You are on page 1of 27

Economic Geography

ISSN: 0013-0095 (Print) 1944-8287 (Online) Journal homepage: http://www.tandfonline.com/loi/recg20

Industrial Agglomeration and Development: A


Survey of Spatial Economic Issues in East Asia and
a Statistical Analysis of Chinese Regions

C. Cindy Fan & Allen J. Scott

To cite this article: C. Cindy Fan & Allen J. Scott (2003) Industrial Agglomeration and
Development: A Survey of Spatial Economic Issues in East Asia and a Statistical Analysis of
Chinese Regions, Economic Geography, 79:3, 295-319

To link to this article: https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1944-8287.2003.tb00213.x

Published online: 22 Oct 2015.

Submit your article to this journal

Article views: 91

Citing articles: 30 View citing articles

Full Terms & Conditions of access and use can be found at


http://www.tandfonline.com/action/journalInformation?journalCode=recg20
#9905—ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY—VOL. 79 NO. 3—79304-Fan_Scott

Economic Geography 79(3): 295–319, 2003.


© 2003 Clark University. http://www.clarku.edu/econgeography

Industrial Agglomeration and Development:


A Survey of Spatial Economic Issues in East Asia
and a Statistical Analysis of Chinese Regions
C. Cindy Fan
Department of Geography, University of California–Los Angeles,
1255 Bunche Hall, PO Box 951524, Los Angeles, CA 90095-1524
fan@geog.ucla.edu

Allen J. Scott
Department of Geography, University of California–Los Angeles,
1255 Bunche Hall, PO Box 951524, Los Angeles, CA 90095-1524
ajscott@ucla.edu

Abstract: In this article, we explore the issue of industrial agglomeration and its
relationship to economic development and growth in the less-developed countries
of East Asia. We present theoretical arguments and secondary empirical evidence
as to why we should have strong expectations about finding a positive relationship
between agglomeration and economic performance. We also review evidence from
the literature on the roles of formal and informal institutions in East Asian regional
economic systems. We then focus specifically on the case of China. We argue that
regional development in China has much in common with regional development
in other East Asian economies, although there are also important contrasts
because of China’s history of socialism and its recent trend toward economic liber-
alization. Through a variety of statistical investigations, we substantiate (in part)
the expected positive relationship between agglomeration and economic perfor-
mance in China. We show that many kinds of manufacturing sectors are character-
ized by a strong positive relationship between spatial agglomeration and produc-
tivity. This phenomenon is especially marked in sectors and regions where
liberalization has proceeded rapidly. We consider the relevance of our comments
about industrial clustering and economic performance for policy formulation in
China and the less-developed countries of East Asia.
Key words: industrial clusters, agglomeration, regional development, new economic
geography, East Asia, China.

In this article, we explore the issue of tionship between agglomeration and


industrial agglomeration and its relationship economic performance in the less-developed
to economic development and growth in the countries of East Asia, as in other parts of
less-developed countries of East Asia, with the world. This phase of our work is based
special reference to China. Our approach on the emerging body of ideas that is now
involves two main lines of attack. First, we often loosely referred to as the “new
present theoretical arguments and secondary economic geography” (cf. Scott 1988,
evidence as to why we should have strong 2002; Krugman 1991; Porter 2001). Second,
expectations about finding a positive rela- we engage in a variety of statistical

This research was supported by the World Bank. We express our thanks to Wenfei Wang for her
able research assistance on this project; to Chase Langford for his cartographic work; and to George
Lin, Henry Yeung, and four anonymous referees for their comments on earlier drafts of the article.

