You are on page 1of 12

Beverly J. Fox Lori L.

Taylor
Assistant Economist Senior Economist
Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas

Mine K. Yücel
Senior Economist and Policy Advisor
Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas

America’s Health Care Problem:


An Economic Perspective

H ealth care expenditures in the United States


are expanding rapidly. Real per capita expen-
ditures on health care more than doubled over the
in demand, then we should focus on reforming
consumer incentives. If distortions in supply fuel the
expenditures increase, then we should respond
period 1970 –90.1 Real expenditures for health with policies that affect suppliers. If the increase
care are now growing nearly 4 percent per year, in health expenditures reflects shifts in market
while real expenditures on other consumer goods fundamentals—for example, the increasing health
are growing only 2.5 percent per year.2 Further- care demands of an aging population—then
more, health services grew more than twice as fast economic analysis suggests that the system does
as any other major industry during the recent not need fixing, and we should leave it alone.
recession. If expenditures continue to grow at the
current rate, health care will represent a larger Why is everyone so concerned?
share of the United States’ gross domestic product
(GDP) than manufacturing by 2000.3 Until recently, health care costs were not a
The explosive growth in health care expen- major concern of most Americans. Surveys on the
ditures concerns many Americans. Citizens fear top problems facing the United States in 1984 did
that they will be priced out of the market for health not even mention health care.4 Today, however,
care. Business people worry that rising health care reforming the health care system is one of the
costs will reduce the international competitiveness primary objectives of state and federal governments.
of U.S. corporations. Politicians worry that rising A look at health care prices suggests one
bills for health care programs like Medicare and reason for this change in perspective. As Figure 1
Medicaid will force the government to raise taxes
or run increasingly large deficits.
The widespread concern has led to demands
for substantial reform of the U.S. health care
system. Some groups call for controls on health Our thanks to Zsolt Becsi, Steve Brown, and Mark Wynne
care prices. Others want to reform the insurance for their comments and suggestions.

industry. There are plans that call for managed 1


Levit et al. (1991).
competition and plans that eliminate competition
by making the government the sole provider of 2
Based on data from the U.S. Department of Commerce,
health services. There are almost as many plans as Bureau of Economic Analysis.
there are interested parties. 3
Based on data from the U.S. Department of Commerce,
However, before we can fix the system, we Bureau of Economic Analysis.
have to know what parts of it are broken. If the
increase in health expenditures reflects distortions 4
For example, see the reader survey in Tift (1984).

Economic Review — Third Quarter 1993 21


indicates, health care prices increased at roughly Figure 1
the same rate as the general price level until the Consumer Prices
early 1980s. After the mid-1980s, however, the
Index, 1982– 84 = 100
medical care component of the consumer price
index shot upward. By 1992, medical care prices 200
were increasing at more than twice the rate of 180
Medical care
inflation.5
160
This sharp increase in health care prices has
led consumers to fear that they are being priced 140

out of the market for health care. Publicity on the 120


All items
35 million uninsured Americans lends credibility 100
to those fears.6 Because many Americans view
80
health care as essential, the prospect of being
60
unable to afford it frightens them.
Rising health care prices also concern busi- 40

ness because employers pay a large proportion of 20


the Medicare and Medicaid taxes and 64 percent 0
of private insurance premiums.7 Wage and price ’60 ’62 ’64 ’66 ’68 ’70 ’72 ’74 ’76 ’78 ’80 ’82 ’84 ’86 ’88 ’90 ’92

controls during World War II encouraged employers


SOURCE: U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics.
to provide fringe benefits such as health insurance
in lieu of wage increases. The tax-exempt status
of fringe benefits led many employers to continue
the practice after the controls were removed.
Therefore, much of the increase in health care of the federal budget in 1992 and will consume
expenditures is a drag on the balance sheets of 28 percent of the federal budget by 2002.9
American employers. Ultimately, however, consumers bear the
Furthermore, government is concerned about burden of increases in health care spending. Much
increasing health care costs. Federal expenditures of the increase in employer health costs is passed
for Medicare, which finances health care services along to employees in the form of lower wages
for the elderly, and Medicaid, which finances (see the box entitled “Health Care Costs and
health care services for the poor and disabled, Profitability”). The increase in government health
have been growing more than 10 percent per year costs is passed along to citizens in the form of
since 1985.8 The Congressional Budget Office higher taxes or fewer alternative services. There-
estimates that health spending consumed 15 percent fore, consumers would be the primary beneficiaries
of health care reform.

