You are on page 1of 97

Economic Impacts of the Olympic Games through State Comparison

Samantha Edds* April 2012 Abstract After the financially profitable 1984 Los Angeles Olympic Games, some cities began to compete for and host the Olympics in part to garner economic growth and development. The purpose of this paper is to study current economic cost and benefit analysis, before quantifying if and when benefits exist for the 1992 Barcelona, 1996 Atlanta and 2000 Sydney Games. To assess the economic impact of hosting the Olympics, the host state/region will be compared to a same-country state/region that did not host the Games through the examination of infrastructure, prestige and general financial growth models over a nine-year period. Apart from one sectionconstructionfrom the 1992 Barcelona Games, all models appear to show that host states/regions do not have significantly different changes in growth compared to the control states/regions.

Contents 1 Introduction 2 Background: History and Economics 3 Literature Review 4 Methodology 4.1 Methodological Considerations 4.2 Ideal Data Collection 4.3 Independent Variable Ideal Data Collection 4.4 Data Collection 4.4.1 Spain Variables 4.4.2 United States Variables 4.4.3 Australia Variables 5 Model and Analysis 5.1 Model Implications Overview 5.2 1992 Barcelona Games Analysis 5.2.1 Spain Construction 5.2.2 Spain Tourism 5.2.3 Spain Financial Services 5.2.4 Spain Conclusions 5.3 1996 Atlanta Games Analysis 5.3.1 U.S. Construction 5.3.2 U.S. Tourism 5.3.3 U.S. Financial Services 5.3.4 U.S. Conclusions 5.4 2000 Sydney Games Analysis 5.4.1 Australia Construction 5.4.2 Australia Tourism 5.4.3 Australia Financial Services 5.4.4 Australia Conclusions 6 Summary and Conclusions 7 Policy Implications
2

References Appendix A: Comparison Explanations A.1 Spain A.2 United States A.3 Australia Appendix B: Methodological Changes B.1 Spain B.2 United States B.3 Australia Appendix C: Regressions C.1 Spain C.2 United States C.3 Australia

Introduction

In recent memory, hosting the Olympic and Paralympic Games* has been considered highly desirable for host cities. Along with irresistible lure of economic prosperity, prestige and other long-term benefits, cities have thus vied aggressively for the coveted hosting role. To help entice their constituents and plead their case to the International Olympic Committee (IOC), cities commission economic impact studies to estimate the seemingly vast economic benefits for different industries through hosting, from increasing tourism rates to job creation. Economic impact studies attempt to measure the costs and benefits of hosting the Games; however, they use complicated modeling and do not account for the impact of the IOC to potentially induce cost coverage and distort incentives, which may lead the studies to incorrectly model the economic costs and benefits of the Olympics. The IOC solicits bids, and as Syzmanski and Giesecke and Madden show, it appears host cities bid away all or almost all future benefit because the IOC can induce host cities and governments to underwrite most of the costs while keeping for itself a large part of the revenues. Given the IOCs actions it seems that becoming an Olympic host city diminishes the positive economic effects originally anticipated at the beginning of the bidding process and detailed in the proposal. Additionally, the IOC has allegedly committed fraud and accepted bribes, further distorting the incentives to host. Yet,


* Samantha Edds, Undergraduate, International Studies Department, University of Chicago, 5801 S. Ellis Ave., Chicago, IL 60637, e-mail: sedds@uchicago.edu * This is the official International Olympic Committee (IOC) designation. From this point forward in the paper I will employ similar terms, such as Olympics or Olympic Games. James A. Giesceke, and John R. Madden. "Modelling the Economic Impacts of the Sydney Olympics in Retrospect ? Game Over for the Bonanza Story?*. Economic Papers: A journal of applied economics and policy 30, No. 2 (2011): 230. Szymanski, Stefan. Playbooks And Checkbooks: An Introduction To The Economics Of Modern Sports. Princeton : Princeton University Press, 2009: 160. Ibid.158.

despite the IOCs bidding process and overestimated benefits, some economists believe hosting the Olympics still has significant benefits.** Evaluating these benefits, however, has its own set of challenges. First, economic effect and benefit need to be defined to provide a clear understanding of what this paper measures compared to other types of studies. Economic effects of the Olympics include costs and revenues, otherwise known as benefits, which exist because of the Olympic Games. For example, in order to host the Olympics there is often a large amount of construction completed solely for the Games. This is a cost of the Olympics. As with any other structure, ones used for the Olympics will then be occupied, which generates revenue. One way Olympic benefits are measured is through consumer spending, otherwise known as expenditures. People who come to the host city for the Olympics will spend money on activities such as hotels, the Games, eating, and shopping, all of which generates revenue. Additionally, because of the Olympics, people may later visit the host city and/or firms may move there, leading to more construction activity that can be seen as a benefit of the Olympics. Thus, the economic effects of the Olympics, for this study, are created by changes in the growth and development of infrastructure (construction), prestige (tourism), and financial services. However, as will be discussed below, calculating costs and revenues for the Olympics is not just calculating all visitors spending throughout the Olympics and comparing it to the cost of construction and changes completed solely for the Olympics; there are complicated pitfalls that can lead to overestimated benefits. In addition to the IOCs ability to skew incentives, which is not registered by economic impact studies, mathematical inaccuracies further distort the studies stated benefits.
**

Jeffrey M. Humpreys and Michael K. Plummer, The Economic Impact On the State of Georgia of Hosting the 1996 Summer Olympics (diss., The University of Georgia, 1995), 1133, http://www.terry.uga.edu/selig/docs/olympics.pdf (accessed March 8, 2012). From this point forward discussion of construction will refer to infrastructure, tourism will refer to prestige and financial data will refer to financial services.

Mathematical overestimations, such as the substitution effect crowding-out effect, or mathematical multiplier*** calculations, misrepresent the predicted costs and benefits of economic impact studies because they incorrectly measure these effects, which are often perpetuated when applied to the host citys overall economy. If focusing on development and international awareness, it is likely these studies could convince cities to bid for the right to host future Olympics based on falsities. In order to avoid these inaccuracies, this paper uses a different form of measuring cost and benefits with a relative comparison model, which does not require distinction between types of visitor spending and mathematical multipliers. Instead, the paper studies relative changes that look at the economic impact of specific variables with all things held equal and compares differences. The comparative model offers a more relative measure of economic effects, and it will avoid many mathematical measurement issues leading to a more accurate study. Since modeling error and the IOCs role are ignored or incorrect, impact studies will overestimate the positive economic effect of the Olympic Games on host cities. This leads to the question: how can the monetary impact of the Olympics be correctly modeled? To correct for inherent flaws, economists have begun to run post-Olympic models. Examining costs and benefits through post-Olympic models will allow authors to reconcile the differences in pre-

Some people have visits that coincide with the Olympics, or were slightly altered to time the visit with the Olympics, but regardless these visitors would have traveled to the host city. Because of this, the visitors would have spent money on things such as eating, hotels and tourist attractions independent of the Olympics. Therefore the visitors are substituting one activity, in this case watching an Olympic event, for another, what they would be doing if the Olympics were not in the host city. Matheson, Victor. Upon Further Review: An Examination of Sporting Event Economic Impact Studies. Sports Journal 5, no.1 (2002): 2. The Olympics acts as deterrence likely due to reports of potential crowding and congestion that divert visitors and spending away from the host city. Ibid.2. *** Money spent on the Olympics that circulates through the economy, is created into a mathematical multipler to account for the effect of each dollar that continues to circulate through the economy, acting as a stimulus. Studies often do not distinguish dollars that stay in the local economy and dollars that will go to corporations and nonlocal vendors, and thus do not count toward the money multiplier. Ibid.2.

Olympic impact studies; accurate data and new models account for the issues Matheson stated. Authors have moved towards precise comparison models with specific variable selection instead of general modeling such as Computable General Equilibrium modeling (CGE) to account for model inaccuracies. While there are many studies that now use comparative modeling, how can these studies best provide cities with a clear picture of the economic effects of hosting the Olympics? Given the issues and inaccuracies of current economic effect studies, does measuring for changes in prestige, infrastructure, and general financial growth produce a more accurate picture of the economic gains that result for Olympic host cities? The purpose of this study is to make cities more aware of the discrepancy in projected benefits, so cities are able to better understand the difference between estimated and actual benefits when they consider bidding. Understanding modeling discrepancy patterns, as well as the actual economic costs and benefits of hosting the Olympics will allow constituents who stand to gain from hosting and cities to make decisions with eyes wide open. Knowing the true opportunity cost of hosting provides cities and developers, hotels and other firms accurate information to either bid while acknowledging potential economic losses, or to use money that would be spent on the Olympics on the next best alternative. For example, funds spent on the Games could be used for other infrastructure, transportation networks, parks and recreation or even on crime prevention that with the existence of the Olympics would not exist.

Ibid.230.

CGE modeling is one of the main ways to estimate the potential economic effects a host city receives as a

result of hosting the Olympics. It involves studying the disaggregated forms of the economy through sector examination, creating a model that Kasimati notes is difficult to compute. Kasimati, Evangelia. "Economic Aspects and the Summer Olympics: A Review of Related Research." International Journal of Tourism Research 5.6 (2003): 433-44. Print.

While there exists a number of post-Olympic studies and comparative model use,

particularly the works by Billings and Holladay, Giesecke and Madden, and Rose and Spiegel, my model aims to create greater specificity and accuracy, by comparing similar Olympic Games host cities to same-country sister-cities at a statewide level to control for countrywide cofounding effects. Because methods of recordkeeping do not provide city level specific data for my dependent or independent variables, they will be state or regional specific, based upon case and definition. Since countrywide effects are held constant and each city is the largest within the comparable studied area, the models may be able to see effects attributable solely to the Olympics Games. I will use a comparison model, similar to the approach of Giesceke and Madden, and Rose and Spiegel because there is less likely to be inaccuracies from data collection and mathematical modeling as with CGE modeling. Compared to other models, my study model attempts to provide greater specificity through relative comparisons and greater accuracy with by holding countrywide effects constant and modeling that does not require difficult to calculate multipliers and effects such as substitution. After running the models, results show that only the 1992 Barcelona Games construction model has a positive economic effect that could be attributable to the Olympics; all other construction, tourism and financial services models show either no difference or less change in growth from the control models. In a number of cases, the control model has greater change in economic growth than the Olympic model. Because there is likely an amount of inaccuracy due to measurement changes and the indication of identity variables, it is not possible to say with total certainty that the 1992, 1996 and 2000 Olympic Games lead to essentially no positive economic growth, and in fact often hamper industry growth.

Identities happen when the independent variables are completely correlated with the dependent variables, thus there exists no difference between them.

