You are on page 1of 22

World Development Vol. 36, No. 10, pp.

1916–1937, 2008
! 2008 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved
0305-750X/$ - see front matter
www.elsevier.com/locate/worlddev
doi:10.1016/j.worlddev.2008.02.010

Slum Real Estate: The Low-Quality High-Price


Puzzle in Nairobi’s Slum Rental Market and
its Implications for Theory and Practice
SUMILA GULYANI
World Bank, Washington, DC, US

and

DEBABRATA TALUKDAR *
State University of New York at Buffalo, US
Summary. — This study of 1755 households in Nairobi’s slums challenges the conventional belief
that slums offer low-quality low-cost shelter to a population that cannot afford better standards. In
Nairobi, slums provide low-quality but high-cost shelter. Although slum residents pay millions of
dollars in rents annually, and better quality units command higher rents, very little is being re-in-
vested to upgrade quality. To resolve the challenge that the Nairobi puzzle poses for theory and
practice, we develop a new analytical framework for understanding quality of living conditions.
Improving conditions in Nairobi’s slums requires, we argue, two simultaneous interventions: alter-
ation of the tenure mix to enhance owner occupancy and infrastructure investment.
! 2008 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

Key words — informal housing markets, tenure, infrastructure, slum upgrading, quality, Kenya,
Africa

1. INTRODUCTION Recovery Strategy (Government of Kenya,


2003).
In a report titled Challenge of Slums, the Uni- The commitment to improve the lives of slum
ted Nations-HABITAT (2003) estimated that, dwellers is well intentioned and important, but
in 2001, about 870 million people were living the task of achieving this goal is fraught with
in urban slums in developing countries. If cur- problems (Gulyani & Bassett, 2007; World
rent trends continue unchecked, the report ar-
gues, the number of slum residents will grow
to 1.43 billion by 2020. World leaders and
development agencies are again, after a signifi- * We are grateful to Natasha Iskander, Ellen Bassett,
cant hiatus, displaying their concern about the Peter Marcuse, Jacqueline Klopp, and four anonymous
issue, and slums appear to be back on the core reviewers for excellent comments; Jaime Biderman,
development agenda. At UN-sponsored sum- Geoffrey Bergen, Colin Bruce, Makhtar Diop, and
mits in 2000 and 2002, world leaders agreed Matthew Glasser for strongly supporting this study;
to a set of millennium development goals which James Mutero for leading the fieldwork in Nairobi;
include a commitment to significantly improve Alyssa Boyer and Cuz Potter for research assistance;
the lives of at least 100 million slum dwellers Adam Samuel for editing tips; and the World Bank and
by 2020 (UN-HABITAT, 2003). In a nation Norwegian Trust Fund for financing this work. The
such as Kenya, this commitment now appears views expressed here are neither attributable to nor
in national development plans and is high- necessarily shared by the World Bank. Final revision
lighted as a key task in the National Economic accepted: February 22, 2008.
1916
SLUM REAL ESTATE 1917

Bank, 2006). First, a generation of earlier ef- We find that Nairobi’s slums constitute a
forts, starting in the 1970s, to upgrade urban serious challenge to the aforesaid conventional
slums has, at best, been only partially success- wisdom. In Nairobi, the slums indeed cater to
ful. Second, there is little information on and low-income residents and offer low-quality liv-
understanding of urban poverty in general, ing conditions. The surprise is that the resi-
and the situation in slums in particular—there dents, most of whom are very poor, are
are few large-scale or representative studies that paying a large sum of money in rents each
examine the current lives of slum residents, year—in 2004 they paid, on average, US$126
their living conditions, or the nature of poverty (Ksh 9840) per household, amounting to a
that they face. Consequently, in most develop- cumulative sum of about US$31 million (Ksh
ing countries, there are no reliable estimates 2.35 billion). Despite such large payments and
even of basic indicators—such as the number a significant history of implicit recognition by
of people residing in these slums and the pro- government, however, housing in the slums
portion of them that are poor. The UN-HABI- has not improved and consolidated. In other
TAT’s figures cited above are also the subject words, Nairobi’s slums offer low-quality but
of much contention and debate, and the data high-cost housing, and, even worse, they seem
problem is particularly acute in Sub-Saharan to be stuck in this sub-optimal equilibrium.
Africa. This type of ambiguity regarding scale By identifying this puzzle and providing a rare
combined with the lack of systematic studies insight into the scale and nature of Nairobi’s
documenting conditions inside informal settle- massive informal rental market, this paper
ments, means that our understanding of the makes an empirical contribution.
nature of slums and their dynamics is extremely Further, to resolve the challenge that the
limited. Such a partial understanding may well Nairobi case poses for both theory and prac-
have been a key reason for the limited success tice, we develop a new framework for analyzing
of previous programs, and is highly likely to and improving ‘‘quality of living conditions.’’
confound the design, implementation, and suc- Specifically, we argue that quality of living con-
cess of the forthcoming generation of slum- ditions must be understood along four dimen-
improvement efforts as well. sions—tenure, infrastructure, the unit itself,
As a step toward addressing this gap in our and the neighborhood—and that these factors
knowledge base, we conducted a large-scale, interact with each other to determine the out-
and representative study of 1,755 households come. Using this framework, we show why
residing in Nairobi’s slums. 1 The focus was Nairobi’s slums are stuck in a low-quality
on understanding who lives there, what they high-cost trap, and suggest how one might
do, and how they live. In this paper, we use intervene to improve the situation. The frame-
data from our population-weighted stratified work also helps us understand, for example,
random sample to examine one aspect of life why a slum upgrading program that focuses
in the slums—quality of housing and living on improving infrastructure (rather than, say,
conditions, and its relationship to the price res- changing the tenure status) may be the right ap-
idents pay for their accommodation. Specifi- proach in certain contexts, but is likely to fail in
cally, we focus on the following questions: Nairobi’s slums. At a broader level, this frame-
how inadequately housed and under-served are work offers a step toward a more complete the-
slum residents in Nairobi? How much do they ory of living conditions and their dynamics—
pay for their housing and what factors explain because it facilitates a multi-dimensional under-
variation in their rents? standing of quality, highlights interactions
The literature on housing in developing among variables and over time, and helps ex-
countries valorizes slums as an affordable op- plain variation among contexts.
tion for the low-income (see Gulyani & Bassett, This paper is structured as follows. Section 2
2007 for a recent review). It argues that briefly reviews the research methodology, pov-
although slums are sub-par from a technocratic erty incidence in the slums, and demographics
planning perspective and unpleasant by middle- of slum households. Section 3 focuses on liv-
class standards, they play a crucial role by ing conditions—it presents the analytical
proving shelter at low-cost to the urban poor. framework and uses it to assess quality in Nai-
Further, if given even implicit recognition by robi’s slums. Section 4 examines the rental
government—for instance, through a morato- market and factors influencing rents. Section
rium on evictions—these settlements consoli- 5 returns to the framework, and Section 6 con-
date and housing improves over time. cludes.
1918 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

2. METHODOLOGY, THE DATA, AND monthly expenditure of Ksh 3,174 (US$42)


THE TYPICAL SLUM HOUSEHOLD per adult equivalent, excluding rent; (its inclu-
sion would make some renters seem artificially
This study is part of a larger World Bank-ini- richer than home owners). 5 This measure is
tiated research project on slums in Africa. 2 based on the 1997 urban poverty threshold as
This paper is based on data gathered, in Febru- defined by government, and adjusted for infla-
ary, and March 2004, from an in-depth survey tion during the period 1997–2004. 6 Using this
of 1,755 households residing in Nairobi’s poverty line, 73% of the households are ‘‘poor’’
slums. A population-weighted stratified ran- and 27% are ‘‘non-poor’’—that is, poverty inci-
dom sample of households was created as fol- dence in the slums is very high.
lows. For census purposes, Kenya’s Central
Bureau of Statistics (CBS) has divided Nairobi (c) Key demographics, and the typical slum
into about 4,700 enumeration areas (EAs), of household
which 1,263 as categorized as ‘‘EA5,’’ or
‘‘informal settlements;’’ these are all character- The average slum household has three mem-
ized by poor quality sub-standard housing and bers (Table 6 in Appendix 1). By comparison,
poor infrastructure. For our purpose, all 1,263 mean household size is 3.2 for Nairobi and
EAs are ‘‘slums’’ (see Section 3 for definition). 3.4 for urban Kenya (Census, 1999). The rela-
From these 1,263 slum EAs, 88 were randomly tively small household size in slums is partly
selected, and lists of their residents were up- attributable to the high proportion of single-
dated by CBS through a field-based re-listing. person households—they account for almost a
About 20 households were then selected ran- third (32%) of all households. The average
domly, from the updated lists, in each of the household head is 35 years old, and most are
88 EAs (see Appendix 1 for a map of surveyed men; female-headed households account for
areas), and all households were assigned a 18% of all households. As locally believed,
weight adjusted to reflect their probability of there are more male than female residents; the
selection. In the results presented in this paper, ratio, however, is 55:45 belying the notion that
all household-level data are weighted but indi- slums are inhabited largely by males.
vidual-level data are not.

