement
to its target (see Result 2). Specifically, to pick them. An interesting question is
it has the nominal rate adjust more than whether a formal methodology would
one-for-one with the inflation rate. To yield something different.
the extent lagged inflation is a good In this spirit, Clarida, Galí, and Gertler
predictor of future inflation, the rule (forthcoming) estimate a simple rule for
thus has real rates adjusting to engineer U.S. monetary policy, and consider how
inflation back to target (see Result 3). this rule has evolved over time. The
Finally, note that the interest rate re- specific formulation is a “forward look-
sponds to the output gap as opposed to ing” version of the simple Taylor rule:
the level of output. Thus, in at least an –) + γ x
approximate sense, the rule calls for a ti∗ = α + γ (E π
π t t+1 −π x t (7.2)
countercyclical response to demand Under this rule, policy responds to
shocks and accommodation of shocks to expected inflation as opposed to lagged
potential GDP that do not affect the inflation. In this respect, the formula-
output gap (see Result 4). tion is consistent with the optimal rules
On the positive side, Taylor showed derived for both the baseline and hy-
that with certain parameter values, the brid models (see equations 3.6 and 6.6).
Clarida, Galí, Gertler: The Science of Monetary Policy 1697

TABLE 1
ESTIMATES OF POLICY REACTION FUNCTION

γπ γx ρ
Pre-Volcker 0.83 0.27 0.68
(0.07) (0.08) (0.05)
Volcker–Greenspan 2.15 0.93 0.79
(0.40) (0.42) (0.04)

Another virtue is that this formulation with standard errors are given by Table
nests the simple Taylor rule as a special 1. 80
case. If either inflation or a linear com- The key lesson involves the parame-
bination of lagged inflation and the out- ter γπ, the coefficient on the inflation
put gap is a sufficient statistic for future gap. The estimate for the pre-Volcker
inflation, then the specification col- rule is significantly less than unity. This
lapses to the Taylor rule. suggests that monetary policy over this
Because of the Federal Reserve’s ten- period was accommodating increases in
dency to smooth interest rate adjust- expected inflation, in clear violation of
ments (see the discussion in section 5), the guidelines suggested by Results 2
a static relation like equation (7.2) can- and 3. For the post-1979 rule the esti-
not capture the serial correlation pres- mate is significantly above unity. It thus
ent in the data. We thus allow for the incorporates the implicit inflation tar-
possibility of partial adjustment to the geting feature that we have argued is a
target rate, according to: critical feature of good monetary policy
management. It is also true that in the
it = ρ it − 1 + (1 − ρ)i∗t (7.3) Volcker–Greenspan era the Federal Re-
where ρ is a parameter that measures the serve was only responding to the output
degree of interest rate smoothing. gap to the extent it had predictive
We estimate different rules for the power for inflation: 81 The estimated co-
pre-Volcker (1960:1–79:2) and Volcker– efficient on the output gap, γx, is not
Greenspan (1979:3–96:4). We do so be- significantly different from zero. Pre
cause it is widely believed that U.S. 1979:4 it is positive and significant. This
monetary policy took an important turn outcome is consistent with the conven-
for the better with the appointment of tional view that pre-1979, the Federal
Paul Volcker as Fed Chairman (see
80 The estimates of the parameters in equation
Friedman and Kuttner 1996 and Gertler
(7.2) are obtained by using an instrumental vari-
1996). Among other things, this period ables procedure based on Generalized Methods of
marks the beginning of an apparently Moments (GMM). See Clarida, Galí, and Gertler
successful and long-lasting disinflation. (forthcoming) for details. The specific numbers
reported here are based on a version of this policy
We find that the simple rule given by reaction function that has the Funds rate respond
equation (7.2) does a good job of char- to expected inflation a year ahead and the current
acterizing policy in the Volcker–Green- output gap (reported in Table 2 of that paper).
The results, however, are robust to reasonable
span era. Further, it adheres to the variations in the horizons for the gap variables.
guidelines for good policy that we have 81 In particular, the output gap enters the in-

established. The estimated pre-Volcker strument set for expected inflation. Thus, the
coefficent γx reflects the influence of the output
rule violates these guidelines. Specifi- gap on the interest rate that is independent of its
cally, the parameter estimates along predictive power for inflation.
1698 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXVII (December 1999)

Reserve was relatively more focused on of capturing the broad movements in


output stabilization and less focused on the Funds rate for the second half of
inflation. the sample, for which it was estimated.
The finding that the Fed responded For the pre-Volcker period, matters are
differently to inflation in the two eras is different. The target (generated by the
apparent from inspection of the data. estimated Volcker–Greenspan rule) is
Figure 4 plots the Federal Funds rate systematically well above the historical
and the rate of CPI inflation from 1965 series. In this concrete respect, policy
to the present. The graph shows a clear was far less aggressive in fighting
break in the Funds rate process around inflation in the earlier period. 83
1979. 82 During most of the 1970s, the Figure 6 compares the ability of the
ex post real rate was zero or negative. forward and backward looking (Taylor)
After 1979 it becomes positive. While target rules to explain the post 1979
many factors influence the real rate, the data. Though we find that the data re-
tight monetary policy engineered by jects the backward looking rule in favor
Paul Volcker surely provides the most of the forward looking one, 84 the two do
logical explanation for this initial run-up. a roughly similar job of accounting for
Figure 5 illustrates the policy change the behavior of the Funds rate. This oc-
by plotting the estimated target value of curs probably because, with U.S. data,
the interest rate under the Volcker–
Greenspan rule over the entire sample 83 Some but not nearly all the difference be-
period. The target rule does a good job tween rates pre-1979 and the target values under a
post-1979 rule could be accounted for by a secular
82 Huizinga and Mishkin (1986) present formal change in the real rate.
evidence of a structural break at this time. 84 See Clarida, Galí, and Gertler (1998).
Clarida, Galí, Gertler: The Science of Monetary Policy 1699