To best understand and analyze the studys model of the economic effects of the

Olympics, first the historical background and current models will be described, then an explanation of why this study is using a slightly different approach, followed by a description of ideal and actual data, model analysis, results and implications. The literature review will focus on types of economic cost and benefits studies that look at the Games retroactively, often through comparative modeling, on which my model is based, instead of predictive modeling to understand the actual costs and benefits of the Olympics. My model is derived from these current comparative modeling studies, with the aim of providing further specificity and accuracy. After describing the studys model, there will be a section on ideal data collection to better explain the shortcomings and aim of this paper, followed by a description of actual proxy data assessed in the model. The results section will interpret the studys model in an attempt to better understand trends within the Olympics and a relative comparison of hosting the Olympics versus not hosting for changes in construction, tourism, and financial growth. In my conclusion I will further discuss the limitations to my analysis, including possible measuring inaccuracies and problems that may affect results, before presenting a section on policy and research implications. The historical background of the Olympics and current models provide a basis for the studys model, which aims for greater specificity and accuracy; results and a conclusion that describes further policy implications will help the constituents and cities considering bidding in the future better understand the costs and benefits of hosting the Olympics.

2 Background: History and Economics

Each Olympic Game takes place under different circumstances; there are a litany of reasons why cities host the Olympics, some, such as Beijing, are meant to show city and country power, while others host for international awareness and yet others host for economic gains. This paper focuses solely on economic gains as the main reason for hosting the Olympics, thus the conclusions drawn about economic effects and feasibility will not be applicable to host cities such as Beijing. The Olympics Games began in 1896 as a small tradition fusing athletic feats and international unity. Over time, the Games have evolved into a display of wealth and economic development. The myths of economic prosperity and development**** have become prominent only after the 1984 Los Angeles Olympics, the only time in which a city did not face competition from other bidders. Below is a short history of the past Olympic legacies to better understand how the Games have evolved and why the paper studies the 1992, 1996 and 2000 Games. Understanding the ever-changing history of the Olympics will show the reader why the 1992, 1996 and 2000 Olympics are the most similar and represent a shift in reason for hosting to economic development, which remains one of the host city focal points. After World War II, the Olympics until 1968 had fairly low attendance as the world began to rebuild and adjust to changes. In 1968 the Summer Games were held in Mexico City. The legacy of the Games is not positive, during 1968 there is the War in Vietnam and anti-war protesters, political and civil rights issues and assassinations in the U.S., and general protests throughout the world. During the 1972 Games in Munich, Israeli athletes were murdered. **** Jeffrey M. Humpreys and Michael K. Plummer, The Economic Impact On the State of Georgia of Hosting the
1996 Summer Olympics.:1-2.


Allen

Sanderson, Olympics Lecture (lecture, University of Chicago, Chicago, IL, January 6, 2012).

10

The 1976 Montreal Games will be remembered for overrun costs and the poor execution of the Games. Because of this, in 1978, when the host city for 1984 was selected, Los Angeles was the only city to bid, meaning it did not have to out bid another city, keeping its costs for hosting low, while taking advantage of the high-quality university facilities from schools such as UCLA and USC. Many of the structures constructed solely for the Olympics are rarely used again after the Olympics given their size, nature of facilities and maintenance costs, however because Los Angeles had so many Olympic, or near Olympic ready facilities, the cost of the Olympics was very low. During this time, given the issues from Mexico City to Montreal, hosting the Games was seen as a burdensome task instead of an honor. After Montreal, China and much of the West boycotted the 1980 Moscow Games because the Soviets invaded Afghanistan.***** Similarly, when the 1984 Los Angeles Games happened, the Soviet block boycotted the Games, further contributing to the small, but inexpensive Olympics. Los Angeles generated a profit, albeit smaller than usually described. However, Seoul, the host of the 1988 Olympic Games, was too far into the building and planning process of their Games to consider the economic development and growth aspect of hosting. Unlike Seoul, Barcelona was able to realize their economic development goals by entering into the Common Market/EU and using the Olympics as a catalyst; this is the first Olympic Games that urban and economic development was considered when bidding to host the Games. Similarly, the 1996 Atlanta Games, focused on development and economic growth, as did the 2000 Games in Sydney. However, in Sydney most of the Olympic facilities have little

Ibid. Ibid. ***** Ibid. Ibid. Allen Sanderson, Olympics Lecture (lecture, University of Chicago, Chicago, IL, January 6, 2012).

11

to no use, but have very high year maintenance costs. 2004 Athens had crippling expenditures, overrun costs from security concerns due to 9/11/2001 and increasingly elaborate and expense facility construction in an attempt to advertise the city as a tourist destination. The 2008 Beijing Games had enormous costs and the government largely decided everything, to showcase the city and country.****** The next Olympics in the summer of 2012 are in London; Rio de Janeiro will be the host city in 2016. Given the shift in hosting reasons, and the level of extenuating different circumstances, I chose the 1992, 1996 and 2000 Games because they are the most similar Games and represent change and the focus on economic development.


Dennis

Passa, A Year Later Sydney Areas Go Unused, Free Lance Star (Sydney), September 16, 2001.


****** Allen

Sanderson, Olympics Lecture (lecture, University of Chicago, Chicago, IL, January 6, 2012).

12

3 Literature Review

Examining current economic modeling and Arthur Andersens consulting report provides the basis for this studys model and results. Arthur Andersens report predicts economic effects of the Sydney Games, and highlights past trends found in the Atlanta and Barcelona Games. Atlanta and Barcelona models show the overall economic situation likely has a great impact on any Olympic effect, meaning any affect attributable to the Olympics is too small to overcome larger economic trends. While this will be important to consider when examining my results, current economic modeling studies guide my choice of a same-country state level comparative model of construction, tourism, financial services and manufacturing variables. By examining current economic modeling, my study will be able to use greater precision and accuracy than current models; Arthur Andersens study will provide a framework to better gauge and study my results. Arthur Andersen, a global consulting firm, conducted a study the year before the Sydney Olympic Games, which is often cited in later Olympic literature as a reliable source that presents the difficulty of distinguishing an Olympic effect. The study offers insight into some overarching economic effects that may be seen in my models comparing NSW to Victoria. The study claims a $6.5 billion dollar extra economic activity in Australia, with $5.1 alone in New South Wales at net present value. Because of this, it appears there would be significant increases in tourism, construction, and financial services industry incomes in New South Wales compared to Victoria, as indicated by the changes in predictor variables. However, the study simultaneously notes NSW income (gross state product) is $77 million dollars lower in the 6 years after the Games than if the Games had not been held in Sydney, which may impact government willingness to CREA/Arthur Andersen. Economic Impact Study of the Sydney 2000 Olympic Games. Sydney: Arthur Andersen (1999): 1-7.Print. 13

help fund projects, and in turn impact some parts of the construction industry. According to the study, if correct, my models should not see a significant change in employment for New South Wales because of the Olympics. While there appears to be an overall small net positive economic effect of hosting the Olympics, it is not equal in every industry. If the studys employment numbers are correct, the idea that the Olympics leads to greater employment because more people are drawn to visit the area and live in the area where the Olympics took place may be misguided and the Olympics actually have a small, short-term effect. The Arthur Anderson study offers trends that, if true, should be seen in this papers model results, such as varying levels of increased GDP among construction, tourism, and financial services. The Arthur Andersen study also describes some of the economic trends that the company discovered about the Atlanta and Barcelona Games. In Atlanta, the study claims there is a tight labor market, so the city could not maximize potential gains for employment, and furthermore, the Olympics were unable to overpower Georgias already struggling economy at the time. Knowing that Georgias economy was already under pressure at the time of the Olympics may override any potential Olympic effect. However, in Barcelona, the study notes that the Olympics and economic activity need to host may have stimulated the economy, which before the Olympics was in an economic downturn.******* Another possibility for economic stimulation is Spain entering the EU, which likely had a large, positive economic impact. Because the models in this study compare autonomous communities within Spain, the EU effect is held constant, and a significant change in construction, tourism, financial services or manufacturing industry in Catalonia compared to Madrid AC might be attributable to the Olympics. Similarly, the province of Barcelonas (a subset of Catalonia) employment rate went from 23.6% to 11.7% from 1986 to
CREA/Arthur ibid.5-6. ******* ibid.5-6.

Andersen. Economic Impact Study of the Sydney 2000 Olympic Games.6.

14

1992. By holding countrywide effects constant it may be possible that significant employment change exists for the construction, tourism and financial services industries. As the study shows, each Olympics Game takes place under different circumstances and larger economic shifts and activities may cover or amplify any potential Olympic effect. While Arthur Andersens study is helpful in providing a framework with which to gauge results, it does not detail a model to create and interpret results, which is why I will examine current post-Olympic studies. A number of authors have created post-Olympic studies using different methods and variables to show the imprecision in economic impact studies and provide a better picture of the relative economic costs and benefits that host cities receive. Giesecke and Madden use a form of more accurate CGE modeling, through post-Olympic analysis, judging four major areas of economic activity, yet their model derives data from different sources and has to account for difficult to accurately compute data, such as the mathematical multiplier. Rose and Spiegel use a more accurate model, examining trade openness through country level comparison to a candidate country, yet using only one variable at the country level does not allow for the examination of more specific Olympic economic effects seen at the city level. Billings and Holladay use a city level comparison model of host cities to finalist cities, examining population, two measure of Gross Domestic Product (GDP)******** and trade openness to best account for all economic indicators, however they are less able to account for countrywide confounding
CREA/Arthur James

Andersen. Economic Impact Study of the Sydney 2000 Olympic Games.5-6. A. Giesceke, and John R. Madden. "Modelling the Economic Impacts of the Sydney Olympics in Retrospect.: 230. Andrew K. Rose, and Mark M. Spiegel. "The Olympic Effect*." The Economic Journal 121.553 (2011): 664665. ******** Gross Domestic Product: A countrys final output of goods and services produced within a certain timeframe. Australian Board of Statistics, Glossary, Australian Board of Statistics,http://www.abs.gov.au/Ausstats/abs@.nsf/glossary/5220.0 (accessed March 9, 2012).

