You are on page 1of 10

C H A P T E R

28
Venetian Finance, 1400–1797
L. Pezzolo
Università Ca’ Foscari Venezia, Venezia, Italy

O U T L I N E

Revenues 301 Public Debt 305


Taxation 302 The Floating Debt 308
Glossary 309
Taxpayers 303
Further Reading 310
Financial Needs 303

REVENUES movement occurred with some delay in the early de-


cades of the seventeenth century, as revenues increased
Like other early modern states, Venice drew most of substantially (2.7% annually). It is, however, hazardous
her resources from taxation. Until the formation of the ter- to correlate fiscal data with the general economic trend,
ritorial state in the early fifteenth century, the Venetian because just a slight rise of a tariff or the expansion of a
state relied mostly on duties on trade and consumption. taxable product can bias the relationship between tax
The change from the budget of a city to the budget of a revenues and real trends.
great power is evident in Table 28.1. The conquest of The great pestilence of 1630 reduced tax revenue and
the Italian mainland proved costly but allowed Venice was followed by a slow recovery. It is interesting to note
to control the key land routes that linked the lagoon to that the plague of 1630 proved to be much more serious
her markets in central Europe. Thus, the territorial needs than that of 1576. The general economic situation had
of the new state, encompassing a wide area from Crete to been changing and the resources that had been exploited
east Lombardy, brought about a remarkable growth of in the 1570s to encourage the quick recovery of tax levels
income that quadrupled, in terms of silver, in little more were not wholly available 50 years later. The long war of
than a century. Crete (1645–69) contributed considerably to the worsen-
Between the mid-fifteenth and the early sixteenth cen- ing conditions of the republic. The early years of the
tury, the level of ordinary revenues was, surprisingly, war were not as dire for taxpayers as one would have
somewhat stable, despite two wars against the Ottomans expected, for the tax burden in real terms (considering
(in 1464–79 and 1499–1502), the war of Ferrara (1480–82), grain prices) did not increase significantly, but the
and the early phase of the Italian Wars (1494–1530). It is 1650s exerted a high pressure on Venetian subjects.
likely that the scanty budgets we have do not register ex- After the war, the growth rate of central revenues
traordinary taxes being levied for urgent needs. Further- remained fairly constant, due to the fact that the extraor-
more, from the mid-sixteenth until the early seventeenth dinary taxes levied during wartime were made partially
century the rate of increase was not significant, even permanent later. The two wars of Morea (1684–99 and
though those decades were characterized by a marked 1714–18) caused a further increase in income, which
rise in prices. The 1% rate of growth annually between reached a level that remained constant for several de-
1550 and 1609 is fairly limited, considering that the silver cades, until the last years of the Republic marked a fur-
price of grain witnessed an average growth rate of 1.5% ther revenue growth, which was quite noteworthy.
per year. It seems rather that the response to price Overall, changes in revenue display a close correlation

Handbook of Key Global Financial Markets, Institutions, and Infrastructure 301 # 2013 Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/B978-0-12-397873-8.00006-2
302 28. VENETIAN FINANCE, 1400–1797

TABLE 28.1 Budget of the Republic of Venice, 1343–1790 political relations of society of the Old Regime have
Income Income
been interpreted using the concept of collaboration –
Years ducats Expenditure kg of silver Expenditure and sometimes even collusion – between the center
and provincial elites. Thus, higher revenues could
1343 250 000 257 000 10 256 10 543
be interpreted as the product of improved political
1469 1 120 000 46 150 bargaining between local ruling groups and state
1500 1 150 000 44 063 authorities.
1550 1 601 000 1 735 000 51 130 55 409

