You are on page 1of 74

Introduction to

Binomial Trees
Chapter 12

Prof. Joseph K. W. Fung


FIN B488F Fall 2022
12.1
A brief history of financial theory
development
 Markowitz: mean-variance analysis for securities
portfolio 1950’s; ranking more than pricing (valid for
both risk-averse & risk-neutral investors GM)
 Sharpe: CAPM late 1960’s, valuation of risky asset
via a model for the required rate of return. V =
E(CF) / 1+RRR; CAPM=>RRR (RRR is proportional
to beta/market risk); assumes risk-averse investors
(separation theorem)
 Black-Scholes-Merton: option pricing model, 1973
(timely, CBOE Chicago board option exchange). V’ =
Ep (CF) / 1+Rf; applicable to all investors (via pure
arbitrage)
Prof. Joseph K. W. Fung 12.2
FIN B488F Fall 2022
A comparison between Sharpe’s
and BSM valuation frameworks
 Markowitz (risk-neutral & risk-averse): mean-variance criteria
provide ranking for assets
 Sharpe (requires risk-aversion):

V = E(CF) / 1+RRR; E(CFs) are based on the subjective and/or


objective belief of the future cashflows; as the CFs are risky or
uncertain, the discount rate RRR reflects the level of risk; E(.)
is based on true or natural probability
Black-Scholes-Merton (independent of risk preference):
V’ = Ep (CF) / 1+Rf; the discount rate is the risk-free rate of
interest (that is common for all asset); Ep(.) is an artificial
probability called risk-neutral probability measure. In
mathematical literature, the pricing model is called martingale
pricing model; Ep(.) is called a equivalent martingale

Prof. Joseph K. W. Fung 12.3


FIN B488F Fall 2022
What is the price of a European
call option?
 A stock price is currently $20 (S)
 A 3-month (OTM) call option on the stock has a strike price of $21 (X)
 The 3-month risk-free interest rate is 12% per annum (r).
 We know the price of the call is between its upper and lower bounds; i.e.,

(lower bound) Max[20-21e – 0.120.25 ,0] < C(X=21,S=20) < 20 = S (upper bound)
 0 < C < 20
 Boundary values are highly robust: but the band is wide. Need more information to fix the call price!

Prof. Joseph K. W. Fung 12.4


FIN B488F Fall 2022
A Simple Binomial Model
 A stock price is currently $20
 In three months it will be either $22 or $18

 Su = Su = $22, u = 1.1 (up-jump factor)

 Sd = Sd = $18, d = 0.9 (down-jump factor)


Up state stock
Price: Su = $22
Stock price: S = $20
Down state stock
Price: Sd = $18

Prof. Joseph K. W. Fung 12.5


FIN B488F Fall 2022
A Call Option (Figure 12.1, page 268)

A 3-month call option on the stock has a strike price of $21

Su = $22
Option payoff/value = $1
S = $20
Option Price=?
Sd = $18
Option payoff/value = $0

Prof. Joseph K. W. Fung 12.6


FIN B488F Fall 2022
Setting Up a Risk-free Portfolio
 Consider the Portfolio (sell 1 call and hedge it with a fraction of a
share; sort of buy-write / covered call):
 long  shares ( 0 <
 short 1 call option $22 – $1

$18

 Portfolio is “risk-free” when $22– $1 = $18 or  = 0.25


 Risk-free means that the values of the portfolio in both states (up state or down state) are equal
44 = 0.25
  exist and unique

Prof. Joseph K. W. Fung 12.7


FIN B488F Fall 2022
Valuing the Portfolio
(Risk-Free Rate is 12%)
 The risk-free portfolio is:
 Long 0.25 shares
 Short 1 call option
 The value of the portfolio in 3 months is
Upstate portfolio value = $22 0.25 – $1 = $4.50
 Down state value = $18 (0.25) = $4.50
 The present value (as discounted by the risk-free rate of
interest) of the portfolio today is $4.5e –
0.120.25
= $4.367
Prof. Joseph K. W. Fung 12.8
FIN B488F Fall 2022
Valuing the Option (no-arbitrage)
 The portfolio that long 0.25 shares and short
1 option is worth $4.367 today
 S – 1C = $4.367
 S = $20, S = $5 (0.25 x $20 )
 C* = S–$4.367 = $5 – $4.367 = $0.633
 “Fair” value of the option is $0.633
 C* is positively related to S and 
Prof. Joseph K. W. Fung 12.9
FIN B488F Fall 2022
Arbitrage with an Overpriced Call (c > c* no-
arbitrage value)
If c = $0.8 > c* = $0.633 (c is overpriced relative to S)
Call is high & stock is low since the fair value of the call is determined by the
price of the stock. Strategy: Short 1 Call and Buy 0.25 Shares (this creates a
sure future payoff of $4.50)