(a) Slum residents account for at least 30% of the 3. ASSESSING QUALITY: THE LIVING
population CONDITIONS DIAMOND

In the 1999 national census, Nairobi’s popu- Although slums universally invoke images of
lation was 2.14 million, and slums accounted squalor, not all are equally bad. Slums vary—
for 640,000 people or about 30% of the city’s some have better access to water, others offer
population. It is worth noting that ‘‘30%’’ better quality housing units, and some are
seems to be a conservative estimate and may re- physically safer. While the vast literature on
flect, in part, CBS’s use of a relatively stringent slums cumulatively demonstrates that there is
definition of slums. 3 We use this number— diversity, it offers few conceptual models that
640,000 slum residents in 1999—as establishing can comfortably accommodate and explain
a ‘‘floor’’ or minimum number of slum resi- such a variation in quality of living conditions
dents in the city. By the time of the survey in among settlements. This is partly due to the
2004, the slum population is estimated to have fact that there are few large-scale empirical
grown from 640,000 to 810,000. 4 The sam- studies that systematically document quality
pling, and results of this study, therefore, per- and variations in it, let alone explain why and
tain to the total population of the 1263 EAs under what conditions quality improves.
in 2004, or an estimated 810,000 people. As a step toward a broader conceptual model
for documenting, understanding, and compara-
(b) Disaggregating ‘‘poor’’ and ‘‘non-poor’’ tively analyzing living conditions among
households in slums settlements, we develop a new framework. Ana-
lytically, we propose that living conditions—in
We use a discrete poverty measure—an any settlement, including slums—can be under-
expenditure-based poverty line—to disaggre- stood as a combination of four types of factors:
gate our sample into poor and non-poor house- (i) tenure, (ii) infrastructure, (iii) unit quality,
holds. Here, the poverty line is defined as a and (iv) the neighborhood’s condition and
SLUM REAL ESTATE 1919

location. These four factors interact with, and investment in the unit, or vice versa. The links
influence each other, and they collectively deter- between tenure and each of the other three
mine the overall quality of living conditions in a components—as theorized in the literature,
given settlement. We represent this framework and in this framework—are discussed in turn
graphically as a diamond with four vertices, below.
and, for ease of reference, call it the living con- The relationship between tenure and the unit
ditions diamond (Figure 1). The literature elu- is much studied and theorized. Many research-
cidates the importance of each of the four ers have argued that residents of slums, despite
components individually, but we aim to extend their apparent poverty, will invest to improve
current conceptualizations by creating a com- their housing, but to do so they need to have
posite and by proposing that the four aspects some security of tenure (e.g., De Soto, 2000;
are interdependent. To illustrate the logic be- Turner, 1972). There continue to be raging de-
hind the framework, and its relationship to bates, however, regarding how tenure security
existing literature, we use the tenure compo- can be enhanced, and whether it can ‘‘follow’’
nent. 7 rather than ‘‘lead’’ investment. For De Soto
We make three main propositions regarding (2000), land titling is the right approach to con-
tenure. First, the type and security of ten- ferring tenure security and unleashing ‘‘dead
ure—for example, whether a resident is tenant capital’’; in this view, legal tenure is a precursor
or owner and whether there is an imminent to housing investment and also leads to broad-
threat of displacement—is in itself an impor- er welfare gains for residents. By contrast,
tant aspect of quality of living conditions. It other analysts have documented cases where
is, therefore, a component of the framework. the sequence was reversed—in Amman, Jor-
Second, tenure and its perceived security are re- dan, and Voi, Kenya, residents invested in
lated to the three other components: unit qual- making their homes more permanent as a strat-
ity; infrastructure access; and the egy for securing their tenure (Bassett, 2007;
neighborhood’s condition and location. Third, Razzaz, 1993). In our framework, both are va-
the direction of influence between tenure and lid: tenure and unit quality are related, and a
any other factor can run either way—for exam- change in either one can lead to a change in
ple, enhanced tenure security can facilitate the other.

Figure 1. Living conditions diamond.


1920 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

Tenure is also related to infrastructure access. can influence changes in the other three, and
Because government agencies see slums as tem- conditions change over time. Therefore, if data
porary or illegal, they are reluctant to invest in are collected at periodic intervals and plotted
extending public services—water supply, elec- using the Diamond, the relationship between
tricity, drainage, sewerage, garbage removal, various factors can be explored and changes
and street lighting—to them (UN-HABITAT, in quality analyzed over an extended time-
2003). If so, a first step to improving services, frame. By drawing attention to the dynam-
and living conditions would be to deem settle- ics—between variables and over time—the
ments legal. This logic resonates with De Soto’s framework helps emphasize that settlements
(2000), and supports his ‘‘title first’’ approach; can follow different development trajectories,
titles can, theoretically, encourage not only pri- and that these can shift with time (e.g., ‘‘slums
vate investment in units but also public invest- of hope’’ can become ‘‘slums of despair,’’ and
ment in infrastructure. In direct contrast, vice versa).
infrastructure proponents argue that the infra- Third, it provides a conceptual model that
structure can lead or even replace efforts to for- can not only accommodate but also help ex-
malize tenure in slums because infrastructure plain variation in quality of living conditions
investment signals ‘‘acceptance’’ or implicit rec- among settlements. It allows us to move be-
ognition of informal settlements by government yond the simplistic notion that slums are homo-
(Gulyani & Bassett, 2007; World Bank, 2002). geneously poor in quality, and facilitates
Infrastructure investments reduce the perceived comparative analyses that can reveal why they
threat of demolition and offer de facto tenure differ. It also moves us away from seeking ‘‘uni-
security which, in turn, encourages residents form’’ or globally applicable definitions of
to invest in their units. In our framework, ten- slums—of the kind the UN-HABITAT (2003)
ure and infrastructure interact, and, in contrast suggests we establish—and toward a more con-
to debates in the literature, we posit that either text-specific understanding of them. 8
one can lead to improvements in the other. In In the next sub-sections, we discuss how the
other words, the framework allows for the con- framework can be used to define slums, and,
sideration of multiple directions of causality then, use it to assess quality of living conditions
and different entry points—the ‘‘correct’’ solu- in Nairobi’s slums. We show that each of the
tion, we contend, is likely to vary by context. four dimensions is in itself a composite of sev-
Finally, tenure is related to a neighborhood’s eral factors and requires the use of multiple
condition and its location. Neighborhoods with indicators. Our selection of indicators is illus-
better conditions—public amenities (e.g., trative rather than prescriptive or comprehen-
parks, schools), safety, layouts that permit ac- sive. We return to the framework in Section 5
cess—are likely to be associated with greater to demonstrate how it serves as an analytical
tenure security. The location matters as well— tool and provide an understanding that is dif-
for instance, slums on hazardous sites (and, of- ferent from current conceptualizations.
ten, those in prime downtown locations) are
more likely to be slated for demolition, even (a) Defining and documenting slums using the
by governments that otherwise support slum- framework
improvements.
Overall, the framework contributes to exist- Slums score poorly on one or more of the four
ing literature in three ways. First, it creates a dimensions of the Living Conditions frame-
composite that offers a more comprehensive work. In fact, in most parts of the developing
and multi-dimensional approach to document- world, slums have some combination of the fol-
ing, and understanding quality. Documenting lowing four characteristics in early stages of
indicators related to the four dimensions of their development: (i) informal or illegal land
the Living Conditions framework can together tenure; (ii) physical infrastructure and ser-
provide a good overview—a snapshot at one vices—such as water supply, electricity, drain-
moment in time—of conditions in a settlement. age, sanitation, and street lighting—that are
These can also be converted to a numerical in- all highly inadequate; (iii) housing units built
dex, by assigning weights to various indicators. with poor-quality or impermanent construc-
Second, it emphasizes interactions among the tion materials, usually in violation of various
variables that are usually treated or studied in standards; and (iv) neighborhood conditions
isolation, and allows for a dynamic understand- and location that are poor, and often also fail
ing of living conditions. A change in one factor to meet legally specified regulations and plan-
SLUM REAL ESTATE 1921