1580 2 000 000 2 070 000 53 220 55 083


1602 2 563 000 2 477 000 68 201 65 913 TAXATION
1621 3 862 000 3 950 000 101 432 103 743
It was critical that taxation be supported as a recog-
1637 3 020 000 2 870 000 60 702 57 687 nized, legitimate necessity, otherwise the taxpayers
1641 2 960 000 2 770 000 59 496 55 677 could easily challenge the government. The rulers
had a clear idea of their limits and tried – not always
1665 3 740 000 5 250 000 72 276 101 456
successfully – not to go beyond them. It should be noted
1679 4 285 000 3 962 000 82 808 76 566 that, unlike in France and England, in the Venetian re-
1710 5 807 000 6 206 000 98 040 104 776 public the notion that the king should ‘live on his
own’ did not exist. A tax was first justified for security,
1736 5 341 000 5 691 000 80 003 85 245
that is, in defense of the state and its Catholic faith. Ven-
1740 5 343 000 5 428 000 80 033 81 306 ice was considered the outpost of Christianity in the east-
1750 5 559 000 5 254 000 83 268 78 700 ern Mediterranean and embraced the common ideology
of the crusade. Thus, the financial effort required to
1760 5 559 000 5 336 000 83 268 79 928
mount certain endeavors took on the characteristics of
1770 6 596 000 5 613 000 98 801 84 077 a sacred duty in the defense of religion. This allowed
1780 6 082 000 5 651 000 91 102 84 646 the passage of the tax obligation from the religious
sphere to the secular one; the subject was required to
1790 7 043 000 7 747 000 105 497 116 042
pay taxes to the state as the secular arm of the divine will.
Source: Pezzolo, L., 2006. Una finanza d’ancien régime. La Repubblica veneta tra The Venetian exchequer relied primarily on indirect
XV e XVIII secolo. Edizioni scientifiche italiane, Napoli, pp. 38–40. taxation, namely duties on trade, consumption, and
economic activities in general. Income from domain
(rental of land and property rights, mint, coinage and
with political events that involved the Republic of Venice; so on) was rather small. In peacetime, the ordinary
military needs – as much in Venice as elsewhere – in fact, budget met usual expenses such as salaries of officers,
were the driving force in state finance. soldiers, and sailors of the fleet, the costs for maintain-
Observing Table 28.1, we see that throughout the ing the arsenal, and the payment of interest on loans.
early modern age the revenue available to the Venetian However, peace was a condition that late medieval
state increased. How should one interpret this trend, Venice rarely enjoyed. Not only conflicts with other
which is indeed common to the rest of the European powers but also with pirates, short but intense cam-
states of the time? Do the data reflect a growing degree paigns against rebels in overseas territories, tensions
of absolutism, or do they instead reveal a pattern of on the border with the neighboring powers, protection
compromises and negotiations? In the historiography from raids, and escorts of the merchant ships – all of
of the Old Regime state, two theories collide: on the these required Venice to maintain an almost constant
one hand the classic approach emphasizes the central- state of emergency and mobilization. It is no coinci-
izing policies of state authorities, intended eventually dence that Venice was the first Mediterranean power
to become ‘modern’; and on the other hand some to rely on a stable fleet, which patrolled the Adriatic
scholars stress the fiscal limits of the state. Until re- since the fourteenth century.
cently, growth of revenue was considered the clear It is worth noting that the structure of state income
manifestation of the coercive capacity of the political changed significantly through the seventeenth century
center, which drew its strength from taxes to develop because of the relative decline of the commercial role
its means of control which, in turn, allowed increasing of Venice in the international market. As taxation on in-
tax collection from the subjects. Recently, following ternational trade decreased, the government relied on
profound revisions about the concept of state and both duties on domestic consumption and the Italian
the crisis in the history of the modern state, the mainland (Figure 28.1).

I. GLOBALIZATION OF FINANCE: AN HISTORICAL VIEW


FINANCIAL NEEDS 303
The structure of income of the Republic of Venice, 1587–1670
60

50

40

Trade
Consumption
%

30 Mainland
Other

20

10

0
1587 1602 1621 1637 1641 1670

FIGURE 28.1 The structure of income of the Republic of Venice, 1587–1670. Reproduced from Rapp, R.T., 1976. Industry and Economic Decline in
Seventeenth-Century Venice. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA, p. 141.

TAXPAYERS burden than that borne by lay subjects. This naturally


led to protests and tensions between different groups
In principle, all the subjects of the Venetian republic of subjects: if the Venetian clergy could not escape the
were called to fiscal duty: lay people and ecclesiastics, loan requirements and tithes, the Church could still en-
women household heads, citizens and peasants, nobles, gage in bitter battles with town councils and representa-
merchants, and landowners. The Doge himself had to tives of taxpayer peasants to defend their own positions
pay taxes. Within this mass of taxpayers, however, there and privilege. Long and wearisome processes dot the fis-
were significant differences that mirrored the structure cal relations between the laity and clergy: the former
of society and the constitution of the state. These divi- emphasized their shouldering of the greater financial
sions distinguished the capital city, the Italian mainland, burden, while the latter reminded their adversaries of
and the overseas colonies by different legal traditions the customs and status that distinguished them from
and economic, social, and political structures. Taxpayers the rest of the population.
of the city capital and taxpayers of the mainland (the Fiscal policy was aimed at the mobilization of as much
so-called stato da terra) were registered in different tax money as possible given the limitations, economic and
lists. The latter, furthermore, were subdivided into city political, that the system imposed. Despite these limita-
dwellers and peasants. Venetian landowners enjoyed tions, however, the government was able to spend large
particular privileges; they were exempted, for example, amounts primarily to maintain a military structure that
from the obligation to provide services for the mainte- supported the economic needs of the capital, needs that,
nance of the army in peacetime. Such differences be- until the sixteenth century, were translated into the con-
tween taxpayers, however, diminished during the last trol of economic areas – both within Italy as well as in
two centuries of the Republic. the eastern Mediterranean – and ways to protect trade
Ecclesiastical taxpayers in the republic of Venice, as routes.
elsewhere, were considered a privileged body. Nonethe-
less, they were subject to taxation, both direct and
indirect. Venice’s role as a power in the defense of Chris-
tendom entitled the republic to tax the ecclesiastics. The FINANCIAL NEEDS
tenth (decima), for example, fell on church property as
well, and was one of the few taxes levied throughout The structure of the Venetian state expenditure did
all the territories of the state. While taxing the church’s not represent an exception within the financial pano-
land was an achievable goal, determining the extent of rama of the old regime. Most of expenses were absorbed
its land was not so easy. In fact, only two assessments from the military apparatus and debt servicing, which in
of ecclesiastical property were ever made in Venice’s its turn was related to war needs. Thus, the trend of pub-
long history (in 1564 and 1773) and the impression these lic expenditure (Table 28.1) was closely linked to the
give is that the taxpayers of the clergy bore a lesser political and military vicissitudes of the republic.