295
#9905—ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY—VOL. 79 NO. 3—79304-Fan_Scott
296 ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY JULY 2003
investigations that seek to document and statistical analyses accordingly fall short of a
substantiate the expected positive relation- full-blown test of the theoretical ideas laid
ship between agglomeration and economic out in the first half of the article. Nevertheless,
performance. Our discussion is focused in so far as they go, the analyses are consis-
specifically on an examination of the tent with our main conceptual claims, and
spatial distribution of manufacturing activity the results provide an encouraging basis
in China. for moving forward into new rounds of
Most of the literature on industrial statistical research in the future.
agglomeration and economic performance
has been concerned with empirical situa-
tions in the advanced Western capitalist Locational Agglomeration and
world. In this article, we hope to demon- Regional Industrial
strate not only that the cluster approach is Performance
as useful in the East Asian context as it is
in Western situations, but that it can also The notion of the region as a nexus of crit-
shed important light on critical dilemmas of ical developmental and growth processes has
development that are specific to non- long been familiar to heterodox economists,
Western countries. We emphasize that such as Hirschman (1958), Jacobs (1969),
theory needs to address both the economic Kaldor (1970), Lampard (1955), Myrdal
bases of regional development and socio- (1959), and Perroux (1961), who took exter-
cultural factors, such as formal and informal nalities and increasing returns seriously—in
institutions. In China, in particular, a history part because they explicitly or implicitly
of central planning and the recent transition recognized the importance of the intellec-
further complicate the applicability of tual legacy of Marshall (1890, 1919)—and
economic theories that are based primarily who saw that one major expression of
on Western experiences. In this article, we these phenomena can be found in local-
show that in China, the positive relations ized complexes of economic activity. Since
between industrial agglomeration and the early 1980s, an enormous surge in the
economic performance are generally as literature in economic geography and
hypothesized, but that genuine industrial allied fields has greatly expanded on this
clusters are more characteristic of sectors earlier work. All this literature has repeat-
and spaces that have been most deeply trans- edly suggested that selected regions—espe-
formed by economic reforms and market cially those in which industries are organized
orientation. in transactions-intensive networks—are
In the first half of the article, we lay out capable of exerting powerful push effects on
a brief statement on the relations between national economic development.
industrial agglomeration and economic Many kinds of industrial systems are trans-
performance and consider the ways in which actions intensive both in a static sense (trans-
these relations throw light on the East Asian actions are numerous and finely grained)
case, and vice versa. In the second half, we and in a dynamic sense (transactions are
focus on regional development in China, first subject to constant flux because of rapidly
by giving a short account of how recent polit- changing production arrangements and
ical economic changes have affected the market instabilities). These features are espe-
space-economy and then by engaging in a cially marked today in industries like elec-
number of statistical exercises to demon- tronics, communications equipment, special-
strate that there is a significant link between ized machinery and components, toys,
agglomeration and economic performance watches, garments, furniture, software,
in Chinese regions. Unfortunately, empir- and business services, where many small
ical work of this sort commonly encounters establishments with narrowly defined core
severe constraints resulting from the defi- competencies perform critical functions
ciencies of available industrial data. Our within constantly shifting and information-
#9905—ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY—VOL. 79 NO. 3—79304-Fan_Scott
VOL. 79 NO. 3 INDUSTRIAL AGGLOMERATION AND DEVELOPMENT 297
intensive systems of interlinkages. Mutual learning and innovation whose cumula-
proximity is often crucial to the success of tive effects greatly reinforce local
the individual establishments that make competitive advantages.
these industries up, partly because it reduces 4. The clustering of many different
the costs of transacting and partly because producers can significantly enhance the
of a series of other factors that intensify local- formation of beneficial business alliances
ized positive externalities. Benefits of and organizations that help to augment
these sorts are identifiable more generally local competitive advantage. Equally,
as agglomeration economies, although in agglomeration promotes the develop-
certain cases, agglomeration diseconomies ment of distinctive business cultures in
can also appear as regions grow in size. particular places, thus facilitating the
Agglomeration effects, in turn, are often tasks of interfirm communication and
categorized as so-called localization understanding.
economies (i.e., efficiency-boosting 5. Significant economies can be obtained
phenomena that come from the clustering when the consumption of infrastructural
of firms in a given sector) and as urbaniza- artifacts is spread out over many indi-
tion economies (i.e., efficiencies that result viduals in any one place. Large localized
from the agglomeration of many different clusters of firms and workers make it
kinds of activities in a given region). In the possible to construct disproportionately