ning standards. If defined very broadly, the ket’’ or system, with enforceable rules of the
term ‘‘slum’’ can include settlements that have game.
any of the above characteristics. The high tenancy rate in the slums reflects a
In this paper, we use a narrow definition of larger problem facing the city as a whole—
slums, focusing on those that score poorly on 82% of the city’s residents are tenants (Census,
all four dimensions of the framework—tenure, 1999), indicating that households across differ-
infrastructure, unit quality, and neighborhood ent income classes have difficulty owning prop-
conditions. In the slums included in our study, erty in Nairobi. 9 This means, for example, that
housing and infrastructure are visibly below programs to regularize tenure or create owner-
minimum standards and land tenure is informal ship for slum residents must consider potential/
or illegal. This definition excludes, for instance, latent demand for such assets from better-off
housing that is built to standard but is deemed citizens. In this context, slum upgrading pro-
informal because it lacks official paperwork or grams that create assets—such as housing with
violates land use and zoning regulations. De- legal title—for slum residents that the better-off
fined as such, Nairobi’s slums are a subset of lack are likely to be the subject to gentrifica-
informal settlements (since all slums are infor- tion, unless they are explicitly scaled and de-
mal, we use the terms interchangeably in this signed to counter such effects.
paper). In the following sub-sections, we exam-
ine each of the four dimensions of the Diamond (c) Housing size and quality—crowded and
in turn, to create a multi-dimensional snapshot constructed with impermanent materials
of living conditions in Nairobi’s slums.
Crowding, as measured by persons per room,
(b) Tenure in Nairobi’s slums: tenuous, short, is far worse in the slums than in Nairobi city
and disproportionately rental and the nation as a whole. There are 2.6 per-
sons per room in Nairobi’s slums as compared
In Nairobi’s slums, we find that the tenure to 1.7 for Nairobi, and 1.55 for Kenya. Fur-
mix is unusually skewed toward tenancy— ther, almost the entire stock of slum housing
92% of the households are rent-paying tenants is constructed with poor-quality and imperma-
and 8% are owner-occupiers. Only 6% claim nent building materials. For instance, only 12%
they own both their house and their land, while of the units have permanent external walls—
2% say they own the structure but not the land. constructed with stone, brick, or block. This
Within this small group of owner occupants, quality indicator compares unfavorably with
60% rent out at least one room and are ‘‘resi- the Nairobi average of 56%, and also with the
dent landlords.’’ Resident landlords thus ac- national average of 26% (Census, 1999). The
count for 5% of the slum population, latter is worth noting, given that housing qual-
indicating that the vast majority are ‘‘absentee ity in rural areas is known to be very poor.
landlords’’ who do not live in the slums. Local
experts emphasize that the technically correct (d) Infrastructure access and service delivery:
term is ‘‘structure owner’’ rather than ‘‘land- worse than anticipated
lord’’ because almost none of them own the
land (the terms landlord and structure owner There is almost universal agreement—be-
are used interchangeably in this paper). tween policy makers, academics, city residents,
Tenancy contracts in slums are based almost development agencies, and other experts—that
entirely on verbal agreements—only 3.6% of Nairobi’s slums have inadequate infrastructure.
the renters have a formal written tenancy agree- At the same time, aggregate data on infrastruc-
ment. Their tenancy is, hence, fragile in legal ture access from the National Census of 1999
terms. It is also short in duration—we find that indicate that the city’s residents (and, by exten-
slum residents have lived in their current home sion, its slum residents) are far better-off than
for an average of five years and in their current those in other parts of the nation. This raises
settlement for about nine years. In other words, the question: just how inadequately served are
the turnover rate is high. About 9% report that Nairobi’s slum residents?
they have been evicted at least once. Neverthe- To provide a systematic and empirical over-
less, about half the residents feel that they have view, we plot ‘‘access’’ indicators for six types
secure tenure. The latter, combined with the of infrastructure as an ‘‘infrastructure services
fact that tenants move frequently, suggests that polygon’’ (see Figure 2). The polygon shows
there is a fairly well-established rental ‘‘mar- that access to public infrastructure in the slums
1922 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

Figure 2. Infrastructure services polygon. Note: Y: yard tap, H: in-house water connection, P: public sewer, S: soak pit.

is appalling—less than a quarter of the polygon vel is low. Specifically, water use averages
is shaded, demonstrating that less than quarter about 23 liters per capita per day (lcd), and
of the slum population has access to any of the the median value is 20 lcd. Slum residents
six services examined. This falls far short of the pay, on average, Ksh130/m3 (US$1.73/m3) for
normative goal of universal access to these ba- their water, and the median cost is KSh100/
sic services, reflected as fully (100%) shaded m3 (US$1.33/m3). Based on data from other
polygon. The polygon also reveals variation studies on water use and prices in Kenya (see
among services—it shows, for instance, that Gulyani, Talukdar, & Kariuki, 2005; Thomp-
about 22% have electricity connections but only son et al., 2000), we can categorically conclude
0.9% benefit from public garbage collection ser- that Nairobi’s slum residents are seriously un-
vice. We discuss some of the service-specific der-served.
findings from Table 1 to provide an insight into
(a) inequality in access in the slums relative to (ii) Reading by kerosene lamps: few electricity
the city; and (b) the types of (informal) options connections
the unserved are forced to rely upon. Only one in five homes in Nairobi’s slums
(22%) is connected to electricity (Table 1). Con-
(i) Water: cash-and-carry service, low use levels, nections rates are significantly higher among
and high-prices non-poor households (31%) compared to the
Previous studies have argued that the urban poor (18%). Among the 78% who are uncon-
poor, especially those residing in slums, are nected, almost all rely on kerosene as their pri-
poorly served by public water utilities. In Nai- mary lighting fuel. Use of electricity as a
robi’s slums only about 19% of the households lighting fuel—an indicator of its relative ‘‘ac-
are directly connected to the public water util- cess, availability, and affordability’’—is far
ity—4% have private piped connections, and lower in Nairobi’s slums compared to the city
15% have yard taps (Table 1). By comparison, and to urban Kenya, but still higher than in
the aggregate city-wide water connection rate rural Kenya.
is estimated to be 71–72% (Collignon & Vézina,
2000). In other words, there is a gap of over (iii) Toilets: shared facilities with high loading
50% points in utility connection rates between levels
the city and its slums. Only about one-quarter of the households
The majority—64%—of slum residents, have access to a private toilet facility. The
therefore, rely on kiosks and buy water by the majority (68%) of slum residents rely on shared
bucket (or 20-l ‘‘jerrycans’’). About 5% rely toilet facilities, and loading factors are high. On
on ground or other natural sources, 2% on ven- average, 19 households or 71 people depend on
dors, and 1% on neighbors. Given the reliance one shared toilet. About 6% of the households
on sources such as kiosks, the unit cost of water are even worse off than those sharing facili-
borne by slum residents is high, and their use le- ties—they have no access to toilets and have
SLUM REAL ESTATE 1923

Table 1. Infrastructure and services


All Poor Non-poor
N Value N Value N Value
Water use and unit cost
Mean per capita water use, liters per day*** 1750 23.4 1277 21 473 29.8
—median use, liters per day 20.0 20 20.0
Mean unit water cost, USD/m3** 1750 1.7 1277 1.7 473 1.8
—median cost, USD/m3 1.3 1.3 2.0
Primary sources of water*** (%)
Private piped 67 4 47 4 18 4
Yard tap 267 15 185 14 82 17
Kiosk 1127 64 838 65 289 61
Others (incl. missing) 294 17 212 17 84 18
Total 1755 100 1282 100 473 100
Connections to electricity(%) 1755 1282 473
Households connected ** 22 18 31
HHs aware of informal connections 44 50 44
Primary source of home lighting** (%) 1755 1282 473
Electricity 22 19 30
Kerosene 77 80 70
Solar/others 1 1 1
Street lighting(%) 1755 1282 473
HHs who say there is street lighting 16 15 15
Toilet facilities—Type (%): 1755 1282 473
No facility/flying toilets 6 6 6
Individual toilet (VIP/ordinary pit/WC) 25 24 26
Shared/public toilet 68 68 67
Average no. HHs sharing a toilet facility (no.) 1615 19.1 1180 19.4 435 18.5
Average no. people sharing toilet facility* (no.) 1613 71.3 1181 73.8 432 64.7
Excreta disposal system (incl. sewerage)* (%) 1755 1282 473
Formal NCC connection to public sewer 12 11 14
Informal connection to public sewer 17 18 14
Septic tank/soak pit 1 0 2
Pit latrine 64 64 63
Garbage disposal system (%) 1755 1282 473
Dumping in own neighborhood 78 79 76
Burning/burying in own compound 10 10 9
Organized private collection system 11 10 13
City collection system 1 1 1
Gray water disposal/drainage (%) 1755 1282 473
Pour into the drain 71 71 70
Pour into the road, or pavement 19 19 17
Pour into pit latrine 1 1 1
HHs with a drain outside their house 58 56 61
HHs whose drain works most of the time 25 25 26
Note: Significance of difference between poor and non-poor indicated by asterisks: ** = 5%, * = 10%.
Figures may not add to 100% due to rounding.

