You are on page 1of 6

See discussions, stats, and author profiles for this publication at: https://www.researchgate.

net/publication/275859463

Heuristics and Biases: The Psychology of Intuitive Judgment

Article  in  The Academy of Management Review · October 2004


DOI: 10.2307/20159081

CITATIONS READS

1,341 2,718

4 authors, including:

William P. Bottom
Washington University in St. Louis
72 PUBLICATIONS   2,574 CITATIONS   

SEE PROFILE

Some of the authors of this publication are also working on these related projects:

Technology transfer in the social sciences View project

Individual Differences in Negotiation View project

All content following this page was uploaded by William P. Bottom on 06 November 2015.

The user has requested enhancement of the downloaded file.


2004 Book Reviews 695

dangers. But the topic, particularly in light of the sions. The papers that ultimately made it
consensus that the full impact of the internet through the screening process are grouped into
will depend on political choices yet to be made, three major sections. Eleven papers reflecting
could have had a greater presence than it does. New Theoretical Directions are sandwiched be-
tween twenty-one papers devoted to Theoretical
and Empirical Extensions and ten devoted to
Real World Applications.
Heuristics and Biases: The Psychology of That distribution of papers is indicative of the
Intuitive Judgment, edited by Thomas major emphasis and strength of the book—
basic psychological theory. Early chapters are
Gilovich, Dale Griffin, and Daniel Kahne-
devoted to revisiting each of the three major
man. Cambridge: Cambridge University general-purpose heuristics from Judgment Un-
Press, 2002. der Uncertainty. These chapters reinforce the
relevance and importance of availability, an-
Reviewed by William P. Bottom, Washington Univer- choring, and representativeness but also pro-
sity, St. Louis, Missouri. vide a very different perspective on their opera-
tion and interplay. Two broad themes emerge.
Individuals cope with the uncertainty and The first is the recognition that judgment is ul-
complexity of their personal and professional timately the product of the interplay between
lives by using a small number of general- two distinctive cognitive systems.
purpose heuristics for simplifying judgments The “two-systems” concept elaborates on the
and making decisions. These tools work reason- distinction that Tversky and Kahneman (origi-
ably well and save time and effort, but they also nally 1984, Chapter 1 here) drew between exten-
lead to predictable errors. In Judgment Under sional reasoning based on the logic of probabil-
Uncertainty: Heuristics and Biases, published ity and intuitive reasoning based on heuristics.
back in 1982, Daniel Kahneman, Paul Slovic, and Gilovich and Griffin (“Heuristics and Biases:
Amos Tversky collected a set of papers that re- Then and Now”), Kahneman and Frederick
flected the growing body of research exploring (“Representativeness Revisited”), Sloman (“Two
this simple yet powerful idea. The papers in Systems of Reasoning”), and Stanovich and
Judgment Under Uncertainty address the opera- West (“Individual Differences in Reasoning”) di-
tion of three general-purpose heuristics: avail- rectly address the evidence for this interpreta-
ability, representativeness, and anchoring and tion. They also show that dual-process theories
adjustment. The book proved instrumental in of cognition that treat the individual as a cogni-
spreading the application of behavioral deci- tive miser are not adequate. System One output
sion theory to diverse fields such as law, medi- is not simply switched off by raising the incen-
cine, economics, and management. It also gen- tives high enough to activate System Two. Un-
erated an outpouring of new research probing, derstanding the dynamic interplay between in-
extending, and challenging the logic of the tuition and deliberation will be essential to
“heuristics and biases program.” In Heuristics better explaining and predicting judgment.
and Biases, Thomas Gilovich, Dale Griffin, and In “Representativeness Revisited,” Kahneman
Daniel Kahneman have pulled together a new and Frederick reinterpret heuristics as a general
collection of papers reflecting those develop- process of “attribute substitution” in which a
ments. target judgment is effortlessly and automati-
The Nobel Prize in Economic Science awarded cally made by substituting a simpler, natural
to Kahneman in 2002 is certainly one indicator of judgment. This attribute substitution is the prod-
the tremendous impact of heuristics and biases uct of the associative, rapid, and parallel infor-
research. The high quality of the papers in this mation processing in the intuitive System One.
book is another. The still larger number of sig- Similarity judgment based on prototype match-
nificant papers that could have been included ing—the process at work in the representative-
may actually be the best measure of all. The ness heuristic—is but one such attribute substi-
editors’ task must have been a challenging one, tution process. Like other System One output, it
and readers will undoubtedly have varying can sometimes be partially overridden by the
opinions about particular choices and omis- controlled, deductive, serial, self-aware, and
696 Academy of Management Review October

