You are on page 1of 17

The Political Consequences of Electoral Laws, 1945-85

Author(s): Arend Lijphart


Source: The American Political Science Review, Vol. 84, No. 2 (Jun., 1990), pp. 481-496
Published by: American Political Science Association
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/1963530 .
Accessed: 30/12/2014 06:03

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at .
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp

.
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of
content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms
of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

American Political Science Association is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to
The American Political Science Review.

http://www.jstor.org

This content downloaded from 128.235.251.160 on Tue, 30 Dec 2014 06:03:04 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
CONSEQUENCES
THEPOLITICAL
LAWS,1945-85
OF ELECTORAL
AREND LIJPHART
Universityof California
San Diego

A systematicanalysis of the relationshipsbetween the main


electoralsystem variables (electoralformula, districtmagnitude,and ballot structure)
and electoraloutcomes (the degreesof disproportionalityand multipartism)in the 20
Westerndemocraciesfrom 1945 to 1985-representing 32 distinctelectoralsystems (an
electoralsystem beingdefinedas a set of electionsheld underbasicallythe same rules)-
shows that the effects of both formula and magnitude on proportionalityare very
strong, muchstrongerthan Douglas W. Rae and subsequentresearchershavesuggested;
that on the other hand, theireffectson the numberof partiesparticipatingin electionsis
surprisinglyweak; and that ballot structureaffects the degree of multipartismonly in
single-memberdistrictsystems. Thesefindingssuggestthat strategicbehaviorby politi-
cians and voters plays a less importantrole in reducingmultipartismthan is usually
assumed.

W henthe first ficientcriticalattention.In theprefaceto


editionof DouglasW. Rae'sThePolitical thesecondedition,Rae(1971,vii) himself
Consequencesof ElectoralLawswas pub- chides "the over-gentlecolleagueswho
lishedin 1967,it wasalmostinstantlyrec- reviewedthe originaledition."'In fact,
ognizedas a greatscholarlybreakthrough. thebooksuffersfroma varietyof concep-
A secondeditionwas publishedin 1971, tual, methodological, and empirical
andit hasmaintained itsstellarreputation weaknesses,which are so grave and
as themostimportantbookin thefieldof numerousthat they cast doubton all of
comparative electoralsystemseversince. Rae'sconclusions.Moreover,someof his
Morerecentmajorinnovativebookshave conclusionsare so surprising-especially
explicitlyusedit bothas a modelandas a thefindingthatdifferences in proportion-
pointof departure (Katz1980,20;Nohlen al representation (PR)formulashaveonly
1978, 14), and contemporaryauthors minor effects and that neithertwo-tier
writingon thesubjectstillunfailinglycite districting systemsnortheballotstructure
it. It receivedthe 1989GeorgeH. Hallett have any effectat all-that they cry out
Awardof the AmericanPoliticalScience for a criticalnew examination.
Association's Representation andElector- My purposehereis to reanalyzeRae's
al Systemssection. classic study with more accuratedata,
As thefirstsystematicbroadlycompar- strongerhypotheses,andbettermethods.
ativestudyof electoralsystemsand as a I shallalso use more data:to Rae'selec-
powerfulstimulusto subsequent research, tions (of the loweror only housesof the
it clearly deservesits reputationas a legislature) in the20 Westerndemocracies
classicin the field.On the otherhand,it duringthe 20-yearperiodfrom 1945 to
hasbeenaccordedthisstatuswithoutsuf- 1964, I shall add the few electionsin

AMERICAN POLITICAL SCIENCE REVIEW


VOLUME 84 NO. 2 JUNE 1990

This content downloaded from 128.235.251.160 on Tue, 30 Dec 2014 06:03:04 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
American Political Science Review Vol. 84

1945-64 missing from Rae's book and, the link between ballot structure and
more importantly, all elections in these multipartism hypothesized and rejected
countries during the subsequent21-year by Rae is in fact valid for one majorcate-
period from 1965 through1985.2 In order gory of electoralsystems-single-member
to save space and becauseI found no ma- districtsystems. In otherwords, the prox-
jor differences between the patterns in imal effects of electoralsystems are much
Rae's 1945-64 period and in the entire stronger than their distal effects. The
1945-85 period, I shall presentthe results theoretical significance of this finding,
for the latter only. which I shall discuss in greater detail in
My reanalysis and update will yield the concludingsection, is that strategic(or
conclusionsthat are significantlydifferent insincere)voting and strategicelite behav-
from the relationshipsthat Rae finds be- ior play a considerablyless importantrole
tween his variables. Rae defines three in helping the larger, and hurting the
aspectsof the electoralsystem as his inde- smaller, parties than is usually supposed.
pendent variables: (1) the electoral for- How do my methods differ from, and
mula, such as plurality, various forms of how are they superiorto, Rae's?Five dif-
PR, and so on; (2) the average district ferencesare of importancethroughoutthe
magnitude,that is, the averagenumberof analysis. Firstin contrastwith Rae'streat-
legislatorselected per district;and (3) the ment of each election as a differentcase,
ballot structure,which may or may not my unit of analysisis the electoralsystem,
allow the voters to split their votes be- defined as one or more elections held
tween two or more parties (pp. 15-46). underbasicallythe same or closely similar
His two dependentvariables are (1) the rules. For instance, instead of counting
proportionalityof the electoral outcome, the 11 Israeli elections as 11 separate
which is the immediateor (in Rae'stermi- cases, I have only two cases: the PR
nology) "proximal"effect of the electoral system that used the d'Hondtformula(the
system's translation of votes into seats; 1949 election and the four elections from
and (2) the degree of multipartismthat 1973 to 1984) and the system under the
is-or is presumedto be-the indirector largest-remaindersrule (the six elections
"distal"effect of the electoralaystem (pp. in the 1951-69 period). My approach
47-64, 67-68, 84-85). avoids the artificial and deceptive infla-
Rae examines five major relationships tion of the weight of the available evi-
between his independentand dependent dence; elections under the same rules are
variables.With regardto all five of these, not really independentcases but merely
my conclusionswill divergefrom Rae'sin repeatedoperationsof the same electoral
crucial respects: (1) the relationshipbe- system. It also avoids the relatedproblem
tween the electoral formula and the pro- of artificiallyweighting the evidence. For
portionalityof the election result is much instance, France held only 3 elections
stronger than Rae finds; (2) the link be- under the pure d'Hondt rule while the
tween districtmagnitudeand proportion- Netherlandshad 12; but this is not a good
ality is also much stronger, especially as reason to give the Frenchevidence only
far as concernsthe effects of two-tier dis- one-fourththe weight of the Dutch. This
trictingsystems(whichRaeclaimsto have approach yields 32 cases (based on 255
no effect);(3) the relationshipbetweenthe elections) in the 1945-85 period.
electoralformulaand the degreeof multi- Second, I use the evidence of all of the
partism is much weaker than in Rae's available cases as much as possible. For
finding; (4) similarly, district magnitude instance, in contrastwith Rae, who simp-
and multipartismare much less strongly ly disregardsthe difficultcases of two-tier
and perfectlyrelatedthan Rae claims; (5) systems that use different formulas at