Sources of increasing health


care expenditures

5
The medical care component of the consumer price index It is possible to determine the best way to
may mismeasure medical inflation somewhat, because it is reform the health care system using the basic
difficult to adjust properly for changes in medical tech-
principles of supply and demand. If no distortions
nology and the quality of care. However, it undoubtedly
influences the public’s perceptions of health care prices.
exist, the health care market achieves the optimal
resource allocation for a given income distribution.
6
Garrison (1990). The increase in health care expenditures then
reflects either an increase in the public’s desire for
7
Levit and Cowan (1991).
health services or an increase in legitimate costs.
8
Levit et al. (1991).
Under these conditions, if society is unhappy with
the allocation, the best solution is to redistribute
9
Burman and Rodgers (1992). income without meddling in the health care market.

22 Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas


Health Care Costs and Profitability

Businesses pay most of the nation’s increases, the total price those firms must pay
health bills, but the effect of increasing health for it decreases, and those firms’ total com-
care costs on profits is not straightforward. pensation costs can fall. Therefore, firms that
Although increases in health costs for retirees offer health insurance as a fringe benefit to
would have a negative effect on firm profitabil- their employees can be made better off—not
ity, increases in health costs for current em- worse off—by the increase in health costs.
ployees can have a positive effect on firm Unfortunately, the savings on total com-
profitability. pensation for current employees can be more
The health care costs of current workers than offset by increased costs for the health
are part of a total compensation offer that is care of retirees. After all, the increases in
determined by the worker’s contribution to the health costs for retirees cannot be offset by
firm’s output. As long as the worker’s produc- decreases in wages. The problem has be-
tivity is unaffected by increases in health care come particularly evident recently as account-
costs, the amount of total compensation the ing rule changes have forced firms to indicate
firm is willing to offer is unaffected by in- their commitments to retiree benefits on their
creases in health costs. Therefore, increases balance sheets. For example, General Mo-
in health costs should be offset by decreases tors was forced to record a $22.2 billion charge
in wages to keep the total compensation in 1992 for retiree and future retiree health
package unchanged. costs.1 Firms that respond to the increase in
Furthermore, the increase in health care health care costs by modifying or eliminating
costs increases the value to employees of the health care coverage for the retired may face
tax exemption for fringe benefits. The advan- increased wage demands by current employ-
tages of being employed by a firm that offers ees who fear being treated in a similar way
health benefits increase, so more workers are when they retire.
attracted to such firms. As the supply of labor
offered to firms that provide health benefits 1
Dallas Morning News (1993).

However, if the health care system is distorted, treatments for health problems, changes in popula-
reform is needed to eliminate the distortions. tion demographics, and society’s reluctance to
We have identified several distortions in the place limits on the value of human life.
current system of health care. First, tax subsidies for
employer-provided health insurance lead to excess The implicit tax subsidy for health insurance
demand for health insurance and, consequently,
to excess consumption of health care. Second, For nearly fifty years, employer-provided
regulations and industry practices restrict the supply fringe benefits have been exempt from both
of health care professionals, leading to higher personal income taxes and payroll taxes such as
prices for health services. Finally, the structure of those for Social Security. Thus, employees avoid
the health insurance industry promotes inefficiency. taxes by taking some of their compensation in the
These distortions of both supply and demand lead form of health insurance. If the combined marginal
to excessive expenditures on health care. tax rate is 28 percent, an employee can receive $1’s
Expenditures also are increasing for several worth of health care instead of 72 cents’ worth of
reasons that are nondistortionary. These reasons after-tax take-home pay (Table 1 ). The difference
include uncertainty about causes and appropriate represents an implied tax subsidy. As Table 1