CFT
Transactions CF0 ST > X ST < X
(ST = $22) (ST = $18)
Borrow (PV $4.5) $4.367 at 12%
+$4.367 – $4.5 – $4.5
for 3m
Short 1 Call (X = $21) +$0.8 – $1 $0
Buy 0.25 Shares of Stock – $5 +$5.5 +$4.5
+$0.167 $0 $0
Prof. Joseph K. W. Fung 12.10
FIN B488F Fall 2022
Arbitrage with an Underpriced Call (c < c*)
If c = $0.5 < c* = $0.633
Call is low & stock is high. Strategy: Buy 1 Call and Short 0.25 Shares (this creates
a future liability of $4.50)

CFT
Transactions CF0 ST > X ST < X
(ST = $22) (ST = $18)

Short 0.25 Shares of Stock +$5 – $5.5 – $4.5


Long 1 Call (X = $21) – $0.5 +$1 $0
Lend $4.367 at 12% for 3m – $4.367 +$4.5 +$4.5
+$0.133 $0 $0
Prof. Joseph K. W. Fung 12.11
FIN B488F Fall 2022
What is a call under the model?
 Short 1 Call + 0.25 Stock create a sure cash
flow of $4.50 after 3-month
 - C + 0.25 S = PV($4.50) = bond (par=4.5)
 C = 0.25 S – Bond; delta dynamic trading
 Margin purchase again! (a “futures”?)
 Hence, the call is a leveraged stock position in
the one-period case; S = 4C + 4 Bond
 Note that under put-call-parity, a call is
composed of a bond, a put, and stock
Prof. Joseph K. W. Fung 12.12
FIN B488F Fall 2022
Generalization (Figure 12.2, page 269)

A derivative ( f ) lasts for time T and is


dependent on a stock (or any underlying
asset) S

Su
ƒu
S
ƒ Sd
ƒd

Prof. Joseph K. W. Fung 12.13


FIN B488F Fall 2022
Generalization (continued)
 Consider the portfolio that is (“long” if f is a call or “short” if f is
a put)  S and short 1 derivative

Su– ƒu

Sd– ƒd

 The portfolio is risk-free when Su– ƒu = Sd– ƒd or

ƒu  f d

Su  Sd
Prof. Joseph K. W. Fung 12.14
FIN B488F Fall 2022
Generalization (continued)
 Value of the portfolio at time T is (a sure thing) Su–
ƒu = Sd– ƒd

 Since the portfolio is risk-free, value of the portfolio today is


(Su – ƒu )e–rT

 The value of the portfolio today is S– f = (Su –


ƒu )e–rT

 Hence, ƒ = S– (Su– ƒu )e–rT

 1st term RHS is the hedge with S, 2nd term is a fixed income
position (leverage stock position if f is a call option)

Prof. Joseph K. W. Fung 12.15


FIN B488F Fall 2022
What is finance?
 We sell hopes (call option that will end up out of
the money )
 We profit from people’s fear ( Sell put to make
people feels safer but the put may end up out of
the money)
 Either way, the people buy options for nothing
 Who produce option? Who sells options?
Investment bankers

Prof. Joseph K. W. Fung 12.16


FIN B488F Fall 2022
A derivative can be
replicated/mimicked by a
combination of S and a “Bond”
 ƒ = S– (Su– ƒu )e–rT
The derivative f can be replicated by a (cash spot)
position in S and a short position in
(Su– ƒu )e–rT of fixed income security (I.E., a
loan or deposit of that amount

Prof. Joseph K. W. Fung 12.17


FIN B488F Fall 2022
Generalization (continued)
 ƒ = S– (Su– ƒu )e–rT

 RHS: 1st term is a stock position and 2nd term


is a bond position; hence a (long) derivative
position is a leverage stock (asset) position
 For Call, > 0; call is a leveraged long stock
position
 For Put, < 0; put is a leveraged short stock
position

Prof. Joseph K. W. Fung 12.18


FIN B488F Fall 2022
Generalization (continued)
 Substituting for  we obtain (verify it!)