482

This content downloaded from 128.235.251.160 on Tue, 30 Dec 2014 06:03:04 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
ElectoralLaws

theirtwo levels, I determinewhich level is perfectly proportional."Rae (p. 84) tries


of predominantimportance and classify to avoid this problem by disregarding
the electoralsystem accordingto the for- parties with less than .5 percent of the
mula at this level. This procedure in- vote, but this arbitrarycutoff point is still
creasesthe numberof casesin my analysis quite low; the presenceof several parties
from 20 to 31; the-onlycase that I cannot with just over .5% of the votes will
use for the purposeof studyingthe effects depressI even if these parties fail to win
of electoralformulasis France(1951-56), any seats.3
because it used majority, d'Hondt, and Finally, a relatively minor difference
largest remainders formulas in such a between Rae's methods and mine con-
complex way (in different parts of the cerns the measure of multipartism.Rae
country, not at differentlevels) that they uses a large number of indicators of
cannot be disentangled. multipartism-such as the total number
Third, since Rae finds that both for- of partiescontestingan election, the total
mula and magnitudestrongly affect pro- numberelectedto the legislature,the vote
portionality and multipartism, it is a and seat shares of the largest party, and
curious omission in his analysis that he the vote and seat sharesof the two largest
fails to examinethe possibleinteractionof parties combined-but his most impor-
his two explanatory variables. I correct tant and comprehensivemeasure is the
this omission by systematically control- fractionalization of the party system,
ling for the influenceof the otherindepen- which is sensitive to both the numbersof
dent variable. partiesand their relativesizes (pp. 47-64,
Fourth,in order to measurethe degree 67-68, 84-85). I shall use an adaptationof
of disproportionalityof differentelectoral Rae'sfractionalizationindex-Laakso and
systems, I use JohnLoosemoreand Victor Taagepera's(1979) "effective number of
J. Hanby's (1971) index D. It has become parties"-which carries exactly the same
the most widely used index of dispropor- information as Rae's index but is more
tionality (see, e.g., Mackie and Rose meaningful. For instance, in a party
1982, 411-12; Rose 1984; Taageperaand system with two equally strong parties,
Shugart1989, 104-11). D is the total per- the effective numberof parties is exactly
centage by which the overrepresented 2.0; for three equal parties it is 3.0; for
parties are overrepresented-which is, of two strongpartiesand one weakerparty,
course,the same as the total percentageof it will be somewherein the neighborhood
underrepresentation. In orderto calculate of 2.5. Rae'sfractionalizationindexescan
D, the absolute values of all differences be easily converted into the Laakso-
between the parties'vote and seat shares Taagepera measure. The effective
are added and then divided by 2. Rae's numberof parties (as well as the index of
measureI appears to be similar. It, too, fractionalization)can be calculatedon the
entails the addition of all vote-seat share basis of either the parties' vote or seat
differences;but this sum is dividednot by shares. The former is the better indicator
2 but by the number of parties. As of the long-term nature of the party
RichardS. Katz (1980, 140) has pointed system. It is affected by the operation of
out, Rae'sindex I has the grave defect of the electoral system in previous elections
"givingtoo much weight to small parties; but not yet by the translationof votes into
at the extreme, if the infinite number of seats in the currentelection. I shall there-
(hypothetical) parties that receive no fore use the effective number of elective
votes and obtain no seats is included, (insteadof legislative)parties as my indi-
every electoral system would appear cator of multipartism.

483

This content downloaded from 128.235.251.160 on Tue, 30 Dec 2014 06:03:04 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
AmericanPoliticalScienceReview Vol. 84

ElectoralFormulasand followingscalefromthemostto theleast


ElectoralDisproportionality proportional:pure Sainte-Lague, modi-
fiedSainte-Lague, andd'Hondt(seeBalin-
Rae finds, as expected,that plurality skiandYoung1982,60-66;Lijphart 1986,
and majorityformulasare considerably 172-75).
lessproportional thanPRbut, rathersur- Similardifferencesoccurwithinlargest
prisingly,thatthereis not a greatdealof remainders (LR)systems.The oldestand
difference within the family of PR best known of these simplyuses as its
systems.The mainreasonfor the latter, quotathetotalnumberof validvotescast
unexpectedconclusionis Rae'simproper in a districtdividedby thedistrictmagni-
classificationof thedifferentPRformulas. tude (m, the total numberof seats avail-
He hypothesizes thathighestaverages(or able in the district).This quota, usually
divisor)formulasyield less proportional referredto as theHarequota,is impartial
results than largestremainders(quota) as betweensmall and large partiesand
formulas.The distinctionbetweenthese tendsto yieldcloselyproportional results.
two typesof list PRformulasis indeedan Lessproportional outcomesareproduced
importantone-but mainlyas regardsthe by the Droop quota, which dividesthe
practical procedureselection officials votes by m + 1 insteadof m, and the Im-
haveto useto allocateseatsto partylists. perialiquota,which uses m + 2 as the
However, the two groups of methods denominatorsThe use of these lower
should not be expectedto differ with quotasmeansthattherewill be fewerre-
regardto the proportionalitythey pro- mainingseats to be allocatedand hence
duce,sincethe degreeof proportionality also more wastageof remainingvotes,
depends on the particularquota that whichis especiallyharmfulto thesmaller
quota methods use and the particular partiesandresultsin a decreasein propor-
divisor used by divisor methods.This tionality.It can be shownthatwhenthe
meansthatdifferences withregardto pro- quotais loweredeven further,to the ex-
portionalityshould occur within each tent thattherewill not be any remaining
groupinsteadof betweenthem. seats, the outcomebecomesexactlythe
Amongthe highestaveragesmethods, sameas thatof thed'Hondtformula(Van
the d'Hondtformula (which uses the den Bergh1955, 68-72). In preferential
divisorseries1, 2, 3, 4, etc.) is the least PR, usuallyreferredto as singletransfer-
proportionaland systematicallyfavors able vote (STV)systems,the quotais as
the largerparties.It contrastswith the importantfor the proportionality of the
Sainte-Lagudformula, which, in the electoraloutcomeas in list-PRlargest-
originalform proposedby its inventor remainders systems.Theone caseof STV
(usingthe odd-integerdivisorseries1, 3, among the Western democracies-Ire-
5, 7, etc.), approximates proportionality land-uses the Droopquota.
very closely and treatslarge and small This discussion suggests a much
partiesin a perfectlyevenhanded way. In strongerand more plausiblehypothesis
practice,theSainte-LaguE methodis more aboutthe effectsof PR formulason the
often used in a modifiedform that uses proportionality of theelectionresultthan
1.4 instead of 1 as the first divisor, Rae'shypothesis,which is basedon the
therebymakingit harderfor smallparties twofold distinctionbetween largest-re-
to gaintheirfirstseatsandhencereducing maindersand highest-averages methods.
the proportionality of the electionresult Mine is based on a threefoldclassifica-
to someextent.Accordingto theirlogical tion: (1) pureSainte-Lagud and LR-Hare
properties,therefore,the three highest arelikelyto be themostproportional; (2)
averagesmethodscan be placedon the modified Sainte-LaguE, LR-Droop,LR-

484

This content downloaded from 128.235.251.160 on Tue, 30 Dec 2014 06:03:04 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
ElectoralLaws

Table 1. AverageDegrees of Disproportionalityof ElectoralSystems Classifiedby


ElectoralFormulaand AdjustedDistrict Magnitude,1945-85 (%)

LR-Droop,
LR-Imperiali,
Adjusted LR-Hare Modified Plurality
District and Pure and
Sainte-LaguE, and
Magnitude Saint-LaguE STV-Droop d'Hondt Majority Alla
1-1.1 - - - 12.93 (6) 12.93 (6)
1.1-5 _~ 4.60 (1) 8.51 (3) - 7.53 (4)
5-10 - 5.18 (3) 5.83 (6) 5.61 (9)
10-25 2.81 (2) - 4.28 (3) - 3.69 (5)
100-150 2.46 (3) 3.53 (2) 4.39 (2) - 3.32 (7)
Alla 2.60 (5) 4.53 (6) 5.87 (14) 12.93 (6) 6.45 (31)

Source:Basedon data in Mackieand Rose1982, 1983, 1984;Mackie1985, 1986;Ornstein,Mann,and Malbin


1987, 47-48; and Luxembourg,ServiceCentralde la Statistique1984, 120-21.
Note: The numbersof cases on which the percentagesare basedare in parentheses.
aExceptFranceof 1951-56.