vocabulary of more recent analysts, these dense and rich infrastructures with many
economies are often referred to, respectively, positive effects on local competitive
as Marshall-Arrow-Romer externalities advantage.
and Jacobs externalities (e.g., Beardsell
and Henderson 1999). Regions that have some or all these attrib-
In practice, these types of externalities can utes, combined with dynamic learning capac-
be further broken down into more detailed ities, stand some chance of becoming signif-
categories. The following five points summa- icant articulations of value-adding activity
rize the main issues: and entrepreneurial energy in the new global
economy. They are apt to exhibit strong
1. Interfirm transactions that are small in increasing-returns effects that lead to ever-
scale, variable in content, and subject superior competitive advantages (as
to frequent readjustment usually incur expressed, for example, by rising quality/cost
high costs per unit of distance. The ratios for final products) as they grow. In
mutual proximity of firms in networks practice, given statistical measurement diffi-
made up of transactions like these is an culties, these effects are typically analyzed
important factor in preventing costs from by economists in the form of aggregate
spiraling out of control and reducing the productivity levels per worker (operationally,
risks of any failure to establish prompt value-added per worker), and in the analysis
interfirm contact (Scott 1988). presented here, we pursue the same strategy.
2. Dense local labor markets represent Much of the econometric work in this regard
spatial concentrations of job seekers and has been focused on cases in the more devel-
job vacancies, and high levels of mutual oped countries (see, e.g., Shefer 1973;
proximity make it relatively easy to Kawashima 1975; Sveikauskas 1975; Carlino
acquire, process, and act on information 1979), and only in recent years has there
about relevant opportunities. been a concerted attempt to apply similar
3. Transactional relations also involve flows approaches to regions in less-developed
of certain kinds of business information countries (e.g., Henderson 1986, 1988; Y.
or knowledge spillovers. Untraded inter- Chen 1996; Shukla 1996; Lee and Zang
dependencies of these sorts are all the 1998). We build on this latter literature with
more important because they tend to a detailed multilevel analysis of regional
underpin many small-scale processes of development across China as it moves
#9905—ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY—VOL. 79 NO. 3—79304-Fan_Scott
298 ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY JULY 2003
from central planning to an economic order Fujita and Tabuchi 1997), our concern here
that is increasingly influenced by liberal- is with the less-developed parts of East Asia.
ization policies. As such, our effort can be seen as a contri-
At the same time, current theories in bution to knowledge about agglomeration
economic geography pay attention not only in the non-Western world in general, and in
to the economic foundations of industrial low- and middle-income countries in partic-
agglomerations, but also to the important ular (see also Nadvi and Schmitz 1994; and
role played by institutional factors in Scott 2002).
promoting localized growth and develop- In these countries, dense industrial clus-
ment. It is generally acknowledged that these ters derive from both local entrepreneurial
factors tend to be extremely place specific efforts and foreign direct investment. In
and often vary greatly from one location to numerous cases, clusters can be shown to
another (Amin and Thrift 1995; Storper and have their roots in traditional artisanal forms
Scott 1995). In most East Asian countries, of production, as in the gem and jewelry
formal and informal institutions have been industry of Bangkok, the furniture industry
critical in shaping regional economic of the Philippines, the pottery and silk indus-
outcomes. In addition, governments have tries in China, and the shoe industry of Agra
played a notably directive role in assigning in India. At the same time, and especially in
investment to different locations and in the case of East Asia, we need to remain
setting up export-processing zones and other alert to the political context and the actions
local development schemes. China presents of governments at various levels of authority
an especially interesting case in this regard in molding regional patterns of development.
because of its history of centralized economic In East Asia, moreover, as in the economi-
planning. An important research and cally developed parts of the world, large city-
policy question raised by any investigation regions are the locations of many of the most
of industrial districts in China is whether vibrant industrial districts. Singapore, Hong
agglomerations that begin as governmental Kong, Seoul, Beijing, Shanghai, and Kuala
projects are able to develop into genuine Lumpur, for example, harbor many special-
growth centers with a strong endogenous ized industrial districts that draw on dense
dynamic of growth. In our empirical analysis, local supplies of skilled labor, infrastructure,
we show that viable industrial regions have educational and research facilities, and so
made their historical and geographic appear- on. In South Korea, high-technology firms
ance in those parts of China where economic have been shown to prefer the Seoul metro-
liberalization has been most prominent, but politan region because of high levels of
that the record is much less positive in other access to technical labor (Park 1994). In
parts of the country. Informal and trust- addition, foreign investors tend to favor
based relationships, too, are important in metropolitan areas that offer a diversity of
China, all the more so since economic liber- infrastructural and input services, as well
