You are on page 1of 10

European Environment

Eur. Env. 10, 75 – 84 (2000)

IS LOCAL TRULY BETTER?


SOME REFLECTIONS ON
SHARING ENVIRONMENTAL
POLICY BETWEEN LOCAL
GOVERNMENTS AND THE EU
Brendan Flynn*

Department of Political Science and Sociology, National University of Ireland,


Galway, Ireland

This paper discusses the appropriate role democratic, as well as including


for local governments in relation to EU indicative responsibilities for local
environmental policy. The discussion is governments in future framework
framed through a critical examination of directives. Copyright © 2000 John Wiley
the principle of subsidiarity. Firstly due & Sons, Ltd and ERP Environment.
to the way the member states have
defined the principle there is a danger of
ARGUMENT AND STRUCTURE
inconsistency in its application. Secondly,
across Europe there is mixed evidence to

T
he subsidiarity principle is now some
suggest local governments cope well seven years old since it was ratified in
with having to do more in the Maastricht Treaty’s article 3b. Ar-
environmental policy. Indeed a sensible guably however, the principle remains con-
balance between the local, regional, fusing in its application and significance for
national and EU level seems at risk of EU environmental policy (Axlerod, 1994; Butt-
being undermined if subsidiarity is taken Philip, 1994, p 127–129). At its simplest article
too far. This paper argues that more 3b ensures that in the exercise of non-exclu-
appropriate roles for local governments sive competences the European institutions
might be to contribute to policy ought to defer to national leadership, unless it
can be clearly shown that EU level action
innovation and better implementation. would be better. Yet in practice this formula-
What seems more needed is an approach tion may be hard to make workable. One
that systematically improves issue in particular that remains comparatively
intergovernmental relationships in unexplored is the extent to which the princi-
environmental policy across Europe. ple might justify a greater environmental pol-
Specific reforms suggested include icy role at the local level.
expanding Commission led networking This issue is discussed here in a number of
while making it more accountable and sections. Firstly it is argued one must note
that the nation states in the Council, together
* Correspondence to: Brendan Flynn, Department of Political with the Commission, have applied the prin-
Science and Sociology, National University of Ireland, Galway, ciple in a highly selective way. While some
Ireland. Tel.: +353 91 512054; fax: + 353 91 525700; e-mail: states appear happy to allow local and re-
brendan.flynn@nuigalway.ie
gional governments considerable autonomy in
Copyright © 2000 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd and ERP Environment. environmental policy, others enforce minimal
B. FLYNN

competences at the local level. In any event for local governments in framework direc-
article 3b seems powerless to impel national tives. Both approaches would address some of
governments to provide a greater role for the limitations that the local level often suffers
local governments. The result is a problem of from, and more importantly add substance to
uneven application of subsidiarity towards all the subsidiarity principle for local
European citizens. governments.
In a second section a quite different ap- To conclude, what seems needed in the
proach is taken. Here some of the empirical coming decade are approaches that situate the
literature on local governments and environ- subsidiarity principle as part of a much wider
mental policy is explored to assess their per- constitutional and administrative debate on
formance. In other words, the question is improving and democratizing intergovern-
asked: would it be a good thing if local gov- mental relationships.
ernments could do more in environmental
policy? In fact a quite mixed performance is
revealed. This is because European local gov- SUBSIDIARITY’S HOLLOW
ernments frequently lack resources (fiscal, PROMISE?
personnel and technical expertise) to success-
fully carry out increased environmental du- While some commentators suggested the in-
ties. Other problems include a risk of troduction of subsidiarity might empower lo-
regulatory capture at the local level, and the cal and regional governments (Balducci, 1996,
need for local bodies to liase with central p 50; Eberlein, 1996; Lerche and Preußer,
government agents to address environmental 1997), the actual application of the principle
spillovers. Thus any argument that local gov- has offered local governments little substan-
ernment ought to have a greater role in envi- tive support in their environmental policy du-
ronmental policy is one that requires ties. This is perhaps strange given the
considerable caution. A simple case for sub- considerable impetus created by the Local
sidiarity for the local level cannot be made Agenda 21 initiative, whereby local govern-
without qualification. ment actors in many states have developed a
On the positive side however, it is stressed distinctively local response to environmental
that local governments can provide valuable issues (Patterson and Theobald, 1995; Little-
proving grounds for policy innovation, and wood and While, 1997; Meadowcroft, 1999).
they often have expert local knowledge that Yet a conservative attitude to subsidiarity
with care can be harnessed to improve imple- for the local level in the EU context can be
mentation. In some cases local governments seen in the Commission’s official rejection of
may also be more responsive to distinctive the application of article 3b sub-nationally. In
local environmental problems and needs. This 1994, Bruce Milan, responding to a series of
suggests that it is a co-ordinated contribution European Parliament questions (OJ 94/C102/
of the local level to any environmental policy 08, 1994a, pp 3–4; OJ 94/C336/36, 1994b, p 17),
that is valuable. Yet this poses the question set out quite clearly the limitations of sub-
then of how to ensure such a co-ordination sidiarity to local governments:
between different levels of governance in
terms of their roles, duties and competences. The application of subsidiarity to the rela-
In a final section this complex question is tions between member states and regional
partly answered by suggesting two possible or local authorities is a matter of institu-
reforms. The first is a system of co-operative tional organization within each member
networking between the Commission, na- state and falls within the competence of
tional and local governments, which might each member state. Nevertheless, the
offer one way to improve implementation and Commission is convinced that regional
ensure that local interests are respected in EU and local authority involvement in the
environmental policy. The second suggestion project of European construction is essen-
is the inclusion of indicative responsibilities tial (OJ 94/C336/36, 1994b, p 17).