ƒ = Ep (f) e–rT = [p ƒu + (1 – p )ƒd ]e–rT

e d
rT
where p
ud
ue rT
1 p 
ud
Prof. Joseph K. W. Fung 12.19
FIN B488F Fall 2022
Conditions for a probability measure
(1): non-negativity 0< p<1
(2): sum of the probabilities of all disjoint events = 1
(3): completeness
Assumption: u > erT > d (the following proof is by way of contraction)
 If erT > u
 Risk-free return > maximum stock return
 nobody speculates in the stick market, hence erT < u
 If d > erT
 return in stock market in the worst case > risk-free return
 nobody invests in the fixed income market, hence d < erT

Prof. Joseph K. W. Fung 12.20


FIN B488F Fall 2022
Risk-Neutral Valuation
 ƒ = [ p ƒu + (1 – p )ƒd ]e-rT
 The variables p and (1– p) can be interpreted as the risk-
neutral probabilities of up and down movements
 The value of a derivative is its expected payoff in a risk-
neutral world discounted at the risk-free rate
Su
p
ƒu
S
ƒ (1 Sd

p) ƒd
Prof. Joseph K. W. Fung 12.21
FIN B488F Fall 2022
Risk Neutral Probability p

Investors are risk neutral if

Se rT
 E ST   pSu  1  p Sd

e rT  d u  e rT
pSu  1  p Sd  Su  Sd  Se rT
ud ud

Hence p & 1 – p are called risk-neutral probabilities


Does p equal to the “real” chance that the market goes up?
Prof. Joseph K. W. Fung 12.22
FIN B488F Fall 2022
Irrelevance of Stock’s (and
derivative’s) Expected Return
(e.g., CAPM required ret) that is
where Samuelson got lost
When we are valuing an option in
terms of the underlying stock the
expected returns on the stock or on the
option are irrelevant
Risk preference irrelevant ! The only
assumption is investors/traders are
GREEDY!! (prefer more to less to
motivate pure arbitrage)
Prof. Joseph K. W. Fung 12.23
FIN B488F Fall 2022
Original Example Revisited
Su = $22
p ƒu = 1
S = $20
ƒ
(1– Sd = $18
p) ƒd = 0
 Since p is a risk-neutral probability: definition
 $20e0.12 0.25 = $22p + $18(1 – p ); p = 0.6523
 Alternatively, we can use the formula
e rT  d e 0.120.25  0.9
p   0.6523
ud 1.1  0.9
Prof. Joseph K. W. Fung 12.24
FIN B488F Fall 2022
Valuing the Option with risk-neutral
probabilities (“equivalent martingale”)
Su = $22
523 ƒu = 1
0. 6
S = $20
ƒ
0.34 Sd = $18
77
ƒd = 0

The value of the option is

= e–0.120.25 (0.65231 + 0.34770) = $0.633

Note that the pricing formula fails to show how to trade

Prof. Joseph K. W. Fung 12.25


FIN B488F Fall 2022
Δ as the hedge ratio
 S0= 20, Su= 22, Sd = 18, Cu= 1, r = 12%, T = 1/4

$22Δ – $1 = $18Δ

4Δ = 1

Δ = 0.25  (long 0.25 shares per 1 short call)

 If stock price goes up, value of portfolio = $22(0.25) – $1 = $4.5

 If stock price drops, value of portfolio = $18(0.25) = $4.5

 Present value of portfolio = $4.5e-0.12/4 = $4.367

Prof. Joseph K. W. Fung 12.26


FIN B488F Fall 2022
Δ as the hedge ratio

SuΔ – fu = SdΔ – fd

Δ = (fu – fd) / (Su – Sd)

Δ: ratio of change in option (any other derivative)


price to the change in stock price.

