You are on page 1of 25

No.

363 November 9, 1999

How and Why to Privatize


Federal Lands
by Terry L. Anderson, Vernon L. Smith, and Emily Simmons

Executive Summary

Fully a third of the land area of the United tioning off all public lands over 20 to 40 years.
States is owned by the federal government. Both environmental quality and economic effi-
Although many Americans support the preserva- ciency would be enhanced by private rather
tion of those lands, analysts on the left and the than public ownership. Land would be auc-
right agree that the federal government has done tioned not for dollars but for public land share
an exceedingly poor job of stewarding those certificates (analogous to no par value stock
resources. Indeed, the failure of socialism is as certificates) distributed equally to all
evident in the realm of resource economics as it Americans. Those certificates could be freely
is in other areas of the economy. transferred at any time during the divestiture
Four criteria should guide reform efforts: period and would not expire until after the
land should be allocated to the highest-valued final auction. Land would be partitioned into
use; transaction costs should be kept to a mini- tracts or primary units, and corresponding to
mum; there must be broad participation in the each tract would be a set of distinct, separable,
divestiture process; and “squatters’ rights” elemental deed rights. Any individual with a
should be protected. Unfortunately, the land documented claim to rights defined by those
reform proposals on the table today fail to meet deeds, however, would be assigned the appro-
some or all of those criteria. priate deed or deeds. Once divested, tract deed
Accordingly, we offer a blueprint for auc- rights would be freely transferable.

___________________________________________________________________________________

Terry L. Anderson is director of the Political Economy Research Center in Bozeman, Montana, and a senior fel-
low at the Hoover Institution. Vernon L. Smith is professor of economics at the University of Arizona. Emily
Simmons was a research fellow at PERC.
Public land man- Introduction ernment’s track record as a resource owner
agement does not and finds pervasive economic and ecological
Americans have entrusted the National mismanagement of the federal estate. We
always deliver Park Service, the U.S. Forest Service, and the then discuss how policymakers might best go
what the citizens Bureau of Land Management with some of about remedying the problem by privatizing
the most treasured and highest-valued land federal land. We establish four important cri-
expect either for in the United States as well as some of the teria for reform plans and suggest an innova-
the treasury or for least desirable properties on the continent.1 tive, politically realistic blueprint for divesti-
the environment. Approximately 630 million acres, or nearly ture. Moving from public to private owner-
one-third of the land area of the United ship with the right sort of divestment blue-
The federal gov- States, are owned by the federal government. print is easier than many people might think.
ernment actually Most of that land is located in the West. Over
loses money in one-half of the land area of Idaho, Nevada,
Oregon, and Utah belongs to the federal gov- The Economic
the course of ernment. Nevada, the extreme case, is 79 per- Mismanagement of
managing federal cent federally owned. It is indeed odd that, in
Public Lands
a society that rejects socialism, such a clearly
land assets esti- socialist resource policy survives with such While most of the public supports federal
mated to be widespread public support. land management as a means of protecting
worth billions. Public land management, however, does the environment, few people remember that
not always deliver what the citizens expect public ownership was originally justified on
either for the treasury or for the environ- economic, not ecological, grounds. The U.S.
ment. It is remarkable that the federal gov- Forest Service, for instance, was established
ernment actually loses money in the course to apply scientific principles to the economic
of managing federal land assets estimated to management of timber resources that were
be worth billions. Moreover, the federal gov- thought to be inefficiently managed by the
ernment has a poor record of ecological stew- private sector.2 Its original charge was to “fur-
ardship. The argument that federal agents nish a continuous supply of timber for the
are better land managers than are private use and necessities of the United States.”3
owners is not only suspect in theory; it is Gifford Pinchot, founder and first chief of
dubious in fact. the Forest Service, argued, for instance, that
Given that record, we might expect “conservation stands for the same kind of
numerous proposals to move public lands practical common-sense management of this
into private hands, but such efforts have country by the people that every business
proven politically elusive. One reason for the man stands for in the handling of his own
difficulty in broaching the subject politically business.”4 In fact, Pinchot opposed New
is the widespread, but dubious, belief that the York State’s preservationist management of
federal government is more likely to preserve the Adirondack Park because it was a waste of
environmental amenities than are private good timber.5
owners. Another is that those who feed at the However, we have learned since the
public trough are unwilling to give up their Progressive Era that public ownership of
free lunches. Finally, and perhaps most assets is less economically efficient than pri-
important, is the difficulty in drafting a vate ownership. As Table 1 shows for fiscal
divestment plan that can appease all the spe- years 1994, 1995, and 1996, the three main
cial-interest groups that consider themselves land-management agencies ran large deficits
stakeholders in the public lands and that can in every year with a total deficit in FY96
mobilize support from the much broader exceeding $2 billion. Those aggregate losses
electorate. came from lands managed by the three agen-
This study briefly surveys the federal gov- cies and valued at $150 billion in 1995.6

2
Table 1
Balance Sheet for Federal Land-Management Agencies

Timber Grazing Minerals Recreation

National Park Service


1994
Receipts $0 $0 $0 $75,688,000
Expenditures $0 $0 $0 $1,365,749,000
Total $0 $0 $0 $(1,290,061,000)

1995
Receipts $0 $0 $0 $80,513,000
Expenditures $0 $0 $0 $1,285,122,000
Total $0 $0 $0 $(1,204,609,000)

1996
Receipts $0 $0 $0 $77,771,000
Expendditures $0 $0 $0 $1,315,468,000
Total $0 $0 $0 $(1,237,697,000)

U.S. Forest Service


1994
Receipts $932,516,000 $11,056,000 $16,817,000 $47,895,000
Expenditures $1,206,685,000 $48,727,000 $33,017,000 $395,653,000
Total $(274,169,000) $(37,671,000) $(16,200,000) $(347,758,000)

1995
Receipts $701,774,000 $8,756,000 $20,663,000 $46,627,000
Expenditures $769,688,000 $19,622,000 $38,932,000 $359,492,000
Total $(67,914,000) $(10,866,000) $(18,269,000) $(312,865,000)

1996
Receipts $616,137,000 $7,352,000 $17,007,000 $49,368,000
Expenditures $994,239,000 $31,659,000 $35,017,000 $310,087,000
Total $(378,102,000) $(24,307,000) $(18,010,000) $(260,719,000)

Bureau of Land Management


1994
Receipts $59,455,339 $18,817,624 $34,294,539 $2,062,252
Expenditures $95,748,131 $54,274,000 $91,176,000 $39,818,809
Total $(36,292,792) $(35,456,376) $(56,881,461) $(37,756,557)

1995
Receipts $36,322,834 $16,428,704 $41,257,572 $2,637,777
Expenditures $105,894,000 $57,794,000 $94,720,000 $40,597,280
Total $(69,571,166) $(41,365,296) $(53,462,428) $(37,959,503)

1996
Receipts $85,188,910 $14,488,721 $46,545,422 $2,749,967
Expenditures $109,823,000 $59,015,000 $101,899,000 $44,334,884
Total $(24,634,090) $(44,526,279) $(55,353,578) $(41,584,917)

Sources: NPS recreation is from written communication from James Giammo, chief, NPS Budget Team, April 25, 1997. FS
expenditures and receipts are from Forest Service 1995–97 Statement of Obligation, National Forest System Funding, and
Statement of Receipts and Budget Explanatory Notes 1998, notes 180, 196. BLM expenditures are from Budget Justifications
1996–98. BLM receipts are from Public Land Statistics 1996–97, statement of receipts by source; and telephone and written
communication with Alice Sonne, BLM accountant, Denver.

3
Since the fall of the iron curtain, there can process, but the Justice Department has won
be little doubt about why this is occurring. As only a handful of cases. The one economic
did the bureaucracies of Eastern Europe, study that finds some evidence of collusion
land-management agencies face conflicting concludes that receipts are reduced by 7.9
policy goals, political pressures, perverse percent when collusion occurs.8
incentives, and poorly defined property A quick glance at Table 1 reveals that
rights. Managers are far removed from the reduced receipts are not the problem; federal
actual costs and benefits associated with land deficits are mainly due to bloated costs.
their actions, and the result is poor resource Federal land managers have few incentives to
economics and stewardship. Instead of seek- cut the administrative and road costs that are
ing profit, public managers seek larger bud- routinely higher than revenues.
gets, more personnel, and expanded power. A recent study by the Political Economy
Instead of producing the goods that are most Research Center comparing national and
highly valued by users, managers produce the state forests illustrates what efficient land
goods demanded by politically powerful spe- management could mean.9 For every dollar
cial interests. Rather than face and charge the Forest Service spent between 1994 and
market prices determined by supply and 1996, it took in only 30 cents. State land
demand, managers face and set prices deter- management in 10 western states, on the
mined by politics, which usually equate to other hand, netted $5.56 for every dollar
low or zero prices for those in political con- spent. The Forest Service averaged 200
trol. Not surprisingly, low receipts and high employees per acre while the states averaged
operating costs combine to create huge only 40 employees per acre. Between 1988
deficits for the federal land-management and 1991, the state of Montana spent about
agencies. $65 per thousand board feet of harvest to
Consider Randal O’Toole’s findings of administer its timber program. During the
deficit spending by each agency. In 1995 the same period, national forests spent about
Forest Service managed 192 million acres $140 per thousand board feet. A mile of road
worth $100 billion. The agency returned only in national forests costs about $50,000, but
$465 million to the treasury and spent $2.4 in state forests the cost is only $5,000.
billion for a net loss of $1.9 billion. In the The costs of compliance with planning
same year the BLM managed 220 million and environmental laws alone often exceed
Federal land acres worth $25 billion. It returned $134 mil- the value of the timber, as this example sug-
lion to the treasury and incurred costs of over gests. The La Manga timber sale in the
deficits are main- $1 billion for a net loss of $913 million. And Carson National Forest in New Mexico origi-
ly due to bloated the National Park Service netted a loss of $1.3 nally was to have been 4.2 million board feet
billion on an 87-million-acre asset worth $25 with an estimated value of about $718,000.
costs. Federal billion. Expenditures were $1.3 billion, and After obtaining new information, including a
land managers receipts were a paltry $1 million. 7 plan by the Fish and Wildlife Service to recov-
have few incen- The deficits from federal land manage- er the threatened Mexican spotted owl, the
ment are often blamed on subsidies to the Forest Service reduced the volume of timber
tives to cut the companies that produce commodities on the to 2.4 million board feet with an estimated
administrative federal estate, but the blame is misplaced. For value of about $411,000. At the same time,
example, it is not the sale of timber for below- the Forest Service spent $300,000 on envi-
and road costs ronmental analysis and $400,000 responding
market prices but excessive expenses that
that are routinely cause the losses related to timber production. to legal challenges, reanalyzing the sale area,
higher than Timber sales are supposed to be made at and updating the information.1 0Not surpris-
competitive auction to give the government ingly, the sale lost money.
revenues. the maximum price. There have been numer- In the case of grazing on federal lands, it is
ous allegations of collusion in the bidding not clear whether ranchers are receiving for-