15

effects. Because of this, and given data availability, my model focuses on a variety of state level variables thought to best see effects attributable to the Olympics through a same country comparison. Giesecke and Madden use CGE modeling for a post-Olympic study, which makes it more accurate than predictive studies, but still requires complicated mathematical calculations, and likely generates some model inaccuracies. They examine whether predicted economic benefit exist for the 2000 Sydney Games by examining Australia and New South Wales state through CGE modeling, the same type of modeling typically used to conduct economic impact studies. Their study is most comparable to pre-Olympic evaluations because it uses the same modeling methodology to best evaluate predicted and actual benefits, although they have two scenarios: Sydney hosting the Olympics and Sydney not hosting the Olympics. The comparison of the Olympic model to the non-Olympic model allows the authors to compute relative costs and benefits by providing outcomes for all possible scenarios. By using the same type of modeling post-Olympics, the authors are able to correct for modeling errors such as visitor spending methodology that cause inexactness in CGE models used for the final bid. Giesecke and Madden found a real consumption loss of $2.1 billion for Sydney. While the authors are able to determine the monetary loss of hosting the Olympics in Sydney, their model requires very precise data measurement that otherwise exacerbates the multiplier, one of the most important parts of the model, for accurate outcomes. The study also derives data from multiple authors, who might have different data collection and measurement methods, which makes the data and variable interactions overall less reliable. With such a complicated model there are many ways
Stephen

B. Billings and J. Scott Holladay. "Should Cities Go for the Gold? The Long-Term Impacts of Hosting the Olympics. Economic inquiry (2011): 1-278. Print. Giesecke and Madden. Modeling the Economic Impacts of the Sydney Olympics in Retrospect? 230. Ibid.230.

16

data can be contaminated and lead to less accurate results. While Giesecke and Madden provide a comparison to most economic impact studies by using more accurate post-Olympic CGE modeling, their study still requires measuring for the substitution effect, among others, and uses data from different authors, which likely creates some inaccuracies in their model. Giesecke and Maddens model uses variables that show the economic impact of the Olympics at both a city and countrywide level. The variables are ones that encompasses the four key economic dimensions of the Games: (i) Games operations; (ii) construction of Games facilities and associated nancing; (iii) spending by interstate visitors in the Games year; and (iv) spending by foreign visitors in the Games year.********* Examining four major economic dimensions allows the authors to test seemingly important costs and benefits that will evaluate overall economic effects from a variety of viewpoints. Games operations will help measure the receipts and contribution to GDP by the Olympics, which is the main measure of a countrys economic growth. Construction and financing variables help show the direct impact of the Games. For example, Olympic facilities were often built solely for the Olympics, never to be used again, or built on a larger size and time scale. Spending by interstate and foreign visitors shows the effect of the Olympics in GDP from interstate visitors. All of the variables measure the real levels of costs and benefits from the Olympics on the city and country in a financial sense. However, given that almost every study is composed differently, there could be some level of bias among the variables that could skew outcomes. Additionally, collection methods for receipts are often measured incorrectly because of the crowding-out effect. Overall the variables appear to measure all different aspects of the Olympics at both a city and country level, albeit in a very complicated model. ********* Giesecke and Madden. Modeling the Economic Impacts of the Sydney Olympics in Retrospect? 225.
Receipts measure customer spend Victor

Matheson. Upon Further Review: An Examination of Sporting Event Economic Impact Studies.: 2.

17

Rose and Spiegel use a country-to-country comparison methodology instead of CGE modeling to provide a more relative evaluation for the economic effects of hosting the Olympics. By comparing the country of a host city to the country of a candidate city, the authors are able to see the whether the benefits of hosting the Olympics are negligible if the candidate country receives similar benefits. Rose and Spiegel examine the effects of the Olympics through increasing exports by quantifying the differences in trade openness between finalist and host countries for 1956-2006.The authors find that trade openness increases about 20% for each country. Rose and Spiegel show while trade benefits do exist for the country in which the Olympics take place, they similarly exist in countries with a finalist host city.********** Because of this, the cost of the Olympics becomes more apparent as well as the amount of benefit received by the host country attributable to the Olympics. However, Rose and Spiegels model is based on the country data. Because of this, it is very possible that the Olympic or candidate city has little overall effect on the results, because the country has other big cities and the Olympics is such a small percentage in city, let alone state or country revenue that it will not be visible. Similarly, the authors model is more likely to have confounding factors that contribute to the countrys trade openness which are not caused by the Olympics and are likely more related to trade openness. While Rose and Spiegels model creates a relative comparison to a candidate country, therefore bypassing more complicated mathematical modeling required for CGE, comparing trade openness at a countrywide level may cover up any effect from host and candidate cities that could be seen through a city level comparison. Unlike Giesceke and Madden, Rose and Spiegel use only one variable, trade openness, in their model to determine the relative costs and benefits of the Olympics. The authors use of
Andrew K. Rose, and Mark M. Spiegel. "The Olympic Effect*." The Economic Journal 121.553 (2011): 664-665. ********** Ibid.664.

18

trade openness shows how active a country is on an international level, and trade is intimately tied to economic growth and GDP. Trade openness may show relative costs and benefits attributable to the Olympics on a countrywide scale, but not a citywide scale. It is a somewhat indirect way to show economic growth and GDP increase, if that is the authors intent. In general the model does not appear to be adequate because it is testing only form of economic growth, GDP and relative costs and benefits. Additionally, trade openness only tests a countrywide indicator, not city level ones that may provide more specific insight into how and what industries the Olympics significantly affect. While trade openness indicates international awareness and legitimacy, because it is the only variable, and measured at a countrywide level, there are different types of economic costs and benefits, which cannot be measured that show a more full picture of the Olympics economic impact. For greater accuracy, Billings and Holladay use city level comparisons to illustrate the relative economic effects of hosting the Olympics for specific variables. The authors compare host and candidate cities to test whether the host city gains long-term economic growth attributable to the Olympics. Their use of city level comparison provides the most direct picture of real economic costs and benefits relative to a control city, because regional and countrywide confounders are not included in the data, which could hide or dilute the effect of the host and control cities. One issue comparing host cities to finalist cities is potential confounding effects, such as countrywide events that effect one country and the costs or benefits outcome, but not the other. Confounding effects make the Olympic or finalist city data seem more significant compared to the other. While the authors may need to better account for potential confounders in


Stephen

B. Billings and J. Scott Holladay. "Should Cities Go for the Gold? The Long-Term Impacts of Hosting the Olympics.:1-278.

19

their model to produce the most accurate results their use of city level comparison provides the most specific relative comparison model. Billings and Holladay use variables that are theoretically similar to Giesecke and Madden, testing both city and country level economic effects. The authors test two measures of population, real GDP per capita and trade openness on the city-level, comparing host cities and finalists. The authors found there was little to no statistical significance between the two groups, from the 1970s onwards because of escalating costs and the ability of the International Olympic Committee to further increase costs, cities to bid away benefits. The use of population is likely trying to examine either if employment increased significantly because of the Olympics or if more people moved to a city because of an increase in popularity and awareness, statistic deemed important by many economists. Real GDP per capita measures the change in total goods and services produced in the country over a certain time span per person in the given population, which is a way to test if city and country income increased because of hosting. As mentioned in Rose and Spiegels model trade openness is another way to measure economic growth and real GDP. Again, the variables used all take slightly different approaches in an attempt to form a full picture and understanding of the relative cost and benefits of the Olympics at a city level with population measures, and at a country level with real GDP per capita and trade openness.


Stephen B. Billings and J. Scott Holladay. "Should Cities Go for the Gold? The Long-Term Impacts of Hosting the Olympics.: 1-278. Ibid.2.

20

4 Methodology

While the authors studies continually evolve in specificity through comparative modeling and accuracy through greater variable reach to explain the depth of economic effect attributable to the Olympics, my study attempts to provide a greater level of specificity and accuracy. Giesecke and Maddens model uses difficult to compute effects such as the mathematical multiplier and uses data from multiple sources, which may affect their variables. Rose and Spiegel offer a more specific model through country level comparison of Olympic countries to candidate countries, but only use one variable, trade openness, to measure the effects of the Olympics. The best model appears to be Billings and Holladay, comparing Olympic cities to finalist cities through population, two measures of GDP and trade openness, accounting for many different areas where the Olympic effect may be seen. My model attempts to similarly use a wide variety of variables in a comparative model, but comparing host cities to same-country sister-cities to hold countrywide effects constant. I will quantify the economic value of prestige, infrastructure, and financial services to determine if there exists an economic payoff by comparing Olympic cities at the state level to same-country states. While the study planned on providing greater specificity in order to produce a more precise evaluation of the Olympic Games economic effects through same-country sister city analysis, the methods of record keeping does not provide the necessary data for city level comparisons. My study will still use comparative analysis instead of CGE modeling for greater precision because there is less chance of model error through the seemingly simplified approach and greater accuracy through relative comparison, except with comparative states or regions. Comparing host and same country sister states or regions offers a somewhat precise picture of

21

economic effects attributable to the Olympics, because countrywide effects are held constant, which may offer a more precise model than Billings and Holladay. 4.1 Methodological Considerations Economic impact studies are predictive and have inherent bias because they are created in favor of hosting the Games, misrepresenting and overestimating many benefits through theoretical and mathematical errors. Olympic impact studies used to be computed by simplistic Input-Output models***********, but more recently economists have been using CGE models, which are relatively more accurate, but still have a large number of deficiencies. Mathesons work Mega-events: The Effect of the Worlds Biggest Sporting Events On Local, Regional, and National Economies, examines the main effects that the modeling used in impact studies ignores. Modeling typically ignores or overstates the substitution effect, understates or ignores the crowding-out effect, especially in already popular tourist destinations, and incorrectly calculates the effect of expenditures by overestimating the mathematical money multiplier. ************ Aside from intangibles, such as prestige or personal utility, the majority of cities describe their reason to host based on urban economic development, or the potential to increase international awareness. However, given modeling inaccuracies and the IOCs role in bidding, cities will often not obtain their desired outcome. I initially chose control cities located in the same country as host cities based upon greatest similarity to host cities at the time of the Olympics in size, growth rate, and
*********** Input-Output models (I-O models) use production and input-output tables, but ignore regression

analysis that is used for behavior equations, such as substitution and crowding out effects. Evangelia Kasimati, Economic Aspects and the Summer Olympics: A Review of Related Research, International Journal of Tourism Research 5 (2003): 433-44, http://people.bath.ac.uk/ecpek/index_files/Paper1.pdf. Ibid.442-444. Victor Matheson, Mega-events: The Effect of the Worlds Biggest Sporting Events On Local, Regional, and National Economies, College of Holy Cross Faculty Research Series (October 2006): 131, http://casgroup.fiu.edu/pages/docs/2744/1277904942_matheson_events.pdf. Ibid.10 ************ Ibid.8-9.

22

industry. However, because the data are not available, I will compare the states or regions, which are the most comparable. Because the host or sister city is the largest city among the studied area, an effect due to the Olympics may be visible, and the variables still inherently control for countrywide confounders, such as Spain entering the EU in 1986. The economic effects of the Olympics are evaluated over a nine-year time period, four years before the Olympics, the year the Games occurred, and four years after the Olympics to best judge both short and long-term effects. The nine-year period is chosen based on the work of Matheson, which notes the Olympic effect eventually become ambiguous after the Games conclude. This studys use of dependent variables, construction, tourism and financial services, is still fairly theoretically similar to Giesecke and Madden, with the aim of capturing any Olympic effects by studying the change and growth in a wide variety of industries. However, as mentioned earlier, the dependent variables will instead be state or regional comparisons.