Imperiali,and STV-Droopshouldbe less betweenhis two types?After carefully


proportional; and (3) d'Hondtis likelyto checkingall of the likelyexplanations,I
be the least proportionalof the PR for- foundthatneitherRae'sdifferentmethod-
mulas. ology nor his empiricalerrors(of the 56
Thebottomrow of Table1 showsthat list PR electionsthat accordingto Rae's
this hypothesisis stronglysupportedby own criteria,shouldhave been included
the evidence.The pluralityand majority in his analysis,28 are misclassifiedor
systemsaremorethantwiceas dispropor- omitted)providethe answer.The expla-
tional as d'HondtPR, and the d'Hondt nationis thatd'Hondthappensto be the
systemsaremorethantwiceas dispropor- mostfrequentlyusedhighestaveragefor-
tional as the LR-Hareand pure Sainte- mula:of the 18 highestaveragescases,14
Laguesystems;thein-between PRsystems are d'Hondt.Since d'Hondtis also the
are also, as hypothesized,roughlyinter- leastproportional of all PRmethods,it is
mediatein termsof theirdegreeof dispro- now clearwhy Rae'scategoryof highest
portionality.Thesefiguresare basedon averagesturnsout to be lessproportional
31 of the 32 cases,as explainedearlier.6 than that of his largestremainders.His
My findingspartly supportand partly finding,modestas it is, is entirelyfor-
contrastwith Rae's. Rae (pp. 96, 106) tuitous.
findsa similardifferencebetweenplural- Table1 also showsthe indicesof dis-
ity-majority andtheleastproportional PR proportionality of the PRformulaswhen
systems:3.96% and 1.78%respectively district magnitude is held constant.
(measured in termsof Rae'sI). Butthedif- Withineachcategoryof adjustedmagni-
ferencebetweenhis two types of PR is tude (to be definedin the next section),
quitesmall:1.22%and1.78%(alsomea- the differencesbetweenthe formulasare
suredin termsof I). reducedto some extent; but they still
Giventheweaknessof Rae'shypothesis showup clearlyandtheyareall in theex-
aboutPR systems,how can we account pecteddirection.
for the fact that he finds any difference
485

This content downloaded from 128.235.251.160 on Tue, 30 Dec 2014 06:03:04 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
American Political Science Review Vol. 84

District Magnitudeand of averagemagnitudes."This is an unsat-


ElectoralDisproportionality isfactory solution because its effect is to
make the averagemagnitudelower than it
The strongest relationship found by would be on the basis of either the low-
Rae is that between district magnitude tier or the high-tier districts by them-
and proportionality: as magnitude in- selves. Forinstance,from 1945to 1970the
creases,disproportionalitygoes down. He Austrian 165-member legislature was
comparesthe effects of electoral systems elected in 25 low-tier and 4 high-tierdis-
classified according to five categories of tricts. Counting the lower tier only, the
averagedistrictmagnitude,m: (1) single- average magnitudewould be 6.6; count-
memberdistrictswhere m = 1, (2) m be- ing the highertier only, it would be 41.2.
tween 2 and 6, (3) m between6 and 10, (4) The most reasonable assumption is that
m between 10 and 20, and (5) m between the "true" magnitude should be some-
100 and 150, which occurs in the two wherebetween6.6 and 41.2. Accordingto
countries with a single nationwide dis- Rae's definition, however, it is 5.7-well
trict, Israel and the Netherlands. Rae below 6.6. Rae states that his solution is
never explainswhy he selected these par- only tentative,but he neverreconsidersit.
ticularfive categories;but with one excep- Since I do not want to prejudgethe effect
tion the dividing lines make good sense, of the superimpositionof a higher tier of
since they coincidewith naturalbreaksin districts (which is often a single national
the distribution of the magnitudes. The district),my own tentativeand temporary
exceptionis that the naturaldiscontinuity solution is to calculateaveragemagnitude
in the range between single-memberdis- solely on the basis of the lower tier.
tricts and a district magnitude of 10 oc- Rae's (p. 124) hypothesis concerning
curs at about m = 5 instead of m = 6. the impact of two-tier or "complex"dis-
Another small improvementis to make tricting is eminently plausible: "One
1.1 the dividing point between the two would expectcomplexdistricting-the use
lowest categories. This takes care of the of two tiers of districts-to increasepro-
few deviations from single-memberdis- portionality at any given level of magni-
tricts in the pluralityand majority coun- tude." However, Rae immediatelyrejects
tries, which are all essentially single- this hypothesis. Without supplying pre-
memberdistrict systems; and it removes cise figures, he states that "the four
Rae'sawkwardgap betweenm = 1 and m systems based on complex districting-
= 2. A final helpful adjustmentis to ex- Icelandic, German, Austrian, and Dan-
pand the 10-to-20-seat category to ish-do not behave in accordance with
10-to-25 so that it can accommodatethe this expectation. For two of them, the
Austriancase, which since 1971 has had a German and the Danish, disproportions
magnitudeof slightly higher than 20.7 are below average for their respective
Averagedistrictmagnitudeis definedas levels of district magnitude. But for the
the averagenumberof seats (or represen- Austrian and Icelandicsystems, complex
tatives) per district; and it can be calcu- districting associates itself with greater-
lated easily by dividing the total number than-averagedisproportions,given their
of seatsin the legislatureby the numberof levels of district magnitude."It is worth
districts.Only with regardto two-tierdis- noting that Rae'sconclusion, for once, is
trictingsystems do we run into complica- based on a controlled test. He does not
tions. The solution proposed by Rae (p. simply compare all complex-districting
21) is that "this problem is tentatively cases with all simple-districtingcases but
resolved by counting the total numberof controls for districtmagnitude.
districtsat both levels in the computation Nevertheless, Rae's negative finding is