4
age at fees below market value,11 but it is clear The Ecological
that excessive costs are the dominant cause of Mismanagement of
the grazing deficits. In FY96 BLM rangeland
management costs totaled $59 million, but
Federal Lands
the government collected less than $15 mil- Perhaps the pain of such great economic
lion in grazing fees. Fees would have to losses would be lessened if public lands were
increase four times to make them cover costs, ecologically healthy, but perverse economic
and few observers would argue that such an incentives inherent to public bureaucracies
increase would be realistic. also lead to perverse ecological results. This
Although small in terms of employment, clearly suggests that the challenge of improv-
acreage, and value of output, mining on fed- ing the ecological state of public lands is less
eral lands produces the highest return per a matter of choosing the right policies than
acre to the treasury. Despite its profitability, of changing the institutional arrangements.
the BLM and Forest Service do not promote Unfortunately, documenting the ecologi-
mining activity. Instead, by withdrawing land, cal health of federal lands is an uncertain
imposing regulatory restrictions, and causing business. That is because the very definition
delays, the agencies discourage the only land of ecological health is hotly contested within
use that returns a profit to the treasury.1 2 the environmental community,1 5 and there
Recreation is not usually mentioned by are few if any objective, analytical yardsticks
environmentalist groups that criticize poor of environmental health. Still, the informa-
federal land management, perhaps because tion available strongly suggests that the fed-
this activity generates large subsidies for their eral government has been a less than compe-
constituents. Many people assume that recre- tent ecological manager. 16 As Hope Babcock,
ation is a low-cost use of federal land com- a former official at the National Audubon
pared to commodity production, but noth- Society and currently a law professor at
ing could be further from the truth. As seen Georgetown University, acknowledges: “Few
in Table 1, recreation losses on the federal would assert that the historical institutional
estate often exceed losses from other activi- paradigm for managing the nation’s public
ties, especially if losses to the National Park lands has protected the natural resource val-
Service are included. ues of those lands or provided an harmo- The information
National parks generate the largest losses nious framework for resolving conflicts over available strongly
of all federal lands. That is mainly because their use. Unless a dramatic change in the suggests that the
park managers have had little or no incentive federalism structure for the management of
to collect fees even in popular parks where public lands is made, the conflict over their federal govern-
revenues could be significant. In 1994 use and management will continue to blight ment has been a
Yellowstone National Park led in losses with the future of these lands, just as it has marred
revenues of slightly less than $4 million and their past.”1 7 less than compe-
expenses of $18 million. With 3,046,000 vis- A U.S. General Accounting Office inquiry tent ecological
its and 67,366,000 visitor hours in 1994, the into U.S. Forest Service and BLM planning manager.
park lost $4.68 per visit or $0.21 per visitor for the period February 1988 to August 1990,
hour. In 1994 only two national park units, for instance, found that the agencies were not
Montezuma Castle Monument in Arizona meeting objectives for sustaining wildlife.
and Arches National Park in Utah, made a Fifty-one Forest Service and BLM plans con-
profit.1 3 To give an idea of how large the taining 1,130 wildlife-related action items
recreational subsidies currently are, former were to have been implemented, but 39 per-
Park Service director James Ridenour esti- cent had not been started, 22 percent were
mated that “it would take a 10-fold increase partially completed, 33 percent were fully
[in entry fees] to even get close to covering the completed, and 6 percent had unknown sta-
operating costs of our present parks.”1 4 tus. GAO also found that 60 percent of the

5
BLM’s grazing allotments were in less than plant communities, the elimination of criti-
satisfactory condition because of overgrazing cal habitat, and a serious decline in biodiver-
and that the agency was doing nothing to sity. The starving elk and bison have repeat-
correct the problem.1 8 edly browsed willow communities and aspen
Examinations of the state of federal stands on the northern range, causing a 95
forests have likewise not been kind. A 1995 percent decline in tall willows and aspens
report of the Forest Policy Center concluded since the establishment of the park and
that, because of perverse institutional incen- destruction of critical riparian and forest
tives, “the majority of forest health problems habitat. Because of the elimination of willows
in the [inland West] region exist on public and aspens, beaver are no longer able to find
lands” and that “the entire forest systems are food and dam-building materials on the
so far out of normal ecological range that vir- northern range and, therefore, have ceased
The Yellowstone tually every element in the system is affected, fulfilling their past ecological role in the
range is overpop- and may be at risk.”1 9 There are at least 39 structuring of the Yellowstone ecosystem.
million acres of federal forest land that are at According to Oregon State University hydrol-
ulated by elk and extreme risk of catastrophic wildfire. 20 ogist Robert Beschta, the damage to the
bison resulting in Photographs published in a Political riparian plain system of the Lamar River
the starvation of Economy Research Center report clearly “could take centuries to repair.”2 4
show the ecological consequences of federal According to ecologist Karl Hess Jr., Rocky
thousands of elk, mismanagement of our national forests.2 1 Mountain National Park also faces serious
an overgrazed Degradation in national parks, the “crown threats to ecological health under “natural
jewels” of the federal estate, is even more regulation” management. Hess describes the
range, the revealing. The mission of the National Park dramatic decline of aspens, willows, wet
destruction of Service is unambiguous: to protect the envi- meadows, and dry grasslands on the winter
plant communi- ronmental health of sensitive ecosystems. range and ascribes the damage to overgrazing
The Park Service’s charge is by elk. As in Yellowstone, beaver have ceased
ties, the elimina- performing their ecological role within
tion of critical to promote and regulate the use of Rocky Mountain National Park. “The con-
the . . . national parks . . . which pur- tinuously expanding herd of elk has impov-
habitat, and a pose is to conserve the scenery and erished some of the biologically richest and
serious decline in the natural and historic objects and most diverse ecosystems in the park.”2 5 The
biodiversity. the wild life therein and to provide overabundance of elk coupled with the even
for the enjoyment of the same in greater destructive force of fire suppression
such manner and by such means as has worked to seriously threaten diversity “as
will leave them unimpaired for the measured in the richness, mixture, and dis-
enjoyment of future generations. 22 persion of species and communities.”2 6 Hess
concludes that the destruction in Rocky
But an increasing number of ecologists Mountain National Park is the result of
are questioning whether that mission is “institutional flight from responsibility and
being accomplished. Charles Kay of Utah the accountability vacuum that has formed
State University, who does independent in its wake.”2 7
research on the Yellowstone ecosystem, is one Parks closer to urban centers face greater
such ecologist. His numerous publications threats from humans. For example, Great
on the ecological health of Yellowstone docu- Smoky Mountains National Park in
ment destruction, not preservation, within Tennessee boasts not only the natural vapors
the park.2 3 According to Kay, the Yellowstone that gave the park its name but air pollution
range is overpopulated by elk and bison from automobiles as well. The exhaust hangs
resulting in the starvation of thousands of heavy along the treetops, making the trees
elk, an overgrazed range, the destruction of more susceptible to disease and clouding the

6
vistas. Instead of decreasing automobile parks from degradation indicates that, even
numbers, however, the National Park Service when given the direct and unambiguous
faces an incentive to increase the number of charge of conserving and protecting environ-
visitors and, therefore, its operating budget. mental quality, the federal government is not
Fredericksburg and Spotsylvania National up to the job.
Military Parks are threatened by develop-
ment along their borders. Apartments with
little open space line the park boundary, and Policy Criteria for
children build tree houses and destroy natur- Privatization
al features. Writing in National Geographic,
John Mitchell said: “Parks were created ‘for Given the economic and environmental
the enjoyment of future generations.’ For costs of operating the federal estate, the time
many, that 78-year-old promise is eroding.”2 8 has come to reconsider proposals for privati-
In general, the National Park Service faces zation that were considered in the 1980s.
a tension between preservation and Private ownership offers an alternative to
tourism.29 In the past, numbers of visitors business as usual in Washington by getting
have driven budgets determined by politi- the incentives right for both the treasury and
cians who control purse strings. Now, under the environment. Privately owned forests and
the Fee Demonstration Program, the agency grazing lands cannot and do not operate year
can retain up to 80 percent of fees collected at to year in the red. Privately owned (and even
certain sites. In either case, there is an incen- state-owned) parks raise revenue sufficient to
tive to attract more visitors with little regard maintain the parks and produce a profit. And
to overcrowding. there is growing evidence that “enviro-capi-
In his book The National Parks Compromised, talists” can produce environmental ameni-
Ridenour decried the impact of “park barrel ties, especially if they do not have to compete
politics” on the nation’s treasures. He states, with below-cost public substitutes.3 2
“The government has just not taken care of An advantage of private land manage-
these beautiful treasures.” Consider his ment is that it promotes conservation of a
description of a visit he made during his resource valued slightly by most but highly
tenure to Sequoia National Park: by a few. That stands in sharp contrast to the
public sector, where conservation is political-
I noticed water running down the ly dictated and those without political clout
pavement and upon closer look, I have little voice. Rosalie Edge and her Hawk
noticed toilet paper. The old sewer Mountain Sanctuary Association are an Private owner-
system was overloaded and the pipes example of private initiative to conserve in
were clogged up. I couldn’t believe it; the face of great public opposition.3 3 The ship offers an
here we were trying to set the envi- Hawk Mountain Sanctuary Association, cre- alternative to
ronmental standard for the nation ated in 1938 to maintain the Hawk business as usual
and we were in blatant violation of Mountain Sanctuary, is a private, member-
the standards ourselves.3 0 supported, nonprofit organization designed in Washington by
to protect raptors that were considered pests getting the incen-
Can there be any doubt that the federal and vermin at the time of the association’s
government is not managing our lands well? conception. The internationally known sanc-
tives right for
Some degree of environmental deterioration tuary thrives today as a conservation, educa- both the treasury
of national forests and rangelands is perhaps tional, and research center. and the environ-
to be expected. After all, federal managers are Furthermore, privatization allows for win-
at least nominally required to facilitate win outcomes in the environmental arena. ment.
nonenvironmental uses of those lands.31 But Currently, one group’s win is by necessity
failure to adequately protect the national another group’s loss, and the dynamics of the