See Appendix A Victor

Matheson, Mega-events: The Effect of the Worlds Biggest Sporting Events On Local, Regional, and National Economies, College of Holy Cross Faculty Research Series (October 2006): 131, http://casgroup.fiu.edu/pages/docs/2744/1277904942_matheson_events.pdf.

23

4.2 Ideal Data Collection

While this paper aims to examine the monetary impact of the Games through the potential increase in construction, tourism, and financial services industry growth at a comparative city level, any changes attributable to the Olympics may be too small to see. As all of the host and sister cities have large economies, factors beyond the Games can also drive growth in construction, tourism, and financial services income. In construction, for instance, at the same time Olympic development takes place, hundreds of other buildings and projects are happening at the same time. If Games related construction is a small part of the citys construction GDP, change on a state/region level will be even harder to see. For example, Barcelona, the largest city in Catalonia, makes up 30 percent of Catalonias GDP, which may not be enough to see Barcelonas construction economic impact on the region. The same idea applies to tourists visiting the city and spending money, as well as financial holdings and investment. Hotels, restaurants and tourist attractions are constructed and used mostly for tourists visiting the city, not because of the 10-day Olympic event. If economic growth is hard to see on the city level, it will be difficult to see changes attributable to the Olympics, even when cities such as Atlanta make up 65 percent of state GDP.************* Overall, for all industries studied in this paper, the Olympics are only a small proportion of that industrys GDP relative to other factors and the overall economy. Thus, it is likely, compared to the main driving forces of the construction, tourism, and financial services, the Olympics has a very small impact that may not be visible at a city or state level. However, the main factors that drive construction, tourism and financial services GDP are in a sense held almost constant because they will similarly impact the industries before and
See *************

Appendix A See Appendix A

24

after the Olympics. Most people will similarly visit and move to host cities completely independent of the Olympics, as they did before the Games were announced. Because these trends will likely be steady before and after the Games, any small variation in GDP may be due to them, because other changes are in a sense constant. If there is a true difference in construction, tourism or financial services GDP caused by hosting there should be a significant difference between the changes in GDP from host to sister city because the Olympic city should have more people come to visit, stay for longer periods of time, and move to the city beyond normal growth patterns and trajectories. A same-country sister city comparison methodology will best show if any change in studied industries is due to the Olympics, however, there was not enough useable data to run complete models for any of the Olympic Games. In the Spain, the United States, and Australia construction, tourism and financial services data were not available at a city level for any necessary 9-year periods, as confirmed by government sources and independent economists in each country. Because city level data are not available, the study will provide state/region proxies, which are most similar. However, ideal data will also be described to best understand proxy data shortcomings. While city level data is ideal, based on data availability, state level data most similar to city level data is used.

In an email message to the author on January 17, 2012 the Bureau of Economic Analysis economist

Ralph Rodriguez confirmed that GDP by metropolitan area series only exists from 2001-2010. Ralph Rodriguez, email message to author, January 17,2012. In an email message to the author on January 19, 2012 Spanish economist Levi Perez confirmed that municipality data likely does not exist for 1988-1996. This was later confirmed by a different Spanish economist Jaume Garcia. Levi Perez, email message to the author, January 19, 2012. Juame Garcia, email message to the author, February 6, 2012. The Australian Board of Statistics (ABS) confirmed that statistical area data does not exist for the necessary dates. Australian Board of Statistics, National Regional Profile: Past and Future Releases, Australian Board of Statistics, http://www.abs.gov.au/AUSSTATS/abs@nrp.nsf/Lookup/Past+Future+Issues20062010?OpenDocument&tabname=Past%20Future%20Issues&prodno=LGA17200&issue=20062010&num=&view=&(accessed March 9, 2012).

25

Ideal dependent variable data would be aggregated GDP for construction, tourism, and financial services. Construction GDP would include building construction, heavy engineering, and special contractors construction income.************** Within the variable there would be three costs: all infrastructure built solely for the Olympics, the opportunity cost of building the infrastructure solely for Olympic use, and infrastructure that would be built regardless of the Olympics, but may have been altered or created on an expedited timescale. Opportunity cost is money that would have been spent elsewhere if the Games did not occur because the stadiums and facilities built solely for them would not be necessary. Thus, projects that would have happened are also counted in construction GDP to account for opportunity cost. Opportunity cost is often overlooked in Olympic economic modeling, but it is important to consider because cities could have spent money used for the Olympics elsewhere, which is why it would be included in construction GDP. Additionally, after the event, construction GDP may grow because, as a longterm effect, more people are moving to the host city because of Olympic awareness, which can be seen through deviation in typical growth trends. Tourism GDP would include income from hotels and other accommodations, restaurants, gaming, and tourist attractions. While tourism is used to explain prestige there are other measures which are also considered prestige, such as trade and the number of new conferences. Data for these ideas do not exist for the necessary years at the state level, thus prestige will be narrowly defined as tourism. However, it seems likely that if a city increases prestige and therefore awareness from hosting the Olympics, there will be a large increase in visitors and tourist expenditures. When people visit a city to see the Games, aside from money spent on the physical events, they spend money on accommodations, eating out at different restaurants, going ************** Heavy engineering includes highways and other infrastructure; special contractors include contractors hired for specific specialty building tasks. 26

to see other events such as plays and local professional sports, and visit various visitor sites such as museums and theme parks. All of this contributes to the studys tourism GDP variable that captures spending due to the Olympics, as well as spending that would otherwise occur. If the Olympics increase the change in tourism GDP, as with any change in GDP, it will be visible through normal growth pattern divergences. Financial services GDP would include income from financial services such as depository institutions and investment offices income. Financial service is used as a long-term economic impact variable. In theory, hosting the Olympics leads to an increase in awareness and popularity, and possible later on an increase in general growth because more people are moving to the host city and more people are visiting the area. Financial services tries to capture the idea that more people are moving into the area and possibly investing in the host city, thus the banks, investment and holding offices will have a significant change in GDP over time aside from usual growth trends. 4.3 Independent Variable Ideal Data Collection For infrastructure, my predictor variables would ideally be city construction employment rate per year, the number of construction firms in business per year, property values, residential construction permits, and non-residential construction permits. These variables would help paint a picture of the changes in the citys construction industry GDP. Construction employment rate and the number of construction firms in business per year both drive construction GDP; the more companies in the business will likely lead to an increase in GDP because the industry is more productive. Similarly, the more people employed in the industry, the more buildings and structures they can produce. Higher property values may indicate a level of citywide growth and desirability to locate businesses and homes there, implying more building starts and an increase

27

in GDP. A similar, but more specific measure than property value is residential and nonresidential permits, which show the number of new construction projects for individuals and businesses. All of the independent construction variables should show increases or decreases in construction GDP change. There are a number of other predictors, which affect construction GDP, and need to be held constant to isolate the effects of the chosen predictor variables. Because I am comparing same-country sister cities, countrywide factors that would influence construction GDP, such as Spain entering the EU, which would likely effect factors such as construction material prices and trade openness, will be held constant. However, there still may be differences between cities that need to be taken into consideration to make an accurate and unbiased comparison. If possible I would hold steady dissimilarities in land and material prices. If they are significantly higher in one city compared to the other there may be a decrease in building and infrastructure creation, decreasing construction GDP. Control variables will hold constant outside effects that cause difference in construction GDP among comparable states due to non-Olympic effects. For prestige, my predictor variables would ideally be city level employment and number of firms per year for the hospitality industry (hotels and accommodations), restaurants, entertainment (amusement parks and tourist attractions) and recreation (sporting and entertainment events), number of hotels and occupancy rate per year, and the number of flights to the city as a final destination. These variables would help demonstrate the changes in the citys overall tourism GDP. Employment and number of tourist related firms in business per year both raise tourism income because visitors need places to stay, restaurants to eat, and activities to keep them interested. Generally, a city with more hotels, restaurants and attractions will have something for all types of visitors. Since wealthier tourists spend more money, cities will likely

28

try to continuously upgrade or build new facilities, which will increase tourism expenditures. Because hotels are only built when there is needalso reflected by a high occupancy ratean increase in the number of hotels and accommodations, should be reflected by an increasing economic growth rate. The number of flights arriving in a city per day, assuming the city is a destination city and not a connection city (for example a large percentage of international and domestic flights connect through Atlanta everyday where Atlanta is not the final destination) is another good indicator of visitors, because international and many out of state tourists will fly into the city. All tourism independent variables aim to demonstrate the change in industry GDP and hope to isolate any affects attributable to the Olympics. To see if an Olympic effect exists for tourism, I need to control for other major factors that will affect GDP. As previously mentioned, countrywide factors such as flight prices and ease of travel for other EU member countries caused by Spain entering the EU will affect both Catalonia and Madrid AC and thus will not influence tourism GDP. However, there still may be differences between cities that affect tourism related GDP. If possible I would hold steady differences in substitute destinations, number of major cities nearby. Substitute destination and number of major cities nearby are closely related because depending on location, one city may split the visitor market share because there are other similar popular locations nearby, while the other city dominates their market share. Controlling for outside between states not attributable to the Olympics will help isolate the potential Games related impact on tourism expenditures. For the financial services industry, my predictor variables would ideally be city level financial services employment, including depository and non-depository institutions, trading firms, and international banks, the number of banks and similar firms in business by year, and number and type of investments made per year. These variables would help show the changes in

29

a citys financial industry income, which is used as a long-term indicator of hosting the Olympics. It may be that more people or firms chose to move to/invest in the host city because of the Olympics. An increase in banking firms and employment (depository and non-depository institutions) reflects an overall demand from citizens and businesses to hold money. Trading firms and hedge funds handle domestic and international investors, which shows both domestic and international individual business economic growth, and may imply an increased interest in a certain city or the overall state. International banks may show the international awareness of a city or state. As with an increasing number of firms, an increase in employment also indicates positive financial services and overall economic growth, and increased state awareness at the national and international level. Similarly, the number of investments per year made by individuals and businesses reveals an interest and commitment to economic growth. Financial services independent variables should explain growth in financial services GDP. To isolate an Olympic impact on financial services GDP, I will control for non-Olympic related effects that impact financial services GDP. The biggest potential difference between cities is economic growth. Economic growth drives all other industries such as tourism and construction that use financial services; it is already held constant through same-country comparisons.