alization has relied heavily on ethnic and as a predictable regulatory environment
kinship ties with Hong Kong, Taiwan, and (Scott 1987; Leung 1993, 1996; Wong and
overseas Chinese. Goldblum 2000). The largest of Asia’s city-
regions sometimes exhibit agglomeration
diseconomies because of congestion,
Geographic Agglomeration in pollution, crime, and so on, although this
the Less-Developed Countries problem is not absolute, in the sense that
of East Asia appropriate policy and planning interven-
tions can invariably clear away some of the
Although the phenomenon of industrial barriers to further growth. In any case, far
agglomeration has been well documented in from seeing large-scale urbanization as an
the advanced economies, including Japan aberration, as some development theorists
(e.g., Nakamura 1985; Patchell 1993; have done in the past (e.g., Lipton 1977),
Kanemoto, Ohkawara, and Susuki 1996; our argument is that it is one of the impor-
#9905—ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY—VOL. 79 NO. 3—79304-Fan_Scott
VOL. 79 NO. 3 INDUSTRIAL AGGLOMERATION AND DEVELOPMENT 299
tant channels through which agglomera- thrive on the basis of its vibrant transactional
tion economies are achieved and acceler- networks, its low wages, and the skilful polit-
ated development occurs. Smaller urban ical maneuvering of its representatives.
centers, too, can play significant roles in the Rasiah’s (1994) study of the machine-tool
development process, especially in Asia industry in Malaysia underscored the
where many traditional craft industries connection between subcontracting and
outside the main metropolitan areas are localization. A number of studies on
beginning to show signs of modern entre- Indonesia have highlighted positive exter-
preneurial energy and orientation to wider nalities and productive effects of industrial
markets. We now examine more precisely clusters (Poot, Kuyvenhoven, and Jansen
how these relationships are worked out on 1990; Smyth 1992; Sandee, Rietveld,
the ground. Supratikno, and Yowono 1994; Nadvi and
Schmitz 1994; Sandee 1995; Weijland 1999;
Industrial Linkages, Subcontracting, Sandee and Rietveld 2001).
and Flexible Production
Learning and Knowledge
There is much evidence on the impor-
tance of industrial linkages as a factor in Many studies have pointed to the impor-
agglomeration processes in East Asia. For tance of the relation between learning and
the case of South Korea, Park (1991) argued proximity in the cities of developing coun-
that polarized regional economies with a tries in general, and East Asia in particular.
diversity of industries, information, and tech- At the same time, formal learning institu-
nical workers generate innovative firms and tions, such as universities and research infra-
spin-offs, which, in turn, encourage further structures, are located mostly in large urban
growth. Park (1993, 1994) further noted that areas in Asia. In Taiwan, the close spatial
vertical disintegration and the clustering of relations between the Industrial Technology
small plants increase the productivity of Research Institute and firms that produce
labor-intensive industries and that subcon- integrated circuits in the Hsinchu Science-
tracting is an important organizational Based Industrial Park are widely regarded
strategy for lowering wages and deflecting as a major factor in the latter’s success
industrial disputes. Similar arguments have (Chang and Hsu 1998). In a comprehensive
been made for the case of Taiwan, where article, Bell and Albu (1999) argued that
subcontracting networks and cluster-based “knowledge systems” are central to the long-
manufacturing were found to be important term dynamism of industrial clusters and
strategies for increasing the competitiveness stressed that the diffusion of innovation
of firms (Shieh 1990; W.-H. Chen 1999). within clusters, as well as the openness of
Focusing on Taiwan’s footwear industry, clusters to flows of knowledge from outside,
Levy (1991) contended that the transactions- are important in developing countries. Liu
costs hypothesis provides a powerful expla- (1998) concluded that learning capability
nation for the emergence of localized and human capital will determine the
subcontracting networks. durability of Taiwan’s industrial success.
Detailed empirical studies on industrial Concomitantly, the absence of these quali-
linkages in the more peripheral parts of East ties in any region means that barriers to
Asia are relatively scarce. In a study of the development are likely to be rapidly encoun-
semiconductor industry in Southeast Asia, tered, even if the region possesses other
Scott (1987) showed that production units kinds of assets. Sandee (1995) demonstrated
in Manila’s semiconductor complex in the how collaboration in a rural industrial cluster
mid-1980s were clustered close to one in Indonesia fosters the diffusion of inno-
another and were intricately linked to vation and the deepening of technological
minimize transactions costs. Scott (1994) capabilities. Johansson and Nilsson (1997)
demonstrated that the gem and jewelry showed that clustering in export processing
industry of Bangkok has been able to zones in Malaysia stimulates local firms to
#9905—ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY—VOL. 79 NO. 3—79304-Fan_Scott
300 ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY JULY 2003
learn from foreign investors how to produce, cated, many proponents of the new
market, sell, and distribute manufactured economic geography have sought to extend
goods on the world market. the theory of agglomeration by emphasizing
the institutional bases of regional economic
development, particularly the role of public
Cluster Development and the
agencies in regulating local market failures
International Division of Labor and other impediments to rapid forward
For the most part, East Asia has been at momentum (e.g., Peck 1992; Amin 1999).