7
A well-defined political process guarantee that a win is only under which deeds to surface rights and
system of alien- temporary. When the political winds shift, water rights are separable and marketable.
the battle will be fought again. Never is the Similarly, remote wilderness areas on which
able, separable, outcome final. Although that process keeps logging or mining is too costly should be pre-
private property many people employed, the result is continu- served from such uses, and land whose “high-
ous economic losses and environmental est value” is for recreational or aesthetic
rights would per- degradation. appreciation should likewise be dedicated to
mit all potential The idea that there must be a better way to those ends.
gains from manage the federal estate is nothing new in This criterion is met by a well-defined sys-
policy circles. Especially in the 1980s, various tem of alienable, separable, private property
exchange in mar- groups involved in the Sagebrush Rebellion rights, which permit all potential gains from
kets to provide called for divestiture of federal lands at least exchange in markets to provide incentives for
incentives for the to the states if not to individuals.34 The the allocation and reallocation of land-use
Sagebrush Rebellion led to the proposal that rights to those functions that are perceived to
allocation and federal lands be transferred to the states, command the highest value.
reallocation of which would then lease them or otherwise
permit private access to them on terms deter- Criterion 2: Low Transactions Costs
land-use rights to mined by the state political environment. In Given a choice between two divestiture
those functions Alaska, where the state income tax was plans, both capable of satisfying the first cri-
that are perceived repealed, a serious effort is being made to terion, the preferred alternative should be the
find a way to ensure that the state transfers to one for which the transaction costs to the
to have the high- the people all income-producing resources. A participants are lowest. Hence, following
est value. number of plans have been discussed, such as divestiture, if Plan A requires more secondary
establishing a pass-through corporation or market exchange than Plan B, then Plan B
irrevocable trust that would own all of the would be preferable.
royalties or mineral rights on state lands and
distribute shares of stock to each Alaskan. Criterion 3: Broad Participation in
Another would devise a subsidized leasing Divestiture Proceedings
system that would allow even those Alaskans Since our concern is with resources now
of modest means to participate. Still another held in the public domain, which in principle
idea, which would give the rights directly to belongs to all citizens, it is desirable to permit
individual Alaskans, would involve a giant the broadest possible participation in any
lottery in which every Alaskan would have a divestiture proceedings. If public lands
chance, based on the luck of the draw, to own belong to all citizens, then all citizens have a
a valuable piece of property, including both legitimate claim to share directly in the
surface and subsurface rights or only subsur- wealth created by divestiture. Note that this
face rights. does not mean that every citizen need be
If divestiture is ever to move forward, a first given an ownership right to some tract of
step will be to develop criteria for evaluating public land.
alternative divestiture plans. Of the many cri-
teria that might be used, we suggest four. Criterion 4: Recognition of Squatters’
Rights
Criterion 1: Land Should Be Allocated to Variously misguided or now obsolete pub-
the Highest-Valued Use lic policies may have created de facto partial
Land whose value is greatest in timber rights in public lands. For example, grazing
production alone should not be used for permits have been issued by the BLM and the
grazing. Land whose value is greatest when U.S. Forest Service, and many have been
water and surface rights are separated should renewed or sold, sometimes along with
be represented by a property rights system adjoining private land. Consequently, the

8
value of those permits has been capitalized per acre, “proved” cultivation, and resided
into the price of home-base ranches.3 5 for five years on the land. Since land is not
Similarly, ground water rights have been cap- homogeneous, the fixed supply price
italized in the price of adjoining land under encouraged misallocation by underpricing
the common or statutory law “rule of cap- more-valuable tracts and delaying the
ture” that governs riparian rights in many divestiture of less-valuable tracts.
states. Perhaps the simplest procedure for Cultivation and residency requirements
dealing with these cases, which has already presupposed that the land was to be used
been followed in practice, is to recognize for agriculture and that residency was a
squatters’ rights officially by a recorded, good screening rule for land allocation.
transferable deed. All remaining land rights Since land use and the efficacy of residency
(for example, rights not previously appropri- are matters for the market to determine, the
ated, de facto) would be part of the divesti- Homestead Act violated Criteria 1 and 2.
ture plan. Since homesteaded land was freely alien-
The first of these four criteria is by far the able, however, Criterion 1 ultimately was
most essential, not so much because efficien- satisfied through the added costs of sec-
cy per se should be the paramount objective ondary exchange. The presumption that all
but because efficiency is achieved by a process land available under the Homestead Act
or atmosphere that encourages a search for should be cultivated is evident in the
and comparison of alternatives. It is that attempt by Congress to prevent “misuse” of
exploratory process, motivated by reward, the act by requiring homesteaders to “swear
that encourages innovation and permits the that the land was intended for actual settle-
best resource use to be discovered and imple- ment and cultivation and that entries were
mented where knowledge is imperfect. Thus, not being made for any other person.”3 7
price and allocation theory (efficiency) can-
not be validly separated from information The Resource Acts
and search theory. Although legislation had provided for
the privatization of land for agricultural
purposes and for mining (via the Mining
Privatizing Public Lands: Act of 1866 and subsequent mining acts),
Some Historical Programs Congress made no specific provision for Since our concern
timberlands until the Timber and Stone is with resources
and Current Proposals Act in 1878. Prior to that date, private tim-
To provide some perspective on the ber holdings were acquired under laws now held in the
divestiture criteria, it is useful to briefly allowing cash or scrip sales, or fraudulently public domain,
examine some historical programs and some under the homestead and preemption laws. which in princi-
of the recent proposals to privatize rights to Any risks associated with fraud were unnec-
public land. essary, artificial additions to the transac- ple belongs to all
tion costs of privatizing public lands. Since citizens, it is
The Homestead Act enforcement was nil, however, the damage
It is worth emphasizing that the was probably slight.
desirable to per-
Homestead Act of 1862, our most impor- Similarly, the Mining Act of 1866 and its mit the broadest
tant divestiture program for opening the successors did not satisfy the above criteria. possible partici-
American West (288 million acres, or 13 As in the Homestead Act, rules required
percent of the United States, were ultimate- that a piece of land (in this case, the lode) be pation in any
ly transferred to private owners under the “worked” before it could qualify as a min- divestiture pro-
act)3 6 did not meet the above criteria. Under ing claim and title could be obtained. Since
the act, title to 160 acres of land could be those claims were alienable, Criterion 1 was
ceedings.
acquired by adult citizens who paid $1.25 satisfied by secondary exchange.

9
The Squatters’ Acts both demanders and suppliers. Suppliers
Concerning Criterion 4, it should be have an incentive to conserve capital value
noted that recognizing full squatters’ rights and, therefore, to negotiate arrangements
by deed has many implementation limita- that limit demanders’ ability to overuse
tions. Where such rights have not been clear- resources. Where such arrangements are not
ly established by administrative records, feasible (e.g., because of monitoring costs),
there will be an incentive to claim those prior there is an incentive to sell rather than lease
rights and invest in proving or acquiring the land to user-owners. Hence, the own-or-
them, which is a deadweight loss. The prob- lease decision is itself a market-disciplined
lems of squatters on public land in the late decision with infeasible lease arrangements
18th century eluded all attempts to control it failing to survive. Private landowners who
by force and eventually gave way to a series of lease their property are not pressured into a
preemption acts beginning in 1830. Those “land of many uses” political philosophy,
acts recognized the preferential right of which we suspect is a euphemism for com-
squatters to purchase land, including mon property mismanagement. Private own-
improvements, at $1.25 per acre. It is possible ers have an incentive to see that property is
that some variety of preferential purchase leased, when feasible, to its highest-valued
The history of right would be appropriate as an alternative uses, net of deterioration costs.
governmental to Criterion 4 for certain present-day private The history of governmental land manage-
land management uses of the public lands. ment and leasing policies does not inspire con-
fidence in the proposition that the political
and leasing poli- Extension of the Federal Leasing process can even come close to emulating
cies does not Program sophisticated market property rights processes.
An alternative to complete divestiture of
inspire confi- the public lands is simply to extend, and per- Long-Term Leasing with Pullback
dence in the haps strengthen, the federal leasing program Modifications
proposition that as it now applies to offshore oil exploration, Marion Clawson suggested an innovative
timber harvesting on forest lands, grazing new public institution that could make the
the political rights, and recreational sites. The major prob- increased leasing of federal land politically
process can even lem with quasi-divestiture via an extension of feasible.3 9 Under Clawson’s proposal, any
leasing is that lease terms would be influ- organization or individual could make appli-
come close to enced, if not governed, by political rather than cation to lease a tract of land for any purpose
emulating sophis- by market processes. This provides incentives satisfying the applicable law. Within a limited
ticated market for the potential holders of leased grazing time after an application was filed, any other
rights, cutting-planting rights, wilderness use person or organization could file a so-called
property rights rights, and so forth to lobby for favorable pullback application for some part of the
processes. terms, such as grandfather rights, road subsi- land area specified in the original applica-
dies for easier access to leased tracts, and the tion. The pullback applicant would have to
relaxation of controls on overgrazing. meet the same terms that apply to the origi-
Likewise, it invites interest groups that are nal applicant. Thus, a forestry firm might
hostile to the commercial use of public lands apply for cutting-replanting rights on a tract
to obstruct the leasing process by raising a of Forest Service land, and the Audubon
host of burdensome bureaucratic obstacles.3 8 Society might file a pullback for one-third of
The fact that leasing is widely used in the the tract to be preserved as a wildlife refuge.
private sector does not imply that it can be Alternatively, or in addition, Kampgrounds
used efficiently in the public sector. Private of America might file to pull back a section
leasing contracts are immensely variable in for a commercial campground. The idea is to
creating property rights arrangements that force various competing potential users to
fine-tune resource use to the preferences of bargain with each other.