Copyright © 2000 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd and ERP Environment Eur. Env. 10, 75 – 84 (2000)

76
IS LOCAL TRULY BETTER?

Arguably the significance of this approach DEBUNKING SUBSIDIARITY LOCAL


has been somewhat ignored, for it strongly BIAS: IS THE LOCAL TRULY BETTER
suggests that the main actors interpreting and IN ENVIRONMENTAL
applying the principle, the Council and Com- GOVERNANCE?
mission, have no conception of the article as
an operating legal doctrine which local mu- In this section, some of the literature on envi-
nicipalities can rely upon to defend their ronmental policy and local governments is
competences. examined. This is in order to be clear whether
Indeed this basic ‘minimalist’ approach has in fact local governments deserve a greater
been re-confirmed with the Amsterdam role in environmental policy. In fact a number
Treaty (Duff, 1997, pp 96–106), which does of problems are evident, which suggests cau-
not alter article 3b. Instead it merely adds as tion in answering this question positively.
an attached protocol, the details agreed at the These can be analysed in turn as problems of
Edinburgh summit of 1992 on how subsidiar- implementation, regulatory resources, regula-
ity would be applied (see CEC, 1992, p 116; tory capture and the existence of pollution
1993, pp 119 – 120). Significantly though, Ger- spillovers.
many, Belgium and Austria have seen fit to
add their own protocol related to subsidiarity. The problem of implementation at the
This indicates that they will apply the princi- local level
ple sub-nationally:
It is often at the local and regional level that
It is taken for granted by the German, environmental laws become ineffective
Austrian and Belgian governments that through poor implementation. Indeed
action by the European Community in Demmke (1997, p 43) has suggested that with
accordance with the principle of subsidiar- the European decentralization and regional-
ity not only concerns the Member States ization trends of the 1970s and 1980s, this
but also their entities to the extent that problem may well have become worse. There
is no doubt that decentralization in states
they have their own law-making powers
such as Belgium, but also in Italy, Germany,
conferred on them under national consti-
Austria and Spain (Demmke, 1997, p 45),
tutional law (Duff, 1997, p 99). has exacerbated implementation problems.
France, Greece and Italy are also suggested to
Confusingly then, it now seems that we are suffer from excessive local government frag-
faced with a future that will see an uneven mentation, with many small units overbur-
application of subsidiarity across the Eu- dened in carrying out environmental duties
ropean Union. In federal or decentralized (Demmke, 1997, p 60). In the UK, in relation
states the principle may well be followed in to waste policy, one source suggests about
the implementation of EU environment mea- 40% of local authorities are experiencing a
sures. Yet in centralized unitary states it serious implementation gap with 70% claim-
would appear unclear whether local authori- ing to suffer some local implementation fail-
ties will be similarly respected. Moreover, for ure (Read, 1999).
local governments it appears there is little
tangible legal, political or policy result that
they can clearly point to as an example of The problem of resources at the local level
subsidiarity. It is tempting then to conclude Related to this often poor record of imple-
that subsidiarity in the European context of- mentation is the issue of the regulatory re-
fers a relatively hollow promise to European sources (in the form of field staff, expertise
local governments, even though theoretically and finance) available to local governments.
the principle favours the local, as well as For example in Spain a lack of expertise and
regional and national levels. finance has been cited as a specific problem

Copyright © 2000 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd and ERP Environment Eur. Env. 10, 75 – 84 (2000)