486

This content downloaded from 128.235.251.160 on Tue, 30 Dec 2014 06:03:04 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
ElectoralLaws

unsatisfactoryfor severalreasons. One is plex districtingor simple districting.The


that he fails to recognize and include one case of near-nationwidedistricts is
Belgiumand Italy as complex-districting Austria since 1971, which has used only
cases. Second, he suddenly shifts from two higher-tierdistricts. For the reasons
electionsto countriesas his unitsof analy- just outlined, the 1946-59 Icelandicelec-
sis and therebyignoresthe majorelectoral toral system should not be included
law changesin Icelandin 1959 and in Ger- among the strong complex-districting
many after the 1953 election. Third, his cases. When the disproportionalitiesof
conclusion is so surprisingthat a closer the two types of districtingsystems are
look at the deviantcases is calledfor. Rae contrasted,the strongcomplex-districting
(p. 124) gives up too quickly: "Sinceno systems do indeed turn out to be more
plausible explanation is available. . . , it proportional within each category of
must be concludedthat complex district- magnitudethan the other systems.
ing does not producegreaterproportion- I can now proposea modificationin my
ality than simple districtingat any given tentative definition of average district
level of district magnitude."In fact, the magnitude: strong complex-districting
deviant Austrian and Icelandiccases do systems should be classifiedone category
have some special features that may ex- higher than what their lower-tiermagni-
plain theirunexpecteddisproportionality. tude would entitlethem to. I shall call this
In the Icelandic electoral system from their adjusteddistrict magnitude. For in-
1946 to 1959, more than half of the seats stance, since 1970 Sweden has had a
at the lower tier were in single-member lower-tier magnitude of 12.5 seats but
districtsand almost a third in two-mem- also a single, nationwide, higher tier; its
ber districts. The few adjustment seats adjusted magnitude is therefore in the
available at the national level could not 100-to-150-seat category together with
neutralizethe disproportionalitiescaused Israel and the Netherlands.The relation-
by these low magnitudes. The Austrian ship between adjustedmagnitudeand dis-
electoral system from 1945 to 1970, proportionality is considerably stronger
despitethe country'srelativelysmall size, than that between magnitude,as I tenta-
had four higher-tierdistricts instead of tively defined it, and disproportionality.
one national district. The last column of Table 1 presents the
The Austriancase suggestsa generalex- average degrees of disproportionalityin
planation. Complex-districtingsystems the five classes of adjusted magnitude.
typically try to restrict the benefits The greatest differenceagain occurs be-
obtainableat the highertier to partiesthat tween the plurality-majority systems
have received a minimum number of (which are also the single-memberdistrict
votes or seats at the lower tier. Since this systems) and the least-proportionalcate-
entailsdiscriminationagainstthe smallest gory of PR systems. Within the family of
parties, it also places a limit on the pro- PR systems, the differencesamongthe dif-
portionalizingeffect of two-tierdistricting ferent categoriesof magnitudeare rough-
systems;and it means that the higher-tier ly similar to the differencesfound earlier
districtsmust be large, preferablynation- among the several formulas. These find-
wide, in orderto make the election result ings are in sharp contrastwith Rae's (pp.
appreciably more proportional. A 114-24) conclusion that district magni-
stronger hypothesis than Rae's would tude is a more potent force than the elec-
thereforebe that complex districtingwith toral formula,which has become the con-
nationwide-or almost nationwide- ventional wisdom (Sartori 1986, 53, 66;
higher-tierdistricts (which can be called see also Taagepera and Shugart 1989,
strong complex districting) yields greater 112-25).
proportionalitythan other forms of com- What is the effect of each of the inde-
487

This content downloaded from 128.235.251.160 on Tue, 30 Dec 2014 06:03:04 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
American Political Science Review Vol. 84

pendentvariables-electoral formulaand fect of magnitudeand formulaon dispro-


district magnitude-on the dependent portionality.The nine majorelectorallaw
variable of proportionality when the changesall produce the expectedchanges
other independentvariable is controlled? in the degree of disproportionality.With
This question is relevant only for the PR the exception of Israel'sreturn from LR-
systems since the non-PR systems do not Hare to d'Hondt after the 1969 election,
vary with regard to magnitude. Table 1 all of these major changes entailed shifts
also shows the indices of disproportional- to more proportionalrules.
ity of all PR cases classifiedaccordingto To sum up, district magnitude was
both effectivedistrictmagnitudeand elec- found to have a very strongeffect on pro-
toral formula.When districtmagnitudeis portionality, confirming Rae's conclu-
held constant, the differencesbetweenthe sion. This effect remains strong-albeit
formulasare reducedbut not at all elimi- not as strong-when the electoralformula
nated. When we control for electoralfor- is held constant, a control that Rae fails to
mula, sizable differences between the apply. And contraryto Rae, complexdis-
magnitudeclasses remain in the d'Hondt tricting was found to make the election
systems; but the differencesare less im- result considerablymore proportional.
pressive for the other formulas. The
reason why these relationshipsnow ap-
pear less strong is that effective district Formula,Magnitude, and
magnitude and electoral formula are Multipartism
themselvescorrelated.As the numbersin
parentheses in Table 1 show, the most Thediscussionof the effectof the elec-
proportionalformulas(LR-Hareand pure toral formula and district magnitude on
Sainte-Lague)occur only in the two most proportionalityhas paved the way for a
proportional classes of adjusted magni- more expeditioustreatmentof their effect
tude (those largerthan 10 seats); and the on multipartism.The reason is that pro-
majority of the least-proportional for- portionality is the logical link that con-
mulas (d'Hondt)are used in the least-pro- nects these electoral system variables to
portional magnitudegroups (less than 10 the number of parties: the more propor-
seats). tional the electoral system is, the more
BecauseTable 1 has severalempty cells, favorable it is for small and new parties
its evidence is somewhat ambiguous. and hence the more it will allow-some
Moreover,thereare a couple of cells with would say encourage-a large numberof
values that are out of monotonic order. parties.Of course, thereare also otherim-
Nevertheless,the overallpatternis one of portant causes of multipartism,particu-
interactionbetween formula and magni- larly the numberand depth of the cleav-
tude but also of the independentimpactof ages in a society (Taageperaand Grofman
each of them on the proportionalityof the 1985). We should thereforenot expect a
electoral outcome. Further evidence of very strong correlation between magni-
this patternis providedby Figure1, which tude and formula on the one hand and
shows the changes in disproportionality multipartismon the other. Rae (p. 141)
due to major electorallaw changesin the correctly points out that "party systems
same country. For instance, Sweden first are influencedby many variables-social,
shifted from d'Hondt to modified Sainte- economic, legal, and political. [The]elec-
Lagueand subsequentlyto a much higher toral law ... is to be counted only one of
adjusted magnitude. Because country- many determining forces. And it is,
specific characteristicsare now also con- secondly, impossible to sort out all the
trolled, we have a rigoroustest of the ef- contributingfactors, or to assigneven ap-

488

This content downloaded from 128.235.251.160 on Tue, 30 Dec 2014 06:03:04 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Electoral Laws

Figure1. Average Disproportionalityand Average Number of ElectiveParties


of ElectoralSystems in Change, 1945-85

ElectoralFormula
LR-Hare LR-Droop
and and
Pure S.-L. Mod. S.-L. d'Hondt
Germany
1953
D= 7.40
N= 3.31
1.1-5 Iceland
1946-59
D =9.72
N = 3.66

Norway Norway Germany


oD 1953-85 1945-49 1957-83
V3 D=7.06 D= 10.80 D=3.31
5-10
.+- N=3.77 N=3.87 N=2.56
CJ)
cm Austria Sweden Sweden
1945-70 1952-68 1948
D = 5.04 D = 3.42 D = 5.25
N = 2.49 N = 3.30 N = 3.35