10
This is a thoughtful proposal, which, as own benefits, not those of a surrogate owner.
we interpret it, has the following constructive Third, a provision that allows one party to
features: intervene and acquire for its own purposes
some portion of a tract that another party
• It would attempt to substitute econom- has attempted to lease (provided that the sec-
ic for bureaucratic criteria in the evalua- ond party meets the lease terms of the first) is
tion and allocation of public land for unnecessarily complicated. The bargaining
and to competing uses. among and the strategic positioning of the
• It seeks to increase the incentive to con- multiple parties (including, perhaps, the leas-
serve replenishable resources through ing agency of the national government)
decentralized management and control would lead to high transaction costs, a dead-
over public lands. weight loss directly attributable to the insti-
• It would promote the economic develop- tution. A cleaner, lower-cost means of intro-
ment of land for recreational wilderness ducing the disciplinary function of the mar-
and natural resource extraction and har- ket is to allow “challenging” parties to simply
vesting purposes in a manner that bid away the rights sought by the first, or any,
would attempt to balance those conflict- party.
ing uses through the lease challenge It seems likely that the simplest way to do The simplest way
(pullback) procedure, forcing the con- that is by holding a competitive auction of the to introduce mar-
flicting interests of various groups to be various lease rights that are associated with ket discipline is
reconciled through bargaining. the land’s use. What is needed is a means
• It attempts to channel more environ- whereby each party can express its willingness to hold a compet-
mentalist-controlled income into the to pay to use or prevent the use of particular itive auction of
direct control, management, and preser- land rights, rather than a pullback procedure.
vation of wilderness resources. The “Different groups interested in the use of fed-
the various lease
social objectives of environmentalist eral lands would be free to compete against rights that are
groups would have to be translated into each other.”4 0 This sounds like a full-employ- associated with
a willingness to pay for preservation. ment program for lawyers. The problem is not
the creation of conflict among interest the land’s use.
The proposal does, however, contain a groups but efficient allocation. This requires
number of defects that would prevent or that wants—now expressible only in terms of
limit the achievement of those desirable political power—be expressed in terms of will-
objectives. First, the present public land- ingness to pay (bids).
management bureaucracy is likely to press Fourth, a more fundamental design defect
for as much control as possible over lease is the proposal’s attempt to specify a detailed
terms, by adding detailed monitoring provi- structure of price and quantity controls: roy-
sions, for example. Bureaucrats will want alties of 12.5 percent for oil and gas and 5
such controls to reflect their employment- percent of gross output for metals; the
creating and budget-maximizing needs, and requirement that only forestland whose pro-
those criteria will not be equivalent to the ductivity is 85 or more cubic feet per acre be
cost-constrained incentives owners face to available for lease; the requirement that tim-
manage the resource in a way that maximizes ber be purchased at prices that reflect present
its net capital value. Bureaucrats are not evil, stumpage prices for sawtimber and pulp-
but they will consciously or unconsciously wood, discounted as might be appropriate;
look out for their own interests. per acre grazing rents equal to the value (mar-
Second, whatever compromise on control ket?) of one pound of beef; the provision that
over lease terms ultimately prevails, bureau- local governments may rent up to 15 percent
crats can be expected to implement and of the federal land in their districts at $1 per
enforce those provisions to maximize their acre plus all costs; and so on. Those provi-

11
sions would substitute a regulatory maze for politically driven as their federal
the current land-management bureaucracy. counterparts. Moreover, the belief
It is not necessary or even feasible to try to that states would be more inclined to
control both prices and use patterns as speci- privatize public land is generally
fied in the leases. Given the lease terms (prop- unsupported. In fact, state govern-
erty rights of lessee), prices could be deter- ments have been rapidly expanding—
mined at auction. not divesting—their land estates, and
Finally, a fundamental problem with the there is little reason to believe that
proposed institution is that it does not solve (with the possible exception of a few
the lease-or-own allocation problem. As states) federal land transferred to
noted above, certain land uses may not be their jurisdictions would be passed
economically viable under lease contracts. A on to private citizens.
free market provides incentives to use lease The fundamental problem is, not
arrangements only if there are net gains from federal incompetence, but the politi-
exchange. cal allocation of natural resources to
Overall, the proposal is a valuable effort to favored constituencies, which subsi-
modify existing institutions and to introduce dizes some at the expense of others
some of the discipline of the market where and inflicts harm on both the eco-
essentially none exists. But the discipline of logical system and the economy as a
the market requires a market wherein each whole. Transferring land to the states
alternative, such as harvesting trees, must will only change the venue of those
pass the test of opportunity cost. (Is the political manipulations.4 3
Sierra Club, perhaps in coalition with Friends
of the Earth, willing to bid more than Some observers have pointed out that
Potlatch Forests to control the timber rights state land-management trusts (arrangements
on a given acreage?) In this regard, it is par- wherein state land managers are charged
ticularly important that the resources of the with managing public resources for the pur-
conflicting groups be used to signal values poses of securing funding for public educa-
and, thereby, to resolve the conflict in favor tion) have a solid track record of economical-
State land-man- of the highest-valued use rather than be dis- ly competent and ecologically sensitive man-
agement trusts sipated in a costly legal bargaining contest. agement of public lands.4 4 Whether states
have a solid track would incorporate federal lands into such
Land Transfers to the States trusts, however, is an open question.
record of eco- A number of policy analysts have flirted
nomically compe- with the idea of transferring most of the feder- Public-Private Land Trusts
al estate to state governments.41 There is some Another suggested divestiture plan would
tent and ecologi- evidence that state governments are more effi- transfer federal lands into public-private
cally sensitive cient land managers than are federal agents,42 trusts modeled after various state land trusts.
management of and there is certainly something to be said for This proposal has the following features:
allowing multiple experiments in land-man-
public lands. agement practices and local control over local • Trusts would be funded out of the net
Whether states resources. But a close examination of state income generated by their lands, not out of
land-management practices by ecological gross income or tax dollars. That would
would incorpo- economist Randal O’Toole found that minimize political attempts to microman-
rate federal lands age the land and provide ample incentives
into such trusts, state governments are no better man- for efficient management.
agers than are federal bureaucrats. • Trust managers would be free to market
however, is an They are just as economically ineffi- resources and to charge whatever they
open question. cient, ecologically short-sighted, and wished for resource access. That would

12
lead to charges that roughly approxi- Bounties continued to be offered during
mated fair market value. It would also the Indian Wars (many of the bounty lands
ensure a level playing field so that all were claimed by the Indians and could not be
resource users could compete with one settled) and the War of 1812. When it became
another in the marketplace rather than apparent that there was not enough land set
in court or the political system. aside to satisfy those claims, in 1830
• A share of trust user fees would be dedi- Congress authorized claimants to land in the
cated to a separate trust fund to be used Virginia Military Tract to exchange their
to protect biodiversity and endangered bounty warrants for Revolutionary War scrip
species. The managers of the second (land office money), which could be used to
trust fund would be able to give trust purchase land in Ohio, Indiana, and Illinois.
managers incentives to protect sensitive Bounty lands and scrip continued to be
ecosystems. One model might be the offered in the 19th century, in 1847 to enlist-
state of Washington’s system for com- ees in the Mexican War4 7 and under the
pensating its trust beneficiaries by “buy- Morrill Act of 1862.48 Under that act, which
ing” timber and not cutting it.4 5 set up the land grant colleges of agriculture
and mechanical arts, the states in which no
While such a plan would meet the first public land was available (mainly in the East,
two criteria for public land divestiture, it the South, and the Midwest) were given scrip
would, however, be vulnerable to criticism in lieu of the land that was granted to
based on the final two criteria, namely that Western states.49 In addition to scrip and
there be broad participation in divestiture bounty sales, cash and credit sales were com-
proceedings and that squatters’ rights be mon throughout the 19th century.5 0
fully recognized in the transition. Current proposals to privatize public
lands tend to emphasize cash sales for gov-
Land Sales for Government Revenue ernment revenue: “Probably the best way (to
Historically, much of the original stock of transfer ownership) would be to sell the lands
public land in the United States was priva- to the highest bidders and use the returns to
tized by land sales to raise government rev- pay off the national debt and to reduce
enue. The government’s taxing power was taxes.”5 1 These proposals meet Criteria 1 and
narrowly limited until late in the 19th centu- 2 and would certainly be acceptable to people
ry, and the intensity of the colonial tax revolt concerned about the perpetual mismanage-
meant that any attempt by the states or the ment of the public lands. However, they fail
Continental Congress to raise money by tax- to meet the broad participation criterion. There is good rea-
ation to prosecute the Revolutionary War Moreover, there is good reason to
would have raised questions about who oppose schemes that would direct revenue
son to oppose
might be the real enemy. That anti-taxation toward the federal government rather than schemes that
mood persisted long after the Revolution the individual. First, given congressional would direct rev-
and, coupled with the fact that state and fed- and bureaucratic behavior, it is not obvious
eral governments were rich in land, made it that the proceeds from cash sales would be enue toward the
all but certain that the public lands would be used either to reduce taxes or to retire the federal govern-
viewed as a major source of—or as a direct debt. More likely they would be viewed as a
substitute for—government revenue. Conse- politically unconstrained bonanza to be
ment rather than
quently, during the Revolution the states spent by Congress for all the usual pet proj- the individual.
offered land bounties to attract enlistees, and ects. There is at least a modicum of disci-
the Continental Congress did not hesitate to pline in requiring legislatures to vote either
promise land it did not have (until states deficits or new taxes to finance any increase
ceded the land to the United States begin- in spending programs. Second, if the pro-
ning in 1784)46 to obtain enlistments. ceeds were used to reduce taxes or the debt,