77
B. FLYNN

for local authorities (Morata and Font, 1998, p ment departments through administrative
221). Demmke suggests in fact that this expe- merger (Lundqvist, 1998, p 243).
rience may be endemic (1997, p 55). In other Another way of seeing this problem is with
cases administrative structures can limit the regard to the issue of regulatory capture
scope of local environmental activities. For (Martimort, 1999). For example, in Danish en-
example Italy’s system of having environmen- vironmental policy, which has taken an ex-
tal functions vested in municipal public health plicit decentralist orientation since the 1970s
agencies means that more pressing responsi- (Andersen et al., 1998, pp 52–54), control and
bilities for public health and services domi- inspection duties previously delegated to mu-
nate over a wider view of environmental nicipalities have in several cases been re-
problems (Lewanski, 1998, p 143). turned to the county level for fear that
The case of local governments in Sweden is municipalities might be ‘captured’ by specific
particularly instructive here. Since the early industries (Christiansen, 1996, p 54). This has
1980s there has been a conscious effort to to be a real fear.
decentralize environmental policy (Lundqvist, Simply put, the closer agencies responsible
1996, pp 277 – 280). Yet this dramatic decen- for inspection duties are to their target
tralization has not actually been matched by groups, the greater the scope for ‘regulatory
new improved fiscal resources (Lundqvist, capture’. Arguably this danger is actually
1998, p 242). Therefore Swedish municipalities greater at the local level (Demmke, 1997, p
often find themselves overburdened with ad- 64). In fact several studies of regulatory cap-
ministrative work (Lundqvist, 1998, p 242). ture have confirmed that frequency of contact
In practice it is difficult not to see in the with regulated firms and limited expert infor-
Swedish experiences, and developments in mation, which local regulators typically have,
the USA (Weber, 1998, pp 54–55), the decen- can both exacerbate this problem (Dion et al.,
tralization of fiscal austerity by central author- 1998; Martimort, 1999). At least with a na-
ities as much as anything else. In many cases tional environmental inspectorate agency
then, central governments frequently expect there is some hope of ‘distance’ and expertise
local administrations to do more on the envi- (Demmke, 1997, p 56). In contrast local repre-
ronment, but provide no greater support for sentatives who oversee local executive agen-
them (Read, 1999; Jansen and Mydske, 1998, cies may well come under intense pressure to
pp 193 – 194). Anyone thus invoking sub- ensure a local plant is not economically disad-
sidiarity would need to be careful lest their vantaged through inspections. Moreover, with
demands are not repackaged as fiscal cut- the added tendency of modern firms to fre-
backs in another guise. quently cluster together in small regions or
even locales (Licht and Nerlinger, 1998;
Sweeney and Feser, 1998), political pressure
The problem of regulatory capture at the
may be more pronounced. There are also ob-
local level
vious questions about relying on local govern-
Of course one other reason why implementa- ments to be the ‘eyes and ears’ of enforcement
tion problems arise locally is because local and implementation when it can be these very
elites, no less than national ones, appear agents themselves who often pollute local wa-
adept in certain cases at re-steering centrally ters and air through poor sewage infrastruc-
set environmental policy goals towards out- ture or waste practices.
comes they prefer (Burby and Strong, 1997;
Deyle and Smith, 1998; Groenendijk, 1998).
The problem of spillovers and scale for
Neither do local political preferences always
local governments
prioritize the environment when faced with
limited finances. In Sweden for example, since Across Europe there appears a growing trend
1991 about half of all Swedish municipalities towards local governments co-operating with
have decreased funding for environmental each other, pooling together resources in novel
protection and downgraded their environ- and ad hoc inter-municipal organizations,

Copyright © 2000 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd and ERP Environment Eur. Env. 10, 75 – 84 (2000)