30

4.4 Data Collection

Because data are not available at the city level, I will be using proxy data from states/regions. For dependent variables in Spain I will use autonomous communities (Catalonia for Barcelona and Madrid AC for Madrid). In the United States I will study statewide dependent variables (Georgia for Atlanta and North Carolina for Charlotte). Similarly in Australia, I will examine variable data among state/territories (New South Wales for Sydney and Victoria for Melbourne). Because the dependent variables are measured fairly similarly and all aim to show industry income (GDP, adjusted gross added value*************** and adjusted factor income), the terms GDP and income will be used to represent all different types of industry income.

4.4.1 Spain Variables Below dependent and independent variables and sources are described for each Olympic Game. In Spain all of the dependent variables for Catalonia and Madrid AC use 1990 euros as the base year. Data from 1988-1996 are inflation-adjusted to 1990 Euros for best comparison.

In size similar to a large U.S. state Also similar to the size of some U.S. states Value added in production by labor and capital within a state. Bureau

of Economic Analysis, Gross Domestic Product (GDP) by State, Bureau of Economic Analysis, http://bea.gov/regional/definitions/nextpage.cfm?key=Gross%20domestic%20product%20(GDP)%20by%20state (accessed March 9, 2012). *************** Output minus Intermediate Consumption at purchaser price (accounts for over 90% of GDP). Eurostat, Glossary: Gross Value Added at Market Prices, Eurostat,http://epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/statistics_explained/index.php/Glossary:Value_added (accessed March 9, 2012). Equivalent to gross domestic product less taxes plus subsidies on production and imports. Australian Board of Statistics, Glossary, Australian Board of Statistics,http://www.abs.gov.au/Ausstats/abs@.nsf/glossary/5220.0 (accessed March 9, 2012). In 1990 the Euro did not exist. For methodological changes to create the 1990 Euro values see Appendix B.

31

The proxy infrastructure variable for Spain is construction and civil engineering works gross added value at market prices, hereby known as construction GAV. The prestige variable is a gross added value at market prices aggregate of recuperation,**************** repair, trade, accommodation, restaurants, foodstuff, beverages, and tobacco. The financial variable is the gross added value at market prices of imputed production of bank services, hereby known as the financial GAV. The construction independent variables for Catalonia and Madrid AC demonstrate changes in construction GAV at the autonomous community level. The predictor variables are new residential building permits, total gross investment and total net capital stock for construction, engineering, rental of buildings, and residential capital.***************** As explained in the ideal data section, building permits can show growth in construction income. Investment and capital stock investment imply a long-term commitment to economic growth for individuals and businesses through equipment and new structure creation, which similarly suggests positive growth in the amount of businesses and people coming to the autonomous community for business and travel.

See footnote 57 for explanation of gross added value at market price. Instituto Nacional de Estadistica, Spanish Regional Accounts, Instituto Nacional de Estadistica,http://www.ine.es/jaxi/menu.do?type=pcaxis&path=/t35/p010/a1996&file=pcaxis (accessed March 9, 2012). Interest receivable minus interest payments. Dennis Fixler, Measuring the Services of Commercial Banks in the Nipas: Changes in Concepts and Methods, OECD, www.oecd.org/dataoecd/10/13/24333573.doc. Public and private un-depreciated total invest value of business assets in this industry. Business Dictionary, s.v. Gross Investment, http://www.businessdictionary.com/definition/grossinvestment.html (accessed March 12, 2012). Net capital stock is the sum of the written-down values of all the fixed assets still in use is described as the net capital stock. OECD Stats, Net Capital Stock, OECD Stats, http://stats.oecd.org/glossary/detail.asp?ID=1752 (accessed March 9, 2012).
****************


***************** Instituto

Nacional de Estadistica, Spanish Regional Accounts, Instituto Nacional de Estadistica,http://www.ine.es/jaxi/menu.do?type=pcaxis&path=/t35/p010/a1996&file=pcaxis.

32

The tourism independent variables for Catalonia and Madrid AC explain growth through change in autonomous community tourism GAV. Predictor variables are the number of hotel establishments, as well as the total gross investment and total net capital stock for food, beverages, hotels and restaurants. As seen in the ideal data section the number of hotel establishments can show increases in tourism GDP change. Investment and capital stock aggregated for tourism strongly imply long-term development and growth for major domestic and international tourism industries in hotels, restaurant and related tourism sales which could be caused by an increased in destination viability. Financial independent variables for the autonomous communities of Catalonia and Madrid AC will determine change in financial GAV. The predictor variables include number of banks and credit institutions, and investment and capital stock for credit and insurance institutions. As seen in the ideal data section the number of firms can impact growth in financial income. Investment and capital stock for credit and insurance institutions indicates overall economic stimulation and a long-term trend in growth and productivity for the autonomous community.

4.4.2 United States Variables In the United States all of the dependent variables for Georgia and North Carolina are measured in real GDP by state, adjusted for inflation from 1992-2000 to 1997 US dollars. The infrastructure variable for the United States is general contractors and operative builders, heavy construction, except buildings, and special trade contractors. Heavy engineering includes highways and infrastructure projects; special contractors
include specific building projects not included under general contractors. Bureau of Economic Analysis, Construction, Bureau of Economic Analysis,http://bea.gov/regional/definitions/nextpage.cfm?key=Construction (accessed March 9, 2012).

33

The prestige variable is a real GDP aggregate of air transportation, transit and ground passenger transportation, arts, amusement and recreation (performing arts, spectator sports, motion pictures, museums and related services), and accommodations. The financial variable is a real GDP aggregate of depository and non-depository institutions, securities and commodities brokers, and holding and other investment offices. The independent variables that indicate changes in construction industry GDP are industry employment per year, the number of construction firms in business per year, and residential building permits. Industry employment and number of firms includes general contractors and operative builders, heavy construction, except buildings, and special trade contractors.****************** As discussed in the ideal data section employment, number of firms, and residential permits can indicate economic growth, and lead to an increase in construction GDP. The independent variables that predict changes in tourism related GDP are tourism industry employment per year, the number of tourism related firms in business per year, and the number of hotels and occupancy rates per year. Employment and number of firms are based upon data aggregated from: eating and drinking places, hotels and other lodging places, motion pictures, amusement and recreation services, museums, botanical and zoological


Bureau

of Economic Analysis, Interactive Data, Bureau of Economic Analysis, http://bea.gov/itable/ (accessed March 9, 2012). Bureau of Economic Analysis, Securities, Commodity Contracts, Investments, Bureau of Economic Analysis, http://bea.gov/regional/definitions/nextpage.cfm?key=Securities,%20commodity%20contracts,%20invest ments (accessed March 9,2012). ****************** Bureau of Economic Analysis, Interactive Data, Bureau of Economic Analysis, http://bea.gov/itable/.

34

gardens. As seen in the ideal data section employment, number of firms, number of hotels and occupancy rates all can show growth or contraction in tourism GDP. Independent variables that show changes in financial services GDP include financial employment and the number of firms in business per year aggregated from depository and nondepository institutions, and holding and other investment offices. As shown in the ideal data collection, employment and number of firms could lead to an increase in that states financial services GDP and reflects an overall economic growth among businesses and individuals.

4.4.3 Australia Variables In Australia, the dependent variables for New South Wales (NSW) and Victoria are measured as total factor income at current prices from 1996-2004, with a base year of 1996. The proxy infrastructure variable is construction total factor income at current prices. The proxy prestige variable is the total factor income at current prices of accommodation and food services and arts and recreation services******************* by state. The proxy financial variable is the total factor income at current prices of financial and insurance services. The independent construction variables for NSW and Victoria show the change in industry income at the state/territory level through construction employment and dwelling unit
Ibid. Australian

Ibid.

Board of Statistics, Glossary, Australian Board of Statistics,http://www.abs.gov.au/Ausstats/abs@.nsf/glossary/5220.0 (accessed March 9, 2012). ******************* Ibid. Ibid.

35

approvals, which are similar to residential construction permits. As noted in the ideal data collection employment and construction permits indicate changes in construction income. Independent tourism variables for NSW and Victoria show changes in industry income at the state/territory level through an aggregate of accommodations and food services, arts and recreation employment, number of hotels, and average length of stay at accommodations. Employment statistics and the number of hotels, as indicated in ideal data collection, will show changes in tourism GDP. The average length of stay at accommodation implies people are spending more money in the state because they are staying longer, which leads to industry growth. The financial independent variables for Australia explain changes in financial services income through financial and insurance employment. Increases in employment may indicate an increase in businesses, possibly driven by an influx of people moving to the area due to the Olympics, as reflected in financial services expenditures. In Spain, the United States and Australia all independent variables are used to show growth or contractions in dependent variables industry GDP. By comparing relative changes, it is hoped to see if short and long-term economic effects of the Olympics, which might cause changes in visitors and firms who move to the Olympic area, exist.

36

5 Model and Analysis In this study, each of these Olympic Games has three types of linear regression models. Regressions are run on each state for construction, tourism and financial models, and then compared to the same-country, sister-state models. All regression equations, models and diagnostic tests can be seen in Appendix C. Each model has a number of potential issues from mathematical changes to model assumptions. Mathematical changes that make data compatible for analysis can be found in Appendix B. Because measurement adjustments made for the study or through country data systemssuch as the U.S. data measurement switching from the SIC to NAICSsome regressions may exhibit influential outliers, which means the removal of that point will significantly change and normalize results. Some of these changes, particularly for Spain, may lead to autocorrelationwhere data are dependent on time and spacewhich will be overlooked because autocorrelation will not inhibit any effect the Olympics have on change in industry GDP. Additionally, each model ignores the linear model assumption of multicollinearity because while using highly correlated variables will not show the importance of the individual variables, the study is looking for an overall change in GDP due to the Olympics, which, if existent will still be visible with multicollinearity. Overall, necessary mathematical compatibility changes might lead to autocorrelation and multicollinearity, which will be disregarded based on study aims.

An example: If the data 1995 Barcelona tourism GDP is an influential outlier, it is significantly

different from all other years in change in GDP, meaning it is inherently different from the other data points. In this paper, the cases appear to be due to measurement differences and changes. Multicollinearity: two predictor variables are very highly correlated

37

Other model considerations include the type and number of predictor variables. While every variable combination is run in each model, models with R-squared values above .95 were not considered because real-world data with numbers that high indicate an identity, meaning the predictors completely explain the outcome/ are the same as the outcome, which given the variables tested, does not seem logically possible.******************** Additionally, since data are being compared across models each pair needs to use the same model for true comparison. Because of the R-squared values and model comparisons, many models will not include all possible variables. Finally, only countrywide effects and variables in the model will be held constant. Effects such as Spain entering the EU, which should have a much larger effect on industries than the Olympics, will be held constant because all states are within the same country. Similarly the overall economic growth trend should be held constant. As the Arthur Andersen study notes, at the time of their Olympic Game the state of Georgia and Spain are in cycles of economic downtown, which perpetuate throughout the country. If one state is experiencing stunted or negative economic growth, it is generally accepted that the other states within that country will experience a similar trend. Overall, all major differences between states from economic growth to countrywide effects will be held constant.