13
If the Audubon that would limit or rule out any direct ben- boundaries that would remain intact, such
Society owned the efits to those citizens who pay little or no as the Grand Canyon or Canyon Lands
taxes during the divestiture period. Third, National Park. Since the auction proce-
surface rights to a divestiture is less likely to be politically dures described in Provision 8 allow the
tract, then it acceptable if it is perceived as a program market, as expressed in individual bids, to
whose benefits are not widely shared by the determine the grouping of primary tracts
could negotiate population, and any serious program must into ownership parcels, it is better to err on
whatever restric- be politically practical. the small side in defining those elemental
tions it pleased on units of land.
the development A New Proposal: Auctioning Provision 3: Deed Rights
of oil and gas Rights to Public Lands Corresponding to each tract of land
resources, includ- would be a set of distinct, separable, ele-
The following proposal consists of many mental deed rights appropriate for each
ing prohibition of provisions defining the extent, procedures, tract. Those deeds could distinguish miner-
development. and process of divestiture of the public lands. al, oil and gas, water, grazing, timber, recre-
These provisions stem from the objective of ational use, wilderness use, and surface or
satisfying the evaluation criteria outlined other rights not otherwise specified (e.g.,
above. Although somewhat detailed for pur- agriculture). Again, within limits, too much
poses of discussion and debate, they are detail is better than not enough. In special
offered not as a final set of divestiture provi- cases, certain land-use restrictive covenants
sions but in an effort to encourage discussion could be written permanently into a deed.
and to suggest a new approach to the public Thus, the surface rights to the Grand
land policy debate that has plagued the Canyon might be permanently restricted to
Republic since its inception. the use of the surface for recreational and
For purposes of discussion, the proposal wilderness purposes. Owners of subsurface
can be divided into eight separate provisions. rights could be enjoined from exercising
such rights without the consent of the
Provision 1: The Scale and Scope of owner of surface rights, as is now common
Divestiture in property deeds. In such cases, for exam-
All federal lands would be divested over ple, the owner of coal rights could not
some reasonable but definite and limited extract coal without a contractual agree-
horizon, say 20, 30, or 40 years. Divested ment with the owner of surface rights. If
would be all BLM, Forest Service, National the Audubon Society owned the surface
Park, National Monument, National Recrea- rights to a tract, then it could negotiate
tional Area, continental shelf, deep sea bed, whatever restrictions it pleased on the
and military lands52 to which the federal or development of oil and gas resources,
state governments have jurisdictional claim. including prohibition of development.

Provision 2: Land Partitions Provision 4: Transferability


All such lands would be partitioned into Once divested, these tract deed rights
tracts or primary units (e.g., quarter sec- would be freely transferable, individually or
tions) as seems appropriate to the topogra- in any combination, by bequest, sale, assign-
phy and certain classifications of land. ment, lease, and so forth, as alienable private
Thus, land near urban areas might be parti- property. The purpose of subdividing rights
tioned into relatively small tracts, while by different land uses is to allow markets to
very large tracts might be appropriate for fine-tune allocations to tastes and use values.
the deep sea bed. Similarly, a tract might be The bidding procedure outlined in Provision
defined by certain “natural” historical 8 will allow deed rights within and across

14
tracts to be packaged in accordance with the time after the initial divestiture. Any individual
willingness to pay expressed by the bids. As already noted, where squatters’ rights with a document-
Alienability allows secondary market are sufficiently uncertain, poorly defined, or
exchange to repackage tract deed rights in inadequately documented, it is questionable ed historical
response to changes in information and eco- whether they should even be recognized by claim to rights
nomic or social conditions. pre-auction deed assignment. If it is thought
that squatters should be given preferential
defined by one or
Provision 5: Acknowledgement of purchase rights, rather than deeded rights, more of the deeds
Existing Rights then one possible procedure is to allow such would be
Any individual with a documented his- individuals the right to acquire title ahead of
torical claim to rights defined by one or the winning bidder at the ruling auction assigned the
more of the deeds would be assigned the price under Provision 8 below. appropriate deed
appropriate deed or deeds. Thus, an estab- or deeds.
lished holder of BLM or Forest Service graz- Provision 6: Block Sales
ing rights would be permanently deeded All tracts and the deed rights associated
those rights. For example, suppose a ranch- with them would be assembled into blocks.
er has been granted permits to graze cattle At regular intervals, say once a year or every
on a 10,000-acre tract of BLM land in six months, the deed rights for one block of
return for an annual rental fee. This ranch- elemental tracts would be put up for sale in
er would be assigned a deeded right to this a sealed-bid auction. Each auction should
arrangement, that is, to graze the 10,000 be preceded, well in advance, by an official
acres in return for the payment of the rental description of each tract and the corre-
fee to whoever might be the subsequent pri- sponding conveyance instruments so that
vate owner of the surface rights to this all interested parties can prepare their bids.
tract.5 3
This has two purposes: (1) it prevents Provision 7: Public Land Share
rights that have in some sense been legiti- Certificates
mately acquired and subsequently acted on Bids would be denominated not in money
in the past from being arbitrarily expropriat- but in public land share certificates, analo-
ed, and (2) it converts an uncertain and per- gous to no par value stock certificates. Unlike
haps poorly defined right into a well-defined, the Revolutionary War scrip, they would not
certain right. Consequently, it has the effect be denominated in acres; and unlike the
of changing the users’ incentives for hus- Mexican War scrip, they would not be
banding or otherwise maintaining the capital denominated in dollars.
value of the right. These certificates would be issued all at
BLM lands now subject to overgrazing, for once by the government well in advance of
instance, would no longer be overgrazed the first land auction and would be
unless that was the choice of the individual redeemable only in land at auction. Each
holder of the deeded grazing rights, who citizen might be granted 10 certificates, so
would now bear the full cost of any decline in there would be about 2 billion shares out-
the land’s capital value. Under the BLM per- standing. The certificates could be freely
mit system, individuals may be poorly moti- exchanged, assigned, or bequeathed at any
vated to manage pasture resources efficiently, time over the entire divestiture period, and
since the permits can be withdrawn or subject- they would not expire until after the final
ed to new restrictions. If the individual who is auction.
assigned the grazing rights deed desires full To facilitate a continuous market in cer-
title to the land, he is free to bid at auction for tificates, they could be listed for trading on
the remaining deed rights. Alternatively, he stock and commodity exchanges, which
may offer to sell his grazing rights deed at any would then be free to create futures or

15
Public land deeds options markets in public land shares. Another feature of this procedure is that
won at auction Consequently, bidders for land at auction it would extend the principle of the second
would always know from the current mar- price sealed-bid auction5 7 to the combina-
would be paid for ket price of a share what would be the dol- torial action and thereby increase the incen-
by surrendering lar equivalent of a given bid in shares. If tive of each individual to submit bids equal
shares were selling for $100, for instance, a to his or her maximum willingness to pay.
certificates, which bid of two and a half certificates for the Only if all bidders bid their maximum will-
could be bought mineral rights to a particular tract of land ingness to pay will land rights be awarded
in the open mar- would be equivalent to $250. to those who value them most.
Public land deeds won at auction would The above proposal would recognize
ket by winning be paid for by surrendering certificates, each citizen’s right to share in the wealth
bidders either which could be bought in the open market created by privatizing the public lands.
before or after the by winning bidders either before or after Individuals without competence or interest
the auction. With an ongoing options mar- in the productive use of any of the auc-
auction. ket, bidders could always hedge their bids at tioned rights would be free to sell their ini-
auction by buying an equivalent quantity of tial assignment of share certificates in the
certificate options and then exercising the open market. Oil companies, forest product
options only if their bids were accepted.5 4 companies, home builders, ranchers, farm-
ers, outdoor recreation companies, private
Provision 8: Combinatorial Auctions individuals, environmentalists, and envi-
The auction procedure would corre- ronmental organizations would be free to
spond to what has been called a “combina- purchase share certificates or receive them
torial” auction.5 5 Each bidder would be free by donation or bequest. Environmental
to bid on any right or any combination of groups, such as the Sierra Club, Friends of
rights for one or more tracts. He might bid the Earth, and the Audubon Society,
for all the deed rights for a given tract, only instead of dissipating their resources in
the surface rights, only the oil and gas political action and lobbying for conserva-
rights, or some combination of those. tionist policies on public lands, could pur-
The winning bidders would be deter- chase certificates in the open market and
mined by computing5 6 those bid combina- actively campaign for the American people
tions that maximize the total economic sur- to donate their certificates to preservation-
plus for the offered block of tract rights. ist funds. Those certificates could be
This procedure permits elementary deed pooled and used to bid for the surface or
rights to be assigned to those package com- other rights to any tracts the environmental
binations valued most highly by the market groups chose. They could then manage
(collection of bidders). Thus if the mineral those tracts as they saw fit. Similarly, tim-
rights to a particular combination of 10 ber or oil companies could bid for these
tracts are more valuable to at least one bid- resource rights only or bid for them in com-
der than are the component tract mineral bination with surface rights.
rights to any collection of bidders, the high- By awarding rights singly or in combina-
est combination bid for the 10 tracts would tions to those uses that command the high-
exceed the sum of the highest bids for the est willingness to pay, the auction market
component tracts, and the combination bid would determine the most efficient way, ini-
would win. Similarly, if a particular combi- tially, to separate or combine elementary
nation of rights, say surface and grazing land-use rights. As new information or con-
rights, were more valuable in combination ditions affecting land-use potential became
than separated, the highest combination available, secondary exchange could recom-
bid would win over the sum of the highest bine or further subdivide combinations of
separate bids. land-use rights.