I. GLOBALIZATION OF FINANCE: AN HISTORICAL VIEW


304 28. VENETIAN FINANCE, 1400–1797

Some comparisons with other state budgets highlight a long period of stability during which expenditure
the change that the Venetian power had been undergo- floated around 80–90 tons; and only in the last years of
ing from the late middle ages to the fall of the Republic the republic did it attain 100 tons.
in 1797. The 10 tons of silver Venice could spend by the War and debt service were the most important entries
mid-fourteenth century demonstrates her great power. of expenditure; these accounted for over half the entire
This rank was maintained until the late fifteenth century, government expenditure (Figure 28.2). The effects of
as the Venetian level of expenditure (about 45 tons) was military expenses changed over time with regard to both
slightly lower than the French and higher than the the players in the conflict and the war zone. Over the late
English revenues. Throughout the sixteenth century the Middle Ages, Venice had invested heavily in her navy to
great monarchies broadened the gap. France attained conquer strategic places in the eastern Mediterranean,
the peak of 440 tons in the 1580s and Castile over the crucial area for her trade. In the early fifteenth cen-
500 tons; the republic of St Mark, however, was still tury, she had one of the most effective military forces
substantial with her 66 tons. Over the next century, the on the Italian peninsula, critical to the expansion of her
growth of European budgets was even more evident; control over the Po valley. The military tool proved to
while Spain attained its zenith by the middle of the cen- be an extraordinary means to build an economic and po-
tury, France and England imitated it in the following litical empire. The Venetian government took up the task
decades. Along with these powers one can put also both to support militarily the commercial expansion,
Holland, which with its 250 tons of expenditure in and to cope with the huge protection costs necessary
1641 could be considered an important player on the for its own merchants. As early as the twelfth century,
international stage. the Venetian state proved successful in using force to
It is worth noting that just as the young Dutch repub- increase national wealth.
lic was showing a striking financial capacity, the Most From the sixteenth century, however, everything
Serene Republic, hit severely by the plague in 1630, was to change. Venice had to face the initiative of the
was unable to reach even 60 tons. Only the war of Crete Ottoman empire and lost important positions in the
(1645–69) provoked a dramatic rise of expenditure. One Levant. In Italy, furthermore, her expansionist policy
hundred tons of silver, which Venice presumably spent underwent a hard setback in 1509 due to the defeat
annually for military and administrative needs, repre- by the armies of the League of Cambrai. After Cambrai
sented a considerable effort, although it cannot be com- the Venetian state borders shifted little until the fall of
pared to those made by more powerful governments. the Republic. The fierce competition of the ‘Northeners’
Post-war expenditure remained at a reasonably high (English, Dutch, and French) in the Mediterranean Sea
level, higher than the entire expenditure of the rising increased transaction costs for Venetians; the navy
Savoyard state (slightly more than 47 tons in 1684). proved inadequate to deal with piracy and foreign
The years of the second war of Morea (1714–18) brought ships. Large amounts of money had to be spent on
about a severe emergency in public expenditure (over ships, crews, and weapons to protect an area that was
100 tons). The eighteenth century was characterized by increasingly shrinking.

100

90

80

70

60

Debt
%

50
Defence

40

30

20

10

0
1555 1575 1579 1587 1594 1602 1609 1633 1637 1641 1679 1710 1736 1740 1750 1760 1770 1780

FIGURE 28.2 Expenditure of the Republic of Venice 1555–1780. Reproduced from Pezzolo, L., 2006. Una finanza d’ancien régime. La Repubblica
veneta tra XV e XVIII secolo. Edizioni scientifiche italiane, Napoli.