********************

In an email message to the author on March 10,2012 Allen Sanderson noted models with .95 or above R-squared values can be considered an identity and variables used in this study will not explain all of the outcome variables. Allen Sanderson, email message to the author, March 10, 2012. CREA/Arthur Andersen. Economic Impact Study of the Sydney 2000 Olympic Games.5-6.

38

5.1 Model Implications Overview The studys Olympic model results suggest that the economic effects of the Olympics to create positive economic growth may be a myth. Regressions run to see the economic impact of the Olympics through change in industry GDP unsurprisingly varied for each set of Games; as noted in the history section, while these Games are the most similar, at the same time each Game takes place under unique circumstances. Furthermore, because each set of regressions for the different Olympic Games do not have the same models, the models are not completely comparable. Overall, despite model differences, it appears the 1992 Barcelona Games could have lead to a positive change in construction GDP growth, but all other regressions and models for the Barcelona, Atlanta, and Sydney Games showed no difference or negative growth when compared to control state/region models.

39

5.2 1992 Barcelona Games Analysis 5.2.1 Spain Construction Spain Construction Catalonia Coefficient Final Model Year 406,197 P-Value (.05) .001 Madrid Coefficient 213,258 P-Value (.05) .031

Residential Construction Permits Adjusted R-squared Value

.8722

.9284

Catalonia experiences a significantly higher positive change in construction income compared to Madrid that may be attributable to the Olympics. Year, which tracks changes in time, significantly predicts some of the change in construction GDP for both Catalonia and Madrid. For Catalonia, with each year increase, GDP increases by 406,197 euro. Over the course of the model, from 1988 to 1996 GDP will increase by 3,249,576 euro, which accounts for 60.15% of the change in Catalonias 1996 GDP. While the effect of individual years cannot be examined due to model issues, overall, year accounts for a significant amount of the change in GDP when adjusted for inflation. If attributable to the Olympics, the GDP change could be due to Olympic building in pre-Olympic years, and increased awareness post-Olympics which may lead to an influx of tourists and people moving to the area, and, necessarily, more construction. Ideally, the model would allow a year-by-year breakdown, to look for specific trends, such as those described above. While year is a significant variable in the model, it must also be compared to Madrid to see if Madrid experiences a similar change, which would imply hosting

40

the Olympics does not have a significant impact on construction GDP, because both countries experienced similar growth. The corresponding model for Madrid also indicates that year has a significant impact on construction GDP. For every year increase, construction GDP increases by 213,258 euro, which over an eight-year change is 1,706,064 euro, or 32.88% of the change in Madrids 1996 GDP. Year account for about 28% more of Catalonias amount of change in GDP compared to Madrids change, which suggests that over the nine-year span Catalonia has more growth, which, holding countrywide indicators constant, could be due to the Olympics. While a yearly breakdown cannot be assessed, it seems Olympic facility construction, and possibly a rise in firms and people moving to Catalonia as a result of the Olympics, could account for some of the difference in growth. 5.2.2 Spain Tourism Spain Tourism Catalonia Coefficient Final Model Number of Hotel Rooms Total Gross Investment Adjusted R-squared Value 205.78 P-Value (.05) .017 Madrid Coefficient 380.40 P-Value (.05) .000

.5256

.9203

The number of hotels does not significantly impact Catalonia or Madrid change in tourism GDP growth. The model for Catalonia and Madrid tourism shows that for both regions, the number of hotel rooms explains a significant change in tourism GDP. Models including year were considered an identity of tourism GDP, and will not be considered. When the number of hotel rooms increases by 1%, GDP increases by 205.78 euro. Compared to overall GDPat its

41

lowest in 1988 is over 4 million euroit appears that even a 50% increase in number of rooms (from 181,262 rooms to 271,893 rooms, which if one hotel is taken to be 250 rooms is an increase in 1,087 hotels) is only an increase of 10,294 euro, or far less than 1% of tourism GDP. Because hotel rooms explain less than 1% of the amount of change in tourism GDP, it appears that the Olympics did not have an effect on hotel and possibly tourism growth. However, Madrids model will be examined to see if hotel rooms have a greater impact on the change in Madrids tourism GDP. The number of hotel rooms accounts for a significant change in Madrids tourism GDP. For a 1% increase in number of hotels, tourism GDP increases by 380.4 euro. With a 50% increase in 1988 hotels rooms from 33,677 to 50,516 rooms, or the equivalent of 202 new hotels, hotel rooms account for less than 1% of the amount of change in tourism GDP. Similar to Catalonia, Madrid did not show that hotels account for some of the change in GDP growth, which suggests that the Olympics did not have a visible effect on the change in tourism GDP growth; however, the number of hotels does not account for other major aspects of the tourism industry and results must be interpreted with caution.

Hotel refers to a general place of accommodation that includes bed and breakfasts, motels, hotels, and other places of accommodations. Using 250 rooms=1 hotel 42

5.2.3 Spain Financial Services Spain Financial Services Catalonia Coefficient Final Model Year 230,394 659 .8351

Madrid P-Value (.05) .001 .024 .7498 Coefficient 641,811 P-Value (.05) .022

Number of Banking Institutions Adjusted R-squared Value

The financial services model indicates that Madrid experiences 51% greater change in growth in nine years that Catalonia, implying the Olympics could have hindered Catalonias industry growth. Both year and number of banking institutes are significant variables for Catalonia. For each year increase, GDP increases by 230,294 euro. Over the nine-year period Catalonia GDP increases by 1,842,352 euro, which account for 41% of the change in financial services GDP. Additionally, a 1% increase in the number of banking institutes (69 banking institutions for 1988) increases GDP by 659 euro. Over the nine-year period studied, the number of banks increases by about 1000 at its peak, but then declines over time. Given the banking trends, it seems highly unlikely to have a more than a 10% increase in number of banks over a nine-year period (676 banks, and only a 6590 euro increase), which suggests that the effect of banking institutions is very small and can be discounted. Over time, more people and firms may come to Catalonia because of an increase of popularity, international awareness, or some other reason, which then leads to a heightened demand for banking services. However, the results must be compared to Madrid to see the model in a relative context. Madrids model shows year causes a significant amount of change in financial GDP. A year increase leads to an increase in GDP by 641,811 euro. By the end of the nine-year period,

43

the yearly change accounts for 92% of the change in financial services GDP. This is 51% more than in Catalonia, which implies that Madrid had a much larger growth rate over this period while not hosting the Olympics. Madrids much larger growth rate compared to Catalonia as seen by the impact of year on the change in financial services GDP might infer that the Olympics negatively impacted Catalonias financial services growth rate. At the same time, it seems likely that the Olympics causing people/firms to move into an area and invest in local institutes may be small and therefore difficult to see on a regional level, thus differences may be due to factors not considered in the scope of the study.

5.2.4 Spain Conclusions The Barcelona Olympics seems to have a positive influence the construction industry, no impact on tourism, and a negative effect on financial services for Catalonia. Change in time accounted for about 38% more of the increase in Catalonias construction GDP growth than Madrids. Tourism models show no difference between Catalonia and Madrid, which indicates the Olympics do not significantly impact the number of hotels, and through this a lack of tourism demand growth. Finally, financial services implied that Madrid experience greater growth without hosting the Olympics than Catalonia.

44

5.3 1996 Atlanta Game Analysis 5.3.1 U.S. Construction U.S. Construction Georgia Coefficient Final Model Number of Residential Permits Adjusted R-squared Value 179.12 .9010 P-Value (.05) .000 North Carolina Coefficient 176.36 .8954 P-Value (.05) .030

Based upon the narrow variable, residential permits, the U.S. construction models show negligible significance on the change in construction GDP. Thus, non-residential building is not measured, which is vital to the Olympics and would likely explain more change in industry income. As seen by the small coefficient, a 1% increase in number of residential construction permits (460 new permits for 1996) leads to a 179 US dollar increase in GDP. A 100% increase in the number of construction permits, which seems unrealistic for a 9-year period (there was about a 50% increase from 1992-2000), still only leads to a 17,900 US dollar increase. This increase accounts for far less than 1% of change in construction GDP over the studied timeframe. It appears that based on model constraints and the final model, any Olympic effect from the change in construction income does not exist, or is not visible. The North Carolina model shows similar results; a 1% increase in number of residential construction permits (499 new permits) produces an increase in GDP by 176 US dollars. Even with a 100% increase in permits, there will be no visible effect on the change in construction GDP. Given that residential building permits only capture the long-term effect caused by people moving to an area overtime, it does not capture a potential Olympic effect from before the Olympics, which might be seen through

45

an increasing number of firms (considered an identity), or nonresidential construction permits.********************* While no difference can be seen between Georgia and North Carolina in the long run, there may be better models to judge whether there is a short-term Olympic effect. 5.3.2 U.S. Tourism U.S. Tourism Georgia Coefficient Final Model Number of Firms Adjusted R-squared Value 380.5 .7850 P-Value (.05) .001 North Carolina Coefficient 191.5 .4412 P-Value (.05) .030

The number of tourism related firms leads to a insignificant change in industry GDP growth for both Georgia and North Carolina. Most models run for Georgia and North Carolina either have R-squared values that imply an identity, or when variables are significant, they account for far less than 1% of changes in tourism GDP. While year appeared to have a large effect for both Georgia and North Carolina, every model with year appeared to be an identity. However, a number of variable changes logically occur over time, especially number of hotel rooms, employees, and number of firms (from hotels to amusement industries). Since the study is looking at changes in tourism GDP, the number of firms should provide the most sensical, concrete change, because an increase in hotel rooms eventually leads to new hotels, but that does not account for other tourism industries, and increases in employees will lead to new firms, yet the number of employees to create a new firm vary. Given R-squared constraints and the levels of data, the model predictor is number of firms. For a 1% increase in the number of firms (205 new firms), there is a corresponding GDP increase of 380.5 US dollars. A 20% increase in the 46

number of firms (in 1988 4,111 firms) would lead to a GDP increase of 456.6 US dollars. If the number of firms increases by 100%, the GDP increase would still be less than 1% of the change in tourism GDP. Georgias modeling results are similarly mirrored by North Carolina, where the number of hotel firms also represents less than 1% of the change in tourism GDP, showing no difference between the model. Based on number of tourism businesses the Olympics did not have any significant impact Georgias tourism expenditures; at the same time North Carolina did not experience significant growth by not hosting. 5.3.3 U.S. Financial Services U.S. Financial Services Georgia Coefficient Final Model Year Number of employees Adjusted R-squared Value .9424 506,232 P-Value (.05) .000 North Carolina Coefficient 2,140,296 -295.0 .9158 P-Value (.05) .000 .027