not much besides lagged inflation is Mishkin 1997 for a recent survey). In-
useful for predicting future inflation. deed a number of central banks, most
Finally, it is interesting to observe notably the Bank of England, have re-
that the other major central banks, the cently adopted formal inflation targets
Bundesbank and the Bank of Japan, (see, e.g., Andrew Haldane 1996).
have behaved very similarly in the post- In one sense, inflation targeting in-
1979 era. In Clarida, Galí, and Gertler volves nothing more than pursuing the
(1998), we estimate our specification kind of gradualist policy that our opti-
for these central banks. The estimated mal policy calculation implies (see Re-
parameters in each case are quite close sult 2). Indeed, all the leading real-
to those obtained for the Federal Re- world proposals call for gradual
serve during the Volcker–Greenspan convergence of inflation to target. None
period. Thus, good policy management recommend trying to hit the inflation
appears to have been a global phenome- target continuously, which is consistent
non. Perhaps this is not surprising since with our analysis. In this respect, the
the successful disinflation has also been rule we estimate for the period is per-
a world-wide event. fectly consistent with inflation targeting.
The rationale for inflation targeting,
7.2 Simple Target Rules
we think, is twofold. The first is simply
There have also been proposed sim- to guarantee that monetary policy
ple rules for targets, as opposed to in- avoids the mistakes of the pre-Volcker
struments. Of these proposed policies, era by identifying a clear nominal an-
inflation targeting has received by far chor for policy. (After all, Alan Green-
the most attention (see Bernanke and span will not be around forever). The
1700 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXVII (December 1999)

inflation target is in effect the nominal der an inflation targeting policy. For all
anchor. Since the anchor is directly in these reasons, it is perhaps not surpris-
terms of inflation, it avoids the poten- ing that no major central bank has
tially instability problems associated adopted a price level target.
with alternatives such as money growth Another candidate variable for target-
that are only indirectly linked to infla- ing is nominal GDP. This approach has
tion. For example, if there are large also received less attention in the re-
shocks to money demand, then a money cent literature, however. One problem
growth target may fail precisely to pin is that if there are shifts in the trend
down the equilibrium inflation rate. growth of real GDP, the rule does not
The second rationale has to do with provide a precise nominal anchor. An-
credibility and commitment. We have other problem, emphasized by Ball
seen that it is in general optimal for (1997), is that the policy may be overly
policy-makers to place a higher weight restrictive. In the hybrid model of sec-
on the costs of inflation than the true tion 5, for example, the optimal policy
social loss function suggests (see Re- in general has the interest rate adjust to
sults 6 and 7). The focus on inflation some linear combination of expected in-
targets may be viewed as a way to instill flation, the output gap and demand dis-
a higher effective weight on inflation in turbances. The weights depend upon
the policy choice. the underlying structural parameters of
Price level targeting is another type the model. Under nominal GDP target-
of simple rule that has been discussed ing, the central bank adjusts the inter-
in the literature. This policy, which may est rate to the sum of inflation and real
be thought of as a more extreme version GDP growth. It thus arbitrarily applies
of inflation targeting, has not received an equal weight to each component of
much support among policy-makers and nominal GDP. High nominal GDP
applied economists. There are several growth, further, could occur when the
problems: First, if the price level over- economy is recovering from a recession
shoots its target, the central bank may and is still well below full capacity. A
have to contract economic activity in or- rule that calls for raising interest rates
der to return the price level to its goal. in response to above-target nominal
That is, inflation above the amount im- GDP growth in these circumstances
plied by the price level target must be could stifle the recovery. 85
followed by inflation below this desired
7.3 Indeterminacy under Interest
amount in order to return the target.
Rate Rules
Under inflation targeting, bygones are
bygones: overshooting of inflation in One criticism of simple interest rate
one year does not require forcing infla- rules is that, under certain circum-
tion below target in the following year. stances, they may induce instability.
Second, the source of positive drift in That is, in many models there may not
the price level maybe measurement er- be a determinate equilibrium under
ror (see the discussion in section 2.) It particular parametrizations of the policy
would be unfortunate to have measure- 85 See Ball (1997) and Svensson (1997b) for ex-
ment error induce tightening of mone- plicit examples of how nominal GDP targeting
tary policy. Third, as McCallum (1997b) could produce adverse outcomes. McCallum
shows, the net reduction in price uncer- (1997c), however, argues that these results are
sensitive to the use of a backward-looking Phillips
tainty under a price level target rule, curve. For the case in favor of nominal GDP tar-
may be small relative that obtained un- geting, see Hall and Mankiw (1994).
Clarida, Galí, Gertler: The Science of Monetary Policy 1701