rule-based System Two. Kahneman and Freder- accurate. These authors show that a simple rule,
ick reinterpret anchoring not as an intuitive heu- such as “take the best,” which uses only the
ristic but as a much more foundational cognitive most valid of many available cues, is a form of
operation. problem simplification that exceeds the predic-
Gilbert (“Inferential Correction”) elaborates tive performance of simple linear rules and even
on this conclusion, tying anchoring back into the some multiple regression models. But these
two-systems framework. Rather than serving as rules-of-thumb and Simon’s notion of satisficing
an alternative to availability or representative- constitute System Two heuristics. These are con-
ness, Gilbert sees anchoring as “the process by scious strategies that are deliberately chosen
which the human mind does virtually all its because of self-awareness of one’s own mental
inferential work” (p. 167). That is, the noncon- capabilities. They are not the product of auto-
scious System One output forms the anchor, matic intuition, although they frequently entail
which System Two may or may not subse- the decision maker’s conscious and very clever
quently correct. The attribute substitution pro- recruitment and manipulation of intuitive Sys-
cess generating that anchor could be availabil- tem One output.
ity or similarity. This new interpretation is Two important parts of the book are less com-
consistent with the review of empirical evidence plete and therefore less satisfactory. In their in-
that Chapman and Johnson report on the impact troduction to the book, Gilovich and Griffin pro-
of experimentally manipulated anchors (“An- vide a selected history of this field of research.
chors in Judgments of Belief and Value”), which They trace the antecedents of Kahneman and
“points to anchors as a type of memory prompt Tversky’s work back as far as Meehl’s empirical
or prime to activate target information similar to studies of clinical judgment, Edward’s labora-
the anchor” (p. 133). Mental laziness is not what tory tests of Bayesian updating, and Simon’s
creates bias from anchoring and adjustment—a theoretical work on bounded rationality. This is
commonly held view in the past. It is the biased certainly accurate as to recent influences. But an
search (either of memory or external sources) the accurate history of the representativeness and
anchor directs that skews judgment. availability heuristics would acknowledge the
The second major theme of the selections in contribution of Walter Lippmann (1922, 1927) in
this volume is the belated recognition that intu- redefining a term that originally referred to a
ition can be neither explained nor predicted process in which “a solid plate. . .is used for
without considering the role of affect, mood, and printing from instead of the forme [sic] itself”
emotion. The papers in Judgment Under Uncer- (Oxford English Dictionary [2nd ed.]) to mean
tainty are primarily experiments on affect- “the pictures in our heads.” The ingenious dem-
neutral cognition. In “The Affect Heuristic,” onstrations of the representativeness heuristic,
Slovic, Finucane, Peters, and MacGregor begin such as “the Linda problem” (is Linda more
to redress this oversight. They review both pre- likely to be “a bank teller” or “a bank teller who
viously neglected and new evidence indicating is also a feminist”?), amply confirm Lippmann’s
that a general feeling of goodness or badness proposition that we make judgments by noticing
associated with a given stimulus automatically “a trait which marks a well known type, and fill
substitutes for such target attributes of judg- in the rest of the picture by means of the stereo-
ment as attractiveness, risk, and willingness to types we carry about in our heads” (1922: 59).
pay. Like availability or prototype matching, Lippmann’s work, in which he notes that “the
this automatic response from the intuitive sys- opportunities for manipulation open to anyone
tem can generate judgments that may or may who understands the process are plain enough”
not be overridden by rule-based deliberation. (1922: 158), was based neither on armchair theo-
The two-systems concept also reconciles the rizing nor on laboratory experimentation. This
heuristics and biases program with other con- was an inductive theory-building exercise in
ceptions of rationality that appeared as cri- which the former Army information officer,
tiques of Judgment Under Uncertainty. As Gig- former foreign policy adviser to Woodrow Wil-
erenzer, Czerlinski, and Martignon demonstrate son, and future adviser to Presidents Hoover,
(“How Good Are Fast and Frugal Heuristics?”), Roosevelt, Truman, Eisenhower, Kennedy, and
many rules-of-thumb for decision making are Johnson described the way in which bounded
not only simple and fast but also remarkably rationality, representativeness, availability,
2004 Book Reviews 697