North Carolina experiences a significantly larger change in financial services growth over time than Georgia. Each year increase leads to a 506,232 US dollar increase in Georgias financial GDP. Over the 9-year timeframe there is a 4,049,856 US dollar increase in financial GDP, accounting for 37.2% of the growth in Georgias financial GDP. Over time, people may choose to invest or move into Georgia as a result of the Atlanta Olympic Games increasing international presence and awareness. For each year change in North Carolina there is a 2,140,296 US dollar increase in GDP. For the study timeframe, there is a 17,122,368 US dollar increase in GDP, which explains 91.5%

47

of the change in financial GDP growth for North Carolina. This is a 54.3% greater increase in financial GDP growth than in Georgia. While the number of employees in financial services appears significant for North Carolina it is unimportant. For a 1% increase in employees (765 new employees, which is 7 new firms) there is a decrease in GDP by 295 dollars. With a 100% increase in employees (76,451 employees or 765 new firms) there is still only a decrease in GDP by 29,500 US dollars, or about 1/10th of a percent decrease in change in GDP growth. Because the number of employees has such a small impact on change in GDP growth it will be considered insignificant. Overall, compared to North Carolina, it appears the Olympics may have stunted Georgias long-term financial services growth.

5.3.4 U.S. Conclusions Overall, the Atlanta Olympics did not appear to create a positive change in economic growth for construction, tourism or financial services. There are a number of model issues and identity variables, which are excluded from models. The lack of differences in construction GDP change due to residential construction permits indicates the Atlanta Games did not bring more firms and people to the area in the long-run, and thus did not positively impact on the construction industry. Similarly, there is not a significant difference in tourism GDP change based on the number of firms, showing the Games did not attract a significant number of new tourism businesses; finally, financial services expenditures appears to be negatively impacted by the Olympics.

When 100 employees equal 1 new firm. 48

5.4 2000 Sydney Olympic Game 5.4.1 Australia Construction Australia Construction NSW Coefficient Final Model Year 515,927

Victoria P-Value (.05) .016 Coefficient 522,186 P-Value (.05) .012

Number of residential construction permits Adjusted R-squared Value

.5651

.7702

Time series changes in construction income show Victoria has more economic industry growth than NSW. For each year increase from 1996 to 2000 there is a 515,927 Australian dollar increase in GDP. Over the course of the 9-year period there is a total increase in GDP of 4,127,416 Australian dollars, which accounts for 23.6% of the change in construction GDP growth. Because there is not a year-by-year model available, pre-and post-Olympic trends cannot be quantified, although it seems construction would heavily increase in the years leading up to the Olympic Games because of facilities and infrastructure projects, and might drop back to normal rates after the Games. Victorias construction expenditures indicate a larger change in growth than NSWs. For each year increase, construction GDP increases by 522,186 Australian dollars. Over the course of the study there is a 4,177,488 Australian dollar increase in construction GDP due to year, which explains 37.2% of the change in Victorias construction GDP. A change in year over time predicts 13.6% more of the growth in Victorias construction GDP, when compared to NSW, which suggest Victoria has a larger growth without hosting the Olympics, implying that hosting the Olympics may have had a negative impact on Sydney construction growth.

49

5.4.2 Australia Tourism Australia Tourism NSW Coefficient Final Model Year Average Stay Adjusted R-squared Value .7810 245,754

Victoria P-Value (.05) .007 Coefficient 202,559 P-Value (.05) .035

.8812

Sydney experiences 2.9% less change in growth in tourism GDP than Victoria indicating the Olympics may have deterred visitors or somehow hindered growth over time. In NSW, every year increase leads to an increase in GDP by 245,754 Australian dollars, which over the 9-year time period leads to a GDP increase of 1,966,032 Australian dollars. The GDP change over the 9-year period accounts for 6.7% of the growth in industry income. However, Victoria experiences greater change in growth by 2.9% over the course of nineyears, indicating a small difference between the regions. A one-year change leads to an increase in GDP by 202,559 dollars, which is 1,620,472 Australian dollars, or 9.6% of the change in GDP growth. This indicates that the Olympic year and after the Olympics may have actually deterred visitors from visiting Sydney, had some other negative impact on visitor rates, or Victoria was able to better capitalize on tourism over time.

50

5.4.3 Australia Financial Services Australia Financial NSW Coefficient Final Model Year Number of Employees Adjusted R-squared Value .9573 1,399,820

Victoria P-Value (.05) .000 Coefficient 845,870 P-Value (.05) .000

.9622

The Australian financial model for NSW and Victoria only has two predictors available, all of which appear to be identities of financial GDP, which makes interpreting the values unnecessary because of real world constraints that indicate other variables better truly predict the change in financial services GDP. The financial services model is already difficult to evaluate for an Olympic effect because it is solely a long-term effect, which combined with the inability of the model to differentiate between year-by-year trends makes it difficult to see whether pre-and post-Olympic tendencies differ. If the Olympics lead to a change in growth in financial services GDP it seems likely that it is because of an increase in the number of people moving and investing in an area, which leads to more banking institutions and employees. If year is a significant variable, for NSW, a year increase leads to a 1,399,820 Australian dollar increase in financial GDP over the 9-year period, which account for 37.7% of the change in NSWs financial GDP growth. Victoria shows a slightly higher amount of overall growth; while a year increase leads to an 845,870 Australian dollar increase in GDP, or 40.0% over the 9-year study. Overall, modeling identity issues, variable selection and the aggregate year variable may cover any potential significant differences between the two states.

51

5.4.4 Australia Conclusions

While there are some model identity issues, overall, the models indicate that Victoria experiences significantly more growth than NSW for construction and tourism industries, which implies the Olympics do not lead to positive economic change in those industries.

6 Summary and Conclusions Overall the regression models run may show a narrow scope of results. As mentioned in the model and analysis section, there are a number of mathematical and model changes that could be problematic, and interpretation must proceed with caution. Because there could be some amount of inaccuracy, it is not possible to be completely certain that the 1992, 1996 and 2000 Olympic Games lead to almost no positive economic growth, and in some cases hinder growth. Only the 1992 Barcelona Olympic Games model indicates a possible positive economic effect due to the Olympics through change in construction GDP. All other models show that the Olympics does not have a significantly positive impact on the change in industry growth when compared to the control model, and in some cases, the control model accounts for greater change in growth than the Olympic model. However, it must be noted that only three industries were studied: construction, tourism and financial services, which try to represent the idea of infrastructure, prestige and financial growth that many cities vie for when submitting bids to host the Olympics, thus non-economic reasons are ignored.

52

7 Policy Implications

Policy implications may be limited because of the somewhat narrow scope of the project, combined with potential error due to mathematical changes and variable issues discussed in the model analysis section. Additionally, because the variables across Olympic models differ, all of the Games are not completely comparable. With these issues in mind, all interpretations must be examined with extreme caution. On the whole, aside from the 1992 Barcelona Games construction, it appears the Olympics did not have a positive impact on change in GDP for construction, tourism and financial services for states/regions where the Olympics took place compared to states/regions where the Olympics did not take place for the 1992, 1996 and 2000 Olympic Games. Aside from the Barcelona Games possibly positively impacting the economic change in construction growth for Catalonia, if there is no overall difference in change in construction, tourism and financial services growth between states, it seems possible that no change exists between cities, and the Olympics have a very small impact. The Barcelona, Atlanta and Sydney Games were chosen for this study because all of the Games hoped to use the Olympics to achieve economic growth and development, which means if the Olympics did not lead to that growth (at least through three major industries studied that seem to target economic development) the host cities should have chosen to construct facilities most needed that might lead to substantial economic growth, and pursue other ways to attract more tourist and people to the area such as renovating historic areas, and building new facilities such as attractions and schools. Since tourism and financial services are long-term growth indicators, investing in projects other than the Olympics may bring more people to visit and move into the area. While the variables have flaws as described above, all of the financial services models and the Sydney

53

tourism model, which could be considered the most complete tourism model, showed that the control state/region leads to greater change in industry GDP growth. This seems to confirm that if a city, and its state/region are hoping for economic growth and development, pursuing options other than the Olympics may lead to more growth and development. Overall, while the analysis results provides a red flag to cities considering bidding for the Olympics, it does not capture non-economic reasons for hosting the Olympics, and aims to open the eyes of potential bidders. From the analysis results, it seems constituents, developers, hotels and those who stand to make a profit (according to economic impact studies) should not take study numbers at face value that promise vast amounts of extra profit garnered by hosting the Games. The economic impact studies are misleading; while there could be profit for developers, restaurants and others involved, the studies greatly amplify the possibilities, as seen through the relative comparison between host cities and control cities. The purpose of this analysis is increase constituents awareness to the economic impact and development that can or cannot be expected as a result of hosting the Olympics or other mega-events, such as the World Cup or Super Bowl. Additionally, the analysis does not account for non-economic reasons to host the Olympics, such as pride, showing off the city and all it has to offer, and personal utility, such as the fun of being in an Olympic city and watching the Games. In the end, the results raise concerns about the economic benefit promised by impact studies to those with a vested monetary interest, and hopes to help cities consider their reasons for wanting to host the Olympics and be open with all constituents.

54

References

Australian Board of Statistics. 2000 Year Book Australia. Australian Board of Statistics.http://www.ausstats.abs.gov.au/Ausstats/subscriber.nsf/0/CA25687100069892CA2568 89000E7506/$File/13010_2000.pdf(accessed March 9, 2012). Australian Board of Statistics. Glossary. Australian Board of Statistics.http://www.abs.gov.au/Ausstats/abs@.nsf/glossary/5220.0 (accessed March 9, 2012). Australian Board of Statistics. National Regional Profile: Melbourne (statistical Division). Australian Board of Statistics.http://www.abs.gov.au/ausstats/abs@nrp.nsf/lookup/205Main+Features120062010(accessed March 9, 2012). Australian Board of Statistics, National Regional Profile: Past and Future Releases, Australian Board of Statistics, http://www.abs.gov.au/AUSSTATS/abs@nrp.nsf/Lookup/Past+Future+Issues20062010?OpenDocument&tabname=Past%20Future%20Issues&prodno=LGA17200&issue=20062010&num=&view=&(accessed March 9, 2012). Australian Board of Statistics. National Regional Profile: Sydney (statistical Division). Australian Board of Statistics. http://www.abs.gov.au/ausstats/abs@nrp.nsf/lookup/105Main+Features12006-2010 (accessed March 9, 2012). Billings, Stephen B. and J. Scott Holladay. "Should Cities Go for the Gold? The Long-Term Impacts of Hosting the Olympics. Economic inquiry (2011): 1-278. Print. Bureau of Economic Analysis, Construction, Bureau of Economic Analysis,http://bea.gov/regional/definitions/nextpage.cfm?key=Construction (accessed March 9, 2012). Bureau of Economic Analysis, Gross Domestic Product (GDP) by State, Bureau of Economic Analysis, http://bea.gov/regional/definitions/nextpage.cfm?key=Gross%20domestic%20product%20(GDP) %20by%20state (accessed March 9, 2012). Bureau of Economic Analysis, Interactive Data, Bureau of Economic Analysis. http://bea.gov/itable/ (accessed March 9,2012). Bureau of Economic Analysis, Securities, Commodity Contracts, Investments, Bureau of Economic Analysis, http://bea.gov/regional/definitions/nextpage.cfm?key=Securities,%20commodity%20contracts,% 20investments (accessed March 9,2012).