Delta shows how the value of a derivative is affected


by the underlying asset; hence the derivative can be
priced relative to S
Prof. Joseph K. W. Fung 12.27
FIN B488F Fall 2022
A Two-Step Example: Call (X=21)
Figure 12.3, page 274

Suu = $24.2
Su = $22

S = $20 Sud = $19.8

Sd = $18
Sdd = $16.2

 Each time step is 3 months; total length 6 m.


 u = 1.1; d = 0.9; r = 12%; T = 0.25; p = 0.6523
 Path independence: Sud = Sdu
Prof. Joseph K. W. Fung 12.28
FIN B488F Fall 2022
Valuing a Call Option (X=21)
Figure 12.4, page 274
Su = $22 D Suu = $24.2
fu = $2.0257 fuu = $3.2
S = $20 B E Sud = $19.8
f = $1.2823 A
C fud = $0
F
Sd = $18 Sdd = $16.2
fd = $0 fdd = $0

 Value at node B = e–0.120.25(0.65233.2 + 0.34770) =


$2.0257
 Value at node C = e–0.120.25(0.65230 + 0.34770) = $0
 Value at node A = e–0.120.25(0.65232.0257 + 0.34770) =
$1.2823

Prof. Joseph K. W. Fung 12.29


FIN B488F Fall 2022
Two-step binominal option price:
a generalization
fu p fuu
p
f 1–p fud
p
1–p
fd 1–p fdd

fu = [ pfuu + (1 – p)fud ] e-rT

fd = [ pfud + (1 – p)fdd ] e-rT

f = [ pfu + (1 – p)fd ] e-rT

f = e-r2T [ p2fuu + 2p(1 – p)fud + (1 – p)2fdd ]


Prof. Joseph K. W. Fung 12.30
FIN B488F Fall 2022
Two-period binomial option
pricing


f  e  2 rt p 2 f uu  2 p (1  p ) f ud  (1  p ) 2 f dd 
e rT  d
p
ud

Prof. Joseph K. W. Fung 12.31


FIN B488F Fall 2022
n-period model
Assume that each period is of length , n = T
n 
C  r n n! j n j j n j

p 1  p  Max u d S  X ,0  
 j 0 j!n  j ! 
where r = 1+ risk free interest rate per period

n!
p j 1  p 
n j

j!n  j ! is the (binomial) probability that the

value of the call is equal to


Max u j n j

d S  X ,0 after n 

periods or (n moves) when the option expires


Prof. Joseph K. W. Fung 12.32
FIN B488F Fall 2022
Nature of options’ Truncated Risk
Define “a” as the minimum no. of up moves such that

u a d na S  X and the call finishes in-the-money,


then

 n 
C  r 
n n! j n j

p 1  p  u d S  X 
j n j

 i  a j!n  j ! 

 n n! n j  u d
j n j
  n n! n j 
 S  p 1  p  
j
  Xr 
n
p j 1  p  
 j  a j!n  j !  j  a j!n  j !
n
 r  

Prof. Joseph K. W. Fung 12.33


FIN B488F Fall 2022
n-period model
na
au d a
SX
Take natural logarithm of both sides, after re-arranging, we have,

a ln u  n  a ln d  S  X

aln u  ln d   X  S  n ln d

a is the smallest non-negative integer greater than



ln X / Sd n 
ln u / d 
wherea n

Prof. Joseph K. W. Fung 12.34


FIN B488F Fall 2022
n n!  u j n j
d    n
n! n j 
C  S  p 1  p   n   Xr  p 1  p  
j n  j n j

 j  a j!n  j !  r   j  a j!n  j ! 

The first bracketed term is the number of shares or the hedge ratio ( Δ)
ƒ = S– (Su– ƒu )e–rT
The second term is the size of the loan in the replicating portfolio
The bracketed expression in the second term is the total prob. That the
option will end up in the money and will be exercised (i.e., the exercise
probability)

Prof. Joseph K. W. Fung 12.35


FIN B488F Fall 2022
 n n! n j  u d
j n j
  n n! n j 
C  S  p 1  p  
j
  Xr 
n
p 1  p  
j

 j  a j! n  j !  r n
  j  a j!n  j ! 

The first bracketed term can be simplified as

n j
 pu   1  p d 
n j
n!
j a
  
j!n  j !  r   r

u d
Let p '  p; 1  p '  (1  p ); and 0  p '  1
r r
 n n! n j   n n! n j 
C  S  p 1  p   Xr 
j n
p 1  p  
j

 j  a j!n  j !   j  a j!n  j ! 