I. GLOBALIZATION OF FINANCE: AN HISTORICAL VIEW


PUBLIC DEBT 305

PUBLIC DEBT war citizens were requested to lend as much as 41% of


their taxable income; the government faced severe diffi-
The public debt was the other side of military spend- culties in regularly paying interest to creditors, to the
ing. The evolution of borrowing went hand in hand with point where they had to suspend payment. The market
the vicissitudes of war and it was indeed its extension in price of state bonds dropped as low as 18% of their nom-
financial terms. The Venetian government usually was a inal value (Figure 28.3).
good debtor. Apart from dire moments, interest on loans The financial and political turmoil brought about a
was paid regularly. large redistribution of wealth within the city, with the
The precarious balance between income and expendi- consequent inability of fiscal authorities to discover
ture that characterized state budgets was constantly en- new taxable assets. The repercussions of this crisis were
dangered by conflicts, political–military commitments, to last for decades to come. The fifteenth-century wars, in
and unforeseen events. Because the collection of taxes fact, put Venetian finances in difficulty and despite some
took time, it was necessary to raise money through brief intervals of peace, the situation gradually wors-
short-term voluntary loans. From the late twelfth cen- ened. The amount of interest arrears grew along the cen-
tury, the government imposed forced loans, which fell tury; during the Turkish war of 1463–79 the delay in
on the Venetian citizens inscribed on the estimo, or the payment to creditors was 20 years and no interest at
tax register. Taxpayers had to pay a given amount all was paid in 1480. Monte credits were priced well be-
according to their assessed wealth and in exchange low par and in the early 1480s the total size of the debt
would receive 5% interest until the repayment of the valued at market prices could be assessed as one-tenth
principal. This system proved beneficial for both the of its nominal value.
state treasury, which could count on money raised in During the War of Ferrara (1482–84), in order to revive
a relatively short time, and the lenders, who could the confidence of lenders and taxpayers, the government
count on a moderate but steady return. Creditors were, launched a new series of loans. The series was entitled
furthermore, allowed to trade their credits, triggering a Monte Nuovo, to distinguish it from the earlier loans
dynamic secondary market of securities. (Monte Vecchio), which had attained a nominal amount
The good health of the Venetian debt until the 1370s is of 8 269 000 ducats. The Monte Nuovo succeeded in
proven by its high market prices. The War of Chioggia awakening the interest of the Venetians, but only mo-
(1378–81) against the traditional Genoese rivals, how- mentarily. The difficulties of the war and the heavy tax
ever, provoked the first real financial crisis of the Vene- burden made Venetians uncertain about their govern-
tian state. The conflict boosted the level of indebtedness ment’s solvency. The news of peace was therefore
and, more importantly, started a spiral that exacerbated greeted with widespread relief and, consequently, the
the structural conditions of public finance. During the market prices of the new series soared. The vicissitudes

(Monte Vecchio and Monte Nuovo)


120

100

80
% at par

Vecchio
60
Nuovo

40

20

0
60

68

80
86
92
97

11
15

35
39
43
49
53
58
64
69
81
99
03
08
56
66
91
50

64

07

20
26
31
72
13

13
13
13
13
13

13

13
14
14
14
14
14
14
14
14
14
14
14
14
14
14
14
14
15
15
15
15
15
13

FIGURE 28.3 Market prices of government credits (Monte Vecchio and Monte Nuovo). Reproduced from Pezzolo, L., 2003. The Venetian gov-
ernment debt 1350–1650. In: Davids, K., Janssens, P., Boone, M. (Eds.), Urban Public Debts, Urban Governments and the Market for Annuities in Western
Europe, 14th–18th Centuries. Brepols, Leuven, pp. 61–74.