55

CREA/Arthur Andersen. Economic Impact Study of the Sydney 2000 Olympic Games. Sydney: Arthur Andersen (1999): 1-7.Print. Eurostat. Glossary: Gross Value Added at Market Prices. Eurostat.http://epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/statistics_explained/index.php/Glossary:Value_added(a ccessed March 9, 2012). Fixler, Dennis. Measuring the Services of Commercial Banks in the Nipas: Changes in Concepts and Methods. OECD. www.oecd.org/dataoecd/10/13/24333573.doc. Humpreys, Jeffrey M. and Michael K. Plummer, The Economic Impact On the State of Georgia of Hosting the 1996 Summer Olympics (diss., The University of Georgia, 1995), 1133, http://www.terry.uga.edu/selig/docs/olympics.pdf (accessed March 8, 2012). Giesceke, James A. and John R. Madden. "Modelling the Economic Impacts of the Sydney Olympics in Retrospect ? Game Over for the Bonanza Story?*. Economic Papers: A journal of applied economics and policy 30, No. 2 (2011): 1-230. Instituto Nacional de Estadistica. Spanish Regional Accounts. Instituto Nacional de Estadistica.http://www.ine.es/jaxi/menu.do?type=pcaxis&path=/t35/p010/a1996&file=pcaxis (ac cessed March 9, 2012). Kasimati, Evangelia. Economic Aspects and the Summer Olympics: A Review of Related Research. International Journal of Tourism Research 5 (2003): 433-44. http://people.bath.ac.uk/ecpek/index_files/Paper1.pdf. Matheson, Victor. Mega-events: The Effect of the Worlds Biggest Sporting Events On Local, Regional, and National Economies. College of Holy Cross Faculty Research Series(October 2006): 1-31. http://casgroup.fiu.edu/pages/docs/2744/1277904942_matheson_events.pdf Matheson, Victor. Upon Further Review: An Examination of Sporting Event Economic Impact Studies. Sports Journal 5, no.1 (2002): 1-5. OECD Stats. Net Capital Stock. OECD Stats. http://stats.oecd.org/glossary/detail.asp?ID=1752(accessed March 9, 2012). Passa, Dennis. A Year Later Sydney Areas Go Unused,.Free Lance Star (Sydney). September 16, 2001. Rose, Andrew K., and Mark M. Spiegel. "The Olympic Effect*." The Economic Journal 121.553 (2011): 664-665. Sanderson, Allen. Olympic Comparisons. Lecture, University of Chicago, Chicago, IL, November 12, 2011. Sanderson, Allen. Olympics Lecture. Lecture, University of Chicago, Chicago, IL, January 6, 2012.

56

Szymanski, Stefan. Playbooks And Checkbooks: An Introduction To The Economics Of Modern Sports. Princeton : Princeton University Press, 2009: 160. US Government Bureau. Georgia Demographic Profile 2000. Censtats.http://censtats.census.gov/data/GA/04013.pdf (accessed March 9, 2012).

57

Appendix A: Comparison Explanations

A.1 Spain Catalonia-Madrid Comparison: Of the autonomous communities in Spain the most comparable to Catalonia is Madrid. From 1988-1996, according to the Instituto Nacional de Stadistica, Catalonia and Madrid had the two largest GDP by autonomous communities in Spain. Barcelona and Madrid are the biggest cities with their autonomous communities, as well as the largest and most traversed nationally and internationally. While Barcelona is 30% of Catalonias GDP and Madrid is 65% of Madrid ACs economy, both are seen as premier tourist and business cities. A.2 United States Georgia-North Carolina Comparison: Only southern states were considered for comparison given their city characteristics are inherently different from northern cities and states.********************** According to the Bureau of Economic Analysis, in the earliest year measured,2002, Atlanta and Charlotte were the largest part of the states economy. Atlanta makes up 65% of Georgias economy, with Savannah, the second largest city, accounting for 4% of state GDP. Charlotte makes up 28% of North Carolinas economy, and although it is much smaller than Atlanta, the next largest city area (Durham-Chapel Hill) account for 8% of the economy.*********************** Compared to other city/state ratios, this is the closest match. Furthermore, their growth patterns are similar, from 1990-2000 Georgias population grew by 26.4%, similar to North Carolinas 21.6% growth rate. Additionally, the states have similar industry breakdowns and growth, with focuses on manufacturing and education, health and social services that make them most comparable. A.3 Australia


Instituto

Nacional de Estadistica, Spanish Regional Accounts, Instituto Nacional de Estadistica,http://www.ine.es/jaxi/menu.do?type=pcaxis&path=/t35/p010/a1996&file=pcaxis. Ibid. ********************** Allen Sanderson, Olympic Comparisons (lecture, University of Chicago, Chicago, IL, November 12, 2011). Bureau of Economic Analysis, Interactive Data, Bureau of Economic Analysis, http://bea.gov/itable/. Ibid. Ibid. *********************** Ibid. US Government Bureau, Georgia Demographic Profile 2000, Censtats,http://censtats.census.gov/data/GA/04013.pdf (accessed March 9, 2012). US Government Bureau, North Carolina Demographic Profile 2000, Censtats, http://censtats.census.gov/data/NC/04037.pdf (accessed March 9, 2012).

58

New South Wales-Victoria Comparison: Within the states, Sydney and Melbourne are the two largest cities in the country. The state populations are the two largest among all Australian states, they have the most air traffic, comparable construction, manufacturing and other industries.************************


Australian

Board of Statistics, National Regional Profile: Melbourne (statistical Division), Australian Board of Statistics, http://www.abs.gov.au/ausstats/abs@nrp.nsf/lookup/205Main+Features120062010 (accessed March 9, 2012). Australian Board of Statistics, National Regional Profile: Sydney (statistical Division), Australian Board of Statistics, http://www.abs.gov.au/ausstats/abs@nrp.nsf/lookup/105Main+Features12006-2010 (accessed March 9, 2012).

************************ Australian Board of Statistics, 2000 Year Book Australia, Australian Board of

Statistics,http://www.ausstats.abs.gov.au/Ausstats/subscriber.nsf/0/CA25687100069892CA256889000E7506/$File/13010_2000.pdf (acc essed March 9, 2012).

59

Appendix B: Methodological Changes B.1 Spain

-Dependent Variables: Originally measured in 1986 pesetas. Convert to 1986 USD. 142.2 pesetas=1 US dollar. (Exchange rates based on historic Federal Reserve Bureau numbers tallied by day, and averaged by months for annual rate). 1986 dollar to 1995 dollar. Multiply by 1986 dollar by 1.38. 1995 dollar to 1995 peseta. Multiply by 124.66. (See above exchange rate note) Given that 1995 and 1996 euro (base 1995) were available from the INEs website, these numbers were used to determine 1988-1994 numbers for each dependent variable. 1995 pesetas and 1996 were divided by 1995 euro and 1996 euro, then vice-versa. The euro/peseta equation was averaged among the two years, then applied to all peseta years to create 1995 base euro for 1988-1996. To check these values, the peseta/euro equation average from above was applied to the new euro base to check for accuracy in equations. However, because one average was applied to each year, which may shift on a year-to-year basis compared to the average, there will likely be autocorrelation where data shows time/space dependent patterns. -1996 dependent tourism numbers did not exist. I averaged changes between 1993,1994,and 1995 numbers, which had a similar trend, then applied that to the 1995 value to create the 1996 value. -95-96 Barcelona hotel rooms drastically change, due an unclear change in measurement classification system. I took 35,000 off the 1995,1996 numbers each because the overall trend/average trend is otherwise a small increase each time, if not by the same percentage change difference by year, and decreasing hotel rooms by 35,000 followed the original trend. -91-92 Barcelona number of financial institutes. 1988-1990 trends averaged and applied to the 1990 number to create the 1991 number. 1993-1996 trends averaged and applied to the 1993 number to create the 1992 number. - 90-92 Madrid house construction orders: I took the average between other years to look for trends, and found a decreasing trend. I then took the average and applied it to the 1993 number to create 1992, and so on to create the 1991 and 1990 value. -92-94 Madrid credit institutions: I took the average between each year with a more than 1 bank change, applied 1991 number times average, 1992 number times average and the 1993 number times average. (average=1.043) B.2 United States -Note: Employment (CBP) and dependent variable data (Bureau of Economic Analysis) changes in 1997 from SIC (Standard Industrial Classification) methodology to NAICS (North American Industry Classification System)

60

-Data was adjusted Many individual NAICS industries correspond directly to industries as defined under the SIC system, most of the aggregate NAICS grouping do not. Employment data is similar enough for no changes. -For category differences in SIC and NAICS numbers I took the category called Finance, Insurance and Real Estate compared to Finance and Insurance. I took away the subset Insurance and Real Estate sections so the variable would be only financial data, and I subtracted the Insurance subset from the NAICS numbers to make them comparable. -Dependent variables: Each 1997 dependent variable was measured by both the SIC and NAICS. Comparing those numbers showed differences with all data adjusted to 1997. Using the SIC as base numbers, I applied the difference between the SIC and NAICS 1997 numbers, to the 1998,1999 and 2000 NAICS numbers which puts them in SIC form. (This change was applied after all numbers were adjusted for a constant year 1997). B.3 Australia -Dependent Variables: Adjusted to 2000 values

61

Appendix C: Regressions C.1 Spain

62

63

64

65

66

67

68

69

70

71

72

C.2 United States

73

74

75

76

77

78

79

80

81

82

83

84

C.3 Australia 85

86

87

88

89

90

91

92

93

94

95

96

97

You might also like