Prof. Joseph K. W. Fung 12.36


FIN B488F Fall 2022
 n n! n j   n n! n j 
C  S  p 1  p   Xr 
j n
p 1  p  
j

 j  a j!n  j !   j  a j!n  j ! 
u
p '  p; 0  p '  1
r
(r  d ) r
and p  
(u  d ) u
u
Hence p is always positive and less than 1.
r

Prof. Joseph K. W. Fung 12.37


FIN B488F Fall 2022
C  Sa; n; p  Xr a; n; p 
' n


 a; n; p '
 is the complimentary probability or delta

a; n; p  is the probability of exercise


a is the smallest non-negative integer greater than ln X /Sd n

ln u / d 
If a>n, then C=0

If S is large relative to X, a is small and the probability of


exercise is high.

p  (r  d ) /(u  d ) and p  (u / r ) p
Prof. Joseph K. W. Fung 12.38
FIN B488F Fall 2022
Delta

 Delta () is the ratio of the change in the price of a


stock option to the change in the price of the
underlying stock
 The value of  varies from node to node

ƒu  f d

Su  Sd

Prof. Joseph K. W. Fung 12.39


FIN B488F Fall 2022
“Deltas” in a 2-period binomial model
Su = $22 D Suu = $24.2
fu = $2.0257 fuu = $3.2
S0 = $20 B E Sud = $19.8
A
f = $1.2823 C fud = $0
F
Sd = $18 Sdd = $16.2
fd = $0 fdd = $0

fu – fd (2.0257 – 0)
 at node A () = = = 0.5064
Su – Sd (22 – 18)
fuu – fud (3.2 – 0)
 At node B (u) = = = 0.7273
Suu – Sud (24.2 – 19.8)
fud – fdd (0 – 0)
 at node C (d) = = =0
Sud – Sdd (19.8 – 16.2)
Prof. Joseph K. W. Fung 12.40
FIN B488F Fall 2022
Dynamic hedging: why?
 At A: delta = 0.5064; c=1.2823
 S = 20
 At B: S = 22 and c = 2.0257
 At A: (riskfree) portfolio = 0.5064 (20) – c
 At B: change in stock value = 0.5064 ($2) = 1.0128; change in
c value = 2.0257-1.2823 = 0.7434
 At D: 0.5057 (4.2) = 2.1219; change in call = 3.20-1.2823 =
1.9177 (lose money!)
 Reason: delta increases for call when S rises
 CONVEXITY (GAMMA RISK) = delta is a function of S
 Need to change hedge ratio: otherwise, under-hedge if S rises
and over-hedge if S drops
 Hedging a call requires an adjustment in delta when S changes
Prof. Joseph K. W. Fung 12.41
FIN B488F Fall 2022
Arbitrage in a 2-step binomial model
If c = 1.5 > c* = 1.2823, the call is overpriced
Strategy: Short 1 Call and buy 0.5064) Shares

Transactions CF0

Short 1 Call +$1.5

-$10.128
Buy  Shares
(- 0.5064 x $20)

Borrow $8.8457 at 12% for 6 months +8.8457


+0.2177

Prof. Joseph K. W. Fung 12.42


FIN B488F Fall 2022
Portfolio rebalancing at node B

At node B, u= 0.7273, to reach the new hedge ratio, need to


purchase an additional 0.2209 (u – = 0.7273 – 0.5064)
shares. Finance the purchase with additional borrowing

Transactions at node B (Su = S3 = 22)

-$4.8598
Buy (u –  Shares
-(0.2209 x $22)

Borrow $4.8598 at 12% for 3 months +$4.8598

Prof. Joseph K. W. Fung 12.43


FIN B488F Fall 2022
Payoff from the overall portfolio at
option expiration (X=$21)

CF6
(Suu = S6 (Sud = S6
= $24.2) = $19.8)
Short 1 Call -$3.2 $0
u Shares: value=0.7273 x S6 +$17.600 +$14.400

Repayment of the initial (6-month) loan -$9.392 -$9.392


Repayment of the second (3-month) loan -$5.008 -$5.008

$0 $0
Prof. Joseph K. W. Fung 12.44
FIN B488F Fall 2022
Portfolio rebalancing at node C

At node C, d= 0, to reach the new hedge ratio, need


to sell all the 0.5064 () shares.