rule. In a classic paper, Thomas Sargent terminacy are possible. First, if in re-
and Neil Wallace (1975), illustrated sponse to a rise in expected inflation,
how nominal indeterminacy may arise if the nominal rate does not increase suf-
prices are perfectly flexible. Under an ficiently to raise the real rate, then self-
interest rate rule the equilibrium pins fulfilling bursts of inflation and output
down the level of real money balances. are possible. A rise in expected infla-
However, there are an infinite number tion, leads to a fall in real rates that, in
of combinations of the nominal money turn, fuels the boom. Indeed, the mone-
stock and the price level that satisfy this tary policy rule that Clarida, Galí, and
equilibrium condition. 86 In this respect, Gertler (forthcoming) estimate for the
the interest rate rule produces nominal pre-Volcker period permits exactly this
indeterminacy. 87 kind of sunspot behavior. The lesson
When there is sluggish price adjust- here is simply that a good monetary pol-
ment, the problem of nominal indeter- icy rule should not accommodate rise in
minacy vanishes. Last period’s price expected inflation. It should instead
level effectively serves a nominal an- pursue the implicit kind of inflation
chor. Simple interest rate rules thus do targeting that we have been emphasiz-
not produce price level indeterminacy ing. This boils down to raising nominal
in the frameworks we have analyzed. rates sufficiently to increase real rates
More generally, since there is little rea- whenever expected inflation goes up.
son to believe that prices are perfectly As Bernanke and Woodford (1998)
flexible, the issue of nominal indetermi- emphasize, indeterminacy is also possi-
nacy does not seem important in prac- ble if the rule calls for an overly aggres-
tice. On the other hand, there is poten- sive response of interest rates to move-
tially a problem of real indeterminacy ments in expected inflation. In this
in the case of price stickiness, as Wil- instance, there is a “policy overkill” ef-
liam Kerr and Robert King (1996), Ber- fect that emerges that may result in an
nanke and Woodford (1997) and Clarida, oscillating equilibrium. Clarida, Galí
Galí and Gertler (forthcoming) have re- and Gertler (forthcoming) show, how-
cently emphasized. 88 Two types of inde- ever, the magnitude of the policy re-
sponse required to generate indetermi-
86 McCallum (1997), however, argues that the nacy of this type greatly exceeds the
price level is in fact determined in this kind of estimates obtained in practice. This po-
environment. tential indeterminacy however does
87 A recent literature shows that the govern-
ment’s intertemporal budget constraint may re- suggest another reason why a gradual
store uniqueness under an interest rule, even in approach to meeting an inflation target
an environment with flexible prices. What is criti- may be desirable.
cal is whether the interest on the debt is financed
by taxes or money creation. See, for example,
Woodford (1994), Sims (1994), and Leeper (1991). 8. Concluding Remarks
88 These papers focus on local indeterminacy.
See Jess Benhabib, Stephanie Schmidt-Grohe, and
Martin Uribe (1998) for a discussion of global in- We conclude by describing several
determinacy. To avoid global indeterminacy, the areas where future research would be
central bank may have to commit to deviate from a quite useful:
simple interest rate rule if the economy were to
get sufficiently off track. This threat to deviate can (1) It is always the case that more
be stabilizing, much the way off the equilibrium knowledge of the way the macro-
path threats induce uniqueness in game theory. economy works can improve the perfor-
Because the threat is sufficient to preclude inde-
terminate behavior, further, it may never have to mance of monetary policy. Particularly
be implemented in practice. critical, however, is a better understanding
1702 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXVII (December 1999)