16
Amenity Resources: What section identified by a separate deed. Except Potential models
Should We Do about the where leases for those resources have already for the private
been granted, the winners of deeded rights
Grand Canyon? would have to obtain permission from (con- ownership and
The “crown jewels” of the federal estate (the tract with) the owner of the surface rights management of
national parks, wilderness areas, and particu- before timber could be cut, wells could be
larly scenic forestlands) make up at most 10 to drilled, or minerals could be mined.
amenity resources
20 percent of the public lands.58 Must they be Under this arrangement the owner of the are provided by
put “off limits” to private owners? surface rights to the Grand Canyon, whether private organiza-
Potential models for the private owner- it was the Nature Conservancy or Atlantic
ship and management of amenity resources Richfield, would have an incentive to seek tions such as the
are provided by private organizations such as donations or charge visitor fees, or both, to Nature
the Nature Conservancy and the direct manage the scenic resources of the Grand Conservancy and
preservation programs of the National Canyon. As a consequence, willingness to pay
Audubon Society. The Nature Conservancy, (or donate) to preserve these scenic resources the National
with 900,000 members, has purchased, would become a factor in preservation—a fac- Audubon Society.
leased, or obtained easements to approxi- tor not now present in public land-manage-
mately 10.5 million acres of land in the ment policy. The greater the willingness to
United States and 60 million acres world- pay for preservation, the greater the incentive
wide. It currently manages approximately 1.2 of a private owner to negotiate restrictions on
million acres and hires managers and uses the development of subsurface, grazing, or
local volunteers for the stewardship of 1,500 timber rights. Thus slant drilling from out-
private preserves.5 9 The National Audubon side the park might be negotiated, where fea-
Society, with 550,000 members, controls sible, and timber cutting might be permitted
250,000 acres including 100 sanctuaries and under a program of replacement planting
nature centers.60 On the society’s 23,000-acre and selective cutting or where it did not inter-
Rainey Wildlife Sanctuary, oil companies fere with amenity values. A slightly more
have drilled several producing gas wells and restrictive alternative would be to prohibit
ranchers graze cattle under rental contracts bids that combined surface rights with any of
negotiated with the society.6 1 Local conserva- the other rights. That would force a separa-
tion organizations have likewise played a fre- tion in the ownership of surface and other
quently unappreciated but important role in rights so that the development of the latter
preserving sensitive ecosystems.6 2 could proceed only by contract with the
What special provisions, if any, should the owner of surface rights.
divestiture plan make for the Grand Canyon Under either approach environmental
and similar national parks, monuments, groups interested in managing amenity
forests, and wilderness areas? One possibility resources would have an incentive to concen-
would be to specify no restrictions at all, trate their bids on surface rights. Radical
except perhaps to define tract size for surface environmental groups desiring to “lock up”
rights to the current boundaries for some petroleum or mineral resources could bid
parcels. Thus the surface rights to Grand directly for those subsurface rights against
Canyon National Park or Yellowstone commercial enterprises for the purpose of
National Park, as these parks are now defined preventing development of those resources.
by the U.S. Geological Survey boundaries, Anyone uninterested in exploiting land for
would be kept intact. All other rights would economic gain would have the right to “lock-
be represented by deeds to elemental tracts, up” any resource.
as appropriate. For example, the unit might More restrictive procedures might include
be a 640-acre section, with mineral, oil and
gas, and timber (or grazing) rights to each • allowing only qualified environmental

17
Surface bound- organizations to bid on the surface self by limiting his resale market with a
aries are inade- rights to the national parks and wilder- restrictive covenant. There is a vast difference
ness areas; between a government auction of certain
quate for defining • employing restrictive covenants to limit public lands with restrictive covenants
rights to the uses of national park or wilderness attached and the Nature Conservancy’s buy-
lands; thus surface rights could be ing land in the open market (or acquiring it
resources that restricted to scenic or wilderness uses, by voluntary gifts) and then reselling or leas-
migrate across or suitably defined, as is now done in pri- ing it with restrictive covenants. The latter is
under those vate deeds; and a market-disciplined decision whose cost is
• combining all extractive resource rights borne privately, while the former is not disci-
boundaries. with surface rights and including a plined by an opportunity cost test, and the
covenant prohibiting all development of cost is borne publicly.
those resources and requiring the land
to be preserved as wilderness.
Common Pool Resources:
Those restrictions, however, set a danger- Deeds to Water, Oil, Gas,
ous precedent by giving special privileges to
particular groups that would be chosen by
and Fish
bureaucratic criteria. Although we have no The surface boundary of land tracts is suf-
doubt that a mix of ownership of scenic ficient in most circumstances to provide well-
resources by the Audubon Society, the Nature defined property rights to cultivation, grass,
Conservancy, and other such groups would timber, subsurface minerals, wildlife refuge
vastly improve upon the National Park or habitat, wilderness, and recreational
Service, we think rigging the outcome of auc- resources. But surface boundaries are inade-
tions is unwise. Those organizations and their quate for defining rights to resources that
policies have evolved in an environment in migrate across or under such boundaries.
which they have had to compete with com- The economic objective in defining property
mercial enterprises for land acquisitions. rights is to limit the quantitative extent of the
They have flourished under this discipline (as rights to particular resources.
of 1994, the 21 largest U.S. environmental Hence, to say that a person has grazing
organizations had a collective annual budget rights to a section of land means that he has
of approximately $736 million and 14 million the right to fence it and consume as much of
members),6 3 and there is no a priori reason to the grass as he chooses, subject to the limita-
suppose that they need be given any preferen- tions of his contract with the owner of sur-
tial rights over commercial enterprises. face rights. A timber right gives a person sim-
Moreover, we think covenants would be ilar control over all timber growing within
very unwise as part of a general policy of certain boundaries. In each of those cases, the
divestiture of amenity resources. Owners of quantity of the resource to which he has a
surface rights are free to follow development right is whatever quantity he finds growing
policies that are as restrictive as they please. within his land boundary. Note that in those
But such owners have earned that right by cases the resource quantity or quality need
paying the opportunity cost of the land, that not be certain for the right to be well defined.
is, by bidding more than other potential own- The market is entirely competent to discount
ers who would have followed less restrictive for uncertainty. Also note that the moment a
policies. Similarly, any winning bidder at auc- person crosses beyond his boundaries to
tion should be free to resell the land with his graze or log, he is poaching on the preserve of
own restrictive covenant provisions. Such an his neighbor, who would have clearly defined
owner, having paid the opportunity cost, rights under our proposal.
would be free to impose a capital loss on him- But if fish swim and water, oil, and gas

18
flow under gravity or pressure, surface feet of water. Any part of the rights conveyed This property
boundaries no longer delineate the quantita- by those deeds could be bought, sold, rights system
tive extent of the resource and no longer assigned, or bequeathed by contracts separa-
define exclusion. What is needed in these ble from contracts for the transfer of real could be applied
cases is a property right defined in units of property. Water deed transfers could be to a common
the resource itself. This principle has already recorded in county or water authority records
been applied to cattle, parakeets, and dogs; in the same manner as transfers of real prop-
property lake or
but fish, water, and oil seem destined to take erty. That would allow existing institutional ocean fishery in
a little longer. procedures that have stood the test of time to which it is feasi-
In many cases, it is feasible to create deed- be extended to water rights. Water deed
ed rights to migratory resources. Consider, prices would be freely negotiable to facilitate ble to estimate
for example, the water supply for Tucson, a continuous market in rights to draw on the the stock of fish
Arizona. The city is located in a basin con- existing stock of water. All pumps would be and meter the
taining a natural subsurface aquifer estimat- metered on farms, ranches, mines, factories,
ed to hold 20 million to 40 million acre-feet or municipalities, as is now the case for met- catch.
of water. All of Tucson’s water is pumped ropolitan area residences. Each user would
from deep wells drilled into this aquifer. receive a monthly bill for the cost of pump-
According to 1975 estimates, the natural ing, distribution, and management (exclud-
recharge rate was 75,000 acre-feet per year ing private well owners who bear this cost
and the consumption rate was about 225,000 directly) and a monthly bill denominated in
acre-feet per year.6 4 Anyone with a surface fractions of an acre-foot of deed certificates
right to land has been free to drill into this to be surrendered for all water consumed
water supply and start pumping. In addition (including that taken from private wells).
to city and county water authority wells, indi- Every few years, depending on cost, the
vidual residences; the University of Arizona; recharge of water to the aquifer could be esti-
and surrounding farms, horse ranches, man- mated, or perhaps the aquifer stock reesti-
ufacturers, and mining companies own pri- mated, and the outstanding stock of deed
vate wells that pump from this common certificates adjusted by a stock dividend to
water stock. Periodically, these wells have to maintain equality between the stock of water
be deepened as the water level declines. The and total claims on water. Alternatively, and
city and county water authorities charge only perhaps more simply, one could adjust the
for the cost of drilling, pumping, distribut- redemption exchange rate for deed certifi-
ing, and managing this water system. The cates. For example, if after 10 years the
water itself is free. aquifer had experienced an 11 percent
To establish property rights to ground increase in inventory, then the redemption
water, we propose that the county issue water charge would be reduced so that the con-
deed certificates for 30 million acre-feet of sumption of 10 acre-feet of water would
water.65 Those deeds could be issued in pro- require the surrender of only nine acre-feet of
portion to the surface area held by landown- deed certificates. In this way, the exchange
ers but with adjustments for land used for rate between certificates and metered water
residences, irrigated agriculture, mining, and use could be adjusted to balance the demand
industry. If feasible, adjustments could be for and supply of water as an asset.
made in proportion to a base period rate of This property rights system could also be
water consumption. The objective would be applied to a common property lake or ocean
to recognize squatters’ rights to water, since fishery in which it is feasible to estimate the
the price of land has already capitalized the stock of fish and meter the catch. Fishermen
right to pump water freely. would own deeds to live fish, which would be
Deeds could be issued in convenient surrendered as the fish were harvested, and
denominations of 1, 5, 10, or fractional acre- would be free to use any technology (now