Economic Review — Third Quarter 1993 23


Table 1
The Subsidized Price of Health Care

Income Effective marginal Price of health care


tax tax rate* in terms of
Wage (percent) (percent) take-home pay
$1 0 14 $.86
$1 15 28 $.72
$1 28 40 $.60
$1 33 45 $.55
*Effective marginal tax rate equals share of the last dollar of monetary compensation paid in
federal taxes and includes both payroll and income taxes.

indicates, those in the highest tax bracket receive sidized and may cause some consumers to be
the largest tax subsidy, while those in the lowest underinsured. Finally, excessive health insurance
tax bracket receive a much smaller subsidy.10 distorts medical research in favor of technologies
Because employees will naturally buy more that extend or improve life at any price rather than
health insurance at 72 cents than at $1, excluding technologies that reduce the costs of treatment.
health-related fringe benefits from taxable income By its nature, health insurance makes con-
increases expenditures on health insurance by sumers less sensitive to health care prices, thereby
those receiving the subsidy. Burman and Rodgers generating more expenditures on health care than
(1992) estimate that the subsidy costs the federal would otherwise occur. Given this relationship,
government $65 billion per year in foregone excessive insurance consumption necessarily leads
revenue and increases private health insurance to excessive health care consumption. Phelps
spending by roughly one-third. (1992) estimates that annual health care expendi-
Excessive consumption of health insurance tures are between 10 percent and 20 percent
has a number of disquieting consequences. First, higher because of the subsidy.
because health insurance leads to increased con- By leading to excessive health care expendi-
sumption of health care, excessive consumption tures, the tax subsidy also can exacerbate the
of health insurance produces excessive consump- problem of the uninsured. Because the subsidy
tion of health care. (For a discussion of the ways increases demand for health care, health care prices
in which health insurance increases health care rise, putting upward pressure on health insurer
consumption, see the box entitled “The Relation- costs. Higher payouts result in higher insurance
ship Between Health Insurance and Health Care premiums. Thus, the subsidy distorts the distribu-
Consumption.”) Second, overconsumption of health tion of health insurance so that higher income
insurance by those receiving the implicit subsidy households overconsume health insurance, while
increases the insurance premiums of the unsub- lower income households can be priced out of
the market for health insurance and health care.
Overconsumption of health insurance also
plays a role in directing technical progress in health
care and has reinforced the development of costly
technologies. Contrary to conventional wisdom,
10
Residents of cities and states with income taxes receive
technological improvements in health care generally
additional subsidies because their fringe benefits are also have not lowered costs. Rather, technological
exempt from local income taxes. innovations have brought about a higher quality

24 Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas


The Relationship Between Health Insurance and Health Care Consumption

Substantial research indicates that as claims. In such a case, consumers have in-
the price to consumers decreases, health centives to limit their health care consumption
care consumption increases (Long and and submit only those claims that are worth
Rodgers 1990, Phelps 1992, Keeler and Rolph the resulting increase in premiums. In prac-
1988, Manning et al. 1987). According to the tice, however, an individual in a large health
Rand Health Insurance Experiment, the price insurance plan pays an average premium that
elasticity of demand for health care is –0.2 is almost independent of the individual’s risk
(Keeler and Rolph 1988, Manning et al. 1987). or health care consumption. Hence, consum-
In other words, every 1 percent decrease in ers do not bear the full costs of their decisions
consumer prices for health care increases about the extent of claims.
health care consumption by 0.2 percent. Furthermore, the loose connection be-
Insurance reduces the consumer’s ef- tween premiums and claims in health insur-
fective price of health care in two ways. First, ance exacerbates problems of moral hazard.
because health insurers typically pay for health Moral hazard arises when insurance changes
treatments rather than for health losses, in- the insured’s behavior in a way that increases
surance lowers the marginal price of treat- claims. For example, people who are insured
ment. If a consumer is fully insured (and, and who, therefore, know that they will bear
therefore, pays none of the billable costs of only part of the cost of illness, may not be as
treatment), then the marginal cost of health careful of their health as people who are not
care becomes the opportunity cost of the insured. Individuals will have no incentive to
consumer’s time. If a consumer is co-insured, curb unhealthy behavior if increased claims
then the marginal cost of treatment becomes are not reflected in higher premiums, espe-
a predetermined fraction of the treatment cially if behavior cannot be easily monitored.
cost, plus the consumer’s opportunity costs. Thus, health insurance increases ex-
For example, with a copayment of 20 percent, penditures on health care. In the Rand experi-
a $10 prescription antihistamine costs the ment, fully insured individuals spent 30 percent
consumer only $2. In either case, health in- more on outpatient services than individuals
surance effectively reduces the consumer’s with a 25 percent copayment. In turn, individu-
marginal cost of health care. als with a 25 percent copayment spent 28
Second, because health insurance pre- percent more than individuals with a 95 per-
miums are only loosely connected to claims, cent copayment (Manning et al. 1987).1
insurance insulates people from some of the
costs of their decisions. Theoretically, insur-
ance premiums, which reflect expected losses, 1
Both co-insurance programs had an annual cap on out-of-
are a function of health risk and the extent of pocket expenses.