the receiving end of the decentralization of This approach has been greatly influenced
manufacturing production from advanced by institutional and evolutionary economics
industrialized economies to developing and economic sociology, which stress that
countries. For example, until the mid-1970s, economic activity is always socially
the four newly industrializing economies of embedded and therefore context specific
South Korea, Taiwan, Hong Kong, and and path dependent (Granovetter 1985;
Singapore accounted for the bulk of the Hodgson 1988).
offshore assembly work of U.S. electronics
corporations (Scott 1987). As these Governance Structures and Regional
economies developed, branch plants in Development
search of cheap labor moved to yet more
peripheral parts of East Asia, including East Asian governments have had signif-
Malaysia, the Philippines, Indonesia, icant impacts on economic development
Thailand, and China (Tsay 1993; Ho 1994; through the adoption of export-oriented
Park 1994; Tang 1996; Eng 1997; Wong and industrialization policies and the establish-
Goldblum 2000). In the same way, consid- ment of industrial parks and export-
erable subcontracting now occurs from processing zones. Kaohsiung in Taiwan,
North America and Western Europe to East Masan in South Korea, Penang and Johore
Asian producers in such sectors as clothing, in Malaysia, and Shenzhen in China were
furniture, and machinery. It is important among the first generation of government-
to note that large urban centers in East Asia sponsored industrial zones for fostering
are especially attractive as locations for this export-oriented industrialization. Yuan and
kind of manufacturing decentralization. Such Eden (1992), in their comparative study of
development typically draws on the cheap, Taiwan, South Korea, and China, under-
surplus labor in cultural and political settings scored the role of governmental policy in
where workers are willing to tolerate long determining the performance of export-
hours, accelerated rhythms of work, and processing zones. Governments in Taiwan
round-the-clock manufacturing schedules. and Singapore have played particularly crit-
As manufacturing decentralization to East ical roles in fostering technological advance-
Asian cities occurs, moreover, local input ment in these zones (Yuen 1991; Ho 1994;
industries often spring up in the local envi- Xue 1997).
ronment, providing backup services and In many cases, however, government-initi-
strengthening local agglomeration ated development zones have not yet really
economies. taken off, in the sense that they generate
limited agglomeration economies. In
contrast to the Marshallian formulation, in
Institutions and Regulation in which endogenously driven growth and local
East Asian Regional embeddedness sustain agglomerations, these
Development clusters are more often than not “hub and
spoke” or “satellite platform” industrial
Formal and informal institutions play a districts (Markusen, Lee, and DiGiovanna
prominent role in the structuring of East 1999). For example, in South Korea, Pohang
Asian economies. Indeed, as we have indi- is anchored by a steel company, and Ulsan
#9905—ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY—VOL. 79 NO. 3—79304-Fan_Scott
VOL. 79 NO. 3 INDUSTRIAL AGGLOMERATION AND DEVELOPMENT 301
is anchored by a petrochemical plant and an ality, trust, and cooperation. Ties of prox-
automobile plant, whereas Kumi, imity and association are especially impor-
Changwon, and Ansan are satellite districts tant in promoting learning effects and the
with branch plants whose external linkages diffusion of know-how (Amin and Thrift
are mostly extralocal (Markusen and Park 1995; Sunley 1996; Storper 1997). Face-to-
1993; Park 1996). Park (1993) observed that face contacts, in particular, help to engender
the South Korean government has increased relational assets or untraded interdepen-
support for collaboration between large firms dencies in the form of information, reputa-
and small or medium-sized firms so that tional capital, economically useful sensibil-
satellite clusters can benefit from the forma- ities and forms of habituation, and so on.
tion of local networks and linkages. Economic agents and firms in regions with
Furthermore, Park (1996) showed that as rich traditions of reciprocity benefit from
firms begin to lose the advantages that the sharing of know-how and expertise,
accrue from governmental incentives, they and by doing so, they increase the local stock
tend to pursue strategies such as the of competitive advantages (Cooke and
formation of local linkages, cooperative inter- Morgan 1998). Transactions, therefore, are
firm relations, and contracting-out activities, to be evaluated not only in terms of their
while spin-off activities and new start-ups costs, but also in terms of their qualitative
also tend to increase (e.g., in Taeduck social characteristics (Harrison 1992).
Science Town). Through this process, Park
contended, initial satellite and hub-and-
spoke industrial districts begin to evolve Geographic Agglomerations in
toward systems marked by local networks China
and embeddedness, as illustrated by the case
of Kumi. China has much in common with other
East Asian economies, from the many big
cities scattered across its landscape to the
Informal Bases of the Local Economy prominent roles of governments and social
Trust-based business relationships are of networks in economic life. However, its
great significance in many East Asian development history has also been heavily
cultures and are reflected not only in local shaped by socialist ideology and, more
transactions, but also in the intricate ties recently, by the trend toward economic
based on the Asian diaspora that exist liberalization.
between East Asia and other parts of the China has a mixed economy, one in which