Denmark Iceland
W 10-25 19361598
D= 3.21 D = 3.94
N =4.01 N = 3.84

Denmark Austria Sweden


1971-84 1971-83 1970-85
D=2.86 D=2.00 D=2.39
100-150 N = 5.49 N = 2.31 N = 3.52 Israel
Israel 1949 Israel
1951-69 D = 5.80 1973-84
D=2.53 N=5.40 D=5.88
N=5.10 ---

489

This content downloaded from 128.235.251.160 on Tue, 30 Dec 2014 06:03:04 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
American Political Science Review Vol. 84

Table 2. Average EffectiveNumbersof ElectivePartiesin ElectoralSystems


Classifiedby ElectoralFormulaand AdjustedDistrictMagnitude,1945-85

LR-Droop,
LR-Imperiali,
Adjusted LR-Hare Modified Plurality
District and Pure Sainte-Lague,and and
Magnitude Sainte-LaguE STV-Droop d'Hondt Majority Alla
1-1.1 -- - 2.95 (6) 2.95 (6)
1.1-5 - 3.04 (1) 3.96 (3) - 3.73 (4)
5-10 - 3.19 (3) 4.10 (6) 3.80 (9)
10-25 4.04 (2) - 4.27 (3) - 4.18 (5)
100-150 4.30 (3) 3.75 (2) 4.76 (2) - 4.28 (7)
Alla 4.20 (5) 3.35 (6) 4.20 (14) 2.95 (6) 3.79 (31)

Source:Basedon datain Mackieand Rose1982, 1983, 1984;Mackie1985, 1986;Ornstein,Mann,andMalbin


1987, 47-48; and Luxembourg,ServiceCentralde la Statistique1984, 120-21.
Note: The numbersof cases on which the percentagesare basedare in parentheses.
aExceptFranceof 1951-56.

proximate weights to them. Worse yet, enceswith regardto multipartism.Rae (p.


electoral laws are themselves shaped by 106) reports that in accordancewith his
party systems." hypothesis, highest-averageformulas are
Notwithstanding these cautionary associated with lower multipartismthan
words, Rae (p. 98) reportsa big difference largest-remainder formulas-3.57 and
in multipartismfor pluralityand majority 4.00 partiesrespectively.However, when
systems (which are also the single- the missing1945-64 data and the 1965-85
memberdistrictsystems)on the one hand data are addedand the numerousmisclas-
and PR multimemberdistrict systems on sifications are corrected, the difference
the other-2.17 and 3.70 parties respec- disappears-4.39 and 4.40 parties.
tively. My figuresshow more modest dif- My own findings are hardly more im-
ferences-2.95 and 4.07 parties.The main pressive, however. They are summarized
reason why Rae finds such a small effec- in Table 2. The d'Hondtsystemshave ex-
tive number of parties in plurality and actly as many partiesas the most propor-
majority systems appears to be that he tional LR-Hare and pure Sainte-Lague
counts in terms of elections:the 2 French systems (see the bottom row of the table).
Fifth Republicmultipartyelections (5.56 Also unexpectedly,the intermediatesys-
parties) are overwhelmed by the 10 tems in terms of proportionality (LR-
almost purely two-party U.S. elections Droop, etc.) are considerablylower than
(2.04 parties). On the other hand, if we the d'Hondtsystemswith regardto multi-
focus on the plurality systems-Canada, partism. We must reject the hypothesis
New Zealand, the United Kingdom, and that within the PR family, formula and
the UnitedStates-and excludethe French multipartismare related.
and Australian majority systems, the The findingsconcerningdistrictmagni-
degree of multipartism is considerably tude are somewhatmore positive (see the
lower-only 2.54 parties. last column of Table 2) but not as strong
Since the differencesin disproportion- as Rae (p. 121) suggests. Rae reports a
ality among PR systems are smallerthan monotonic relationship between magni-
those between PR and plurality-majority, tude and the numberof partiesfor the PR
we should also expectmore modest differ- systems-from 3.18 parties in the lowest

490

This content downloaded from 128.235.251.160 on Tue, 30 Dec 2014 06:03:04 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Electoral Laws

category of magnitudeto 4.65 parties in almost negligible -.10. However, as I


the highest, an increaseof approximately shallpointout shortly,thisnegativefind-
1.5 parties. My reanalysisshows a much ing needs to be qualified in several
smallerincrease-only about .5 parties. respects.
When the two independent variables
are cross-tabulated,the weak relationship
between magnitude and multipartismis Ballot Structureand Multipartism
not weakenedfurther.The monotonic in-
creasein multipartismas magnitudegoes With regardto the impactof ballot
up is even maintainedwithin each of the structureon multipartism,Raeformulates
three groups of formulas, but the differ- hismostoriginalhypothesis.Basedon the
ences are small. Controlling for magni- distinctionbetweenordinalballots,which
tude makes the influenceof the electoral "allowthe voterto favormorethanone
formulaon multipartismlook worse. For partywith his mandate,"and categorical
each magnitude class, multipartism is ballots,which"require thatthevotergive
lower insteadof higherin the intermediate his mandateto a singleparty,"Rae (p.
categorythan in d'Hondtsystems. And in 126) hypothesizesthat ordinal ballots
two of the four classes of magnitudethat "alloweach voter'smandateto be dis-
allow a comparisonof d'Hondtwith LR- persed among several parties, thereby
Hareand pureSainte-Lague,multipartism producinga sort of microfractionaliza-
is higher, not lower, in the d'Hondt sys- tion"and that electionsheld with such
tems-again contraryto our expectations ballots,and hencewith repeatedmicro-
based on the formulas'tendenciesto dis- fractionalizations,"producemore frac-
proportionality. tionalizedelective party systems than
Similar, mainly negative, evidence is would be found underother elections."
provided by Figure1, which applies the However,he findsthattherelationship is
within-countrytest of the effect of major theotherway around:hisordinalsystems
electoral law changes-applied earlier to havean averageeffectivenumberof only
changes in disproportionality-to 2.94partiescomparedwith3.23partiesin
changes in multipartism. Whereas the categoricalsystems. His conclusionis,
electoral law changes produced the ex- 'My theoryis absolutelywrong"(p. 127).
pectedchangesin disproportionalityin all Hereagain,we musttakea criticallook
nine cases, thereis no commensuratepat- at Rae's methods and procedures.He
tern for multipartism:the evidence runs makestwo seriousmistakesof classifica-
five to four against the hypothesis.Of the tion. His ordinal ballot systems are
five changes in electoral formula, only Australia, Ireland, Luxembourg,and
one yields the expected change in the Switzerland. Thefirsttwo usepreferential
degree of multipartism;and of the five ballotsthatallow-in theAustraliancase,
shifts to larger magnitudes (one case, require-the votersto rank-order candi-
Austria, entails a change in both formula datesandpartiesaccordingto the voters'
and magnitude)threeyield more, and two preferences.Luxembourg andSwitzerland
yield less, multipartism. uselist PRsystemsbutgiveeachvoteras
These findings suggest that the impact manyvotes as thereare seatsin the dis-
of disproportionalityon the number of trict and allow the voter to distribute
parties is even weaker than our modest these votes over two or more parties,
expectationshad led us to believe. When equallyor preferentially.
Thesefourelec-
we take a direct look at this relationship, toral systems are correctly classified.
we find that it is in the expecteddirection However,Rae misclassifiesthe German
but that the correlationcoefficient is an andFrenchFifthRepublicsystemsas cate-