I. GLOBALIZATION OF FINANCE: AN HISTORICAL VIEW


306 28. VENETIAN FINANCE, 1400–1797

of the new Monte were closely related to the military in 1570–73. The Depositi proved to be an excellent invest-
commitments of the republic; political troubles made ment for the Venetians. With a yield of 7–8% in wartime,
Monte prices drop, while rumors of peace sufficed to in- they attracted huge amounts of money thanks to the up-
crease them. So, for example, the Monte Nuovo securi- swing of the economy and the attractive terms offered by
ties rose above par in 1505–06. But the euphoria in the the government.
Rialto lasted only for a while, for war reappeared soon. After the turmoil of the war of Cyprus and the plague
The war of Cambrai (1509–17) brought about the col- in 1576–77, the government initiated a massive reim-
lapse of the Monte Nuovo, which in 1509 was joined by a bursement of its obligations, despite strong resistance
new series of loans in the so-called Monte Nuovissimo. within the aristocracy. The result was that within two de-
By the mid-1520s, the government debt did not seem cades the burden of the public debt stood at zero. The
in good health: interest due was in arrears, Monte Depositi in Zecca first, and subsequently the old Monte
Vecchio credits were priced at as low as 3% of par, those credits, were paid back at market price. It was a gigantic
of the Monte Nuovo at 10, and those of the Monte operation that undoubtedly enhanced the republic’s rep-
Nuovissimo at 25. The system of forced loans, in short, utation for debt worthiness. The liquidation was worth
proved to be inadequate both to finance wars quickly about ten million ducats, about four times as much as
and for the Venetians, who had been transformed the annual government income. On average each citizen
into taxpayers. However, according to Lane, in the received slightly more than 66 ducats, which corre-
mid-sixteenth century wealthy Venetians were able to sponded to the annual wage of a building worker.
benefit from state debt, as received through interest Almost unique within Europe, the Venetian economy
and reimbursements rather than paid as direct taxes. for a number of years was nearly free from the burden of
A new response to the financial difficulties emerged interest payments on debt. Of course, such a situation
between the 1520s and 1530s and established itself by could not last for long, and from the second decade of
the middle of the century. After the creation in 1526 of the seventeenth century the government began to bor-
a new fund (Monte del Sussidio), the system of forced row. It is important to stress, however, that the leader-
loans, being now worn and overused by continuous ship chose to terminate a Venetian flow of revenue
wars, was gradually replaced by borrowing directly that largely benefited the wealthiest families in the city,
from the open capital market. The government began, who were themselves members of the government.
more systematically than it had in the past, to collect The events of the first three decades of the seven-
loans from among those Venetians who were willing teenth century forced the government to call for loans;
to invest in government debt. The series of voluntary between 1609 and 1641, the annual average capital raised
loans was managed by the Mint and entitled Depositi through Depositi in Zecca was 244 500 ducats, with
in zecca (deposits in the mint). It was the most important peaks during the years of the war of Gradisca (900 000
and powerful means of financing the Venetian state until ducats in 1616). During those years public finance,
the republic’s end. Proceeds of some taxes were ear- however, was not heavily burdened by indebtedness.
marked for interest payment. Unlike Monte interest, that In 1619, the Senate, to meet investors’ pressing demand,
of the Depositi was not taxed. Instead, the terms for launched redeemable loans at 5% and life annuities at
repayment of the principal were not set and bonds were 10%. These terms were rather favorable to the Republic,
freely tradable and transferable to heirs. The Venetian and show a fair equilibrium between state demand and
Depositi represented an advanced means of deficit fi- private supply. Considering the fact that in Holland, the
nancing and, to some extent, anticipated some character- most developed financial area in the seventeenth cen-
istics of modernity that are usually attributed to other tury, in the same period, redeemable loans yielded
forms of government debts. 6.25% and life annuities 11–14%, this meant that confi-
The type of Depositi issued depended on the duration dence in the Venetian state as a debtor was quite high
and interest rate offered. In 1538, during the Turkish and, in turn, that the government was able to attract cap-
war, the government issued a series of life annuities at ital despite the fact that returns were not particularly
a rate of 14%, while in that period redeemable loans high. The yield of 5%, in fact, was just below the prevail-
returned as high as 8%. It is worth noting that life annu- ing interest rate on private capital markets; in the early
ities, although they were well known in the cities of seventeenth century, the average rate in the Venetian
southern Germany, Switzerland, northern France and mainland was around 6%.
Flanders, represented a novelty in the Venetian market. The contraction of investment opportunities in the tra-
After the establishment of the Depositi in Zecca, how- ditional overseas trade probably prompted Venetians to
ever, Venice did not resort to life-term loans. If during seek a safe income guaranteed by the State. Between the
the war in 1537–41 life annuities accounted for 37.5% 1610s and 1620s, Genoese investors broadened the sup-
of the money raised through Depositi, only 50 000 out ply of credit in Venice. The reason for this was that most
of 3 500 000 ducats were collected in the successive war financiers were increasingly moving their money from