to use open areas or ‘‘flying toilets’’ (i.e., plastic lated services is the cause for alarm. First, solid
bags that are tied up and flung away). waste disposal services barely exist. Less than
one in a hundred households (0.9%) is served
(iv) Neighborhood-level sanitation infrastructure by a publicly-provided garbage collection sys-
and services: a health crisis? tem; consequently, most households dump or
Access to various neighborhood-level ser- burn waste in their immediate vicinity. Second,
vices is no better, and the state of sanitation-re- about 12% of households say they are
1924 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

connected to a public sewer, and 1% have a ownership schemes (Hansen, 1997). Yet others
soak pit; the majority rely on pit latrines that protest the stereo-typical portrayals of land-
contaminate ground water if they are unlined lords as villains, arguing that there is wide-
or when they overflow. Third, only 25% have spread prevalence of petty landlordism that
a working drain outside their house; stagnant generates only small profits while facilitating
water is a health hazard and, during the rainy consolidation in self-help settlements (e.g., Dat-
season, flooding of homes is common. ta, 1995; O’Connor, 1983). In Gaborone, Bots-
wana, for example, women outnumbered men
(e) Neighborhood and location: unsafe from as landlords among the urban poor in self-help
crime in their own neighborhood housing areas and they earned relatively low
rents (Datta, 1995). Similarly a small-scale
For brevity, we report just one neighbor- study of two low-income settlements in South
hood-level indicator—safety. 10 As many as Africa found that ‘‘few landlords make any
63% of households report that they feel unsafe money at all . . . [and] the poor quality of
inside their slum and 27% report that someone accommodation keeps rents low . . .’’ (Gilbert
in their household actually experienced a crim- et al., 1997). Based on a review of such analy-
inal incident over the previous 12 months. ses, the UN-HABITAT (2003) concluded that
Among those who were victims, the majority ‘‘aid programs for rental tenure remain a ne-
report that the incident occurred inside their glected element of international assistance,
own settlement. The average number of inci- and knowledge about informal landlords and
dents experienced by a victimized household tenants and the kinds of programs that might
in the previous year was 1.67, with an average benefit them are rare.’’
of 1.2 occurring inside the slum and 0.46 else- By contrast, among local experts, and policy
where. makers, 11 there is a raging debate over whether
the rents are too high, and whether the Nairobi
(f) Conclusions on quality slum rental market, allegedly dominated by
politically well-connected landlords, is helping
In sum, the quality of living conditions is or hurting the poor. Based on analyses pre-
unambiguously bad, with appalling indicators sented in this section, we will argue that the ren-
on each of the four dimensions—tenure, infra- tal market in Nairobi’s slums is not serving the
structure, unit quality, and neighborhood—of poor well, and that it is highly desirable to
the living conditions diamond (see Figure 1). reach a better outcome. Although the case
In the existing literature on slums, it is widely poses a major challenge for proponents of ren-
accepted that such low quality and standards tal housing, 12 it also contributes to this litera-
help keep housing affordable (e.g., Gilbert, ture by revealing conditions under which
2003; Gilbert, Mabin, McCarthy, & Watson, rental housing can hurt rather than help the
1997). Intuitively, quality and price should be poor.
correlated—the better the standard of living In this section, we take a closer look at rents
conditions, the higher the market price or per- and behavior of the rental market. Ascertaining
ceived value of a unit or neighborhood. In the whether ‘‘rents are too high’’ is, however, not
next section, we test whether poor quality is easy; it requires an examination from two
indeed keeping rents low and affordable in opposite perspectives—from the demand-side
Nairobi’s slums, and also examine which as- to assess affordability, and from the supply side
pects of quality are correlated with higher to assess returns on investment. We start by
rents. examining rent levels and affordability, cash
flow in the rental market, and factors influenc-
ing rents. On the supply side, we examine rates
4. THE SLUM RENTAL MARKET of return and review what we know about land-
lords.
Several analysts have highlighted the impor-
tance of rental housing in providing shelter (a) Rents are not highly affordable and operate
for the poor (e.g., Gilbert, 2003; Kumar, within a narrow band
1996; Miraftab, 1997). Some even argue that
the expressed demand is for low-cost rental At first glance, the slums appear to offer
accommodation and strongly oppose the accommodation at a wide variety of prices.
emphasis, in development planning, on home- As Table 2 shows, the maximum reported
SLUM REAL ESTATE 1925

Table 2. Rents in different areas (administrative non-poor (Figure 4). The non-poor do spend
divisions) of Nairobi more on rent—but, surprisingly, only about
N Mean Median Min. Max. SD 20% more—than the poor. On average, the
non-poor pay a monthly rent of Ksh 913
Dagoretti 295 1090 900 300 3230 570
(US$12) or about 11% of their income, while
Westlands 57 1080 1000 400 3000 590
the poor pay Ksh 753 (US$10) accounting for
Pumwani 111 890 700 300 3000 590
Central 189 860 700 260 2600 400
about 12% of their income; the median rent is
Makadara 170 780 750 400 2000 200
Ksh 750 (US$10), and Ksh 700 (US$9) for
Embakasi 167 670 600 200 3200 330 the two, respectively (Table 3).
Kasarani 182 640 500 250 2000 320 The relatively small difference in rental
Kibera 450 620 500 300 2000 260 expenditures between the poor and non-poor
reflects in our view, lack of choice. First, as a
Total 1621 790 700 200 3230 440 comparison of Figures 3 and 4—cumulative
plots of rents and incomes—graphically re-
veals, there is a significant gap in the income
monthly rent is Ksh 3,230 (US$43.1) which is curves for poor versus non-poor households,
about 16 times higher than the minimum rent but the profile of rents paid by the two groups
of Ksh 200 (US$2.7). It also shows, as one is virtually identical. Second, there is a large
might expect, that rental values differ among difference in their absolute expenditures in
the eight administrative divisions of the city. other categories such as food, water, and trans-
Rents are, on average, highest in the slums lo- port. Compared to the poor, the non-poor
cated in Westlands and Dagoretti, and lowest spend about twice as much on food per person
in those located in Kibera and Kasarani. A clo- per day, 1.5 times more on water, and three
ser examination suggests, however, that major- times more on transport (Table 3). The diver-
ity of the rents fall within a narrow range, and, gence in transport expenditure patterns is par-
as noted earlier by Amis (1984), the typical rent ticularly striking. The median absolute
is anything but low or easily affordable. expenditure on transport is zero for poor
To assess affordability, we looked at income, households—that is, half of all poor house-
and expenditure levels of residents (Table 3). holds spend nothing on transport, and opt to
We know that 73% of slum households fall be- walk; they appear to be coping by cutting back
low the absolute poverty line, defined as an on a ‘‘luxury’’ such as transport. In other
expenditure of Ksh 3,174 (US$42) per adult words, the poor spend far less than the non-
equivalent per month, excluding rent. With re- poor when they have discretion; with respect
spect to income, households reported an aver- to housing, the poor seem not to have discre-
age monthly per capita income of Ksh 3,705 tion—the market does not offer cheaper, or
(US$49). The median income is Ksh 3,000 more affordable units. This appears to be a
(US$40)—that is, half of the slum households key reason why rental expenditures differ little
earn less than US$40 per capita per month. between the poor and non-poor. Overall, this
As one would expect, poor and non-poor discussion suggests that even the cheapest slum
households differ significantly—compared to housing, although less expensive than other op-
the poor, average income and expenditure tions in the city (e.g., Huchzermeyer, 2006), 14
among the non-poor is twice as high (see Table is probably not cheap enough for its poor resi-
3 and Figure 3). dents.
Regarding rents, four points are worth high-
lighting. First, rent constitutes a major expense (b) The multi-million dollar slum rental market
for slum households—second only to food—
and it accounts for about 12% of monthly Rents constitute a significant expense for
household income on average. 13 Second, the these relatively poor people individually, but
typical rent is significant in absolute terms— how much is this real estate worth cumula-
the average monthly rent is Ksh 790 (US$11), tively? In 2004, slum residents paid at least
and the median rent is Ksh 700 (US$9). Third, US$31 million (Ksh 2.3 billion) in rents. This
rents move within a narrow band overall. Apart figure is estimated using an average rent of
from the outliers on either end, the vast major- Ksh 790 per month per household, a tenancy
ity (80%) pay rents between Ksh 400 and 1,200 rate of 92%, and a slum population of
(US$5.3–16.0). Fourth, there is only a small dif- 810,000. This is a very large sum—it exceeds,
ference between the rents paid by the poor and for example, Nairobi city’s annual budget for
1926
Table 3. Incomes and expenditures
All HH Poor HH Non-poor HH

WORLD DEVELOPMENT
N Mean Median N Mean Median N Mean Median
Per capita income in Ksh/month ** 1,400 3,705 3,000 1,011 2,776 2,444 389 6,023 5,500
Per capita expenditure on basics, typical month (Ksh) ** 1,754 2,493 2,000 1,281 1,874 1,750 473 4,121 4,000
Per capita spending on food per day (Ksh) *** 1,755 43.00 40.00 1,282 34.31 31.00 473 66.04 60.00
Per capita spending on transportation per day (Ksh) *** 1,754 9.68 4.00 1,281 5.98 0.00 473 19.44 15.00
Per capita daily expenditure on water (Ksh) *** 1,754 2.95 2.40 1,281 2.57 2.00 473 3.95 3.00
Rent per month (Ksh) ** 1,601 797 700 1,173 753 700 428 913 750
Household monthly spending on refuse collection (Ksh) 161 51 40 117 51 40 44 51 40
Household spending per month on electricity (Ksh) ** 362 286 250 218 295 275 144 274 200
Note: (i) Statistical significance of difference between poor and non-poor indicated by asterisks. *** = 1%; ** = 5%, and * = 10%.
(ii) The relevant exchange rate is US$1 = Ksh75.
SLUM REAL ESTATE 1927

Figure 3. Cumulative plot of per capita household income. Note: households are categorized as ‘‘poor’’ or ‘‘non-poor’’
based on a ‘‘0,1’’ classification using an expenditure-based (not income-based) poverty threshold.