Transactions at node C (Sd = S3 = $18)

+$9.115
Sell  Shares
(0.5064 x $18)

Lend $9.115 at 12% for 3 month -$9.115

Prof. Joseph K. W. Fung 12.45


FIN B488F Fall 2022
Payoff from the overall portfolio at
option expiration

CF6
(Sud = S6 (Sdd = S6
= $19.8) = $16.2)
Short 1 Call 0 0
Repayment of the initial (6-month) loan -$9.392 -$9.392

The second (3-month) investment +$9.392 +$9.392

0 0

Prof. Joseph K. W. Fung 12.46


FIN B488F Fall 2022
Summary on dynamic portfolio
rebalancing
 If S up, delta or hedge ratio up, need to buy more
shares to maintain the hedge (delta neutral)
 If S down, delta or hedge ratio down, need to
sell/unload some or all shares to maintain the hedge
(delta neutral)
An alternative strategy
 If S up, need to buy more call to maintain the delta
neutral position (buy call when call price goes up)
 If S down, need to sell more calls to maintain the
delta neutral position (sell calls when call price drops)
 These may show the cost for selling options for
investment banks
Prof. Joseph K. W. Fung 12.47
FIN B488F Fall 2022
dynamic portfolio rebalancing (example)
 Initial call delta = 0.5
 Sell 1000 calls, buy 500 shares

 Now S rises, new delta = 0.75

 To adjust the hedge according to the higher delta:

1. Buy more stock: required number of share to hedge the


call = 750 shares, need to buy 250 shares
2. buy back some calls, with 500 shares and new call delta
of 0.75, can hedge only 500/0.75 = 667, buy back 333
calls, 500/667 = 0.75
Note that either way, the option seller has to buy more stock
or option when they are the rise
Similarly, if S drops, delta drops, IB sell some stock or sell
more call when they are falling
Prof. Joseph K. W. Fung 12.48
FIN B488F Fall 2022
Arbitrage in a 2-step binomial model
If c = 1 < c* = 1.2823, the call is underpriced
Strategy: Long 1 Call and Short 0.5064) Shares

Transactions CF0

Long 1 Call -$1

+$10.128
Short  Shares
(0.5064 x $20)

Lend $8.8457 at 12% for 6 months -8.8457


+0.2823

Prof. Joseph K. W. Fung 12.49


FIN B488F Fall 2022
Portfolio rebalancing at node B
At node B, u= 0.7273, to reach the new hedge ratio, need to
short an additional 0.2209 (u – = 0.7273 – 0.5064) shares.
Invest the additional cash inflow

Transactions at node B (Su = S3 = 22)

$4.8598
Short (u –  Shares
(0.2209 x $22)

Lend $4.8598 at 12% for 3 months -$4.8598

Prof. Joseph K. W. Fung 12.50


FIN B488F Fall 2022
Payoff from the overall portfolio at
option expiration

CF6
(Suu = S6 = (Sud = S6 =
$24.2) $19.8)
Long 1 Call +$3.2 $0
u Shares -$17.600 -$14.400

The initial (6-month) investment +$9.392 +$9.392

The second (3-month) investment +$5.008 +$5.008

$0 $0
Prof. Joseph K. W. Fung 12.51
FIN B488F Fall 2022
Portfolio rebalancing at node C

At node C, d= 0, to reach the new hedge ratio, need to


buy back the 0.5064 () shares. Finance the purchase
with additional borrowing

Transactions at node C (Sd = S3 = $18)

-$9.115
Buy  Shares
(- 0.5064 x $18)

Borrow $9.115 at 12% for 3 month +$9.115

Prof. Joseph K. W. Fung 12.52


FIN B488F Fall 2022
Payoff from the overall portfolio at
option expiration

CF6
(Sud = S6 (Sdd = S6
= $19.8) = $16.2)
Long 1 Call 0 0
The initial (6-month) investment +$9.392 +$9.392

Repayment of the second (3-month) loan -$9.392 -$9.392

0 0

Prof. Joseph K. W. Fung 12.53


FIN B488F Fall 2022
Investment banks and market momentum
(world federation exchanges vol/turnover)
 IB short call and hedge with long stock