78
IS LOCAL TRULY BETTER?

and even handing over power to regional or One interesting starting point for this dis-
intermediate levels of governance (Forbes, cussion is to note that many authorities do not
1993; Morata and Font, 1998, p 221; Scott et al., actually prescribe greater autonomy for local
1998). governments in environmental policy, or even
One reason why this happens is the nature subsidiarity more generally. Instead they
of the complex environmental problems they endorse the need for more efficient and
face. Many of these problems exhibit a democratic patterns of intergovernmental co-
‘spillover’ pattern whereby environmental ex- operation between the different tiers of envi-
ternalities fall outside the jurisdiction in ronmental governance (Birnesser et al., 1993;
which they are generated. This can lead to Stoker, 1995; Guy and Marvin, 1996; Cimitile
problems whereby some local jurisdictions at- et al., 1997; McEvoy et al., 1998). Indeed some
tempt to export their pollution problems and authors are relatively cautious about the sub-
they may as a result raise environmental stan- sidiarity principle in environmental policy per
dards locally to push pollution beyond their se, or the scope for local environmental policy
boundaries (Glazer, 1999). Of course central- generally unless a wider pattern of central–
ization of policy can prevent this. More sim- local relations is first extensively reformed
ply, centralization may be also attractive in (Wise and O’Leary, 1997; Groenendijk, 1998;
terms of economies of scale and scope, as Rocher and Rouillard, 1998).
local municipalities can no longer cope with This section places the issue of subsidiarity
certain environmental issues themselves. and local governments’ roles in EU environ-
One might cautiously note, however, that mental policy into a broader discussion about
the mere existence of some pollution spillover intergovernmental relations and ‘collaborative
does not in itself justify a centralization of government’. In recent years an extensive lit-
policy. It is rather if spillovers are of an ap- erature has developed that stresses the im-
preciable scale and if bilateral action between portance of negotiation, competition and
local agents cannot first address the problem collaboration between different levels of gov-
(Smith, 1993, p 71). By itself then the trans- ernance (Kamieniecki and Ferrall, 1991;
boundary spillover argument does not actu- Scholz, 1991; Freeman, 1997; Wise and
ally suggest local governments are unable to O’Leary, 1997; Davis, 1998; Graham and
meet most environmental problems within Phillips, 1998; Blom-Hansen, 1999). Arguably
their resources. Indeed, while the most seri- this approach marks an important shift away
ous types of spillover might be better ad- from much of the subsidiarity debate hereto-
dressed at a central government level, more fore in that it emphasizes the way in which
generally it appears that what is needed is a different tiers of governance interact to im-
pattern of highly co-ordinated intergovern- prove policy, rather than whether any one
mental relations between local, regional, na- should enjoy particular legislative pre-
tional and EU levels to address such dominance.
problems. Such a co-operative approach seems
needed, for while one can think of many
European municipalities that have introduced
innovative local environmental policies, these
TOWARDS A REALISTIC ROLE FOR efforts would seem limited unless co-
LOCAL ENVIRONMENTAL ordinated. For example sustainable urban
GOVERNANCE? transport can be addressed extensively at the
local level, but very quickly local govern-
In this section, the positive role local govern- ments will find themselves facing single mar-
ments can play in EU environmental policy is ket issues of vehicle and fuel taxes, road
discussed. The question posed here is: what pricing or the even more basic issue of vehicle
specific roles can be argued for local govern- emission harmonization. It is useful to briefly
ments in EU environmental policy in a way discuss two examples of the valuable role
that respects subsidiarity? local governments can play in this regard.

Copyright © 2000 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd and ERP Environment Eur. Env. 10, 75 – 84 (2000)

79
B. FLYNN

Local governments as environmental policy sponsiveness of any local government may


innovators then be conditional on their relationship
with central state actors. The literature on
In the case above, it was noteworthy the
the so-called ‘joint-decision trap’ (Scharpf,
Brussels actors do actually need evidence
1988; Blom-Hansen, 1999) has pointed to
from the local ‘pacesetters’ if they are ever
how, in complex states, conflicting interests,
to know whether sustainable transport tax
along with shared competences between dif-
instruments work. Often the local level will
ferent levels of government, can lead to
be an ideal test bed for policy design and
stalemate and a lack of clarity in policy.
innovation. Concepts and instruments, if
Once again it appears that in order to avoid
proven, can later be lifted upwards for EU-
this problem one needs to return to an ex-
wide acceptance. Indeed there is evidence
amination of the pattern of intergovernmen-
that nationally based policy entrepreneurs
tal relations overall, with the suggestion in
often scour the local level for proof of their
particular that the existence of alternative
reform proposals and for novel policy ideas
decision ‘exit points’ may encourage co-op-
(Mintrom, 1997). On the other hand if the
erative rather than conflictual behaviour
pattern of central–local relations is overly
(Blom-Hansen, 1999). Intriguingly then a vi-
dominated by certain interest groups and
tal role for intergovernmental relationships
limited by excessive fiscal centralism then
is re-confirmed here.
the scope for innovation at the local level
can be limited (Groenendijk, 1998). Of
course innovation has also emerged in envi- Reform suggestion 1: democratizing
ronmental policy at the local level, quite in- Commission–local networking
dependent of central state fiscal reforms,
In recent years EU environmental policy has
chief of which has been the Local Agenda
actually developed a more flexible and co-
21 process (Patterson and Theobald, 1995),
operative approach to environmental policy
in this case suggesting the local level has a
as described above. There is greater respect
relatively robust residual capacity for inno-
for the fact that local governments no less
vation.
than national ones need to be listened to,
either because they have examples of inno-
vation to share or because they have distinc-
Local governments as responsive
tive knowledge and problems. One other
environmental regulators
reason is simply because local governments
One obvious advantage of local governments have moved to Brussels to engage in direct
is that they often add value to policy where lobbying and negotiation with the Commis-
they have special local information that re- sion (Marks et al., 1996, p 40). In addition,
duces implementation costs or the marginal new institutional ventures such as the re-
costs of pollution abatement generally. This cently strengthened European Green Forum
is because they can fine-tune policy to on the Environment or the proposed expert
match local preferences and problems (van European freshwater monitoring network
den Bergh, 1996, p 370) and in that regard (EUROP, No. 2, 1997) are important im-
there is a case for also arguing they are of- provements in preventing Brussels from be-
ten highly responsive to local citizens (Bre- coming a remote technocracy in this regard.
ton et al., 1998). More intriguingly, networking between
However, it is important not to overstate the Commission and local city municipalities
this argument, for national actors often have on environment policy and related issues
important incentives as well to respond to has been extensively documented (Ward and
local citizens’ needs, as the costs of electoral Williams, 1997; Perkmann, 1999). Of course
defeat for them may be higher and their such links pose risks if they are not properly
ability to provide public goods may be organized, as opaque networks may bypass
greater (Breton et al., 1998, p 48). The re- local voters and national governments