world (Hamilton 1991; Smart 2000; Yeung the government’s role and institutional lega-
and Olds 2000). Since the 1990s, an cies from the former command economy
emerging body of work on East Asia has have had profound effects on the geography
sought to highlight the role of interpersonal of production. Prior to the 1980s, the
relations and ethnic and kinship ties in Chinese government’s blueprint for national
regional economic development. Thus, Olds economic development, with its stress on
(2001) argued for a relational geography that large-scale vertically integrated units of
focuses on networks and flows, linkages, production, was not especially conducive
interdependence, connections, and mutu- to the formation of dynamic industrial
ality. This kind of relational geography is districts rich in positive externalities. The
characteristic of “Chinese capitalism” and of socialist economy was focused on state-
the operations of large Chinese-controlled owned enterprises, domestic investment and
international conglomerates. markets, and a locational rationale that
The importance of interpersonal relations emphasized political goals more than
in East Asia further reinforces the notion economic efficiency. From the 1950s to
that economic behavior is embedded, in part, the early 1970s, the Chinese government
in social networks that are defined by mutu- deliberately discouraged investment in
#9905—ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY—VOL. 79 NO. 3—79304-Fan_Scott
302 ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY JULY 2003
coastal areas and promoted the growth of ment depended on parts brought from
inland cities. It also selected remote inland Taiwan. Since the mid-1990s, however,
sites for key sectors, such as cars and iron strong local networks underpinning the
and steel, but discouraged spatial clustering production of printed circuits have emerged,
(Huang 1999; Naughton 1988). Sit and Lu with interrelated factories constituting a
(2000) showed how the geography of China’s growing spatial agglomeration. As a result,
car industry is still strongly influenced by a complete computer can now be assembled
these past locational decisions. This influ- from parts made entirely in factories located
ence is reinforced by regulatory structures within 50 kilometers of one another. Park
that restrict foreign investments in the car (1996) also noted that small firms in satel-
industry to joint ventures with domestic lite industrial districts in China, such as
firms. Shenzhen, are becoming increasingly inte-
Since the economic reforms of the 1980s, grated into local network structures.
however, the Chinese government has In contrast to the socialist period, when
actively pursued alternative policies that are the government had strict control over
directed to economic liberalization. It economic activities, economic liberalization
promoted export-oriented industrialization since the 1980s has boosted the role of the
programs by designating special economic market and has been conducive to industrial
and open zones, most notably in the eastern linkages that respond to market signals.
coastal zone (Fan 1995, 1997). New policy Perhaps the most vivid example is the hosiery
incentives, infrastructural investments, and cluster in Zhejiang province, where more
social relationships that include ties with than 10,000 village households in 120 villages
overseas Chinese (Hsing 1996; Leung 1993) in and near Datang have become China’s
have paved the way for the eastern coastal biggest center of the production of socks and
zone to be integrated quickly with Western stockings and cluster development is now
capitalist production. Fan (2001, 2002) strongly under way (Wang 2001). Each
contended that the government has used enterprise specializes in a particular aspect
socialist-type policies to foster rural-urban of production, including manufacturing,
migration and, by doing so, has engendered machinery, marketing, and services, and this
a migrant labor regime and increased the networked organization is considered to be
supply of cheap rural labor to coastal areas. the primary reason for the success of the
In contrast to industries that are heavily cluster (Guo and Cai 2000). The intricate
influenced by Maoist legacies, the consumer division of labor and face-to-face networking
electronics and garments industries, which in the system enable enterprises to respond
tend to dominate in these areas, are char- quickly to changes in the market and to
acterized by high levels of foreign invest- ensure high levels of efficiency and mini-
ment, export orientation, and functional flex- mization of risks. This system is strongly
ibility. We argue that it is in these spaces, embedded in local social relationships in that
where economic reforms and market orien- interfirm linkages depend on trust and social
tation are the most deeply rooted, that capital. Wang (2001) argued that the close
agglomeration economies appear most force- and specific relations among enterprises, the
fully in China. low barriers to entry and exit, and external
Some government-sponsored industrial economies that are due to interlinkages
areas in China’s open economic zones create a situation that is similar to the Third
initially resembled satellite platforms of Italy model of flexible specialization.
the South Korean type, where many firms Similarly, flexible production systems in the
were tied to overseas markets but had only garment, textile, toy, and footwear/leather
weak local linkages. Tong and Wang’s (2002) industries in south China permit fast
study of the personal computer industry in turnover and quick response to market
Dongguan, Guangdong, for example, changes—key factors in firms’ competi-
showed that during the 1980s, printed-circuit tiveness in the global market (Christerson
assembly plants with foreign capital invest- and Lever-Tracy 1997). Also prominent in