I. GLOBALIZATION OF FINANCE: AN HISTORICAL VIEW


PUBLIC DEBT 307
the traditional commitments to the Habsburg crown to In 1641, at least one-seventh of the consolidated debt in
safer harbors, particularly the Papal and Venetian debts. the Mint (7 435 723 ducats) belonged to non-Venetians.
It seems that the Genoese appeared as lenders to the The presence of foreign investors in Venetian debt was
Venetian government in 1617, during the War of Gra- not a novelty. As far back as the fourteenth century, the
disca, and from that point until the mid-eighteenth authorities had allowed foreign investment, but its share
century they were to play an important role. They pre- had been rather small. In the 1610s, the government
ferred life annuities, as much for their excellent return signaled its intention to broaden the base of potential sub-
as, perhaps, the fact that, despite the efforts of the Vene- scribers by declaring its willingness to accept money from
tian consul in Genoa, a nominee’s death could be hidden both subjects and foreigners. Was this a sign of a lack of
for long from the financial authorities in Venice. In 1641, capital at the Rialto? There is some evidence indicating
the Genoese held 1 008 648 ducats as life annuities out of that money was scarce; and the same Mint tried to attract
2 177 795 ducats. This means that 46.3% of the series at 10, through incentives those willing to bring silver. This was
12, and 14% was supplied by Genoese investors. not merely a short-term expedient, for appeals to foreign
Over the seventeenth century, life annuities were investors continued and even intensified during the war
largely used, in Venice as elsewhere in Europe, but with of Candia. Quantifying the contribution of foreign capital
more prudence than in the previous century. Some gov- in financing a war is impossible, but it is very likely that
ernments began to classify all subscribers in relation to the money coming from Genoa increased significantly.
their age thereby varying the rate of interest. Thus, in For example, 81.5% of the government’s short-term loans
1625 the Venetian Senate issued annuities that would in 1654–56 was provided by the Genoese. A few years
yield 10% to creditors under the age of 30 years, 12% after the war it turned out that 30.3% of the funds at 3%
to those between 30 and 50 years and finally 14% over belonged to financiers of Genoa.
50 years. The authorities had to verify nominees’ age The enlargement of the geographical range of in-
by checking parish registers, while foreign investors vestors warrants some reflection. One might suppose
had to submit a statement signed by Venetian represen- that the institutionalization of foreign debt was, as
tatives abroad. In 1645, soon after the outbreak of the war mentioned, a symptom of the difficulties affecting the
of Candia, the government offered investors life annu- domestic credit market, which was no longer able to
ities at just 6% with a ceiling of 100 ducats for each support the government’s demand. But evidence that
subscriber. money was scarce in the lagoon is neither numerous
The interest rate was fairly low for a life-term loan, but nor convincing. The inflow of foreign investors’ capital
was justified by the fact that the money saved by nomi- is undoubtedly proof that the Depositi in Zecca enjoyed
nees’ deaths would be shared among the survivors. Al- wide approval and merited confidence. Trust had to be
though still vague in its form, it is likely that Venetian rewarded and not coincidentally the documentation
projects at this time anticipated somewhat similar mech- reflected the concern of the government to meet its finan-
anisms (the Tontine) that appeared toward the end of the cial commitments, first of all to the creditors from Genoa.
seventeenth century in northern Europe, especially To be sure, the financial dependence on the capital of
France. In 1669, furthermore, the government launched Genoa, although not overwhelming, could have induced
a life annuity based on eight age groups with returns Venetian patricians to pay particular attention to the
that, apparently, would increase the benefit of the survi- moods and voices from Genoa. That risk, however,
vors. It has to be stressed that the mechanism for diver- was apparently never realized, based on the limited suc-
sifying the return was not a common practice in Europe cess of Genoese representatives in defending investors’
at the time. Both the English and the Dutch governments interests in Venice.
had long been issuing annuities that did not take into ac- Pressing financial needs led the government to exploit
count the different ages of subscribers. It seems, then, the emerging social attitudes that characterized Euro-
that in Venice the political and cultural environment pean society in the seventeenth century. In addition to
was particularly eager to accept innovations that were lifetime loans, the government proposed a series of lot-
emerging in the actuarial calculations, which reflected teries. The lottery (or lotto) was not unknown in Venice.
a change in the new system of values and beliefs related In the previous centuries, public lotteries had already
to the concepts of events bringing good or bad luck and been set up as prizes in buildings and shops in the Rialto
probability forecasting. Although the government real- area, while individuals were allowed to sponsor a lot-
ized the heavy administrative burden that these loans tery, usually as a means of satisfying creditors. But it
imposed, the practice of issuing age-specific life annu- was in the mid-seventeenth century that the government
ities was followed over the years by many other govern- used the lottery as a means of revenue. Between the late
ments. At first, the Venetian authorities tried to limit the 1640s and the early 1650s, the government sold lottery
nominees only to the inhabitants in the state, but compel- tickets offering money, state securities, and offices. Lot-
ling wartime needs forced them to seek investors abroad. teries constituted a kind of government loan, made