491

This content downloaded from 128.235.251.160 on Tue, 30 Dec 2014 06:03:04 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
American Political Science Review Vol. 84

Table 3. Average EffectiveNumbersof ElectivePartiesClassifiedby


AdjustedDistrict Magnitudeand Ballot Structure,1945-85

AdjustedDistrictMagnitude
Ballot Structure 1-1.1 1.1-5 5-10 10-25 100-150 All
Categorical 2.54 (4) 4.28 (2) 3.99 (8) 4.34 (4) 4.28 (7) 3.92 (25)
Ordinal 3.78 (2) 3.18 (2) 4.00 (2) 3.53 (1) - 3.64 (7)
All 2.95 (6) 3.73 (4) 3.99 (10) 4.18 (5) 4.28 (7) 3.85 (32)
Source:Basedon data in Mackieand Rose1982, 1983, 1984;Mackie1985, 1986;Ornstein,Mann,and Malbin
1987, 47-48; and Luxembourg,ServiceCentralde la Statistique1984, 120-21.
Note: The numbersof cases on which the percentagesare based are in parentheses.

gorical; they are clearly ordinal. The numbersof parties under categoricaland
French two-ballot system allows the ordinal ballots when magnitude is con-
voters to vote for differentparties on the trolled. In the multimemberdistrict sys-
first and second ballots and quite often- tems, my findings are still mainly nega-
when candidatesare eliminatedor with- tive: two of the three pairs of values still
draw after the first ballot-require that run counterto the hypothesis,and the one
they do so. In Germany, each voter has positive instanceis only marginallyposi-
two votes, which may be cast for different tive. However, in single-memberdistrict
parties;this ordinal ballot system has ex- systems, ordinal ballots result in a dra-
isted since the 1953 election.8 matically higher degree of multipartism
When these misclassificationsare cor- than categoricalballots. The differenceis
rectedand also, as usual, the missingdata roughly that between a two-and-a-half-
are added and electoral systems rather party system and an almost-four-party-
than elections are used as the cases for system. The explanationis not difficultto
analysis, the findingsare still negative(see find. The categoricalsystemsare plurality
the last column of Table 3). The ordinal systems in which the incentive to vote
systems have less, insteadof more, multi- strategicallyor insincerely,in ordernot to
partism than categorical systems; al- waste one's vote, is strong. This resultsin
though the differences are relatively greater support for the large parties by
small. In trying to explain his negative voters and by politiciansand a reduction
result, Rae (p. 129) speculatesthat "ballot in the effectivenumberof parties.The or-
structureconstitutes a rather weak vari- dinal ballot removes most of the risk of
able. It may be much less importantthan wasting one's vote; hence it encourages
electoral formulae, district magnitude, both sincerevoting and multipartism.
and, more likely still, the sociopolitical When we control for the electoral for-
forces which underlieparty competition." mula, we find the same importantdiffer-
He continues, "Unfortunately,the avail- ence among the plurality-majorityfor-
able data allow no definitive test of this mulas, since these coincide with the
notion, and it must be left unverified." single-memberdistrict systems, and the
This is an unnecessary defeatist stance, same mainly negative result for the PR
since we can test the influence of ballot systems.9 The link between ballot struc-
structureon multipartismwhile control- ture and multipartism applies only to
ling for formula and magnitude. single-memberdistrictsystems, but it is a
Table 3 shows the average effective strong link.

492

This content downloaded from 128.235.251.160 on Tue, 30 Dec 2014 06:03:04 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Electoral Laws

Conclusion multipartism(4.00 parties) on the other.


However, within the PR category,thereis
The two electoralsystemvariables,for- virtually no relationshipbetween the two
mula and magnitude,have a strong effect variables;the correlationis .02. This find-
on electoral disproportionality(consider- ing casts doubt on Sartori's (1986, 54)
ably stronger than reportedby Rae) but assertionthat within the family of PR sys-
only a weak effect on multipartism(much tems, a distinctionmust be made between
weaker than Rae suggests).The reason is highly proportional, hence "feeble,"
that disproportionality-the intervening systems and less proportional "strong-
variablebetween the electoralsystem and feeble"systems, with the latterin an inter-
multipartism-is only a weak predictorof mediateposition betweenthe "feeble"sys-
the numberof parties.However, this con- tems and "strong"pluralitysystems.
clusion has to be qualifiedin threeimpor- The third qualificationis that since the
tant respects. focus has been on gauging the electoral
In the first place, the hypothesis that system's long-range effect on the party
disproportionalityshould reduce multi- system, multipartismhas been consistent-
partism is based on the assumption of ly measured in terms of the effective
strategicbehavior. When smaller parties numberof elective parties. It is logical to
are expected to be discriminatedagainst, expecta strongerimpactof disproportion-
voters, as well as politicians, political ac- ality on the effectivenumberof legislative
tivists, and money givers will favor the parties because the latter is affected not
largerparties (Gunther1989; Riker1986, only by strategicresponsesto the expecta-
33-41). The findingon the effect of ballot tion of discriminationagainstsmallerpar-
structure suggests that the majority ties-what Rae (pp. 67-68) calls the elec-
systems should be excluded from the toral system's "distal"effect and Maurice
hypothesizedrelationship.They are char- Duverger (1963, 226) its "psychological"
acterizedby high disproportionality;but effect-but also by the immediate,"prox-
becauseof their"ordinal"ballot structure, imal" (Rae) or "mechanical"(Duverger)
they do not encouragestrategicbehavior effect of the translationof votes into seats
and hence do not discourage multi- in the particularelection under observa-
partism.10The case of Franceof 1951-56 tion. For the 29 cases, the correlationbe-
should also be excluded because its dis- tween disproportionalityand the effective
proportionalitywas designedto favor the numberof legislativepartiesis a stronger
smaller parties-those in the ideological -.45. This means that disproportionality
center-and thereforeencouragedinstead explainsonly about 8 % of the variancein
of discouraged multipartism (Campbell elective multipartismbut about 20% of
1965, 113-26). Forthe remaining29 cases, that in legislativemultipartism.The latter
the coefficientof correlationbetween dis- percentage must be interpreted as the
proportionalityand the effective number combined effect of the psychological and
of partiesis now -.29 (comparedwith an mechanical factors, but it still indicates
r of -.10 for all 32 cases). that the mechanical factors are the
The second qualification is that this strongerinfluences."
somewhat stronger relationship mainly To sum up, electoral systems display
reflects the differencesbetween the four wide and predictable differences in dis-
plurality systems with high average dis- proportionality, smaller differences in
proportionality (11.08%) and low aver- multipartismthat are the direct effect of
age multipartism(2.54 parties)on the one disproportionality,and even smaller dif-
hand and the 25 PR systems with lower ferences in elective multipartismdue to
disproportionality (4.89%) and higher strategiccalculationsby elites and voters,

493

This content downloaded from 128.235.251.160 on Tue, 30 Dec 2014 06:03:04 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
AmericanPolitical Science Review Vol. 84