#9905—ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY—VOL. 79 NO. 3—79304-Fan_Scott
VOL. 79 NO. 3 INDUSTRIAL AGGLOMERATION AND DEVELOPMENT 303
south China are firms in the computer analysis of subcontracting activities in the
industry that have attained to high levels of Pearl River Delta that highlighted the role
competitiveness because agglomeration of cultural and kinship ties between distant
enables them to ensure that their products investors and local producers (see also Hsing
are high quality through rapid access to 1995, 1996, 1998). Christerson and Lever-
information and inputs (Tong and Wang Tracy (1997), who also focused on Fujian
2002). Even many small rural areas in the and the Pearl River Delta, argued that the
Pearl River Delta have grown considerably family and social relationships of overseas
because of subcontracting orders from over- Chinese investors have been of major impor-
seas. Here, as in some other parts of East tance in the growth of the garment industry
Asia, industrialization has blurred the distinc- in south China.
tion between the urban and the rural, giving Y. Chen (1996) made a major econometric
rise to the desakota phenomenon described contribution to the study of industrial
by McGee (1991) and Lin (2001). agglomeration in China. He estimated
Another case is the agglomeration of high- sectoral value added as a function of capital,
technology firms in Zhong’guancun, Beijing, labor, and a regional factor multiplier that
which benefits not only from a local pool consists of five components, including
of skilled labor, but also from the proximity agglomeration. The impact of agglomeration
of a large number of research establish- on productivity was found to be positive and
ments, such as Beijing University and high for the machinery industry but lower
Qinghua University (Wang and Wang 1998). for less technology-intensive industries such
Many firms in Zhong’guancun are spin-offs as food manufacturing. In the next section,
from state-owned enterprises and continue we propose a framework similar to Chen’s
to receive strong support from parent insti- and on this basis seek to push the study of
tutions or universities. Wang (2001) industrial agglomeration in China forward
observed that a club culture has emerged in one more notch. Even though our analysis
the area, which further stimulates interac- was greatly hampered by the lack of data,
tion among entrepreneurs, managers, we have nevertheless been able to bring a
engineers, and professionals and promotes variety of different perspectives and scales
a climate of entrepreneurship, innovation, of analysis to bear on the central problem.
and risk taking. This case suggests that locally
embedded cultures, norms, and social rela- Agglomeration and Industrial
tions are major factors in the dynamism of
agglomerations in China. Productivity in China
Similarly, the strong ethnic and kinship We begin our analysis by probing gener-
ties of China with Hong Kong, Taiwan, ally into the relations between industrial
and overseas Chinese in other countries have location and productivity in China. One way
heavily shaped spatial patterns of foreign of measuring the broad locational charac-
direct investment and have been a crucial teristics of an industry is to compute a
factor in the development of new indus- Herfindahl index (hereafter H-index) to
trial agglomerations in the eastern and assess the industry’s overall level of spatial
southern coastal areas. Labor-intensive agglomeration or dispersal. Thus, for Sector
industrial clusters in Fujian and the Pearl i, let pij be the proportion of total activity
River Delta in Guangdong, for example, are located in the jth region or province. The
strongly dependent on such ties. Much of term pij is defined more explicitly as xij / Xi,
the growth of these regions has been due where xij is the amount of activity in industry
to the relocation of manufacturing produc- i in province j and Xi is the total amount of
tion from Taiwan and Hong Kong and to activity in industry i in China as a whole (i.e.,
subcontract orders from manufacturers of Xi = Σjxij). The H-index for Sector i is then
Chinese origin in the United States (cf. computed as Hi = Σjpij2. When all the activity
Bonacich and Appelbaum 2000). Leung in Sector i is concentrated in one province,
(1993, 1996) stressed the same point in an the index is equal to one; when all activity
#9905—ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY—VOL. 79 NO. 3—79304-Fan_Scott
304 ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY JULY 2003
is evenly dispersed, the index converges obtained for all 31 provinces in China,
asymptotically to zero for a sufficiently large although for 10 sectors, data were available
number of provinces; intermediate locational for only 30 provinces, and for 2 sectors, they
patterns are represented by values of the were available for 29 provinces. The quality
index between these two extremes. We of these data leaves much to be desired, but
computed two sets of H-indexes for all two- the results we obtained appear, with certain
digit manufacturing sectors in China (except reservations, to be reasonably reassuring.
armaments, for which the published statis- Table 1 shows H-indexes for this exercise,
tics are heavily censored), using the number ordered from high to low values. The index
of establishments and employment as raw for establishments is usually smaller than the
data inputs. Data for this purpose were taken index for employment, a statistical effect that
from the statistical yearbooks of the Chinese seems to arise because of the occurrence
provinces for 2000. In most instances, the of large establishments in many sectors (and
number of establishments and employment all the more so given the labor-hoarding
figures for two-digit sectors could be propensities of state-owned enterprises in