product, which is most often more expensive than rather than the cost-effective technologies that
the older product. Weisbrod (1991) finds that our probably would develop if consumers were more
system of pricing (that is, paying the health care sensitive to health care prices.
provider based on costs incurred or on a fee-for- One could argue that the tax subsidy is
service basis) has led the research and develop- necessary because without it, poor people would
ment sector to develop new technologies that receive less medical care and there would be
enhance the quality of care irrespective of cost greater public health risks from communicable

Economic Review — Third Quarter 1993 25


Figure 2 performing many medical tasks. The restrictions
Average Employer-Provided Health Benefits are ostensibly designed to protect the consumer by
increasing the quality of the health care product.
Dollars
Studies have shown, however, that regulations
3,500 that limit supply do not always lead to higher
quality and tend to increase expenditures because
3,000 Estimated tax subsidy they increase incomes in the profession.
People who want to become doctors must first
2,500
gain entry into an accredited U.S. medical school.
2,000
Doctors who train at nonaccredited schools or in
other countries frequently are not permitted to prac-
1,500 tice medicine in the United States. The market for
medical training is monopolistic, and the number of
1,000 medical school applicants greatly exceeds the number
of openings at accredited schools. Each year since
500
1960, medical school applications have exceeded
0
classroom openings by at least 50 percent (Associa-
$0 to $7,600 to $21,600 to $36,300 to $57,100 tion of American Medical Colleges 1993, Table B–
$7,600 $21,600 $36,300 $57,100 and higher
1). In the 1992–93 school year, there were two
Income quintile applicants for every opening. Restrictions on the
SOURCE: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census.
supply of medical training necessarily restricts the
supply of physicians. Assuming that those students
who were not accepted into medical schools were
only 50 percent as likely to complete their education
diseases such as tuberculosis. However, the pro- as those who were accepted, the restriction reduces
gressive nature of the income tax code negates physician supply by approximately 30 percent.
those arguments. As Figure 2 indicates, high-income Once physicians have graduated from
households receive a greater health insurance medical school, they face additional restrictions
subsidy than low-income households. Households imposed by state and local agencies. States have
that fall in the lowest income tax bracket receive a licensing and regulatory agencies or boards that
small subsidy because health benefits are exempt regulate the medical profession. The agencies
from Social Security and other payroll taxes. Mean- establish the minimum level of education and
while, some of the households in the highest income experience required to practice, define the functions
tax bracket receive a federal subsidy of nearly 50 of the profession, and limit the performance of
percent when both income and payroll taxes are certain functions to licensed professionals. Restric-
considered. In combination with an exemption tions include the use of trade names, restrictions
from state taxes, high-income households in high- on branch offices and location of offices, and, until
tax states receive an even larger subsidy. There is 1977, a ban on advertising (Haas –Wilson 1992).
little risk that high-income households will not be Many studies have shown that occupational
able to afford insurance and no obvious consen- licensing leads to lower consumer welfare and
sus that these groups deserve public assistance. higher incomes in the licensed profession. Economic
theory suggests that self-licensing by the medical
Supply constraints profession leads to economic rents (Friedman
1962 and Stigler 1971). Leland (1979) finds that
Numerous restrictions on entry to the health although minimum quality standards may be
care profession distort health care supply and lead desirable in markets in which suppliers have more
to higher consumer prices. These restrictions information than consumers, the minimum quality
include limits on access to medical training, licens- standards set by the medical industry may be too
ing and certification requirements for doctors, and high. Chan and Leland (1982) show that when both
work rules that exclude paraprofessionals from price and quality are hard to observe, uninformed