Figure 4. Cumulative plot of typical monthly rent.

investment as well as operations and mainte- (c) What drives rents in Nairobi’s informal
nance. 15 If viewed as repayments on a com- housing market?
mercial housing development loan, this cash
flow would be sufficient to leverage, and pay We find that rents vary not only between
off a 20-year loan of about US$358 million, at slums located in different parts of the city but
an interest rate of 6%. Unfortunately, very little also within each settlement. To identify vari-
of this vast cash flow is currently being invested ables that drive rents in slums, we conducted
or leveraged to improve living conditions in the a multivariate regression analysis with
slums; this is evident from the previous section ‘‘monthly rent’’ as the dependent variable. The
on quality. complete results of this hedonic-type analysis
1928 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

are presented in Table 4 and the main findings cance of 10% or less as the threshold value
are discussed below. for determining whether a variable is systemat-
The results show that this model—comprised ically correlated with rent.
of independent variables corresponding to the Characteristics of the rented unit strongly
four dimensions of the living conditions dia- influence rent. A unit’s size, in terms of number
mond—explains 50.5% of the observed varia- of rooms, is strongly and positively related to
tions in rents. Given that the regression rent. Housing quality also matters—rents are
analysis is based entirely on cross-sectional higher for units that received a higher quality
data, the explanatory power of this rent regres- rating from enumerators, and also for housing
sion model is quite high. By using a step-wise constructed with permanent building materials.
regression approach, we examined the relative Units with external walls of stone, brick, or
explanatory power of the four categories of block have higher rents than those with walls
variables. Variables related to the unit size of wood, mud, or tin. Similarly, units with ce-
and quality have the greatest explanatory ment or wooden floors have higher rents than
power—they explain about 32% of the varia- those with mud floors.
tion in rents. Infrastructure variables explain Unit-level infrastructure access is also corre-
an additional 8% of the variation, neighbor- lated with rent. Units with an electricity con-
hood conditions and location account for nection, and those with an in-house or yard
about 10% and tenure-related variables explain connection for water, have higher rents than
about 0.5% of the total variation in rents. In the units without these amenities. Similarly, rents
discussion below, we take a statistical signifi- are higher for units that provide ‘‘reasonable’’

Table 4. Regression for monthly rent (N = 1601)


Coefficient Std. Err. P-value
(1) Unit size and quality
Number of rooms for household 314.270*** 64.096 0.000
Assessor’s estimate of building quality 77.894*** 29.560 0.010
Permanent walls 305.829*** 67.993 0.000
Concrete roof !78.396 95.140 0.412
Permanent floor 115.384*** 21.733 0.000
(2) Infrastructure: unit and neighborhood-level
Has electricity 241.176*** 26.683 0.000
Has piped water 73.353** 35.664 0.043
Reasonable access to toilet 33.523* 19.704 0.092
Has drain outside !18.418 16.080 0.255
Internal roads unpaved !16.021 39.745 0.688
Street lights exist 42.600 71.856 0.555
(3) Neighborhood conditions and location
Settlement has been improved !91.958 68.597 0.184
Public school present in neighborhood 48.946* 26.482 0.068
Considers area safe !15.872 15.190 0.299
Neighborhood location (ii) (ii) (ii)
(4) Tenure
Perceives tenure to be secure !20.448 21.295 0.340
Length of stay in unit (in years) !2.689 1.895 0.159
Constant 150.388 99.620 0.135
Adj. R2 = 0.505
Notes: (i) The regression model is estimated using the sampling weights for households. Statistical significance of
coefficients is indicated by asterisks: *** = 1%, ** = 5%, and * = 10%.
(ii) The results for the 24 ‘‘location’’ dummy variables are not shown here to conserve space. Out of the 24, 15 show a
statistically significant difference in rents as compared to the location selected as ‘‘base’’ case (viz., Mathare).
SLUM REAL ESTATE 1929

access to a toilet facility, defined as those where manent walls and floors, as well as those with
the renter shares a toilet facility with less than connections to electricity or piped water. They
ten households (as noted earlier, the average are higher in neighborhoods that have a public
loading is 19 households per facility). school, and the sub-division in which a unit is
In terms of neighborhood-level infrastruc- located imposes a premium or discount on the
ture, we find that drains, street lights, and rental value. Overall, as in formal real estate
paved internal roads do not affect rents system- markets, rents in Nairobi’s slums depend on
atically. This is not to suggest that such infra- or vary with a unit’s size, location, construction
structure has no value in terms of rent. quality, and access to infrastructure.
Rather, as our additional analyses suggest, this
is mostly because infrastructure facilities vary (d) Supply side issues: extraordinary returns and
more across locations than within a settlement, entry barriers?
and because of multicollinearity with the ‘‘pub-
lic school’’ variable. This means that any sys- Previous studies suggest that the business of
tematic effects of neighborhood-level being a slum landlord in Nairobi is highly prof-
infrastructure are being mostly captured by itable. In his study of landlordism in Nairobi’s
the ‘‘location’’ and ‘‘public school’’ variables. slum of Kibera, Amis (1984) estimated that
Among other ‘‘observed’’ neighborhood ‘‘[In the case of] a 10-room structure, the
characteristics, or features for which we con- [undiscounted] annual capital return was 131
trolled, schools matter—rents are higher in set- percent. Thus after only nine months the land-
tlements with a public school. This may be lord’s income is pure profit, since the mainte-
related to the fact that, in 2003, the government nance, and running costs are more or less
introduced free primary education in public non-existent.’’ In a recent rapid appraisal com-
schools; if so, landlords are benefiting from missioned by UN-HABITAT, Syagga, Mitul-
government investment in education. We find lah, and Karirah-Gitau (2002) also concluded
that residents’ perception regarding the relative that in Kibera—with an average monthly rent
safety of their neighborhood (in terms of crime) per room of Ksh 1,300—it takes only 9.75
is not correlated in any significant way to the months for an investor to recoup the Ksh
rents that they pay. 12,686 investment entailed in constructing a
Location of a slum directly influences rent. room. Other informal settlements have lower
Of the 23 location dummies, 15 are statistically rents but returns are still excellent—annual re-
significant—compared to Mathare (the ‘‘base,’’ turns range from 60% to 80% and payback
or ‘‘comparator’’ case), rents are systematically periods average 16 months.
higher in five locations and lower in the remain- We find that rents are lower than those re-
ing ten. The results strongly underscore that ported by Syagga et al. (2002). Our data show
even after controlling for several observable that rents in Kibera average about Ksh 620
characteristics of the house, infrastructure, (US$8) and they are lower than the average
and neighborhood, the location imposes a rent in the city’s slums (Ksh 790 or US$11) (Ta-
‘‘premium’’ or a ‘‘discount’’ in the home rental ble 2). If so, then the pay back period for a Ksh
markets across Nairobi’s slums. 12,686 investment for a single room would be
Finally, we find no systematic relationship 20.4 months rather than 9.75 months—still
between rent and the renter’s perception of ten- high, but not quite as high as the rapid apprai-
ure security. Nor do we find a relationship be- sal suggests. It is, therefore, worth moving be-
tween rents and the length of a household’s yond rapid appraisals and toward more
stay in their unit. The former does not suggest rigorous assessments of the costs and benefits
that tenure security has no rental value. Rather, of being a slumlord in Nairobi; our data
as in the case of neighborhood-level infrastruc- provide a crucial building block for such anal-
ture such as drainage, tenure security also var- yses.
ies more across locations than within a High returns are often indicative of high en-
settlement. The ‘‘location’’ dummies appear to try barriers. Entry into the business of being a
pick up the systematic effects of tenure security slumlord in Nairobi entails, at a minimum, con-
on rent. struction or purchase of a unit. And this,
In sum, we find a formal (but distorted) real according to existing studies (Amis, 1984; Syag-
estate market in the midst of informality. Rents ga et al., 2002), requires (i) political connec-
in Nairobi’s slums increase with number of tions; (ii) payment of significant (illegal) fees
rooms and are higher for units that have per- to get permission to build or approve a unit;
1930 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

and (iii) willingness to bear the risk of demoli- We find a somewhat larger proportion of
tion and loss of capital. What is the profile of both owner-occupiers (8% of residents), and
people who have successfully overcome such resident landlords (5% of residents). The 90 res-
barriers to own a shack? ident landlords in our sample report an average
of 5.9 rent-paying tenants (Table 5). Disaggre-
(e) Who owns the shacks? Owner-occupiers and gated by welfare, resident landlords who are
landlords poor report an average of 4.6 rent-paying ten-
ants as compared to 8.4 tenants among non-
In his study of Kibera’s landlords, Amis poor landlords. When asked to estimate the
(1984) noted that there is an informal system sale value of their home, owner-occupiers who
for allocating building rights and that it is an are poor placed the average value at Ksh
important source of political patronage for pol- 239,203 (US$3189), as compared to Ksh
iticians and the local administration (i.e., gov- 723,977 (US$9653) among the non-poor. Their
ernment employees). He also found that some own estimates can provide an alternative basis
landlords owned multiple units (e.g., four of for understanding decisions by slum investors
the largest landlords owned more than 100 regarding whether to build or not, and whether
units each), and that many of the large land- to sell or rent; they can also be used to under-
lords were from the administration. Syagga stand what kind of deal the landlords may or
et al. (2002) came to similar conclusions: much may not be willing to accept, if the government
of the squatter land in Kibera has been ac- were to come in with proposals for slum
quired or allocated by politicians and govern- upgrading. More research is required to im-
ment employees with enough influence to prove our understanding of both resident and
ensure that they are not displaced. In their sam- absentee landlords, their incentives, and what
ple of 120 landlords, 41% were government offi- it would take to have them invest in improving
cers, 16% were politicians, and 42% were other living conditions in the slums.
absentee owners. Only a handful of the struc-
tures belonged to people who lived in the slums.
This is unlike the situation in Mathare and 5. SOLVING THE HIGH-COST
Pumwani, the report notes, where a large num- LOW-QUALITY PUZZLE WITH THE
ber of investors are residents who ‘‘lived at a le- FRAMEWORK
vel fairly similar to their tenants and
demonstrated a keen interest in maintaining The above discussion suggests that Nairobi’s
the community and improving it’’ (Syagga slums are stuck in a high-cost, low-quality trap.
et al., 2002). The tenants are paying a lot for very poor qual-