of the determinants of inflation. As we point where this constraint clearly is a


have emphasized, the output/inflation consideration for policy management.
trade-off is highly sensitive to both the Similarly, in the U.S. and Europe, the
degree and nature of the persistence in inflation rates have fallen to the point
inflation. As a consequence, so too is where the zero bound limit could con-
the speed at which monetary policy ceivably affect the ability to ease rates
should try to reach the optimal inflation in the event of a downturn. Under-
rate. Rationalizing the observed persis- standing how monetary policy should
tence in inflation is thus a high priority. proceed in this kind of environment is
Work by Galí and Gertler (forthcoming) an important task. When the nominal
and Argia Sbordone (1998) suggests that rate is at zero, the only way a central
the short-run aggregate supply curve bank can reduce the real interest rate is
employed in our baseline model may to generate a rise in expected inflation
provide a reasonable approximation of (see the discussion in Alexander Wol-
reality, so long as real marginal cost man 1998, and the references therein).
(specifically real unit labor costs) is used How the central bank should go about
as the relevant real sector forcing vari- this and whether cooperation from fis-
able instead of the output gap, as the cal policy is necessary are important
theory suggests. Galí and Gertler (forth- open questions. As Wolman (1998) sug-
coming) argue further that persistence gests, the conclusions are quite sensi-
in inflation may be related to sluggish tive to the nature of the inflationary
adjustment of unit labor costs vis-a-vis process.
movements in output. Sorting out this (4) A more specific issue, but none-
issue will have important repercussions theless an important one, is to under-
for monetary policy. stand why central banks smooth interest
(2) Our analysis of monetary policy, rate adjustments. As we discussed in
as in much of the literature, was re- section 5, optimal policies implied by
stricted to closed economy models. Ex- most existing macroeconomic frame-
tensions to open economy frameworks works generate paths for the interest
are likely to provide new insights on the rate that are much more volatile than
desirability of alternative monetary pol- what is observed in reality. The possi-
icy rules, and raise a number of issues bility thus arises that existing models
of great interest, including: the choice may fail to adequately characterize the
of exchange rate regime, the potential constraints that policy-makers face in
benefits from monetary policy coordi- practice. We suggested in section 5 that
nation, the optimal response to shocks some form of model uncertainty might
originating abroad, and consumer price be able to account for this phenome-
index versus domestic inflation target- non. Another alternative is that central
ing. Recent work by Ball (1998), Svens- banks may be exploiting the depen-
son (1998), and Monacelli (1999) along dency of demand on expected future in-
these lines will undoubtedly lay the terest rates, as argued by Rotemberg
ground for further research on this front. and Woodford (1999). Whether these
(3) Throughout the analysis, we as- explanations or any others, such as fear
sumed that the lower bound of zero on of disruption of financial markets, can
the nominal interest rate was not a con- account for interest rate smoothing
straint on the performance of monetary needs to be determined.
policy. In Japan, for example, the short- (5) A somewhat related issue involves
term nominal rate has fallen to the how a central bank should deal with
Clarida, Galí, Gertler: The Science of Monetary Policy 1703

financial stability. The policy rules Appendix: The General Solution


discussed in the literature do include under Commitment
contingencies for financial crises. A fre- At time t, the central bank commits to a state
quently cited reason for why monetary contingent sequence for xt + i and πt + i to maximize
policy should not adhere tightly to a 1 ∞ i
 

2 ti∑
simple rule is the need for flexibility in max − E  β [α x2t + i + π2t + i]
=o 
the event of a financial collapse. In the  
subject to the short-run aggregate supply curve
wake of the October 1987 stock market
crash, for example, most economists πt + i = λ xt + i + β E t{πt + 1 + i} + u t + i
supported the decision of the Federal
Reserve Board to reduce interest rates. with
This support was based largely on in- u t + i = ρu t + i − 1 + εt + i
stinct, however, since there is virtually
no formal theoretical work that rational- Following Currie and Levine (1993) and Wood-
izes this kind of intervention. More ford (1998), form the Lagrangian:

generally, concern about financial sta- 1 ∞ i
2 ti∑
max − E  β {[αx2t + i + π2t + i]
bility appears to be an important con- =o

straint on policy-making. As we sug-  
 
gested in section 5, it is one possible  + φt + i[πt + i − λxt + i − βπt + 1 + i − u t + i]}
 