26 Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas


consumers may pay a higher price and receive a Inefficiencies in the insurance
lower quality of goods. Haas –Wilson (1986) finds industry’s structure
that increasing the restrictiveness of optometrists’
licensing examinations increased the price of eye Another distortion in the health care system
exams and eyeglasses significantly but had an arises from the structure of the insurance industry.
insignificant effect on the quality of the eye exams. The market for health insurance is dominated by
Whenever entry into a market is artificially noncompetitive firms. Medicare and Medicaid,
constrained, either through restricted access to which represent 57 percent of the insurance market,
medical training or through obstacles such as are government entities.12 Furthermore, much of
licensing and certification, consumer prices are the private market for health insurance is domi-
inefficiently high. Therefore, restrictions on entry nated by not-for-profit groups like Blue Cross and
into the health care profession, together with Blue Shield. Only 30 percent of the health insur-
work rules that prevent competition within the ance market is served by for-profit commercial
profession between physicians and less-expensive insurers. Without the discipline of competition,
paraprofessionals, increase medical costs. the market for health insurance is inefficient and
Relaxing some of the restrictions on entry encourages higher health care costs.
into the medical profession should make consumers Considerable economic research indicates
better off. Shaked and Sutton (1981) show that that government agencies are, in general, ineffi-
granting monopolistic powers to the self-regulat- cient (Breton 1974, Downs 1967, and Tullock
ing profession is likely to be welfare-reducing and 1965 and 1967). According to Niskanen (1971), gov-
that the entry of paraprofessionals would be ernment agencies are more likely to try to maxi-
welfare-improving. Moreover, the size of the para- mize the size of their budgets than to maximize
profession that leads to the greatest improvement profits because budget size is a mark of the power
in welfare is the size that leads to the greatest and prestige of the agency. Among other bureau-
income loss for members already in the profession. cratic goals are salaries, office perks, and patronage.
Evans and Williamson (1978) estimate that in Weatherby (1971) cites the expansion of personnel
Ontario, Canada, a dental care system that made as a goal pursued by bureaucrats. Borcherding’s
optimal use of paraprofessionals could reduce the (1977) and Spann’s (1977) findings on the growth
cost of care by 30 percent to 40 percent. More of government and lack of productivity growth
recent studies on restrictions in the dental profes- are consistent with Niskanen’s theory. Since agencies
sion (Liang and Ogur 1987) estimate that state have to return any unused moneys to the U.S.
restrictions on the number of auxiliaries a dentist Treasury, they are not residual claimants on cost
can hire and the functions they may perform cost savings in the budget and have few incentives to
consumers $700 million in 1982. cut costs. There is no reason to believe that
Counter to the principles of supply and Medicare and Medicaid administrators behave
demand, there are some who assert that an increase differently than other bureaucrats.
in physician supply would, in fact, cause higher Like government agencies, not-for-profit
prices. They cite the phenomenon that doctors firms also face incentives to behave inefficiently.
charge higher fees in communities with high (Alchian and Demsetz 1972, Eisenstadt and Ken-
physician-to-patient ratios than they charge in nedy 1981, and Sindelar 1988). Nonprofit health
communities that are less well supplied, even insurers have incentives to dissipate any potential
after adjusting for input cost differences. profits through excess payments to doctors and
However, there is no need to suspend the
laws of supply and demand to explain this phe-
nomenon. Where there is a greater density of
physicians, there also may be a greater degree of
specialization and nonprice competition. Physicians
segment a large market and respond to a greater 11
Phelps (1992, 202).
variety of needs and preferences by treating fewer
patients but charging higher prices.11 12
U.S. Bureau of the Census (1992).