 Market goes up, buy stock because delta


rises
 Market drops, sell stock because delta
decreases
 In both cases, the investment bank add
momentum in both up and down market
 Testable hypothesis: markets with active
options trading have higher volatility
Prof. Joseph K. W. Fung 12.54
FIN B488F Fall 2022
market momentum
 Momentum  positive return correlation In
both cases
 If derivative market (due to manipulation
and/or the technical requirement for
dynamic portfolio rebalance) adds to
market momentum, then markets with
active and large derivative trading would
have greater price momentum; that means
that the returns have higher auto-
correlation; test that with trading rules
Prof. Joseph K. W. Fung 12.55
FIN B488F Fall 2022
IB and market momentum
 Short put and hedge with short stock
(futures) position
 Market goes up, reduce the short position,
buy stock
 Market drops, increase the short position,
sell stock
 In both cases, they add momentum to the
market
Prof. Joseph K. W. Fung 12.56
FIN B488F Fall 2022
A Put Option Example (X=52)
Figure 12.7, page 277

Suu = $72
Su = $60

S = $50 Sud = $48

Sd = $40
Sdd = $32

 Each time step is 1 year


 u = 1.2; d = 0.8; r = 5%; T = 1; p = 0.6282

Prof. Joseph K. W. Fung 12.57


FIN B488F Fall 2022
Valuing Put Option (X=52)
Figure 12.7, page 277
Su = $60 D Suu = $72
fu = $1.4147 fuu = $0
S = $50 B E Sud = $48
f = $4.1923 A
C fud = $4
F
Sd = $40 Sdd = $32
fd = $9.4636 fdd = $20

 Value at node B = e–
0.120.25
(0.62820 + 0.37184) = $1.4147
 Value at node C = e–
0.120.25
(0.62824 + 0.371820) = $9.4636
 Value at node A = e–
0.120.25
(0.62821.4147 + 0.37189.4636) = $4.1923
Prof. Joseph K. W. Fung 12.58
FIN B488F Fall 2022
What Happens if the Put Option is American
(Figure 12.8, page 278)

Su = $60 D Suu = $72


fu = $1.4147 fuu = $0
S = $50 B E Sud = $48
f = $5.0894 A
C fud = $4
F
Sd = $40 Sdd = $32
fd = $12 (ex.) fdd = $20

 Value at node B = e–0.120.25(0.62820 + 0.37184) = $1.4147


 Value at node C = $12 (early exercise)
 Value at node A = e–0.120.25(0.62821.4147 + 0.371812) = $5.0894
 American option ($5.0894) is more valuable than European option
($4.1923 ) if there is a chance of early exercise
 Difference between the two prices is the value of early exercise option
Prof. Joseph K. W. Fung 12.59
FIN B488F Fall 2022
Value of the put option at node “C”

 Value of the option without early exercise:

a = [ pSud + (1 – p) Sdd ]e–rT

= (0.62824 + 0.371820)e–0.120.25 = $9.4636


 Value of the option with early exercise:

b = Max [X – Sd , 0] = $12

 Value of the option at note c

= Max [a, b] = $12

Prof. Joseph K. W. Fung 12.60


FIN B488F Fall 2022
Delta
Example: Valuing a Put Option (Figure 11.7, page 252)
 The  over the first time step:

= (1.4147 – 9.4636) / (60 – 40) = – 0.4024


 The  over the second time step:
 If there is an upward movement over the first step:

= (0 – 4) / (72 – 48) = – 0.1667


 If there is an downward movement over the first step:

= (4 – 20) / (48 – 32) = – 1.0000

Prof. Joseph K. W. Fung 12.61


FIN B488F Fall 2022
The Probability of an Up Move

a–d
p =
u–d
a = e r t  for a non-dividend paying stock

a = e(r - q)t  for a stock index where q is the


dividend yield on the index

a = e(r – rf)t  for a currency where rf is the foreign


risk-free rate
a = 1  for a futures contract (exp futures
return is zero)
Prof. Joseph K. W. Fung 12.62
FIN B488F Fall 2022
Choosing u and d
One way of matching the volatility is to set

u  e t

d  1 u  e  t

where  is the volatility andt is the length


of the time step. This is the approach used
by Cox, Ross, and Rubinstein

Prof. Joseph
Options, K. W.and
Futures, Fung
Other Derivatives, 8th Edition, Copyright © John C. Hull 2012 63
FIN B488F Fall 2022
Size up u and d
One way of matching the volatility is to set
u  e t

d  1 u  e  t

example:  = 20%
t = 1 u  e 0.2 1

 1.22
d  1 1.22  0.82

Prof. Joseph
Options, K. W.and
Futures, Fung
Other Derivatives, 8th Edition, Copyright © John C. Hull 2012 64
FIN B488F Fall 2022
Size up u and d
t u  e 0.2 1/1386
1: u =  1.005
d  1 / 1.005  0.995