I. GLOBALIZATION OF FINANCE: AN HISTORICAL VIEW


308 28. VENETIAN FINANCE, 1400–1797

attractive by the prospect of winning money. The mini- The guilds were requested to borrow from investors
mum amount involved was quite low (corresponding to through a private contract and then to transfer the
the wage of 3–15 working days of a building laborer) and money to the government. The mediation of a local insti-
allowed the lottery player to aspire for better things. tution, which could boast of prestige relying on its
From the government’s standpoint, lottery did not repre- considerable financial strength, was thus used to find
sent a heavy burden in the short term, although one money that otherwise would not have flowed directly
should consider that this system was usually used in into the state coffers. Besides the guilds, charitable insti-
cases of acute necessity. The eighteenth-century budgets tutions and the Jewish communities of the state were
record an average net income of just over 111 000 ducats also involved. During the war of Candia, the former
a year; this fluctuating revenue, similar to the case of were forced to lend substantial sums, which endangered
Naples, is not correlated with the trend of grain prices. their financial health. In some cases, hospitals were
The incentive of players did not stem from their neces- forced to sell a portion of their real assets to collect the
sity, but by their aspirations to improve their economic money requested, as well as to borrow from Venetian no-
and social situation. bles. As for the Jews, they were often asked to pay spe-
In addition to voluntary loans, the government, albeit cific taxes and loans. During the years of the war and in
in a manner far less pronounced than in the past, also the following decades, for example, the Jewish commu-
resorted to forced loans through direct taxes, and devel- nity of Venice was obliged to deposit money and silver in
oped the sale of annuities to be assigned directly to cred- the Mint. Seeking liquidity among the various social
itors, thus bypassing the mint. These so-called Deposits bodies of the capital and of the mainland was a sign of
outside the mint were a sign of the current difficulties of difficulty in obtaining money from traditional investors,
the public finances. Although this practice was wide- who were unable or unwilling to provide large amounts
spread in other states, the Venetian government had to the government.
been very sparing up to this point in alienating portions The nominal principal held by foreigners dropped
of tax income, but the extreme urgency of war forced the from about 21 million ducats in 1760 to 13.5 million in
use of this device. In November 1645, for example, 28 000 1787, but the diminishing foreign investment did not
ducats of the duty on olive oil were sold at an interest mean that the Venetian debt was considered risky, for
rate of 7% for 20 years, which was the current interest even in 1797 – the last year of the Republic – 17.9% of
rate during the war. This type of operation multiplied the debt was held by foreign creditors. While, on the
in the succeeding years, so that after the war the amount one hand, the gradual reduction of interest rates had
of deposits outside the Mint exceeded 13 million ducats. led to disinvestment, on the other hand, the Venetian
In fact, the method of payment of interest rate was rather finances certainly benefitted from those operations in
simplified, as creditors were paid directly by tax collec- the second half of the eighteenth century.
tors. Moreover, the quality and importance of duties Although the public debt may be seen as a powerful
alienated (wine, oil, salt . . .) reassured the creditors political tool, the reforms undertaken by the Venetian
about payments, for the collection of indirect taxes, rulers suggest that they prized state interests over those
particularly those on consumption, seemed more secure of investors, at least potentially. The conversions of the
than direct taxes. The system worked effectively, century affected creditors, which saw their income
which is why it was so widely applied throughout the progressively fall; it was a sort of tax on state securities
eighteenth century. The war of Candia, therefore, which brought about a redistribution of financial
marked an extremely important moment for the Vene- resources between taxpayers and lenders. This mecha-
tian state exchequer, especially for strategies that were nism, which was implemented on several occasions in
put in place to address the emergency. As on other occa- Venetian history, aimed to hurt particularly those who
sions, after the end of the war the government took ac- speculated in the secondary market of state securities.
tion on its debt by examining the amount of interest
not yet paid and starting operations of conversion to a
lower rate. THE FLOATING DEBT
At the end of the war of Candia, the conversion
brought only temporary relief to state finances, for debt It is well known that Venice was one of the most im-
levels began to rise during the wars of Morea and the portant financial centers of early modern Europe. She
phases of armed neutrality throughout the eighteenth probably reached her heyday in the fifteenth and six-
century. During this period, the government resorted teenth centuries, as her financial institutions represented
to another system of state financing, by involving the a model for other European centers. The most important
guilds in both Venice and the mainland. The government aim of the Venetian financial market was first to provide
used the guilds as intermediaries for providing credit, merchants, rightly considered as the protagonists of the
because of the lack of trust among potential investors. economic success of the city, with services. A foreign

I. GLOBALIZATION OF FINANCE: AN HISTORICAL VIEW


THE FLOATING DEBT 309
merchant coming into Rialto was immediately struck by It is worth noting that the authorities kept the size of
the ease of doing business without cash. From the late the floating debt fairly limited. The sector where
thirteenth century, in fact, some local bankers kept their the Bank operated – mostly trade – was particularly del-
customers’ deposits and transferred money by simply icate, and the government chose to borrow mainly
writing the sum from one account to another one. These through the deposits in the Mint rather the Banco Giro,
banks di scritta facilitated transactions and limited con- still in those years conceived as a provisional financial
siderably the use of coins. The main features of the Ve- institution. In addition, a disproportionate expansion of
netian banking system were the generally accepted use the Bank debt would have caused a deterioration
of bank money, a lower stock of money than deposits, between currency and bank money at the expense of
and the fact that bankers had accounts in other banks. the latter, with severe consequences on the Venetian
As bankers permitted their customers to overdraw, they market.
created credit. Venice thus had public financial institutions that facil-
From the fifteenth century until the Italian wars, gov- itated transactions by both reducing payments in cash
ernment agencies asked local bankers to provide finan- and providing a relatively stable bank currency. It would
cial services (short-term loans and transfers of money be wrong to argue that customers of these banks were ex-
through bills of exchange), but after the Turkish war of clusively rich people and professional traders. A wide
1537–40 their involvement in the mechanisms of state fi- array of people were involved with private bankers,
nance was substantially reduced. It is likely that the and later, public banks. Nobles, merchants, craftsmen,
institution of the Depositi in Zecca and the small finan- women, charitable institutions, trusts, common people,
cial deficit had limited the resort to bankers. Neverthe- and foreigners made up the social profile of customers.
less, the period between the two Turkish wars saw an Venice, therefore, offered an efficient financial market
increase of the banks di scritta. While in 1545 there was at both the international and domestic level, despite
just one banker in the Rialto, on the eve of Lepanto five the economic decline over the last two centuries of her
bankers operated there. history.
Frequent bank crises, however, forced the government
to intervene. In 1568, the Venetian senate forbade the
opening of new banks, and in 1584 the failure of the last
bank, that of the Pisani-Tiepolo, paved the way for the
first public bank. Three years later, in 1587, the Banco SEE ALSO
della Piazza di Rialto, which basically took up the same role
of the former private banks, was founded. The novelty, Globalization of Finance: An Historical View: Geno-
however, was that the government itself exerted a ese Finance, 1348–1700; Low Countries Finance, 1348–
close control over the management of the new financial 1700; Milanese Finance, 1348–1700; Papal Finance,
institution. It received deposits and made giro transac- 1348–1848; Rentes and the European ‘Financial
tions between current accounts. The customers’ Revolution’.
ability to remain in the red for any length of time
disappeared, for the function of the Bank was limited to
controlling the monetary system by providing, at least Glossary
up to the end of the sixteenth century, reliable bank Banco della piazza di Rialto First public bank established in Venice in
money. 1587. It was a deposit bank and limited itself to ease money transfer
In 1637, the Banco della Piazza di Rialto was suppressed among customers.
Banco Giro Venetian state bank founded in 1619. It managed the float-
due to the growing importance of the Banco Giro. Estab-
ing debt of the government and facilitated transactions on the finan-
lished in 1619 as a temporary institution managing the cial market.
relations between the mint and its silver suppliers, it Decima (tenth) Direct tax paid by Venetian taxpayers. It was levied on
was to last until the fall of the Republic in 1797. The regular basis from the mid-fifteenth century.
Banco Giro took up the same role of the Banco della Piazza Depositi fuori Zecca (Deposits outside the Mint) Loans issued by the
Venetian government whose interest was paid directly to bond-
di Rialto and also managed the floating debt of the gov-
holders from tax collectors.
ernment. Suppliers’ credits were registered at the Banco Depositi in Zecca (Deposits in Mint) Bonds sold by the Venetian gov-
Giro, which could be freely transferred. The state did not ernment from the early sixteenth century.
resort to the Banco Giro only to meet its suppliers. In 1629, Estimo Tax register in which real estates of Venetian taxpayers were
it was decided that interest on deposits in the Mint could inscribed.
Monte In some Italian city-states, it was the fund of the government
be paid at the Banco; likewise, some series of state annu-
debt. In Venice, the first series of loans was gathered in the Monte
ities were issued by the new institution, and it proved Vecchio, other Monti (Nuovo, Nuovissimo, and Sussidio) were
opportune to allow Venetians to pay taxes, at least established between the late fifteenth and the early sixteenth
partially, through the bank. centuries.