Table 5. Owner-occupiers and resident landlords


All Poor Non-poor
N Percent (%) N Percent (%) N Percent (%)
Feel tenure is secure 150 62.2 105 62.3 45 61.8
Believe its easy to sell or buy property in neighborhood* 150 33.7 105 38.2 45 23.3
Aware of a property sale in vicinity in last 12 months* 150 33.9 105 38.0 45 24.1
Mean expected value of property if sold (Ksh)** 150 398,400 105 239,200 45 724,000
Type of ownership document 150 105 45
–None 36.6 37.2 35.0
–Temporary occupation license 19.2 22.7 11.0
–Freehold title 11.2 8.1 18.6
–Certificate of title (long-term lease from city 7.8 7.8 7.6
council/govt.)
–Letter from the chief (provincial administration) 4.8 6.2 1.5
–Others including share certificate 20.4 17.9 26.3
Rent out rooms (i.e., are resident landlords) 150 60.0 105 57.5 45 65.9
Mean number of rent-paying tenants 150 5.9 4.6 8.4
Note: Statistical significance of difference between poor and non-poor indicated by asterisks: *** = 1%, ** = 5%, and
* = 10%.
SLUM REAL ESTATE 1931

ity housing. Despite the large cash flow in the What are the (dis)incentives for improving the
system, and the fact that better quality units units? Tenants are not only poor but also mo-
command higher rents, landlords are not rein- bile, and these factors appear to reduce their
vesting to significantly improve the housing ability and willingness to invest in their units.
stock. It is easy to vilify the landlords and they If tenants believed that could stay longer, or if
often are—by local media, and by local and they had rights vis-à-vis their landlords, they
international experts. In our view, however, may have invested in the units even though they
the quality problem cannot be blamed on the do not own them. What about the landlords? Is-
landlords alone. Even if the landlords were, sues pertaining to the competitiveness of the
for instance, nicer, or better regulated, or sub- rental market aside, the fact that majority of
ject to somewhat more competition, this would the landlords are ‘‘absentee’’—in that they do
not, we argue, lead to large gains in quality of not live on site—means that they neither suffer
living conditions for current slum residents. from the appalling living conditions nor gain
any of the prestige associated with owning and
(a) The framework as a diagnostic and analytical living in a good-quality and well-functioning
tool home. This eliminates a major incentive for
investment in their units. For instance, if the
As the living conditions diamond visually roof was constantly leaking during the rainy
shows, the quality problem is not limited to season, a resident landlord would have a greater
the unit alone. Infrastructure services and incentive to replace it than a non-resident owner
neighborhood conditions—two of the other who neither experiences the misery it causes, nor
dimensions of the diamond—have very poor sees it, nor feels any social connection to or
quality indicators as well, and these too have pressure from the tenant to fix the problem.
not been improving over time. This stubborn There are, however, financial incentives—if
lack of improvement and consolidation in Nai- landlords invest in improving the quality of
robi’s slums stands in contrast to the experience their units they can get higher rents. Why is this
in slums of many other cities, such as Dakar incentive not working? One possible reason is
and Rio de Janeiro, where conditions have im- that investing heavily in units may attract un-
proved steadily over time. wanted attention from the authorities. Land-
We argue that the current trap is the result of lords are likely to be averse to such attention
an interaction of factors along different dimen- for fear that the government will assert its rights
sions of the living conditions diamond. Together over the land, and directly or indirectly, cut into
these factors have created severe disincentives their profitable business (e.g., by extracting
for action and investment for all three of the kick-backs, trying to regulate it, tax it, or,
key stakeholders in Nairobi’s slums—landlords, worse, declare it illegal and re-possess the land).
tenants, and government. A key piece of the Not investing in the units allows them to stay
problem, and by extension the solution, lies in ‘‘under the radar’’ or relatively invisible.
two variables associated with tenure. But it is What about incentives for improving infra-
not the usual suspects—illegal land tenure or structure or other neighborhood conditions?
distortions in the rental market. Rather, in Nai- Landlords and tenants could, for instance,
robi, the problem is that the tenure mix is highly potentially lobby government for such
unusual—there are too many tenants and too improvements. It seems, however, that the ab-
few owner-occupiers and resident landlords— sence of government in service provision has
and the duration of stay of an average resident created profitable infrastructure businesses for
is relatively short. To offer one comparison, in landlords and eroded their incentives for seek-
Dakar’s slums the proportion of tenants to own- ing improvements. Local experts suggest—and
er occupants is 29:71 as compared to 92:8 in Nai- our data and other studies support their obser-
robi. 16 Further, the average resident in Dakar’s vation—that landlords own and control not
slums has stayed in the same house for 19 years, just the housing units but also many of the yard
as compared to an average stay of five years in taps, water kiosks, in-house connections for
Nairobi’s slums. The combination of excessive electricity and water, and many of the toilet
rental in the tenure mix and a high turnover rate facilities (including ‘‘public’’ pay-per-use toi-
among slum residents has weakened the incen- lets), and all these are known to be good busi-
tives for landlords and tenants to invest in nesses. 17 If so, landlords are unlikely to want,
improving their unit, the infrastructure, and/or let alone ask, government to improve services
their neighborhood. in the slums; such interventions would directly
1932 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

reduce the scale and scope of their infrastruc- jects, the current tendency of practitioners
ture-related businesses. In other words, land- and academics is to identify a key entry
lords are strongly likely to prefer—and work point—usually, either tenure or infrastruc-
to maintain—the status quo. ture—and suggest that action on their selected
Tenants do have incentives to seek infrastruc- factor alone is sufficient to generate wider ben-
ture and neighborhood improvements but, thus efits, and improvements (De Soto, 2000; World
far, wide-spread tenant action has not material- Bank, 2002). Grappling with the Nairobi case
ized. Even though they move their home often, revealed, however, that approaches which favor
tenants tend to stay in the same settlement one entry point over others reflect a partial
longer—on average about nine years—and they understanding of slums, and, thereby, offer
are the ones who suffer most directly from the incomplete solutions: these solutions might
horrible neighborhood conditions and inade- work in certain conditions but will fail in other
quate access to infrastructure. They can poten- contexts.
tially organize to improve their neighborhood In Nairobi’s slums, neither the titling-based
in ways that do not entail heavy cash invest- approach recommended by De Soto (2000),
ment—for example, by organizing around gar- nor supports for rental housing advocated by
bage collection or community policing, and by Gilbert (2003), nor the infrastructure upgrading
using their power to vote to pressure govern- approach championed by the World Bank is
ment into improving services. Certain slum likely to work independently. Titling-based ten-
communities are indeed organizing and mobi- ure legalization is likely to confer benefits on
lizing with assistance from NGOs, but such ef- structure owners and not tenants, unless explic-
forts are yet to go to scale. itly treated as a land reform exercise. Support-
In improving infrastructure and neighbor- ing structure owners, as providers of rental
hood conditions, however, the key actor is the housing, will not work without altering the
government. Infrastructure and neighborhood structure of the market and eliminating other
amenities have public good characteristics disincentives. Investments in infrastructure are
meaning that, even in conditions highly condu- likely to translate into higher rents—as shown
cive to private investment, public investment is by the rent analysis—and, thereby, displace
required to achieve optimal levels of service. many of the current slum residents, not least
These improvements require more than tacit ap- because the majority of them fall below the
proval—public utilities and infrastructure agen- poverty line.
cies need approval to connect slum residents The government’s goal should be to break
and also need significant budget to make this the high-cost low-quality trap across Nairobi’s
happen. Unfortunately, the government has slums. Unlike previous small-scale or pilot pro-
not invested—there have been no large-scale, jects, this effort needs to be systematic and city-
let alone city-wide, government-supported pro- wide. And the government needs to act on two
grams to improve public infrastructure in the facets of the diamond—tenure and infrastruc-
slums. This is, in part, attributable to the com- ture—simultaneously. By enhancing owner
plex political economy in the slums. Given the occupancy in the tenure mix and simulta-
high proportion of tenants and the politically neously upgrading infrastructure, the govern-
well-connected landlords, it is hard to design ment can create a basis for private
win–win solutions and any intervention carries investments in units and facilitate neighbor-
a high risk of serious opposition from potential hood-level improvements. In fact, the new
losers; this creates a major disincentive for gov- infrastructure could be explicitly designed to
ernment to act. In sum, the rare tenure mix, create additional neighborhood-level bene-
combined with the lack of investment and effort fits—for example, while paving paths and
by all three of the main stakeholders that is, the building drains, the settlement layout can be al-
government, landlords, and tenants, has to- tered to facilitate access by fire trucks. In other
gether resulted in the appalling conditions in words, the dual-entry approach, if well de-
the slums. So, what should be done? signed, can catalyze improvements on all four
fronts—it can set in motion a longer-term pro-
(b) Using the framework to propose an cess of consolidation of the housing stock and
alternative solution neighborhoods. Using these principles, several
design options are possible.
In contrast to the comprehensive thinking The government could, for instance, offer a
that characterized early slum upgrading pro- slum development package that combines
SLUM REAL ESTATE 1933