Copyright © 2000 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd and ERP Environment Eur. Env. 10, 75 – 84 (2000)

80
IS LOCAL TRULY BETTER?

through irregular channels of communication Reform suggestion 2: framework directives


and dialogue (Hay, 1995). In fact then a more that enumerate local responsibilities
realistic and useful subsidiarity debate might Several member states spell out specific envi-
be focused on how such networking does not ronmental policy duties for each level of their
end up merely empowering local elites or state, through enumerated powers based on a
controlling local authorities even further. Too blend of common sense, custom, obvious
frequently Commission sponsored networks scale effects and local preferences (Sorenson,
do not go far enough in ensuring accountabil- 1992; Føllesdal, 1998, p 191). This makes pol-
ity and transparency, or are too ad hoc and icy clearer and reduces the scope for turf
involve interest and issue groups in pref- wars. The Austrian constitution for example
erence to formally elected government au- attempts this with regard to environmental
thorities (Jacobs, 1997; Heritier, 1999). policy where it distinguishes between various
Alternatively such EU networking can merely duties for the national and regional level (FPS,
confirm the power of the central state rather 1995, article 10(9), article 11(1.7), pp 11, 15).
than effect a genuine decentralization of pol- Such an approach seems in keeping with a
icy (Martin, 1998). broad definition of the subsidiarity principle.
While it is beyond the scope of this paper to A practical manifestation of this approach
indicate in detail how such EU networking in the EU context might be to add to frame-
could be reformed, the networking approach work directives drafted by the Commission, a
does suggest a workable and concrete way of distinct section that sets out responsibilities
linking the local with the Brussels level for the and tasks ideal for each of the national, re-
benefit of policy. Also many innovative re- gional and local levels in such a way that they
forms in European local governance in recent mutually reinforce each other. In practice of
years have taken the form of modifying sim- course a wide margin of discretion would
ple hierarchical relations with novel participa- continue to exist in each state as to how this
tory linkages to various civic–social partners would work, as such a section should be
(Bogason, 1998). More generally some demo- indicative only. This approach might allow
cratic theorists have begun to recognize the for ideal duties and targets on implementa-
valuable role state–social networks can play tion to be agreed in advance of the directive
in improving the quality of state institutional- coming into force. In other cases it could
detail the acceptable legal margin of discre-
ized democratic practices (Busch, 1999).
tion for further measures each tier might want
Such networking could for example be as-
to pursue – for example setting higher local
signed the goal of making the Commission
standards due to higher levels of pollution.
respond to local needs, and to improve imple-
Local, regional and national governments
mentation of EU policy. Indeed this is a job would therefore know what is expected of
that is already being started by the expanding them in a general sense under a particular
IMPEL network, which examines issue of im- directive’s terms, by being effectively written
plementation (Demmke, 1997, p 70). Above all into the drafting process from the outset.
though, it should provide local governments Of course there are those who will still
with a means to supervise EU level policy argue that the national governments and min-
developments at an early stage and signal istries ought to best be left to represent such
their concerns. Indeed Ward and Williams local interests. Yet local and national interests
suggest that various urban environment pol- in the detail of policy are not always the
icy related networking was embarked upon same, and there may be some features of local
by some German city states, exactly so that expertise, or conversely a particularistic prob-
they might monitor the Commission (Ward lem, which requires a more direct source of
and Williams, 1997, p 457). This latter point representation.
leads to a second suggested reform approach Above all this approach would be useful, as
below. local governments would not have to wait for

Copyright © 2000 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd and ERP Environment Eur. Env. 10, 75 – 84 (2000)