Plurality systems are an exception: their RichardG. Niemi, Matthew S. Shugart,and Rein
high disproportionalityaccounts, via the Taageperafor helpfulcomments.And I should like
to expressmy appreciationfor the financialsupport
effect of strategicbehavior, for theirrela- of the GuggenheimFoundationand the German
tively small effective number of elective MarshallFundof the UnitedStates.
parties. Strategicvoting is neutralizedin 1. My referenceswill be to the 1971 edition of
majority systems, which can therefore Rae'sbook.
2. Raewas so kind as to makehis originaldatafor
combine high disproportionality with 1945-64 availableto me, but I decidedthat it was
high elective multipartism.And the sub- preferableto use the election data in Thomas T.
stantial differencesin disproportionality Mackie and RichardRose's (1982) standardhand-
among PR systems are apparently not book in order to facilitate replication by other
large enough to produce either commen- researchersandbecauseI also usedthe latterdatafor
the 1965-85 period.The Mackie-Rosehandbookin-
suratedifferencesin strategicbehavioror, dudes the elections held through 1981. For the
as a result, commensuratedifferencesin 1982-85 electionsI turnedto the annualupdatesin
elective multipartism. the European Journal of Political Research by
Mackie and Rose (1983, 1984) and Mackie (1985,
1986). The resultsof U.S. House of Representatives
elections, not reportedby Mackie and Rose, were
Notes takenfromOrnstein,Mann,andMalbin1987. Since
the Luxembourgvoting figuresprovidedby Mackie
This is a revisedand muchshortenedversionof a and Rose fail to adjustfor the unequalnumbersof
paperpresentedat the fourteenthWorldCongressof votes that voters have in differentdistricts,I used
the International Political Science Association Luxembourg,ServiceCentralde la Statistique1984.
(IPSA),Washington,1988.1 shouldlike to acknowl- 3. It may be arguedthat comparedwith 1, D errs
edge the assistance and advice, especially with in the oppositedirection:it has a slight tendencyto
regard to electoral laws and election data, that I exaggeratethe disproportionalityof systems with
have receivedfrom my collaboratorsin the compar- manyparties.However,the two-major-parties index
ative and collaborativeproject of which this is a (definedas the averagevote-seatsharedeviationof
product: Don Aitkin (AustralianResearchCoun- the two largest parties), which was expresslyde-
cil, Canberra),Asher Arian (Tel Aviv University, signedto steera middlecoursebetweenD and1, is in
Israel), Thomas C. Bruneau(Naval Postgraduate practicemuch closer to D than to I (Lijphart1985,
School, Monterey), Ivor Crewe (University of 10-12). A greatadvantageof D comparedwith both
Essex),WilfriedDewachter(CatholicUniversityof I and the two-major-parties indexis that it does not
Leuven,Belgium),A.-P. Frognier(CatholicUniver- entailarbitrarydecisionseitheron cutoff points (for
sity of Louvain, Belgium), William P. Irvine I, should the cutoff point be .5%, which is Rae's
(Queen's University, Kingston, Canada), W. K. criterion,or shouldit be 1, 2, 5, or 10%?)or on the
Jackson (Universityof Canterbury,Christchurch, numberof partiesto be counted.(Insteadof the two
New Zealand), Gary C. Jacobson (University of largestparties,why not the three largestpartiesor
California,San Diego), MarkkuLaakso(University perhaps just the largest party?) Mackie and Rose
of Kuopio, Finland),RafaelL6pezPintor (Autono- (1982)and Rose (1984)use a slightlydifferentform
mous University, Madrid), Thomas T. Mackie of D. Insteadof usingthe "negative"indexof dispro-
(Universityof Strathclyde,Glasgow), George Th. portionality,they preferto thinkmorepositivelyin
Mavrogordatos (University of Athens), Sten S. termsof an indexof proportionality;that is, instead
Nilson (Universityof Oslo), DieterNohlen (Univer- of D, they subtractD from 100%.
sity of Heidelberg),CorneliusO'Leary(Queen'sUni- 4. If the index of fractionalizationis represented
versity, Belfast), Jea-LucParodi (Fondation Na- by F and the effectivenumberof partiesby N, they
tionale des Sciences Politiques, Paris), Mogens are relatedas follows: N 1/(1 - F). The F values
Pedersen (Odense University, Denmark), Anton correspondingto 2.0, 2.5, and 3.0 partiesare .50,
Pelinka (University of Innsbruck), Bo SArlvik .60, and .67.
(GothenburgUniversity, Sweden), Yasunori Sone 5. In ContinentalEurope, the Droop quota is
(Keio University,Tokyo), Alberto Spreafico(Uni- often called the Hagenbach-Bischoff quota. Strictly
versity of Florence),Bjorn S. Stefansson(Agricul- speaking, there is a slight differencebetween the
tural ResearchInstitute, Reykjavik),Jfirg Steiner two. If v standsfor the total numberof districtvotes
(Universityof North Carolina,ChapelHill), andJan and m for the districtmagnitude,the Hagenbach-
Verhoef (Ministryof Housing, Physical Planning, Bischoffquota is v/(m + 1), usually roundedup,
andthe Environment,The Hague).I am also grateful whereasthe Droop quota is definedas v/(m + 1) +
to the IPSA panel participantsand to Andre Blais, 1, roundeddown if necessary(Leonardand Natkiel
Keith Bybee, David Collier, Richard Gunther, 1987, 3). Therefore,the two quotasdifferif v/(m +

494

This content downloaded from 128.235.251.160 on Tue, 30 Dec 2014 06:03:04 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
ElectoralLaws