Prof. Joseph
Options, K. W.and
Futures, Fung
Other Derivatives, 8th Edition, Copyright © John C. Hull 2012 65
FIN B488F Fall 2022
Girsanov’s Theorem
 Volatility is the same in the real world and
the risk-neutral world
 We can therefore measure volatility in the
real world and use it to build a tree for an
asset in the risk-neutral world

Prof. Joseph
Options, K. W.and
Futures, Fung
Other Derivatives, 8th Edition, Copyright © John C. Hull 2012 66
FIN B488F Fall 2022
Assets Other than Non-Dividend
Paying Stocks

 For options on stock indices, currencies


and futures the basic procedure for
constructing the tree is the same except
for the calculation of p

Prof. Joseph
Options, K. W.and
Futures, Fung
Other Derivatives, 8th Edition, Copyright © John C. Hull 2012 67
FIN B488F Fall 2022
Proving Black-Scholes-Merton from
Binomial Trees (Appendix to Chapter 12)
n
n!
ce  rT

j  0 ( n  j )! j!
p j (1  p ) n  j max(S 0u j d n  j  K , 0)

Option is in the money when j >  where


n ln( S 0 K )
 
2 2 T n
so that
c  e  rT ( S 0U1  KU 2 )
where
n!
U1   p j (1  p ) n  j u j d n  j
j   ( n  j )! j!

n!
U2   p j (1  p ) n  j
j   ( n  j )! j!

Prof. Joseph
Options, K. W.and
Futures, Fung
Other Derivatives, 8th Edition, Copyright © John C. Hull 2012 68
FIN B488F Fall 2022
Proving Black-Scholes-Merton
from Binomial Trees continued

 The expression for U1 can be written


U1  [ pu  (1  p )d ]n 
n!
  j
p* 1  p* 
n j
 e rT 
n!
  j
p* 1  p* 
n j

j   ( n  j )! j! j   ( n  j )! j!

pu
p* 
where pu  (1  p )d

 Both U1 and U2 can now be evaluated in terms of the


cumulative binomial distribution
 We now let the number of time steps tend to infinity
and use the result that a binomial distribution tends to
a normal distribution by CENTRAL LIMIT THEOREM
Prof. Joseph
Options, K. W.and
Futures, Fung
Other Derivatives, 8th Edition, Copyright © John C. Hull 2012 69
FIN B488F Fall 2022
Impacts of changes in delta on risk
management (1)
 The hedge of an option position has to be
adjusted (rebalance) dynamically
according to asset price movements
 Sellers or buyers: call seller adjust the
long asset position, call buyer adjust the
short asset position; similarly put seller
adjust the short asset position and put
buyer adjust the long asset position

Prof. Joseph K. W. Fung 12.70


FIN B488F Fall 2022
Impacts of changes in delta on risk
management (2)
 Sellers of options will adjust the hedge in such a
way that will add to market momentum
 Both call and put seller need to increase (decrease)
size (+/-) asset holding to maintain delta neutrality
when asset price rises (drops); these imply that the
options sellers are buying when market rises and
selling when market drops; hence will increase the
market impact cost in the dynamic hedge (market is
not a perfect market where the trader can buy and
sell an infinite amount of an asset at the same price;
note that the supply curve is horizontal in a perfect
market)
Prof. Joseph K. W. Fung 12.71
FIN B488F Fall 2022
More on hedging option position (3)
 What if there is a big jump (gamma risk which
is associated with change in delta) in the asset
price over-night?
 For example: S&P was closed at 1850 but
open at 1900 with a 50 points jump
 Buy S&P at 1900?
 What about the price of the calls being sold
yesterday?
 If the calls were sold for 37 points with a delta
of around 0.5, the price should have gone up
by 0.6 (50) = 30 points
Prof. Joseph K. W. Fung 12.72
FIN B488F Fall 2022
Ch 12: exercises ???
 1, 2, 4, 5,
 9, 10, 11, 12, 16, 17

Prof. Joseph K. W. Fung 12.73


FIN B488F Fall 2022
 Financial analyst journal
 Journal of portfolio management
 Derivatives and hedge fund
 Journal of futures markets
 Review of futures markets
 Journal of derivatives

Prof. Joseph K. W. Fung 12.74


FIN B488F Fall 2022

You might also like