infrastructure investment with legitimization of 6. CONCLUSIONS, AND IMPLICATIONS


tenure. Residents would select infrastructure FOR THEORY, AND PRACTICE
investments based on their priorities and neigh-
borhood conditions, subject to a budget con- In summary, this study finds that the vast
straint. Government would legally recognize majority (92%) of Nairobi’s slum residents do
tenure and transfer title to individuals and/or not own their homes. They are tenants, and
the community (as in the Voi case). This offer they are crammed—2.6 persons per room—in
would be open to all slums, but would initially poor-quality housing structures built with
be implemented only in those settlements where impermanent materials. Their access to basic
tenants and landlords reach agreement on a infrastructure is appalling. For instance, only
formula for sharing the costs and benefits of 22% of slum households have an electricity con-
these changes—including the terms under nection and barely 19% have access to a supply
which landlords agree to divest some of their of piped water, in the form of either an in-
units to current tenants. house water connection or a yard tap.
An example of such a ‘‘deal’’ is the one bro- Rents in the slums are significant, despite the
kered by Pamoja Trust, an NGO, in Nairobi’s informal tenure status, the poor quality of
Huruma settlement. This agreement—between housing, and inadequate infrastructure. In
landlords, tenants, and Nairobi City Coun- 2004, slum households paid ‘‘structure owners’’
cil—required landlords to give up control over an average rent of about US$11 per month, a
some of their units in exchange for a formal ti- sum that amounts to an extraordinary US$31
tle and investment in improving the retained million for the year. Unfortunately, this large
units (Personal interview with Jane Weru, cash flow does not translate into investments
Director, Pamoja Trust, September 20, 2006; that improve the quality of living conditions
also see Baliga, 2005). For instance, a landlord for the residents, nor does any fraction of it ac-
with 12 units agreed to retain three and give up crue formally to the official land owner, that is,
the remaining nine, which were then legally the government. This informal rental market,
transferred to the tenants. Subsequently, the albeit distorted, appears to follow many of the
NGO also facilitated construction of new/im- rules that apply in ‘‘formal’’ real estate mar-
proved units for the 70 participating house- kets—rents vary with house size, quality, infra-
holds, using a combination of grant funds and structure access, and location.
residents’ savings. In our view, a key advantage Although previous studies of Nairobi’s slums
of this solution is that it results in a better mix have documented some of the above features,
of owner-occupiers, tenants, and landlords on researchers and practitioners have struggled
the site; it is a small-scale land reform project. with their interpretation of the findings. All
Overall, we now know that the value of main- seem to agree that the situation in Nairobi’s
taining status quo is a flow of at least US$31 slums is bad, but there are major disagree-
million per year to landlords and those they ments, for example, on whether the rents are
need to unofficially pay—none of this translates too high and need to be regulated, whether
either into improved living conditions for ten- the landlords are villains or not, and whether
ants, or into official revenues or taxes for gov- this rental housing market is helping or hurting
ernment. The government, as the official land the poor. Not surprisingly, then, there is no
owner in majority of the city’s slums (Syagga agreement on what to do about the ‘‘terrible
et al., 2002), can convene a meeting with the living conditions’’ in these slums. From an aca-
two other stakeholders (the structure owners demic perspective, many researchers have
and the tenants) to decide whether and how this acknowledged that Nairobi does not fit well
pie can be carved up in a fairer manner. Theo- with their broader conceptual framework and
retically, if it were rich and generous, the gov- argument, but have left the case hanging as
ernment could also offer to just buy out the an outlier or unresolved puzzle.
landlords with an appropriate compensation We argue that Nairobi’s slums should not be
package. Yet another alternative would be for dismissed as an outlier or unique case. First, we
the government to try and mandate a solution, speculate that Nairobi is probably not entirely
but the complex political economy may not al- unique—there are possibly many other cities
low for such an approach to work. On our part, in which sub-standard slum accommodation
we favor a negotiation between the three stake- comes at a high-price, and yet others that have
holders, with the government using a combina- slums with a high proportion of renters (Mum-
tion of carrots and sticks to reach a solution. bai may be an example of both). Identification
1934 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

and analyses of such cases and rental markets In Nairobi, the standard prescription of in situ
are important areas for future research. Sec- upgrading of infrastructure will not work.
ond, the Nairobi case and other alleged outliers Usual approaches to legalizing tenure or sup-
should not be dismissed precisely because they porting rental markets are likely to benefit
bring into question the very core of our current structure owners rather than tenants. Using
understanding of slums. As difficult cases, they the living conditions diamond, we argue that
force us to revise or expand the conceptual instead of choosing either infrastructure or ten-
frameworks that we use to analyze and under- ure as a single entry point, the government
stand slums. We offer the living conditions dia- needs to act on both simultaneously. The gov-
mond as an analytical framework, and a step ernment can deploy infrastructure investment-
toward a more complete theory of the dynamics cum-tenure legitimization as incentives, and
of living conditions in settlements. This frame- use them explicitly to enhance owner occu-
work allows us to understand, for example, pancy in slums. The government’s goal should
why Nairobi is a difficult but not counter-intu- be to break the low-quality high-cost trap in
itive case, and how its ‘‘slums of despair’’ might slum housing, and one way to get there is to
be converted into ‘‘slums of hope.’’ bring both structure owners and tenants to
What are the implications of this study for the table, and negotiate a deal.
improving living conditions in Nairobi’s slums?

NOTES

1. For an excellent large-sample study of population 7. For a more detailed theoretical discussion of the
and health in Nairobi’s slums, see APHRC (2002). For a framework, see Gulyani and Bassett (2008).
profile of Nairobi, see UN-HABITAT (2006).
8. Although it acknowledges that slums are diverse,
UN-HABITAT (2003) argued for a quantitative, oper-
2. Results are reported in a series of papers, including
ational, and common definition of slums. It defines
World Bank (2002, 2004, 2006), Gulyani and Talukdar
‘‘slum as an area that combines, to various extents, . . .:
(2007), and Gulyani and Bassett (2007).
(i) inadequate access to safe water; (ii) inadequate access
to sanitation and other infrastructure; (iii) poor struc-
3. Some studies estimate that slum residents account tural quality of housing; (iv) overcrowding; and (v)
for 55% of Nairobi’s population (e.g., Matrix Consul- insecure residential status;’’ it also proposes thresholds
tants/USAID 1993 cited in Alder, 1995). Possible for each (Table 1.2, p. 12).
explanations for the divergence include (i) use of
different boundaries for Nairobi—some focus on the 9. The wider land market in the city is not working
metropolitan area and include slums abutting the city’s well. For discussions on the complexity and constraints
boundaries, while CBS excludes slums outside the in the land market, see, for example, Government of
administrative boundary, and (ii) CBS may have under- Kenya (2007), Southall (2005), and Klopp (2000).
estimated the number of EAs that are slums—it may
have mis-categorized some of the EAs either accidentally 10. Our definition of neighborhood ‘‘conditions’’ is
or by using too narrow a definition (also see Section 3). broader than safety; it also includes amenities (such as
Additional research is required to resolve this issue. parks, open spaces, community halls, schools), housing
density, and settlement layout and access (e.g., whether
4. During 1989–99, Nairobi’s annual population fire engines, and ambulances can enter). Further, ‘‘loca-
growth rate was 4.85%; we use this rate to estimate that tion’’ refers not only to the relative access that a
the slum population grew to 810,000 by 2004. neighborhood provides to jobs, schools, and markets,
but also the environmental acceptability or precarious-
5. Adult equivalents are calculated as follows: children ness of its physical site.
of age 0–4 are 0.24 adult equivalents, children of age 5–
14 are 0.65, and individuals of age 15 or more are 1.0 (or 11. During our research (2003–07), we have benefited
‘‘adult’’) (see World Bank, 2006 for details). from discussions with numerous Kenyan experts, includ-
ing James Mutero (consultant), Peter N’gau (Nairobi
6. For information on Government of Kenya’s poverty University), Paul Syagga (Kenya Planning Association),
line, see World Bank (2003). We used the Consumer Jane Weru (Pamoja Trust), Julius Malombe (Ministry of
Price Index to adjust the 1997 poverty line for inflation. Housing), and Mukami Kariuki (World Bank).
SLUM REAL ESTATE 1935