1) happensto be an integer;but in mass elections 1957 on as two separatecases because they differ
wherev is measuredin thousandsof votes, this dif- with regardto districtmagnitude.
ferenceis so tiny that it can be safely ignored. To 9. In spite of these negative findings for PR
makematterseven more complicatedand (unfortu- systems, Rae's hypothesis still has a good deal of
nately) confusing, the term Hagenbach-Bischoff plausibility,and perhapsit should not be rejected
methodis sometimesalso used to describea divisor completely.Forinstance,it seemsquiteclearthatthe
system, as in Switzerland. This method merely smallbut cruciallyimportantFreeDemocraticparty
representsa shortcut in the application of the (FDP)in West Germanyhas benefitedsubstantially
d'Hondtformula,and Itsresultsareexactlythe same from its appeal to the voters to give it theirsecond
as those of d'Hondt. For all practical purposes, votes (whichare actuallythe moreimportantof the
therefore, the two can be regardedas identical. two votes); the FDP has in fact been called
Finally,I have to add a qualificationto my descrip- (somewhat sarcastically) the "party of second
tion of the Imperialiquota, whichis usedexclusively choice"(Dittberner1987). It is virtuallycertainthat
in Italy. It has been definedas v/(m + 2) since the withoutthe ordinalballot, the partywould not have
1958election;but it was evenlower-v/(m + 3)-in faredso well and thatmultipartismwouldhave been
the 1948and 1953electionsand, on average,slightly reduced.
higher in 1946, when v/(m + 2) applied to the 10. Thisis especiallyclearin the case of the French
higher-magnitude districtsand v/(m + 1) (in effect, Fifth Republic. The Australian ordinal majority
the sameas the Droop quota)in the smallerdistricts system does not behave very differentlyfrom the
(Carstairs1980, 157-59; Spreafico 1983, 188-90, pluralitysystems.
194). 11. For the 25 PR systems (excludingFranceof
6. In orderto classifythe difficulttwo-tiersystems 1951-56), the correlationbetweendisproportionali-
accordingto electoralformula,I distinguishbetween ty and legislativemultipartismis still only a very
two basictypes. In one type the districtsat the lower weak -.17.
level are used for the initial allocationof the seats;
but the final allocation takes place at the higher
level, often the nationallevel, on the basis of all of References
the votes cast in all of the lower-tierdistrictsthat
togethermakeup the higher-leveldistrict.Thus, the Balinski, Michel L., and H. Peyton Young. 1982.
formulaat the higherlevel is clearlythe moreimpor- Fair Representation:Meeting the Ideal of One
tantone. Belgium,Denmark,Germany,and Iceland Man, One Vote. New Haven: Yale University
(1946-59) fit this type. (Sweden from 1970 on is Press.
anotherexample;but since it uses the same formula Campbell, Peter. 1965. French Electoral Systems
at both levels, it does not representa classification and Electionssince 1789. Hamden,CT: Archon.
problem.Thisalso appliesto Icelandsince1959, but Carstairs,AndrewMcLaren.1980. A Short History
not to the earliercase of Iceland).The second type of ElectoralSystemsin WesternEurope.London:
uses one of the varietiesof largest-remainders for- Allen & Unwin.
mulasin the lower-tierdistricts;but insteadof allo- Dittberner,Jurgen.1987. FDP-Partei der zweiten
catingthe remainingseats to the remainingvotes in Wahl: Ein Beitragzur Geschichteder liberalen
these districts, all remainingvotes and seats are Partei und ihrer Funktionenim Parteiensystem
transferredto and allocatedin higher-tierdistricts. der Bundesrepublik.Opladen:Westdeutscher.
Here the formulaat the lower level is decisive. No Duverger, Maurice. 1963. Political Parties: Their
higher-levelformulais able to favor the largerover Organizationand Activity in the ModernState.
the smallerpartiessystematically,since the parties New York:Wiley.
with the highest totals of remainingvotes are not Gunther, Richard. 1989. "ElectoralLaws, Party
necessarilythe largestparties.Rather,the lower-tier Systems, and Elites: The Case of Spain."
formuladetermineshow many seats will be avail- AmericanPoliticalScienceReview 83:835-58.
able at the higherlevel, which is of crucialimpor- Katz,RichardS. 1980.A Theoryof PartiesandElec-
tance to the smallerparties. Only LR-Hareat the toralSystems.Baltimore:JohnsHopkinsUniver-.
lower tier is fully proportional.Examplesof the sec- sity Press.
ond type are Austria and Italy. Becausesome of Laakso, Markku,and Rein Taagepera.1979. "The
these six complex-districtingcountries underwent 'Effective'Number of Parties:A Measurewith
changes in formula, district magnitude, or ballot Applicationto WestEurope.ComparativePoliti-
structure,there are 11 additionalcases of electoral cal Studies12:3-27.
systemswith which the hypothesiscan be tested. Leonard,Dick, and RichardNatkiel. 1987. World
7. An unintendedbut welcomebyproductof these Atlas of Elections:VotingPatternsin 39 Democ-
adjustmentsis that the few erroneous magnitude racies.London:Hodder& Stoughton.
valuessuppliedby Raeno longerentailmisclassifica- Lijphart,Arend. 1985. "TheFieldof ElectoralSys-,
tions. tems Research: A Critical Survey." Electoral
8. I treatthe 1953electionand the electionsfrom Studies4:3-14,

495

This content downloaded from 128.235.251.160 on Tue, 30 Dec 2014 06:03:04 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
American Political Science Review Vol. 84

Lijphart,Arend. 1986. 'Degrees of Proportionality Rae, Douglas W. 1971. The Political Consequences
of ProportionalRepresentationFormulas."In of ElectoralLaws.2d ed. New Haven:Yale Uni-
ElectoralLawsand TheirPoliticalConsequences, versity Press.
ed. BernardGrofmanand Arend Lijphart.New Riker,WilliamH. 1986. "Duverger's LawRevisited.'
York:Agathon. In Electoral Laws and Their Political Conse-
Loosemore,John, and VictorJ. Hanby. 1971. "The quences, ed. Bernard Grofman and Arend
Theoretical Limits of Maximum Distortion: Lijphart.New York:Agathon.
Some Analytic Expressions for Electoral Rose, Richard.1984. "ElectoralSystems: A Ques-
Systems." British Journal of Political Science tion of Degreeor of Principle?"In Choosingan
1:467-77. Electoral System: Issues and Alternatives, ed.
Luxembourg.ServiceCentralde la Statistique.1984. Arend Lijphart and Bernard Grofman. New
"LesElectionslgislatives de 1945 A1984."Bulle- York:Praeger.
tin du Statec 30:119-31. Sartori,Giovanni.1986. The Influenceof Electoral
Mackie, Thomas T. 1985. "GeneralElections In Systems: Faulty Laws or Faulty Methods7"In
WesternNationsduring1984."EuropeanJournal ElectoralLawsand TheirPoliticalConsequences,
of Political Research 13:335-39. ed. BernardGrofmanand Arend Lijphart.New
Mackie, Thomas T. 1986. "GeneralElections In York:Agathon.
Western Nations during 1985." European Journal Spreafico, Alberto. 1983. "Systznes klectorauxet
of Political Research 14:695-97. system politiqueen Italie depuis 1945."In Les
Mackie, Thomas T., and RichardRose. 1982. The modes de scrutin des dix-huit pays libres de
International Almanac of Electoral History. 2d l'Europeoccidentale-leurs resultatset leurs ef-
ed. New York:Factson File. fets compares: elections nationales et euro-
Mackie, Thomas T., and Richard Rose. 1983. "Gen- p6enes, ed. JacquesCadart. Paris: PressesUni-
eral Electionsin WesternNations during1982." versitairesde France.
European Journal of Political Research Taagepera,Rein, and BernardGrofman.1985. "Re-
11:345-49. thinkingDuverger'sLaw:Predictingthe Effective
Mackie, Thomas T., and Richard Rose. 1984." Gen- Numberof Partiesin Pluralityand PRSystems-
eral Electionsin WesternNations during1983." Parties Minus Issues Equals One." European
European Journal of Political Research Journalof PoliticalResearch13:341-52.
12:335-42. Taagepera,Rein, and Matthew S. Shugart. 1989.
Nohlen, Dieter. 1978. Wahtsysteme der Welt- Seatsand Votes:TheEffectsandDeterminantsof
Daten und Analysen: Ein Handbuch. Munich: ElectoralSystems. New Haven: Yale University
Piper. Press.
Ornstein, Norman J., Thomas E. Mann, and Van den Bergh,G. 1955. Unity in Diversity:A Sys-
Michael J. Malbin. 1987. Vital Statistics on Con- tematic Critical Analysis of All Electoral
gress, 1987-1988. Washington: Congressional Systems. London:Batsford.
Quarterly.

Arend Lijphartis Professorof Political Science, Universityof CaliforniaSan Diego,


La Jolla, CA 92093.

496

This content downloaded from 128.235.251.160 on Tue, 30 Dec 2014 06:03:04 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

You might also like