reason why central banks smooth inter-  
1
est rate changes. Understanding the na- where φ is the multiplier associated with the
2 t+i
ture of this concern is clearly a fertile constraint at t + i.
area for research. The first order necessary conditions yield:
(6) Finally, with few exceptions, vir- λ
α xt + i − φ = 0, ∀i ≥ 0
tually all the literature ignores the issue 2 t+i
of transition to a new policy regime. 89 1 1
In particular, the rational expectations πt + i + φ − φ = 0, ∀i ≥ 1
2 t+i 2 t+i−1
assumption is typically employed. Policy 1
πt + φt = 0
simulations thus implicitly presume that 2
the private sector catches on immedi- Combining the first order necessary conditions to
ately to any regime change. In reality, eliminate φt + i then yields the optimality condi-
tions
however, there may be a period of tran-
sition where the private sector learns λ
xt + i − xt + i − 1 = − π t + i, ∀i ≥ 1
about the regime change. This kind of α
λ
scenario may be highly relevant to a xt = − πt
α
central bank that has accommodated in- Substituting the optimality conditions in the ag-
flation for a sustained period of time gregate supply curve to eliminate πt + i then yields
but is intent on embarking on a disinfla- a stochastic difference equation for xt:
tion. Modeling private sector learning λa
xt = a xt − 1 + aβ E t{xt + 1 } − ut
is a challenging but nonetheless impor- α
tant task. Sargent (1999) provides a α
where a ≡ . The stationary solution to
promising start in this direction. More α(1 + β) + λ2
this difference equation is given by:
work along these lines would be highly
λδ
desirable. xt = δ xt − 1 − ut (8.1)
α(1 − δβρ)
89 An exception is Brayton, Levin, Tyron, and 1−√
  2
1 − 4βa
Williams (1997) who present simulations of policy where δ ≡ ∈(0,1), implying the pro-
2aβ
regime changes under different assumptions about cess for xt is stable. Substituting the solution for xt
the behavior of private sector expectations.
1704 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXVII (December 1999)
in the aggregate supply curve then yields a solu- Bernanke, Ben S. and Frederic Mishkin. 1997.
tion for πt. “Inflation Targeting: A New Framework for
Monetary Policy?” J. Econ. Perspect., 11:2, pp.
δ 97–116.
πt = δ πt − 1 + (u t − u t − 1 )
(1 − δβρ) Bernanke, Ben S. and Michael Woodford. 1997.
“Inflation Forecasts and Monetary Policy,” J.
Since πt = p t − p t − 1, the solution implies a station- Money, Credit, Banking, 29:4, pp. 653–84.
ary process for the price level: Blanchard, Olivier J. 1997. Macroeconomics. Up-
δ per Saddle River, NJ: Prentice-Hall.
pt = δ pt − 1 + ut Blinder, Alan S. 1997. “What Central Bankers Can
(1 − δβρ)
Learn from Academics—and Vice-Versa,” J.
The stationary behavior of the price level results Econ. Perspect., 11:2, pp. 3–19.
from the fact that the optimality condition effec- Bomfin, Antulio N. and Glenn D. Rudebusch.
tively has the central bank adjust demand in re- 1997. “Opportunistic and Deliberate Disinfla-
sponse to movements in the price level relative to tion Under Imperfect Credibility,” mimeo, Fed.
trend. Given πt = p t − p t − 1, the optimality condi- Res. Bank San Francisco.
tion may be expressed as Brainard, William C. 1967. “Uncertainty and the
Effectiveness of Policy,” Amer. Econ. Rev., 57,
λ pp. 411–25.
xt + i = − pt + i ∀i ≥ 1
α Brayton, Flint; Andrew Levin, Ralph Tryon, and
Thus, for example, the central bank contracts demand John C. Williams. 1997. “The Evolution of
when the price level rises above trend: hence, the Macro Models at the Federal Reserve Board,”
trend-reverting behavior of the price level. Finance Econ. Discuss. Paper Series, 1997–29,
Fed. Res. Board.
REFERENCES Calvo, Guillermo. 1983. “Staggered Prices in a
Utility Maximizing Framework,” J. Monet.
Aiyagari, Rao S. and R. Anton Braun. 1998. “Some Econ., 12:3, pp. 383–98.
Models to Guide the Fed,” Carnegie-Rochester Campbell, John Y. 1995. “Some Lessons from the
Conf. Ser. Public Policy, 48, pp. 1–42. Yield Curve,” J. Econ. Perspect., 9:3, pp. 129–
Ball, Laurence. 1995. “Disinflation with Imperfect 52.
Credibility,” J. Monet. Econ., 35:1, pp. 5–23. Carlstrom, Charles T. and Timothy S. Fuerst.
——— . 1997. “Efficient Rules for Monetary Pol- 1995. “Interest Rate Rules vs. Money Supply
icy,” 1997. NBER Working Paper 5952. Rules: A Welfare Comparison in a Cash-in-Ad-
——— . 1998. “Policy Rules for Open Economies,” vance Model,” J. Monet. Econ., 36:2, pp. 247–
NBER Working Paper 6760. 68.
Barro, Robert J. and David B. Gordon. 1983. “A Chari, V.V.; Lawrence J. Christiano, and Martin
Positive Theory of Monetary Policy in a Natural Eichenbaum, 1998. “Expectation Traps and