81
B. FLYNN

detailed national direction on implementation, 3. A better way to conceive of a role for local
or confuse their duties with that of another environmental actors towards the EU is
level. Administrative problems of local imple- arguably one that evaluates their contribu-
mentation may also be usefully discussed with tions in the context of a broader intergov-
the Commission before a final text is agreed, ernmental relations perspective. What
thus pre-empting what has been a problem in emerges here is that local governments
the past. In short this approach would institu- offer scope in particular for policy innova-
tionalize a type of negotiation between the tion and for more responsive and finely
Commission and local government environ- tuned types of regulation.
mental experts to go hand in hand with the 4. Two specific reform suggestions were of-
networking approach discussed above. Indeed fered building on this perspective. The
such an approach has been argued for in the first was that expert policy networking
USA in the context of groundwater policy, in could allow for a flexible style of dialogue
order to give local states sufficient flexibility to emerge between the Commission and
(Redifer and Davis, 1996). local governments, through which exam-
ples of innovation and the need for local
flexibility could be discussed. This ap-
CONCLUSION proach is beginning in any case, but needs
to be made more accountable and trans-
Before some final closing comments, it is use- parent. To give effect to this, a second
ful here to reiterate, in schematic form, the suggestion was that local experts could be
reasons why one might be sceptical about the more involved in the drafting process for
scope for the application of the subsidiarity future framework directives. These could
principle to the local level. These are the include enumerated indicative duties and
following. responsibilities for local governments.
1. The definition given to subsidiarity in the After some seven years since the inclusion
EU context suggests a serious problem of of subsidiarity into EC law, it seems apt to
uneven application. Some states, notably consider how the principle might be applied
Germany, Belgium and Austria, have indi- in a more concrete way to local governments.
cated they will apply the principle to the To date, the principle appears to offer little for
sub-state level. In other states it remains local governments. There is also a danger
unclear how local governments can rely on that, if taken too far, the idea of subsidiarity
the principle without nation state could be contorted to justify localized policy
permission. autarky, a problem appearing in the USA
2. Local governments in any event appear to (Press, 1995). In contrast current trends in its
have a very mixed performance at envi- definition by the EU institutions seem to sug-
ronment related duties, which suggests gest the continued concentration of political
caution in advocating further decentraliza- decision-making power at the national level.
tion. In fairness this is often a function of Somewhere between these two extremes, this
their limited resources, yet in other cases paper has argued for a more realistic ap-
local governments may suffer from poor praisal of the role of local governments in EU
expertise, regulatory capture and the prob- environmental policy.
lem of spillovers. This typically adds up to That is not to say that faith in the subsidiar-
a serious problem of implementation. One ity principle should be abandoned outright,
has to conclude that it appears many at- for its usefulness all depends on how it is
tempts at decentralizing environmental constitutionally operationalized over time to
policy in Europe have largely failed to make policy more rational and democratic. In
deliver improvements and in fact some- the shorter term, it might also be useful to
times merely masked a decentralization of develop the type of co-operative policy and
fiscal austerity. networking that can help local governments

Copyright © 2000 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd and ERP Environment Eur. Env. 10, 75 – 84 (2000)