Economic Review — Third Quarter 1993 27


hospitals, unusually generous insurance coverage, Nondistortionary sources
or artificially low insurance premiums. Sindelar of increasing expenditures
(1988) finds that, unlike for-profit insurers, Blue
Cross and Blue Shield plans (the Blues) do not In addition to the distortions, a number of
respond to market forces by changing the price of nondistortionary factors lead to higher health care
health insurance (measured as the ratio of pre- expenditures. Uncertainties on the part of both
miums to benefits). In particular, Sindelar finds physicians and consumers as to the nature and
that administrative costs for the Blues increase as causes of health problems lead to more health
the size of the typical insurance claim increases, care consumption than would occur if all informa-
suggesting that the Blues do not take advantage tion were freely available. However, information
of economies of scale that are exploited by com- is not free, and some of these expenditures are the
mercial insurers. natural result of optimization under uncertainty.
In most industries, the existence of a com- Other nondistortionary factors that contribute to
petitive fringe of efficient firms would discipline higher expenditures include changes in the demo-
the inefficient nonprofit firms (Baumol, Panzar and graphic composition of the U.S. population and
Willig 1988; Caves and Christensen 1980). How- the nearly infinite value placed on human lives.
ever, in the insurance industry, inefficient non- Uncertainty has a major influence on medical
profit insurers receive tax advantages not available decision-making. Doctors and patients have in-
to for-profit insurers. Most states tax the insurance complete information about causes and cures for
premiums of for-profit insurers, while they exempt many health problems. Phelps (1992) shows that
the premiums of nonprofit insurers or tax them at there is substantial disagreement and uncertainty
lower rates. Eisenstadt and Kennedy (1981) find within the medical profession about the marginal
that Blue Shield plans were less efficient in states productivity of alternative medical treatments.
where the plans had a tax advantage than in Uncertainty about the optimal course of action for
states where they did not.13 According to Eisen- various health problems, together with consumers’
stadt and Kennedy, “the regulatory advantages distaste for taking risks with their health, leads to
given to the ‘blues’...allow inefficient behavior to increased testing and treatments and, therefore,
be maintained.” 14 higher health expenditures.
One could argue that nonprofit insurers Further, because patients lack the informa-
should receive tax advantages because they gener- tion to reliably judge medical care quality, they
ally accept customers with preexisting conditions must rely on their doctor’s advice and judgment.
that other insurers consider uninsurable. However, But much like an auto mechanic, the doctor has
society could subsidize insurance for individuals incentives to provide (and bill for) more services
with preexisting conditions without requiring that than absolutely necessary and to provide those
the insurer be a nonprofit organization. For ex- services with less than maximum effort. Economists
ample, the government could provide Medicare refer to these situations as principal – agent prob-
and Medicaid recipients with the resources to lems. The usual solution to such problems is a
purchase private insurance rather than providing contract that provides the agent (in this case the
the insurance itself. There is no need to finance health professional) with incentives to behave
an inefficient market structure. optimally and a mechanism for monitoring the
agent’s compliance with that contract. The mecha-
nism to monitor doctors’ behavior and provide
incentives for optimal performance is the mal-
practice suit.
Unfortunately, asymmetric damages make
malpractice suits more effective at inducing careful
13
Inefficiency is measured by the ratio of administrative costs
care than cost-effective care. After all, if the doctor
to premiums. Both administrative costs and premiums are
expressed as net of premium taxes, if any.
orders too few tests and a patient is injured or
killed, the potential damage is huge. However, if
14
Eisenstadt and Kennedy (1981, 27). the doctor orders too many tests, the damage is

28 Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas


limited to the cost of the tests. Whenever there is Figure 3
uncertainty about the appropriate number of tests, Per Capita Health Care Expenditures by Age, 1987
the risk-averse doctor will prescribe more tests. Thus,
Dollars
malpractice laws and asymmetric damages create
incentives for defensive medicine—procedures 10,000
designed to ward off lawsuits rather than diseases. 9,000
According to the American Medical Association,
8,000
defensive medicine and malpractice insurance add
$36 billion to the nation’s medical bills each year. 15 7,000