Rate Model,” J. Polit. Econ., 91:4, pp. 589–610. Discretion,” J. Econ. Theory, 81:2, pp. 462–92.
Benhabib, Jess; Stephanie Schmitt-Grohe, and Christiano, Lawrence J. and Christopher J. Gust.
Martin Uribe. 1998. “The Perils of Taylor 1999. “Taylor Rules in a Limited Participation
Rules,” mimeo, New York U. Model,” NBER Working Paper 7017.
Bernanke, Ben S. and Alan Blinder. 1992. “The Christiano, Lawrence J.; Martin Eichenbaum, and
Federal Funds Rate and the Channels of Mone- Charles Evans. 1996. “The Effects of Monetary
tary Transmission,” Amer. Econ. Rev., 82:4, pp. Policy Shocks: Evidence from the Flow of
901–21. Funds,” Rev. Econ. Statist., 78:1, pp. 16–34.
Bernanke, Ben. S. and Mark Gertler. 1995. “In- ——— . 1997. “Sticky Price and Limited Participa-
side the Black Box: The Credit Channel of tion Models of Money: A Comparison,” Europ.
Monetary Policy Transmission,” J. Econ. Per- Econ. Rev., 41:6, pp. 1201–49.
spect., 9:2, pp. 27–48. ——— . 1998. “Monetary Policy Shocks: What
Bernanke, Ben. S.; Mark Gertler, and Simon Gil- Have We Learned and To What End?” NBER
christ. 1998. “The Financial Accelerator in a Working Paper 6400.
Quantitative Business Cycle Framework,” Clarida, Richard and Mark Gertler. 1997. “How
NBER Working Paper 6455. Forthcoming in the Bundesbank Conducts Monetary Policy,” in
The Handbook of Macroeconomics. John Taylor Reducing Inflation: Motivation and Strategy.
and Michael Woodford, eds. Christina Romer and David Romer, eds. Chi-
Bernanke, Ben S.; Mark Gertler, and Mark Wat- cago: NBER, pp. 363–412.
son. 1997. “Systematic Monetary Policy and the Clarida, Richard; Jordi Galí, and Mark Gertler.
Effects of Oil Price Shocks,” Brookings Pap. Forthcoming. “Monetary Policy Rules and Mac-
Econ. Act., 0:1, pp. 91–142. roeconomic Stability: Evidence and Some The-
Bernanke, Ben S. and Ilian Mihov. 1997. “What ory,” Quart. J. Econ.
Does the Bundesbank Target?” Europ. Econ. ——— . 1998. “Monetary Policy Rules in Practice:
Rev., 41:6, pp. 1025–53. Some International Evidence,” Europ. Econ.
——— . 1998. “Measuring Monetary Policy,” Rev., 42:6, pp. 1033–67.
Quart. J. Econ., 113:3, pp. 869–902. Currie, David and Paul Levine. 1993. Rules, Repu-
Clarida, Galí, Gertler: The Science of Monetary Policy 1705
tation and Macroeconomic Policy Coordination. ——— . 1999. “Rules vs. Discretion Revisited: The
Cambridge: Cambridge U. Press. Gains from Commitment in the Absence of an
DeLong, J. Bradford. 1997. “America’s Peacetime Inflationary Bias,” work in progress.
Inflation: The 1970s,” in Reducing Inflation: Gertler, Mark. 1996. “Comments on Friedman
Motivation and Strategy. C. Romer and D. and Kuttner,” Brookings Pap. Econ. Act., 1, pp.
Romer, eds. Chicago: NBER, pp. 247–80. 77–125.
Erceg, Christopher J.; Dale W. Henderson, and Goodfriend, Marvin. 1991. “Interest Rates and the
Andrew T. Levin. 1998. “Output-Gap and Price Conduct of Monetary Policy,” Carnegie-Roches-
Volatilities: Reaffirming Tradeoffs in an Opti- ter Conf. Ser. Public Policy, 34, pp. 7–37.
mizing Model,” mimeo, Fed. Res. Board. Goodfriend, Marvin and Robert G. King. 1997.
Estrella, Arturo and Frederic S. Mishkin. 1997. “Is “The New Neoclassical Synthesis and the Role
There a Role for Monetary Aggregates in the of Monetary Policy,” in NBER Macroeconomics
Conduct of Monetary Policy?” J. Monet. Econ., Annual. Ben Bernanke and Julio Rotemberg,
40:2, pp. 279–304. eds.
——— . 1999. “Re-Thinking the Role of NAIRU in Gordon, Robert J. 1997. “The Time-Varying
Monetary Policy: Implications of Model Formu- NAIRU and Its Implications for Economic Pol-
lation and Uncertainty,” forthcoming in Mone- icy,” J. Econ. Perspect., 11, Winter, pp. 11–32.
tary Policy Rules. John B. Taylor, ed. Haldane, Andrew. 1995. Inflation Targeting. Bank
Faust, John and Lars E. O. Svensson. 1998. of England.
“Credibility and Transparency: Monetary Policy Hall, Robert E. 1997. “Comments on Shiller,”
with Unobservable Goals,” mimeo, Fed. Res. Brookings Pap. Econ. Act., pp. 219–23.
Board. Hall, Robert E. and N. Gregory Mankiw. 1994.
Feldstein, Martin S. 1997. “The Costs and Bene- “Nominal Income Targeting,” in Monetary Pol-
fits of Going from Low Inflation to Price Stabil- icy. N. G. Mankiw, ed. Chicago: U. Chicago
ity,” in Reducing Inflation: Motivation and Press.
Strategy. C. Romer and D. Romer, eds. Chi- Henderson, Dale W. and Warren J. Mckibbon.
cago: NBER, pp. 123–66. 1993. “A Comparison of Some Basic Monetary
Feldstein, Martin and James H. Stock. 1996. “Meas- Policy Regimes for Open Economies,”
uring Money Growth when Financial Markets Carnegie-Rochester Conf. Ser. Public Policy,