82
IS LOCAL TRULY BETTER?

better implement European laws and ensure Countries, Nord:5, Christiansen PM (ed.). Nordic Coun-
the Commission proposes only those laws cil of Ministers: Arhus; 29 – 103.
that municipalities have had an opportunity Commission of the European Communities (CEC). 1992.
Communication on the principle of subsidiarity –
to extensively comment on. Such approaches 27/11/92. Bulletin of the European Communities 10: 116.
could be of use in maintaining cohesion and Commission of the European Communities (CEC). 1993.
unity in environmental policy where needed, Inter-institutional agreement between the European
and at the same time allow for local adjust- Parliament, the Council and the Commission on the
ments based on reasonable custom, political procedures for implementing the principle of sub-
sidiarity – 25/11/93. Bulletin of the European Communi-
legitimacy and, where useful, economic evi- ties 10: 119 – 120.
dence as well. Is it not time then to give up Davis G. 1998. Carving out policy space for state gov-
the somewhat ambiguous subsidiarity debate ernment in a federation: the role of coordination.
of the past for a more pragmatic and work- Publius – the Journal of Federalism 28: 4.
able approach in the future? Demmke C. 1997. Implementation and enforcement in
the member states: internal management of European
policy. In Managing European Environmental Policy: the
Role of the Member States in the Policy Process. EIPA:
Maastricht; 41 – 79.
REFERENCES Deyle RE, Smith RA. 1998. Local government compli-
ance with state planning mandates – the effects of
Andersen MS, Christiansen PM, Winter S. 1998. Den- state implementation in Florida. Journal of the American
mark: consensus seeking and decentralisation. In Gov- Planning Association 64(4): 457 – 469.
ernment and Environment in Western Europe: Politics, Dion C, Lanoie P, Laplante B. 1998. Monitoring of pollu-
Policy and Administration, Hanf K, Jansen A (eds). tion regulation: do local conditions matter? Journal of
Longman: Harlow; 40–59. Regulatory Economics 13: 1.
Axlerod RS. 1994. Subsidiarity and environmental policy Duff A (ed). 1997. The Treaty of Amsterdam: Text and
in the European Community. International Environ- Commentary. Federal Trust: London.
mental Affairs 1: 3. Eberlein B. 1996. French center – periphery relations and
Balducci M. 1996. Introductory report. In Conference on science park development: local policy initiatives and
the Occasion of the 10th Anniversary of the European intergovernmental policymaking. Governance – an In-
Charter of Local Self-Government. Proceedings, Copen- ternational Journal of Policy and Administration 9: 4.
hagen, 1996. Council of Europe: Strasbourg; 36– 55. EUROP. 1997. Green Forum strengthened. EUROP-News
Birnesser DJ, Moore LH, Kaye TP. 1993. Development of – Environment Supplement Issue 2.
a regional integrated solid waste system. Public Works Federal Press Service (FPS). 1995. Austrian Federal Laws
124: 4. (Selection). Federal Press Service: Vienna.
Blom-Hansen J. 1999. Avoiding the ‘joint-decision trap’: Føllesdal A. 1998. Survey article: subsidiarity. Journal of
lessons from intergovernmental relations in Scandi- Political Philosophy 6(2): 190 – 218.
navia. European Journal of Political Research 35: 1. Forbes GI. 1993. National recording of environmental
Bogason P. 1998. Changes in the Scandinavian model. incidents in Scotland. Journal of the Royal Society of
From bureaucratic command to interorganizational Health 113(6): 295 – 297.
negotiation. Public Administration 76: 2. Freeman J. 1997. Collaborative governance in the admin-
Breton A, Cassone A, Franschini A. 1998. Decentralisa- istrative state. UCLA Law Review 45: 1.
tion and subsidiarity: toward a theoretical reconcilia- Glazer A. 1999. Local regulation may be excessively
tion. University of Pennsylvania Journal of International stringent. Regional Science and Urban Economics 29: 5.
Economic Law 19(1): 21–51. Graham KA, Phillips SD. 1998. ‘Who does what’ in
Burby RJ, Strong DE. 1997. Coping with chemicals – Ontario: the process of provincial – municipal disen-
blacks, whites, planners, and industrial pollution. tanglement. Canadian Public Administration – Adminis-
Journal of the American Planning Association 63(4): 469 – tration Publique Du Canada 41: 2.
480. Groenendijk JG. 1998. Local policy-making under fiscal
Busch L. 1999. Beyond politics: rethinking the future of centralism in the Netherlands: consequences for local
democracy. Rural Sociology 64: 1. environmental policy. Environment and Planning C –
Butt-Philip A. 1994. Subsidiarity. In Maastricht and Be- Government and Policy 16(2): 173 – 189.
yond: Building the European Union, Duff A, Pinder J, Guy S, Marvin S. 1996. Disconnected policy: the shaping
Pryce R (eds). Routledge: London; 127–129. of local energy management. Environment and Plan-
Cimitile CJ, Kennedy VS, Lambright WH, O’Leary R, ning C – Government and Policy 14(1): 145 – 158.
Weiland P. 1997. Balancing risk and finance: the chal- Hay C. 1995. Re-stating the problem of regulation and
lenge of implementing unfunded environmental man- re-regulating the local state. Economy and Society 24: 3.
dates. Public Administration Review 57(1): 63–74. Heritier A. 1999. Elements of democratic legitimation in
Christiansen PM. 1996. Denmark. In Governing the Envi- Europe: an alternative perspective. Journal of European
ronment: Politics, Policy, and Organisation in the Nordic Public Policy 6(2): 269 – 282.

Copyright © 2000 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd and ERP Environment Eur. Env. 10, 75 – 84 (2000)