and egocentric bias had distorted peace negoti- work demonstrated, this was never truly an is-
ations with Germany and the former Ottoman sue. Practice in the field by those who “under-
Empire (Bottom, 2003a). This process ultimately stood the process well enough” was consider-
generated a vindictive but unenforceable treaty, ably ahead of theory in 1922 and arguably still
which was “not wise, which was partly impos- well ahead of it today. Collecting together pa-
sible, and which threatened the life of Europe” pers on important applied problems that have
(Keynes; cited in Bottom, 2003b: 4). Lippmann’s drawn on the insights of cognitive heuristics
theory was also based on personal practice—his would have shed much needed light on the gen-
earlier contribution to the propaganda cam- eral social, organizational, and policy implica-
paign that manufactured consent for an Ameri- tions of basic theory.
can crusade against “the Hun” in Europe. Just before the recent scandal among profes-
Were the history of these concepts better sional accounting firms broke, Bazerman and
known, the authors might have constructed a Loewenstein (2001) used heuristics and biases to
more complete section on Real World Applica- note the impossibility of truly independent au-
tions. My initial interpretation of this section led dits. Roll (1986) highlighted the way in which
me to believe that the editors had compiled systematic miscalibration of probability has
some of the many important social problems fueled the explosive growth of the market in
that have been illuminated by research on heu- mergers and acquisitions, in spite of the disap-
ristics. Some of the papers in this section do fit pointing track record of such corporate transac-
that interpretation. De Bondt and Thaler use tions. Pogarsky and Babcock (2001) showed how
heuristics to predict and explain systematic anchoring undermines the intended rationale
bias among professional security analysts. The
for policies that would cap the size of legal
scandals plaguing the industry in recent years
claims. And Kuran and Sunnstein (1999) pre-
mark this paper, originally published in 1990 in
sented a series of case studies, including the
the American Economic Review, as both pre-
Alar controversy, on what they call “availability
scient and of continuing relevance to policy
entrepreneurs”—those who capitalize on the
makers and investors. Koehler, Brenner, and
workings of the availability heuristic to manip-
Griffin provide a new and comprehensive re-
ulate public discourse so they can further a
view of studies of the judgmental calibration of
given social agenda. Lippmann, a very able
professional experts. This study should be es-
availability entrepreneur, would have recog-
sential reading for those interested in under-
standing when and under what circumstances nized these as further evidence of the opportu-
overconfidence is likely to arise among experi- nities for manipulation open to those who un-
enced professionals. derstand how to manufacture consent.
However, several of the papers might have The limitations of historical context and real-
been better placed in other sections of the book. world application aside, this new collection of
Gilovich, Vallone, and Tversky’s study of the papers should rapidly become a staple for doc-
misperception of streaks of consecutive made toral courses in cognitive psychology, social
shots in basketball is an essential study of rep- psychology, economics, and various profes-
resentativeness, which the editors could have sional fields, including management. Research-
included in the section Theoretical and Empiri- ers in those fields who are looking for an ad-
cal Extensions. Medvec, Madey, and Gilovich’s vanced reference work on the subject will
study of regret among Olympic medallists certainly want to add this to their library. Even
would have made an excellent addition to the those who already have a number of the previ-
section New Theoretical Directions. The under- ously published papers will welcome having
lying interest in grouping together these papers them in one compact source. They will also wel-
in the concluding section appears to be in dem- come the many new and important contributions
onstrating empirically that heuristics generate to our understanding of the psychology of intu-
bias in a nonlaboratory context. itive judgment crafted just for this volume. The
The justification would seem to be a perceived theory building begun by Lippmann, the work
need to demonstrate that these biases exist in collected in Judgment Under Uncertainty, and
“the real world”—that they are not simply a lab- the contributions in this new book have begun to
oratory curiosity. As Lippmann’s very grounded permit social science to catch up to practice.
698 Academy of Management Review October