Are Changing,” J. Monet. Econ., 37:1, pp. 3–27. 39, pp. 221–317.
Fischer, Stanley. 1995. “Modern Approaches to Huizinga, John and Frederic S. Mishkin. 1986.
Central Banking. NBER Working Paper 5064. “Monetary Policy Regime Shifts and the Un-
Friedman, Benjamin M. 1990. “Targets and In- usual Behavior of Real Interest Rates,”
struments of Monetary Policy,” in Handbook of Carnegie-Rochester Conf. Ser. Public Policy,
Monetary Economics. Friedman and Frank 24, pp. 231–74.
Hahn, eds. Amsterdam: North-Holland. Ireland, Peter N. 1996a. “The Role of Countercy-
Friedman, Benjamin M. and Kenneth N. Kuttner. clical Monetary Policy,” J. Polit. Econ., 104:4,
1996. “A Price Target for U.S. Monetary Policy? pp. 704–23.
Lessons from the Experience with Money ——— . 1996b. “Expectations, Credibility, and
Growth Targets,” Brookings Pap. Econ. Act., 1, Time-Consistent Monetary Policy,” mimeo,
pp. 77–146. Rutgers U.
Fuhrer, Jeffrey C. 1996. “Towards a Compact, Jovanovic, Boyan and Masako Udea. 1997. “Con-
Empirically Verified Rational Expectations tracts and Money,” J. Polit. Econ., 105, Aug.,
Model for Monetary Policy Analysis,” mimeo, pp. 700–708.
Federal Reserve Bank of Boston. Kerr, William and Robert G. King. 1996. “Limits
——— . 1997a. “Inflation/Output Variance Trade- on Interest Rate Rules in the IS Model,” Econ.
offs and Optimal Monetary Policy,” J. Money, Quart., LXXXII, pp. 47–76.
Credit, Banking, 29:2, pp. 214–23. King, Robert G. and Alexander L. Wolman. 1996.
——— . 1997b. “The (Un)Importance of Forward “Inflation Targeting in a St. Louis Model of the
Looking Behavior in Price Setting,” J. Money, 21st Century,” NBER Working Paper 5507.
Credit, Banking, 29, Aug., pp. 338–50. ——— . 1998. “What Should the Monetary Author-
Fuhrer, Jeffrey C., and George R. Moore. 1995a. ity Do When Prices Are Sticky?” Forthcoming
“Inflation Persistence,” Quart. J. Econ., 440, in Monetary Policy Rules. John B. Taylor, ed.
Feb., pp. 127–59. Kydland, Finn E. and Edward C. Prescott. 1977.
——— . 1995b. “ Monetary Policy Trade-offs and “Rules Rather Than Discretion: The Inconsis-
the Correlation between Nominal Interest tency of Optimal Plans,” J. Polit. Econ., 85, pp.
Rates and Real Output,” Amer. Econ. Rev., 473–91.
85:1, pp. 219–39. Leeper, Eric M. 1991. “Equilibria Under ‘Active’
Galí, Jordi, 1992. “How Well Does the IS/LM and ‘Passive’ Monetary and Fiscal Policies,” J.
Model Fit Post-War U.S. Data?” Quart. J. Monet. Econ., 27. pp. 129–47.
Econ., 92, pp. 709–38. Leeper, Eric M.; Christopher Sims, and Tao Zha.
Galí, Jordi and Mark Gertler. Forthcoming. “In- 1996. “What Does Monetary Policy Do?”
flation Dynamics: A Structural Econometric Brookings Pap. Econ. Act., 2, pp. 1–63.
Analysis,” J. Monet. Econ. Lown, Cara S. and Robert Rich. 1997. “Is There
1706 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXVII (December 1999)
an Inflation Puzzle?” Fed. Res. Bank New York Rotemberg, Julio and Michael Woodford. 1997.
Econ. Policy Rev., 3:4, pp. 51–69. “An Optimization-Based Econometric Frame-
McCallum, Bennett T. 1988. “Robustness Proper- work for the Evaluation of Monetary Policy,”
ties of a Rule for Monetary Policy,” Carnegie- NBER Macroeconomics Annual. Ben Bernanke
Rochester Conf. Ser. Public Policy, 29, pp. 173– and J. Rotemberg, eds.
204. ——— . 1999. “Interest Rate Rules in an Esti-
——— . 1997a. “Crucial Issues Concerning Cen- mated Sticky Price Model,” in Monetary Policy
tral Bank Independence,” J. Monet. Econ., 39, Rules. John B. Taylor, ed. Forthcoming.
June, pp. 99–112. Rudebusch, Glenn D. 1995. “Federal Reserve In-
——— . 1997b. “Issues in the Design of Monetary terest Rate Targeting, Rational Expectations
Policy Rules,” NBER Working Paper 6016. and the Term Structure,” J. Monet. Econ. 35:
Forthcoming in The Handbook of Macro- pp. 245–74.
economics. Rudebusch, Glenn D. and Lars Svensson. 1998
——— . 1997c. “The Alleged Instability of Nomi- forthcoming. “Policy Rules for Inflation Tar-
nal Income Targeting,” NBER Working Paper geting,” in Monetary Policy Rules. John Taylor,
6291. ed.
McCallum, Bennett T. and Edward Nelson. 1997. Sack, Brian. 1997a. “Uncertainty and Gradual
“An Optimizing IS-LM Specification for Mone- Monetary Policy,” mimeo, Fed. Res. Board.
tary Policy and Business Cycle Analysis,” NBER ——— . 1997b. “Does the Fed Act Gradually? A
Working Paper 5875. VAR Analysis,” mimeo, Fed. Res. Board, May.
Monacelli, Tommaso. 1999. “Into the Mussa Puz- Sargent, Thomas J. 1998. “The Conquest of
zle: Monetary Policy Regimes and the Real Ex- American Inflation,” mimeo, Econ. Dept., Stan-
change Rate in a Small Open Economy,” ford U.
mimeo, Boston College. ——— . 1999. “Comment on Ball,” forthcoming in