83
B. FLYNN

Jacobs B. 1997. Networks, partnerships and European Western Europe: Politics, Policy and Administration, Hanf
Union regional economic development initiatives in K, Jansen A (eds). Longman: Harlow; 208 – 229.
the West Midlands. Policy and Politics 25(1): 39– 50. Official Journal of the European Communities. 1994a. 94/
Jansen A, Mydske PK. 1998. Norway: balancing environ- C102/08 37; 3–4.
mental quality and interest in oil. In Government and Official Journal of the European Communities. 1994b. 94/
Environment in Western Europe: Politics, Policy and Ad- C336/36 37; 17.
ministration, Hanf K, Jansen A (eds). Longman: Har- Patterson A, Theobald KS. 1995. Sustainable develop-
low; 181–207. ment, Agenda 21 and the new local governance in
Kamieniecki S, Ferrall MR. 1991. Intergovernmental rela- Britain. Regional Studies 29(8): 773 – 778.
tions and clean-air policy in southern California. Pub- Perkmann M. 1999. Building governance institutions
lius – The Journal Of Federalism 21: 3. across European borders. Regional Studies 33: 7.
Lerche C, Preußer J. 1997. The Bavarian perspective on Press D. 1995. Environmental regionalism and the strug-
the subsidiarity principle – with particular reference gles for California. Society and Natural Resources 8: 4.
to implications for EC environmental policy. In Sub- Read AD. 1999. Making waste work: making UK na-
sidiarity and Shared Responsibility: New Challenges for tional solid waste strategy work at the local scale.
EU Environmental Policy, Collier U, Golub J, Kreher A Resources Conservation and Recycling 26(3-4): 259 –285.
(eds). Nomos: Baden-Baden; 79–89. Redifer J, Davis S. 1996. Building regimes in ground-
Lewanski R. 1998. Italy: environmental policy in a frag- water policy; contaminating the message. Society and
mented state. In Government and Environment in West- Natural Resources 9: 2.
ern Europe: Politics, Policy and Administration, Hanf K, Rocher F, Rouillard C. 1998. Decentralization, subsidiar-
Jansen A (eds). Longman: Harlow; 131–151. ity and neoliberalism in Canada: when the tree hides
Licht G, Nerlinger E. 1998. New technology-based firms the forest. Canadian Public Policy – Analyse de Politiques
in Germany: a survey of the recent evidence. Research 24: 2.
Policy 26(9): 1005–1022. Scharpf FW. 1988. The joint-decision trap: lessons from
Littlewood S, While A. 1997. A new agenda for gover- German federalism and European integration. Public
nance? Agenda 21 and the prospects for holistic local Administration 66: 239 – 278.
decision making. Local Government Studies 23(4): 111 – Scholz JT. 1991. Co-operative regulatory enforcement
123.
and the politics of administrative effectiveness. Ameri-
Lundqvist LJ. 1996. Sweden. In Governing the Environ-
can Political Science Review 85: 1.
ment: Politics, Policy, and Organisation in the Nordic
Scott P, Miller C, Wood C. 1998. Planning and pollution:
Countries, Nord:5, Christiansen PM (ed.). Nordic Coun-
an unusual perspective on central – local relations. En-
cil of Ministers: Arhus; 259–336.
vironment and Planning C – Government and Policy
Lundqvist LJ. 1998. Sweden: from environmental
16(5): 529 – 542.
restoration to ecological modernisation. In Government
and Environment in Western Europe: Politics, Policy and Smith S. 1993. Subsidiarity and the co-ordination of
Administration, Hanf K, Jansen A (eds). Longman: indirect taxes in the European Community. Oxford
Harlow; 230–252. Review of Economic Policy 9: 1.
Marks G, Nielsen F, Ray L, Salk J. 1996. Competencies, Sorenson LR. 1992. Madison on the meaning of the
cracks and conflicts: regional mobilization in the Eu- general welfare, the purpose of enumerated powers,
ropean Union. In Governance in the European Union, and the definition of constitutional government. Pub-
Marks G et al. (eds). Sage: London; 40–62. lius – the Journal of Federalism 22(2): 109 – 121.
Martimort D. 1999. The life cycle of regulatory agencies: Stoker G. 1995. Intergovernmental relations. Public Ad-
dynamic capture and transaction costs. Review of Eco- ministration 73: 1.
nomic Studies 66: 4. Sweeney SH, Feser EJ. 1998. Plant size and clustering of
Martin S. 1998. EU programmes and the evolution of manufacturing activity. Geographical Analysis 30(1):
local economic governance in the UK. European Urban 45 – 64.
and Regional Studies 5: 3. van den Bergh R. 1996. Economic criteria for applying
McEvoy D, Gibbs DC, Longhurst JWS. 1998. Urban the subsidiarity principle in the European Commu-
sustainability: problems facing the ‘local’ approach to nity: the case of competition policy. International Re-
carbon-reduction strategies. Environment and Planning view of Law and Economics 16: 363 – 383.
C – Government and Policy 16(4): 423–432. Ward S, Williams R. 1997. From hierarchy to networks?
Meadowcroft J. 1999. The politics of sustainable devel- Sub-central government and EU urban environment
opment: emergent arenas and challenges for political policy. Journal of Common Market Studies 35(3): 439–
science. International Political Science Review 20(2): 219 – 464.
237. Weber EP. 1998. Pluralism by the Rules: Conflict and
Mintrom M. 1997. The state–local nexus in policy inno- Co-Operation in Environmental Regulation. Georgetown
vation diffusion: the case of school choice. Publius – University Press: Washington, DC.
the Journal of Federalism 27: 3. Wise C, O’Leary R. 1997. Intergovernmental relations
Morata F, Font N. 1998. Spain: environmental policy and and federalism in environmental management and
public administration. A marriage of convenience offi- policy: the role of the courts. Public Administration
ciated by the EU. In Government and Environment in Review 57: 2.

Copyright © 2000 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd and ERP Environment Eur. Env. 10, 75 – 84 (2000)

84

You might also like