In addition to uncertainty, the changing 6,000


demographics of the U.S. population also contrib- 5,000
ute to increases in health care expenditures. Per
4,000
capita health care expenditures increase with both
3,000
age and income. For example, consumers 65 and
over consume more than three-and-one-half times 2,000

as much health care as consumers ages 19 to 64 1,000


(Figure 3). The aging of the population is expected
0
to explain one-seventh of the increase in health Under 19 19 – 64 65 – 84 Over 84

care expenditures over the 40 years from 1990 to Age


2030.16 Furthermore, real U.S. income per capita
SOURCE: U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics.
has grown 2.2 percent per year over the past three
decades, and as populations grow wealthier, they
consume more of all normal goods, including
health care. Simple regression analysis suggests some of the recent increases clearly represent the
that one-quarter of the increase in per capita health demands of an aging and increasingly wealthy
expenditures over the period 1960 – 90 can be population. However, we have identified a number
explained by these two demographic factors. of distortions in the health care market that have
Finally, the high value we place on human a substantial impact on health care expenditures.
life leads to higher expenditures in the health The personal income tax code subsidizes health
care system. Because most consumers would be insurance consumption, thereby fostering exces-
willing to spend huge amounts to avoid dying, sive consumption of health care. Tax exemptions
insured consumers will demand any treatment, for nonprofit insurers and restrictions on the
however costly, that will prolong a patient’s life. supply of health services also lead to higher costs.
The Council of Economic Advisers (1993) esti- To be effective, health care reform must
mates that the 5 percent of beneficiaries who are address these distortions in the health care system.
in the last year of their lives consume 29 percent Eliminating the tax subsidy for employer-provided
of the Medicare budget. health insurance, reducing the tax advantages of
nonprofit insurers, and reducing the restriction
Summary and conclusions on health care providers would go a long way
toward eliminating America’s health care problem.
Health care expenditures in the United States Only after these distortions are removed can the
have expanded rapidly in the past twenty years. economy achieve an efficient allocation of health
This growth in expenditures concerns business resources.
people, politicians, and individual consumers of
health care, although most of the burden falls on
the consumer. Hence, health care reform has
become a primary objective of policymakers.
Increasing expenditures for health care are 15
Felsenthal (1993).
not a problem when they reflect consumer demands
for health care in an undistorted market, and 16
Council of Economic Advisers (1993).

Economic Review — Third Quarter 1993 29


References

Alchian, Armen, and Harold Demsetz (1972), Downs, Anthony (1967), Inside Bureaucracy
“Production, Information Costs and Economic (Boston: Little, Brown, and Co.).
Organizations,” American Economic Review
62 (December): 777– 95. Eisenstadt, David, and Thomas E. Kennedy (1981),
“Control and Behavior of Nonprofit Firms:
Association of American Medical Colleges (1993), The Case of Blue Shield,” Southern Economic
AAMC Databook: Tabulations of Statistical Journal 48 ( July): 26 –36.
Information Related to Medical Education
(Washington, D.C.: AAMC, January). Evans, Robert G., and Malcolm F. Williamson
(1978), Extending Canadian Health Insur-
Baumol, William J., John C. Panzar, and Robert D. ance: Policy Options for Pharmacare and
Willig (1988), Contestable Markets and the Denticare, Ontario Economic Council Re-
Theory of Industry Structure (Fort Worth, search Study no. 13 (Toronto: University of
Texas: Harcourt Brace). Toronto Press).

Borcherding, T.E. (1977), “One Hundred Years of Felsenthal, Edward (1993), “Curing Health Care:
Public Spending,” in Budgets and Bureau- Doctors are Spurring Effort to Remedy the
crats, T.E. Borcherding, ed. (Durham, N.C.: Nation’s Ailing Malpractice System,” Wall
Duke University Press). Street Journal , March 1, B1.