12. Gilbert (2003, p. 239) himself admitted that Nai- though still unauthorized, is in extremely dense multi-
robi is a challenge: ‘‘Renting in Nairobi currently storey rooming districts. However, rents for single room
represents a worst case scenario, in terms of living . . . with shared toilets . . . are at least three times those
conditions offered to tenants; it is a classic example of for slums.’’ Huchzermeyer reports rents for wattle, and
what rental housing should not be like. It should be daub units at Ksh 400–500, and for a single room in a
noted, however, that these rental units provide affordable Huruma multi-storey at Ksh 1,800–2,000.
housing to a considerable share of the labor force’’
[emphasis added]. 15. Nairobi city’s budget for 2006–07 was estimated at
Ksh 5.44 billion, with Ksh 1.83 billion for investment,
13. Amis (1984) found that rents accounted for 14% of operations, and maintenance, and the rest for salaries
income, constituted a major burden for most slum and allowances (The Daily Nation, October 25, 2006).
residents, and were squeezing other basic expenditures,
including food. He denounced the assumption that an 16. Data drawn from a parallel survey of 1960 house-
expenditure of 20% of income is affordable, noting that holds in Dakar’s slums (see World Bank, 2004).
‘‘to suggest that such individuals are not paying
enoughon housing, as are the international agencies, is 17. Among slum residents with electricity, just over
little short of criminal.’’ half (53.8%) pay their landlord for it, and not the utility
(World Bank, 2006). Landlords also serve as intermedi-
14. According to Huchzermeyer (2006) ‘‘Within the aries between the water utility and users; they collect
current housing market in Kenyan cities, an affordable payments from users and decide what price to charge
housing alternative to wattle and daub slum rooming (Water & Sanitation Program, 2007).
does not exist. . . . The next best accommodation . . .

REFERENCES

Alder, G. (1995). Tackling poverty in Nairobi’s informal De Soto, H. (2000). The mystery of capital: Why
settlements: Developing an institutional strategy. capitalism triumphs in the West and fails everywhere
Environment and Urbanization, 7(2), 85–107. else. New York: Basic Books.
Amis, P. (1984). Squatters or tenants: The commercial- Gilbert, A. (2003). Rental housing: An essential option for
ization of unauthorized housing in Nairobi. World the urban poor in developing countries. Nairobi: UN-
Development, 12(1), 87–96. HABITAT.
APHRC (African Population and Health Research Gilbert, A., Mabin, A., McCarthy, M., & Watson, V.
Center), (2002). Population and health dynamics is (1997). Low-income rental housing: Are South Afri-
Nairobi’s informal settlements: Report of the Nairobi can cities different? Environment and Urbanization,
cross-sectional slum survey 2000. Nairobi: APHRC. 9(1), 133–148.
Baliga, N. (2005). Community-based upgrading and Government of Kenya. (2003). Economic recovery strat-
tenure regularization: Insights from Nairobi, Kenya. egy for wealth and employment creation. Ministry of
Unpublished masters thesis. Urban Planning, Planning and National Development.
Columbia University. Government of Kenya. (2007). National land policy.
Bassett, E. M. (2007). The persistence of the commons: Kenya Ministry of Lands. May.
Upgrading and tenure decision-making in Voi, Gulyani, S., & Bassett, E. (2008). The living conditions
Kenya. African Studies Quarterly, 9(3). diamond: A framework for assessing quality. Working
CBS (Central Bureau of Statistics). (2003). Geographic Paper. AFTU1. Washington, DC: The World Bank.
dimensions of well-being in Kenya: Where are the Gulyani, S., & Talukdar, D. (2007). Inside informality:
poor? CBS, Ministry of Planning and National Poverty, micro-enterprises and living conditions in
Development. Nairobi: Regal Press Kenya. Nairobi’s slums. Working Paper. AFTU1. Washing-
‘‘Census 1999.’’ (2002). The 1999 population and housing ton, DC: The World Bank.
census: Popular report. Nairobi: CBS. Gulyani, S., & Bassett, E. (2007). Retrieving the baby
Collignon, B., & Vézina, M. (2000). Independent water from the bathwater: Slum upgrading in Sub-Saharan
and sanitation providers in African cities: Full report Africa. Environment and Planning C: Government and
of a ten-country study. Washington DC: The World Policy, 25, 486–515.
Bank. Gulyani, S., Talukdar, D., & Kariuki, R. M. (2005).
Daily Nation (The). 25 October, 2006. Preparation of Universal (non)service? Water markets, household
LASDAP: Local authority revenue and resource demand and the poor in urban Kenya. Urban
envelope. Public notice issued by Town Clerk, City Studies, 42(8), July.
Council of Nairobi. Hansen, K. (1997). Keeping house in Lusaka. New York:
Datta, K. (1995). Strategies for urban survival? Women Columbia University Press.
landlords in Gaborone, Botswana. Habitat Interna- Huchzermeyer, M. (2006). Slum upgrading initiatives in
tional, 19(1), 1–12. Kenya within the basic services and wider housing
1936 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

market: A housing rights concern. In Paper presented Turner, J. (1972). Housing as a verb. In J. F. C. Turner,
at ISA conference, Durban, South Africa, July. & R. Fichter (Eds.), Freedom to build (pp. 148–175).
Klopp, J. (2000). Pilfering the public: The problem of New York: Macmillan.
land grabbing in contemporary Kenya. Africa Today, UN-HABITAT. (2003). The challenge of slums, Global
47(1), 7–26. report on human settlements 2003. Nairobi: WSP.
Kumar, S. (1996). Landlordism in third world urban UN-HABITAT. (2006). Profile of Nairobi, Kenya, rapid
low-income settlements: A case for further research. urban sector profiling for sustainability DVD. Nai-
Urban Studies, 33(4–5), 753–782, May. robi: UN-HABITAT.
Miraftab, F. (1997). Revisiting informal-sector home Water and Sanitation Program. (2007). Citizen’s report
ownership: The relevance of household composition card on urban water, sanitation and solid waste
for housing options of the poor. International Journal services in Kenya: Summary of results from Nairobi.
of Urban and Regional Research, 21(2), June. Nairobi: WSP.
O’Connor, A. (1983). The African city. London: Hutch- World Bank. (2002). Slum upgrading in Africa: Ten
inson. country assessment reports. Africa Upgrading Team
Razzaz, O. (1993). Examining property rights and (Gulyani, S., Farvacque-Vitkovic, C., Debomy, S.,
investment in informal settlements: The case of Connors, G., Casalis, A., Carroll, A., Banes, C.).
Jordan. Land Economics, 69, 341–355. Working Papers. Africa Urban and Water. Wash-
Salon, D., & Gulyani, S. (2008). Travel ‘‘choices’’ of ington, DC: The World Bank.
slum residents in Nairobi, Kenya. In Paper presented World Bank. (2003). Kenya: A policy agenda to restore
at transport research board meetings, Washington DC, growth. Report No. 25840-KE. Washington DC: The
January. World Bank.
Southall, R. (2005). The Ndungu report: Land and graft World Bank, (2004). Upgrading of low-income settle-
in Kenya. Review of African Political Economy, ments in Africa. Consultants’ report, TF No. 024943,
32(103), 142–151, March. Africa Urban and Water. Washington, DC: The
Syagga, P., Mitullah, W., & Karirah-Gitau, S. (2002). A World Bank.
rapid economic appraisal of rents in slums and World Bank. (2006). Kenya: Inside informality: Poverty,
informal settlements. Prepared for Government of jobs, housing and services in Nairobi’s slums. Report
Kenya and UN-HABITAT Collaborative Nairobi No. 36347-KE. Washington DC: The World Bank.
Slum Upgrading Initiative.
Thompson, J., Porras, I. T., Wood, E., Tumwine, J. K.,
Mujwahuzi, M. R., Katui-Katua, M., et al. (2000).
Waiting at the tap: Changes in urban water use in
East Africa over three decades. Environment & APPENDIX
Urbanization, 12(2), 37–52, October.
See Figure 5 and Table 6.

Figure 5. Nairobi City depicting the sampled slum neighborhoods. Source: Salon and Gulyani (2008).
Table 6. Demographics, household size, and composition
All Poor Non-poor
N Percent of total (%) N Percent of total (%) N Percent of total (%)
Households 1755 1282 473

SLUM REAL ESTATE


Household size 2.97 3.38 1.88
Single-person households 560 31.9 261 20.4 299 63.2
Female-headed households 310 17.7 244 19.0 66 14.0
Mean age of household head (yrs) 34.8 34.8 34.6
Median age:household head (yrs) 32.0 32.0 32.0
Total number of individuals 5256 100.0 4345 100.0 911 100.0
Gender ratio, male:female 2899:2357 55:45 2320:2025 53:47 579:332 64:36

Available online at www.sciencedirect.com

1937

You might also like