19
Rights to discov- extensively regulated to control catch rates) separate or repackage tracts and rights in
ered oil and gas in they pleased. Regular stock dividends or response to changing information and eco-
adjustments in the exchange rate between nomic conditions.
petroleum reser- deeds to fish and fish consumed could be Third, the expropriation of squatters’
voirs could be used to compensate for growth in the fish rights already recognized by the government
stock or variations due to other factors. (for example, outstanding BLM grazing per-
assigned in the Similarly, rights to discovered oil and gas mits) is avoided by deed assignment to those
form of freely in petroleum reservoirs could be assigned in individuals. This aspect of the plan would
marketable and the form of freely marketable and transfer- discourage opposition to divestiture from
able deeds based on the estimated size and individuals who rightly feel they have some
transferable deeds extent of the reservoir stock.6 6 The owner of real economic stake in the present system.
based on the esti- the oil and gas rights on a tract of land with a Fourth, the bidding mechanism provides
mated size and proven well need not drill additional wells to an incentive for combination bids to express
exercise the right to oil and gas. Instead, the maximum willingness to pay, by guarantee-
extent of the owner might sell his oil deed certificates to ing that except in rare cases (for example, tied
reservoir stock. the owner of an adjoining tract on which bids) the winning bidders will pay prices that
drilling may be less costly or to a neighbor are less than the amounts bid. The effect is to
who has already drilled an efficient number maximize allocative efficiency.
of producing wells. The idea is to create a Fifth, the proposal provides opportunities
property rights system in which the value of and incentives for environmentalists and
oil reservoir stocks can be captured without their organizations to participate directly in
producing oil for the market. In this way the the ownership and management of amenity
decision to drill wells or to produce from resources by bidding for the surface rights to
existing wells can be based on the profitabili- park and wilderness lands. Present federal
ty of those activities rather than on a concern laws that restrict certain parcels of land to
that others will capture any oil that is not specified economic uses (such as timber har-
recovered. vesting or mining) would be abolished.
Finally, in the case of certain common
pool resources such as ground water and
Conclusion fisheries, we propose that the appropriate
governmental unit issue deeded certificate
The divestiture proposal in this paper is rights to unrecovered ground water and to
characterized by the following principal fea- live fish by species. These transferable and
tures. First, it is fair in the sense that all citi- marketable certificates would then be surren-
zens would share equally in the value of the dered in payment for extracted water or for
628 million acres of federal land that would landed fish. Equality between the stock of
be capitalized into the market price of land outstanding certificate claims and the esti-
share certificates, and all would benefit from mated stock of the resource could be main-
the productive opportunities created by tained by periodic adjustment of the surren-
divestiture. der terms of certificates to reflect updated
Second, elementary property rights are estimates of the resource stock. This proce-
defined by deeds to the various functional dure, in effect, creates exclusive marketable
uses of unit tracts of land. The size of owner- property rights in common property
ship parcels and the manner in which use resources, which allows the natural scarcity
rights to the land were combined into pack- of such resources to determine their prices
ages of ownership rights would be deter- and thereby discipline the individual owner’s
mined by the market in the primary auction decision to extract the resource.
by a combinatorial sealed-bid mechanism, Many individuals and groups may oppose
and subsequently by exchanges that could the divestiture of public lands because they

20
believe that only the government can be government with the proper stewardship and The public man-
trusted to preserve and beautify such lands.6 7 husbanding of such resources. It is also agement of lands,
This view receives intellectual support from important to realize that the public manage-
economists who perpetuate the myth that ment of lands, which is subjected to a spec- which is subject-
the theory of market failure in the presence trum of conflicting political interests, creates ed to a spectrum
of public goods implies, ipso facto, the need common property–like incentives to over-
for government production, ownership, and graze grassland, overcut some forests (but
of conflicting
management of such goods. But this is a non undercut others), or overcrowd many parks. political interests,
sequitur, since the same economic logic leads And where public land management encoun- creates common
to the theory of government failure in pro- ters weakly organized political opposition,
viding public goods through majority rule the budget-expanding incentives of govern- property–like
and bureaucratic processes.68 Even a public ment agencies tend to dominate policy deter- incentives to
lands supporter such as resource economist mination. That is particularly evident in the overgraze grass-
John Loomis of Colorado State University 80-year history of large dam construction by
acknowledges that “despite the best of inten- the Bureau of Reclamation and the Army land, overcut
tions by managers, politicians often impose Corps of Engineers. No private power com- some forests, or
inefficiencies to benefit their local con- pany, no consortium of such companies, and
stituencies. These inefficiencies are not only no industrial combine would have wasted its
overcrowd many
economically unsound, they are environmen- capital by flooding 186 miles of the Colorado parks.
tally unsound.”6 9 River from Glen Canyon to Cataract Canyon
Other individuals and groups may oppose then followed with a downstream proposal
divestiture, though they strongly disapprove to flood Marble Canyon and Grand Canyon
of public land-management policies, because behind two great new dams.
they hope to change those policies directly Neither is it an efficient use of environ-
within existing institutions. We think both mentalist resources to carry out political bat-
views are naive in their assessment of the real- tles aimed at preventing environmental
ity of public land management and of the degradation at the hand of the government.
efficacy of resource allocation and manage- Everyone would benefit if the funds and
ment through political processes. effort expended by environmental groups
The proposal outlined in this paper is were diverted from political action to the
unlikely to be received with favor, initially, direct acquisition and management of
by environmentalists or by many econo- amenity resources. Similar benefits would
mists with well-intentioned concern for the result if the expenditures by oil, forest prod-
existence of “public good” externalities in uct, and ranching and mining interests to
amenity resource use. We share the con- influence the leasing policies of public land-
cerns of both groups, but we think it is time management agencies were channeled into
to get beyond superficial market failure the direct acquisition and development of
theorems that ignore the role of property subsurface, grazing, and timber resources.
rights and institutions in a market econo- The premise of this paper is that land use
my. For economists, the problem is to iden- should be depoliticized and determined by
tify those property right characteristics that economic criteria operating through markets
have allowed private markets to succeed, to in which the various functional uses of land
develop some principles of the relationship are recognized in the form of elemental prop-
between property rights and market effi- erty rights. Where public lands have already
ciency, and to ask how and at what cost been set aside as primitive, wilderness, or park
those principles can be applied to public areas, a case can be made for keeping the sur-
resource allocation problems. face rights intact. Just as environmental orga-
For environmentalists, it is important to nizations such as the Nature Conservancy
get beyond the visceral misidentification of and the National Audubon Society have

21
Land use should acquired private land in competition with 8. Laura H. Baldwin, Robert C. Marshall, and
Jean-Francois Richard, “Bidder Collusion at
be depoliticized other users, it can be expected that environ- Forest Service Timber Sales,” Journal of Political
mental organizations, by diverting funds now Economy 105, no. 4 (August 1997): 657–99.
and determined spent on political action and by launching
9. Holly Lippke Fretwell, Forests: Do We Get What
by economic crite- new fundraising efforts for direct land acqui- We Pay For? (Bozeman, Mont.: Political Economy
sition, would be able to bid successfully for
ria operating many of these public lands. If the rights to
Research Center, 1999), pp. 1, 5. See also Donald
Leal, “Making Money on Timber Sales: A Federal
through markets public lands can be divested as we suggest, all and State Comparison,” in Multiple Conflicts over
owners and users will face the opportunity Multiple Uses, ed. Terry Anderson (Bozeman, Mont.:
in which the vari- Political Economy Research Center, 1994), pp. 8–9.
cost of their actions so that both the treasury
ous functional and the environment will benefit. 10. U.S. General Accounting Office, “Forest
uses of land are Service Decision-Making: A Framework for
Improving Performance,” GAO /RECD-97-71,
recognized in the 1997, p. 29.
Notes
form of elemental 11. See Karl Hess Jr. and Jerry Holechek, “Beyond
1. John Loomis, a defender of public ownership of
property rights. land and professor of agricultural and resource
the Grazing Fee: An Agenda for Rangeland
Reform,” Cato Institute Policy Analysis no. 234,
economics at Colorado State University, contends July 13, 1995.
that much of the land in the federal estate is there
because “the lands were so unproductive in pro- 12. David Gerard, “The Mining Law of 1872:
ducing commodities that the government could Digging a Little Deeper,” PERC Policy Series PS-
not even give them away to railroads, homestead- 11, December 1997.
ers, ranchers, or miners.” John Loomis, “Economic
Rationales for Continued Ownership of Land,” 13. Randal O’Toole, 1994 Park Data, July 1997,
Presentation at the conference “Challenging http://www.ti.org/~rot/nps94data.html.
Federal Ownership and Management: Public
Lands and Public Benefits,” Natural Resources 14. James Ridenour, “Our National Parks: The
Law Center, University of Colorado School of Law, Slide towards Mediocrity,” Presentation at the
Boulder, October 11–13, 1995. conference “Challenging Federal Ownership and
Management: Public Lands and Private Benefits.”
2. See generally Roger Sedjo, “Forest Resources:
Resilient and Serviceable,” in America’s Renewable 15. For an overview of the uncertainties within
Resources: Historic Trends and Current Challenges, ed. the field, see K. S. Shrader-Frechette and E. D.
Kenneth Frederick and Roger Sedjo (Washington: McCoy, Method in Ecology (New York: Cambridge
Resources for the Future, 1991), pp. 88–91. University Press, 1993).

3. Policy statement of the Forest Reserve Organic 16. U.S. General Accounting Office, “Forest
Administration Act of 1897, as amended. Cited in Service Decision-Making,” p. 32. That degrada-
Frederick Cubbage, Jay O’Laughlin, and Charles tion need not occur on public lands is demon-
Bullock III, Forest Resource Policy (New York: John strated by the management of state forests that
Wiley & Sons, 1993), p. 19. actually earn a profit. An environmental quality
audit, requested by the Montana legislature and
4. Gifford Pinchot, The Fight for Conservation (Seat- performed by the Forestry Division, concluded
tle: University of Washington Press, 1967), pp. that the state does a better job of protecting
79–80, cited in Karl Hess Jr., Visions upon the Land: watersheds from the impact of logging than does
Man and Nature on the Western Range (Washington: the Forest Service. See Bill Schultz, Montana
Island Press, 1992), p. 77. Forestry Best Management Practices Implementation
Monitoring (Missoula: Montana Department of
5. Robert Nelson, “How and Why to Transfer BLM State Lands, 1992).
Lands to the States,” Competitive Enterprise
Institute, Washington, January 1996, p. 25. 17. Hope Babcock, “State Primacy, Federal
Consistency, or Collaborative Management: Can
6. Randal O’Toole, “Run Them Like Businesses: Cooperative Federalism Models from Other Laws
Natural Resource Agencies in an Era of Federal Save Our Public Lands?” Presentation at the con-
Limits,” July 1997, http://www.ti.org/~rot/business. ference “Challenging Federal Ownership and
html. Management: Public Lands and Private Benefits.”
7. Ibid., Table 1. 18. U.S. General Accounting Office, “Rangeland

22
Management: More Emphasis Needed on Pork Barrel Politics and America’s Treasures
Declining and Overstocked Grazing Allotments,” (Merrillville, Ind.: ICS Books, 1994), p. 108.
GAO/RCED-88-80, 1988.
31. The Multiple-Use Sustained Yield Act of 1960
19. Lance Clark and R. Neil Sampson, Forest Ecosystem says: “It is the policy of the Congress that the
Health in the Inland West: A Science and Policy Reader national forests are established and shall be
(Washington: Forest Policy Center, American Forests, administered for outdoor recreation, range, tim-
1995), pp. 2, 5, cited in Nelson, “How and Why to ber, watershed, and wildlife and fish purposes.
Transfer BLM Lands to the States,” p. 4. ‘Multiple Use’ means the management of all the
various renewable surface resources of the nation-
20. U.S. General Accounting Office, “Western al forests so they are utilized in the combination
National Forests: A Cohesive Strategy Is Needed that will best meet the needs of the American peo-
to Address Catastrophic Wildfire Threats,” ple.” Quoted in Cubbage, O’Laughlin, and
GAO/RCED-99-65, 1999, p. 29. Bullock, p. 19.