REFERENCES neur, businessman, leader, public servant, so-


Bazerman, M. H., & Loewenstein, G. 2001. Taking the bias out cial agent, citizen, and sportsman. Harman, the
of bean counting. Harvard Business Review, 79(1): 28. founder of a very successful international busi-
Bottom, W. P. 2003a. Keynes’ attack on the Versailles Treaty: ness, Harman International, which specializes
An early investigation of the consequences of bounded in high-fidelity audio systems, is a self-
rationality, framing, and cognitive illusions. Interna- proclaimed business maverick of over sixty
tional Negotiation, 8: 367– 402. years. Playing the devil’s advocate, one may ask
Bottom, W. P. 2003b. Smoke and mirrors: Cognitive illusions whether this old maverick has passed his time
and the origins of appeasement at the Paris Peace Con- for learning new tricks. Harman belies the vul-
ference. Paper presented at the International Biennale
gar phrase “You can’t teach an old dog new
on Negotiation, Paris.
tricks,” advocating just the opposite—a way of
De Bondt, W. F. M., & Thaler, R. H. 1990. Do security analysts
doing business informed by both academic and
overreact? American Economic Review, 80(2): 52–57.
practitioner knowledge and sensemaking with
Kahneman, D., Slovic, P., & Tversky, A. 1982. Judgment under
entrepreneurial spirit supported by a strong eth-
uncertainty: Heuristics and biases. Cambridge: Cam-
bridge University Press. ical stance. The book is a tribute to his experi-
ences of venturing with values, advocating a
Kuran, T., & Sunnstein, C. R. 1999. Availability cascades and
risk regulation. Stanford Law Review, 51: 683–768. “new old” (p. 4) business perspective that con-
siders values an essential ingredient of busi-
Lippmann, W. 1922. Public opinion. New York: Macmillan.
ness conduct.
Lippmann, W. 1927. The phantom public. New York: Mac-
Sidney Harman narrates his experiences in an
millan.
unpretentious and accessible manner, free from
Pogarsky, G., & Babcock, L. 2001. Damage caps, motivated
management jargon. The book will appeal to an
anchoring, and bargaining impasse. Journal of Legal
Studies, 30: 143–159. audience of entrepreneurs, business practitio-
ners, management biographers, and business
Roll, R. 1986. The hubris hypothesis of corporate takeovers.
Journal of Business, 59: 197–216. studies academics with an interest in biograph-
ical works and discourse analysis of autobio-
Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. 1984. Extensional versus intui-
tive reasoning: The conjunction fallacy in probability graphical narratives. Through the successful
judgment. Psychological Review, 91: 293–315. use of storytelling techniques, the book demon-
strates that it is possible to envisage a princi-
pled business life informed by human values.
The storytelling technique by which the book is
Mind Your Own Business, by Sidney written generates vignettes providing deep un-
Harman. New York: Random House, derstanding of many issues. The vignettes in the
2003. text are suitable for use as a point of discussion
in teaching a wide range of business manage-
Reviewed by Mustafa Özbilgin, University of Surrey, ment subjects. These narratives provide time-
Guildford, United Kingdom.1 less insights into some very pertinent issues,
including the significance of enterprising and
There has been a proliferation of biographies human aspects of employment relations, mar-
recounting “leadership and management suc- keting, finance, negotiation, and linkages with
cess” from prescriptive and “best practice” per- social life. Reconciling entrepreneurial enthusi-
spectives, promising the replication of such suc- asm with a genuine concern for stakeholder
cess to their readers. Sidney Harman’s Mind welfare appears to be the main stance Sidney
Your Own Business is an autobiographical work, Harman takes in this book, and this is, at the
which does not fit in this genre. In this text same time, the main distinguishing attribute of
Harman takes us through his journey of key the book. In the age of corporate greed and scan-
learning events and episodes of epiphany in dals, this book, with its timely call for business
business, leadership, and life, recounting sto- with values, is as rare as rain in a desert.
ries from his multifaceted life as an entrepre- The book is based on self-reporting of lived
experience. The subjective nature of the ac-
counts offered and the possibility of post hoc
1
I thank Finola Kerrigan for her valuable suggestions on rationalization in presentation of life histories
earlier drafts of this review. may appear, at first sight, to be the weakness of
View publication stats

You might also like