Breton, Albert (1974), The Economic Theory of Friedman, Milton (1962), Capitalism and Freedom
Representative Government (Chicago: Aldine (Chicago: University of Chicago Press).
Publishing Co.).
Garrison, Louis P., Jr. (1990), “Medicaid, the
Burman, Leonard E., and Jack Rodgers (1992), Uninsured, and National Health Spending:
“Tax Preferences and Employment-Based Federal Policy Implications,” Health Care
Health Insurance,” National Tax Journal 65 Financing Review Annual Supplement, 167.
(September): 331– 56.
Haas–Wilson, Deborah (1992), “The Regulation of
Caves, Douglas W., and Laurits R. Christensen Health Care Professionals Other than Physi-
(1980), “The Relative Efficiency of Public and cians,” Regulation: The Cato Review of Busi-
Private Firms in a Competitive Environment: ness and Government, Fall, 40 – 46.
The Case of Canadian Railroads,” Journal of
Political Economy 88 (October): 958 –76. ——— (1986), “The Effect of Commercial Practice
Restrictions: The Case of Optometry,” Journal
Chan, Yuk–Shee, and Hayne Leland (1982), of Law and Economics 29 (April): 165 – 86.
“Prices and Qualities in Markets with Costly
Information,” Review of Economic Statistics 49 Keeler, Emmett B., and John E. Rolph (1988),
(October): 499 – 516. “The Demand for Episodes of Treatment in
the Health Insurance Experiment, Journal of
Council of Economic Advisers (1993), Economic Health Economics 7 (December): 337– 67.
Report of the President (Washington, D.C.:
U.S. Government Printing Office). Leland, Hayne E. (1979), “Quacks, Lemons, and
Licensing: A Theory of Minimum Quality
Dallas Morning News (1993), “GM To Take $22.2 Standards,” Journal of Political Economy 87
Billion Health Charge,” February 2: 1D. (December): 1328 – 46.

30 Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas


Levit, Katharine R., and Cathy A. Cowan (1991), H.E. Frech III, ed. (San Francisco: Pacific
“Business, Households, and Governments: Research Center for Public Policy).
Health Care Costs, 1990,” Health Care Financ-
ing Review, Winter, 83 – 93. Spann, R.M. (1977), “Rates of Productivity Change
and the Growth of State and Local Govern-
———, Helen C. Lazenby, Cathy A. Cowan, and ment Expenditures,” in Budgets and Bureau-
Suzanne W. Letsch (1991), “National Health crats, T.E. Borcherding, ed. (Durham, N.C.:
Expenditures, 1990,” Health Care Financing Duke University Press).
Review, Fall, 29 – 54.
Stigler, George (1971), “The Theory of Economic
Liang, J. Nellie, and Jonathan D. Ogur (1987), Re- Regulation,” Bell Journal of Economics , Autumn,
strictions on Dental Auxiliaries: An Economic 2 – 31.
Policy Analysis (Washington, D.C.: Federal
Trade Commission, Bureau of Economics, 89). Tift, Susan (1984), “Basking in the Sunshine:
During the Final Heat, a Time Poll Shows a
Long, Stephen H., and Jack Rodgers (1990), “The GOP Romp,” Time, November 5, 21.
Effects of Being Uninsured on Health Care
Service Use: Estimates From the Survey of Tullock, Gordon (1967), Toward a Mathematics
Income and Program Participation,” Congres- of Politics (Ann Arbor, Mich.: University of
sional Budget Office Working Paper no. 9012. Michigan Press).

Manning, Willard G., Joseph P. Newhouse, Naihua ——— (1965), The Politics of Bureaucracy,
Duan, Emmett B. Keller, Arleen Leibowitz, (Washington, D.C.: Public Affairs Press).
and Susan Marquis, (1987), “Health Insurance
and the Demand for Medical Care,” American U.S. Bureau of the Census (1992), Statistical
Economic Review 77 ( June): 251–77. Abstract of the United States: 1992, 112th ed.
(Washington, D.C.: U.S. Goverment Printing
Niskanen, William A., Jr. (1971), Bureaucracy and Office).
Representative Government (Chicago: Aldine
Publishing Company). Weatherby, J.L. (1971), “A Note on Administrative
Behavior and Public Policy,” Public Choice,
Phelps, Charles E. (1992), Health Economics (New Fall, 107–10.
York: HarperCollins Publishers).
Weisbrod, Burton A. (1991), “The Health Care
Shaked, Avner, and John Sutton (1981), “The Self- Quadrillemma: An Essay on Technological
Regulating Profession,” Review of Economic Change, Insurance, Quality of Care, and Cost
Studies 48 (April): 217– 34. Containment,” Journal of Economic Literature
29 ( June): 523 –52.
Sindelar, Jody L. (1988), “The Declining Price of
Health Insurance,” in Health Care in America,

Economic Review — Third Quarter 1993 31


32 Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas

You might also like