21. Fretwell. 32. Terry Anderson and Donald Leal, Enviro-


Capitalists: Doing Good While Doing Well (Lanham,
22. Organic Act, 16 U.S.C.A. 1, 1 (1916). Md.: Rowman & Littlefield, 1997).

23. Charles Kay, “The Yellowstone Dilemma: Part 1,” 33. Ibid., pp. 44–46.
Bugle 1, no. 1 (1984): 30–33; idem, “Yellowstone’s
Northern Elk Herd: A Critical Evaluation of the ‘Natural 34. Robert Nelson, Public Lands and Private Rights:
Regulation’ Paradigm,” Ph.D. diss., Utah State The Failure of Scientific Management (Lanham, Md.:
University, Logan, 1990; idem, “Aspen Seedlings in Rowman & Littlefield, 1995).
Recently Burned Areas in Grand Teton and Yellowstone
National Parks,” Northwest Science,no. 67 (1993): 94–104; 35. Nelson, “How and Why to Transfer BLM
idem, “The Impact of Native Ungulates and Beaver on Lands to the States,” p. 4.
Riparian Communities in the Intermountain West,”
Natural Resources and Environmental Issues, no. 1 (1994): 36. Paul W. Gates, History of Public Land Law
23–44; idem, “Browsing by Native Ungulates: Effects on Development (Washington: Government Printing
Shrub and Seed Production in the Greater Yellowstone Office, 1968), p. 395.
Ecosystem,” Proceedings of the Wildland Shrub and
Arid Land Restoration Symposium, in U.S. Forest Service 37. Ibid., p. 67.
General Technical Report, ed. B. A. Roundy et al., INT-315,
1995, pp. 310–20; idem, “Viewpoint: Ungulate 38. See Richard Gordon and Peter VanDoren,
Herbivory, Willows, and Political Ecology in Yellow- “Two Cheers for the 1872 Mining Law,” Cato
stone,” Journal of Range Management, no. 50 (1997): Institute Policy Analysis no. 300, April 9, 1998,
139–45; and idem, “Yellowstone: Ecological Malprac- pp. 18–21.
tice,” PERC Report 15, no. 2 (June 1997): 1–39.
39. Marion Clawson, The Federal Lands Revisited
24. Quoted in ibid., p. 30. (Baltimore: Resources for the Future, 1983), pp.
200–224.
25. Karl Hess Jr., Rocky Times in Rocky Mountain
National Park (Niwot: University Press of Colorado, 40. Ibid., p. 216.
1993), p. 33.
41. See, for instance, Nelson, “How and Why to
26. Ibid., p. 60. Transfer BLM Lands to the States.”

27. Ibid., p. 97. 42. Ibid., pp. 24–32; and Leal.

28. John Mitchell, “Our National Parks: Legacy at 43. Randal O’Toole, “Should Congress Transfer
Risk,” National Geographic, October 1994, p. 54. Federal Lands to the States?” Cato Institute Policy
Analysis no. 276, July 3, 1997, p. 1.
29. Michael Jeffrey, “Public Lands Reform: A Reluctant
Leap into the Abyss,” Virginia Environmental Law Journal 44. Jon Souder and Sally Fairfax, State Trust Lands
16 (1996): 79–143; and Dennis Herman, “Loving (Lawrence: University of Kansas Press, 1995). See also
Them to Death: Legal Controls on the Type and Scale Terry L. Anderson and Holly Lippke Fretwell, “A
of Development in the National Parks,” Stanford Trust for Grand Staircase–Escalante,” PERC Policy
Environmental Law Journal, no. 11 (1992): 3–67. Study PS-16, Bozeman, Mont., 1999.

30. James Ridenour, The National Parks Compromised: 45. For a full discussion of how such a plan might

23
work, see O’Toole, “Run Them Like Businesses.” fully transferable and could even be listed on the
stock exchanges. But if this is done, these special
46. Gates, p. 515. mutual fund shares become equivalent to our
suggested public land shares, that is, each will rep-
47. Ibid., pp. 270–73. resent the same ultimate capital value and will
discount the same stream of future auction out-
48. Ibid., p. 438. comes. One difference is that the mutual fund
would have to be managed by someone (also there
49. Ibid. would be transactions costs in acquiring the
mutual fund portfolio), but if there is a market in
50. See, for example, Gates, pp. 501–17; and “Land mutual fund shares, such management would be
for Sale,” Editorial, Wall Street Journal, January 25, subjected to some market discipline. One of the
1982, p. 22. authors (Smith) has argued elsewhere that the
fact that holding company (closed-end mutual
51. Charles Batten, “Toward a Free Market in Forest fund) shares tend to sell for less than the market
Resources,” Cato Journal 1, no. 2 (Fall 1981): 515. value of their investment portfolio suggests that
the market discounts the value of anything that
52. The government can lease back military reser- passes through an extra layer of such manage-
vations at market rates. If all governmental facili- ment. See Vernon L. Smith, “The Measurement of
ties had to pay opportunity costs, the true cost of Capital,” in Measuring the Nation’s Wealth, Studies in
such facilities would be included in current bud- Income and Wealth, ed. John Kendrick, vol. 29 (New
gets, and land rentals could discipline facility York: National Bureau of Economic Research,
location decisions. With that discipline, more 1964), pp. 343–44.
defense might be obtained from a given budget by The mutual fund, with marketable shares,
relocating bases that now occupy prime land sites. might have greater popular appeal by virtue of its
greater familiarity.
53. Since rental fees have been increasing over
time, some provision for increases should perhaps 55. See S. J. Rassenti, V. L. Smith, and R. L. Bulfin,
be made. One possibility is for the obligations of “A Combinatorial Mechanism for Airport Time
the holder of the grazing rights deed to include Slot Allocation,” Bell Journal of Economics, Autumn
provision for rent to be adjusted for inflation each 1982.
year. Alternatively, and less mechanically, the deed
terms might make some provision for reopening 56. Algorithms for this computation have been
negotiations on the lease terms every five years. developed by S. J. Rassenti, “01 Decision Problems
We assume that provisions for changing fees are with Multiple Resource Constraints: Algorithms
already part of the permit agreement between and Applications,” Ph.D. diss., University of
ranchers and government agencies. If so, these Arizona, 1981.
contract provisions would be written into the
grazing rights deed. The operating rule in recog- 57. See William Vickrey, “Counterspeculation,
nizing “squatters’ rights” should be to include in Auctions, and Competitive Sealed Tenders,”
the deed no more and no less than those rights Journal of Finance, March 16, 1961, pp. 837.
and obligations that are now part of what is the
recognized practice or legal arrangement between 58. Nelson, “How and Why to Transfer BLM Land
the agency and the squatter, or permit holder. to the States,” p. 14.
Should the deeded grazing rights be held in per-
petuity? It they are, this would seem to maximize 59. Information from the Nature Conservancy,
the incentive of the deed holder to maintain capi- http://www.tnc.org/welcome/about/about.htm.
tal value by good range management practices.
60. Information from the National Audubon
54. An alternative to Provision 7 as a means of Society, http://www.audubon.org/.
reducing the transactions costs associated with
the issuance of (and maintenance of a market in) 61. Jonathan Adler, “Balancing Oil Interests and
land shares: Instead of issuing land share certifi- Ecology,” Detroit News, July 19, 1991.
cates for bidding, let the bids be denominated in
U.S. currency. The proceeds of each auction 62. The Center for Private Conservation, a project
would then be deposited in a mutual fund to be of the Competitive Enterprise Institute in
shared equally by all citizens. Each citizen would Washington, D.C., has documented dozens of
be free to “cash out” of the fund at any time. cases of local conservationists’ banding together to
However, if this procedure is to take full advan- protect sensitive ecosystems from development.
tage of the discipline of the market, fund share For an index of those studies, see http://www.cei.org/
certificates should be issued in advance and be cpc/index.html.

24
63. Data for 1993–94 from Jonathan Adler, converted into deeded rights after an oil or gas
Environmentalism at the Crossroads (Washington: strike. What is needed is a way of extending the
Capital Research Center, 1995), pp. 147–238. definition of traditional oil and gas rights in land
to include descriptions of how those rights
64. See James L. Barr and David E. Pingry, become rights to share in discovered common
“Rational Water Pricing in the Tucson Basin,” property reservoirs.
Arizona Review, no. 25 (October 1976): 112.
67. For a compelling rejoinder to that argument,
65. See Vernon L. Smith, “Water Deeds: A see John Chant, Donald McFetridge, and Douglas
Proposed Solution to the Water Valuation Prob- Smith, “The Economics of the Conserver
lem,” Arizona Review, no. 26 (January 1977): 710. Society,” in Economics and the Environment: A
Reconciliation, ed. Walter Block (Vancouver: Fraser
66. Note the need to distinguish between rights to Institute, 1989), pp. 1–93.
undiscovered oil and gas, which include explo-
ration rights, and rights to draw on discovered oil 68. See further Richard Gordon, “The Case for
and gas reservoirs whose size and extent have been Public Lands Privatization,” Cato Institute Policy
estimated. A knotty problem, which we will not Analysis, 1999, forthcoming.
attempt to treat in this proposal, is the process
whereby rights to undiscovered oil and gas get 69. Loomis.

Published by the Cato Institute, Policy Analysis is a regular series evaluating government policies and offer-
ing proposals for reform. Nothing in Policy Analysis should be construed as necessarily reflecting the views
of the Cato Institute or as an attempt to aid or hinder the passage of any bill before congress. Contact the
Cato Institute for reprint permission. Additional copies of Policy Analysis are $6.00 each ($3.00 each for five
or more). To order, or for a complete listing of available studies, write the Cato Institute, 1000 Massachusetts
Ave., N.W., Washington, D.C. 20001, call toll free 1-800-767-1241 (noon - 9 p.m. eastern time), fax (202) 842-
3490, or visit our website at www.cato.org.

25

You might also like