I. GLOBALIZATION OF FINANCE: AN HISTORICAL VIEW


310 28. VENETIAN FINANCE, 1400–1797

Further Reading Mueller, R.C., 1997. The Venetian Money Market. Banks, Panics and the
Public Debt, 1200–1500. Johns Hopkins University Press, Baltimore,
Borelli, G., Lanaro, P., Vecchiato, F. (Eds.), 1982. Il sistema fiscale ve- London.
neto. Problemi e aspetti, XV–XVIII secolo. Libreria Universitaria, Pezzolo, L., 1990. L’oro dello Stato. Società, finanza e fisco nella Repub-
Verona. blica veneta del secondo ‘500. Il Cardo, Venezia.
Del Torre, G., 1986. Venezia e la Terraferma dopo la guerra di Pezzolo, L., 2003a. The Venetian government debt 1350–1650. In:
Cambrai. Fiscalità e amministrazione (1515–1530). Franco Angeli, Davids, K., Janssens, P., Boone, M. (Eds.), Urban Public Debts,
Milano. Urban Governments and the Market for Annuities in Western
Einaudi, L., 1904. L’economia pubblica veneziana dal 1736 al 1755. La Europe, 14th–18th Centuries. Brepols, Leuven, pp. 61–74.
Riforma Sociale 11, 177–196, 261–282, 429–450, 509–537. Pezzolo, L., 2003b. Il fisco dei veneziani. Finanza pubblica ed economia
Georgelin, J., 1978. Venise au siècle des lumières. Mouton, Paris-La tra XV e XVII secolo. Cierre, Verona.
Haye. Pezzolo, L., 2006. Una finanza d’ancien régime. La Repubblica veneta
Hocquet, J.-C., 1979. Guerre et finance dans l’état de la Renaissance: la tra XV e XVIII secolo. Edizioni scientifiche italiane, Napoli.
Chambre du Sel et la dette publique à Venise. In: Favier, J. (Ed.), Rapp, R.T., 1976. Industry and Economic Decline in Seventeenth-
Actes du 102e Congrès national des Sociétés savantes. Etudes sur Century Venice. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA.
la fiscalité au Moyen Age. Comité des travaux historiques et scien- Tucci, U., 1973. Convertibilità e copertura metallica della moneta del
tifiques, Paris, pp. 109–123. Banco Giro veneziano. Studi Veneziani 15, 349–448.
Lane, F.C., 1973. Public debt and private wealth: particularly in six- Zannini, A., 1998. La finanza pubblica: bilanci, fisco, moneta e debito
teenth century Venice. In: Mélanges en l’honneur de Fernand pubblico. In: Del Negro, P., Preto, P. (Eds.), Storia di Venezia,
Braudel, vol. 1. Privat, Toulouse, pp. 317–325. vol. 8. Istituto dell’enciclopedia italiana, Roma, pp. 431–477.

I. GLOBALIZATION OF FINANCE: AN HISTORICAL VIEW

You might also like