Onatski Alexei, and James H. Stock. 1999. “Robust Monetary Policy Rules. John B. Taylor, ed.
Monetary Policy Under Model Uncertainty in a Sargent, Thomas J. and Neil Wallace. 1975. “Ra-
Small Model of the U.S. Economy,” mimeo, tional Expectations, the Optimal Monetary In-
Harvard U. strument and the Optimal Money Supply Rule,”
Orphanides, Athanasios. 1998. “Monetary Policy J. Polit. Econ., 83, pp. 241–54.
Evaluation with Noisy Information,” mimeo, Sbordone, Argia. 1998. “Prices and Unit Labor
Fed. Res. Board. Costs: A New Test of Sticky Prices,” mimeo,
Orphanides, Athanasios and David Wilcox. 1996. Rutgers U.
“The Opportunistic Approach to Disinflation,” Shiller, Robert J. 1997. “Public Resistance to In-
Finance Econ. Discuss. Paper Series, 96–24, dexation: A Puzzle,” Brookings Pap. Econ. Act.,
Fed. Res. Board. pp. 159–212.
Orphanides, Athanasios; David H. Small, Volker Sims, Christopher. 1994. “A Simple Model for the
Weiland, and David W. Wilcox. 1997. “A Quan- Determination of the Price Level and the Inter-
titative Exploration of the Opportunistic Ap- action of Monetary and Fiscal Policy,” Econ.
proach to Disinflation,” Finance Econ. Discuss. Theory, 4, pp. 381–99.
Paper Series, 36, Fed. Res. Board, Washington Svensson, Lars E. O. 1997a. “Inflation Forecast
D.C. Targeting: Implementing and Monitoring Infla-
Persson, Torsten and Guido Tabellini. 1997. “Po- tion Targets,” Europ. Econ. Rev., 41, June, pp.
litical Economics and Macroeconomic Policy,” 1111–47.
mimeo, Inst. for International Economics, ——— . 1997b. “Inflation Targeting: Some Exten-
Stockholm. sions,” NBER Working Paper 5962, March,
Poole, William. 1970. “Optimal Choice of Mone- forthcoming in Scand. J. Econ.
tary Policy Instruments in a Simple Stochastic ——— . 1997c. “Optimal Inflation Targets, Con-
Macro Model,” Quart. J. Econ., 84, pp. 197– servative Central Banks, and Linear Inflation
216. Contracts,” Amer. Econ. Rev.
Roberts, John M. 1997. “Is Inflation Sticky?” J. ——— . 1998. “Inflation Targeting as a Monetary
Monet. Econ., 39, pp. 173–96. Policy Rule,” NBER Working Paper 6790,
Rogoff, Kenneth. 1985. “The Optimal Degree of forthcoming in J. Monet. Econ.
Commitment to an Intermediate Monetary Tar- ——— . 1998. “Open-Economy Inflation Target-
get,” Quart. J. Econ., 100:4, pp. 1169–89. ing,” mimeo, forthcoming in J. Int. Econ.
——— . 1987. “Reputational Constraints on Mone- Svensson, Lars E.O. and Leonardo Leiderman.
tary Policy,” Carnegie-Rochester Conf. Ser. 1995. Inflation Targets. London: CEPR.
Public Policy, 26, 141–81. Taylor, John B. 1979. “Estimation and Control of
Romer, Christina D. and David H. Romer. 1989. Macroeconomic Model with Rational Expecta-
“Does Monetary Policy Matter? A New Test in tions,” Econometrica, 47, Sept., pp. 1267–86.
the Spirit of Friedman and Schwartz,” NBER ——— . 1993a. “Discretion versus Policy Rules in
Macroeconomics Annual. Practice,” Carnegie-Rochester Conf. Ser. Public
Rotemberg, Julio. 1996. “Prices, Hours and Out- Policy, 39, pp. 195–214.
put: An Empirical Analysis Based on a Sticky ——— . 1993b. Macroeconomic Policy in a World
Price Model,” J. Monet. Econ., 37, pp. 505–34. Economy. NY: W.W. Norton.
Clarida, Galí, Gertler: The Science of Monetary Policy 1707
——— , ed. 1999a. Monetary Policy Rules. Chi- and the Zero Lower Bound on the Nominal In-
cago: U. Chicago Press. Forthcoming. terest Rate,” mimeo, Fed. Res. Bank Richmond.
——— . 1998b. “An Historical Analysis of Mone- Woodford, Michael. 1994a. “Nonstandard Indica-
tary Policy Rules,” in Monetary Policy Rules. tors for Monetary Policy,” in Monetary Policy.
John B. Taylor, ed. Forthcoming N. Gregory Mankiw ed. Chicago: U. Chicago
Theil, Henri. 1961. Economic Forecasts and Pol- Press, pp. 95–115.
icy, 2nd ed. Amsterdam: North-Holland. ——— . 1994b. “Monetary Policy and Price Level
Tinbergen, Jan. 1952. On the Theory of Economic Determinacy in a Cash-in-Advance Economy,”
Policy, 2nd ed. Amsterdam: North-Holland. Econ. Theory, 4, pp. 345–80.
Walsh. Carl. 1998. Monetary Theory and Policy. ——— . 1996. “Control of the Public Debt: A Re-
MIT Press. quirement for Price Stability?” NBER Working
Wieland, Volker. 1997. “Monetary Policy and Un- Paper 5684.
certainty about the Natural Unemployment ——— . 1998. “Optimal Monetary Policy Inertia,”
Rate,” mimeo, Fed. Res. Board. mimeo, Princeton U.
Williams, John C. 1997. “Simple Rules for Mone- Yun, Tack. 1996. “Nominal Price Rigidity, Money
tary Policy,” mimeo, Fed. Res. Board. Supply Endogeneity, and Business Cycles,” J.
Wolman, Alexander. 1998. “Staggered Price Setting Monet. Econ., 37, pp. 345–70.

You might also like