Table 1
H-Index Values for Two-Digit Industrial Sectors in Chinese Provincesa
Values of H-Index

Industrial Sector Establishments Employment

Stationery, education, and sporting goods 0.1381 0.3316


Electronics and telecommunications 0.1274 0.1970
Furniture manufacturing 0.1259 0.1183
Garments and other fiber products 0.1225 0.1849
Metal products 0.1182 0.1074
Instruments, meters, educational and office machinery 0.1180 0.0926
Leather, furs, down, and related products 0.1044 0.2612
Chemical fibers 0.1016 0.1082
Other manufacturing 0.0974 0.1551
Electric equipment and machinery 0.0959 0.1178
Plastic products 0.0933 0.1476
Textiles 0.0885 0.1095
Printing and record pressing 0.0859 0.0770
Ordinary machinery manufacturing 0.0846 0.0925
Petroleum processing and coking products 0.0800 0.0977
Special-purpose equipment 0.0763 0.0877
Rubber products 0.0755 0.0925
Transportation equipment manufacturing 0.0721 0.0689
All manufacturing 0.0676 0.0810
Papermaking and paper products 0.0646 0.0934
Chemical raw materials and chemical products 0.0639 0.0742
Timber processing, bamboo cane, palm fiber, and straw products 0.0592 0.0798
Smelting and pressing of nonferrous metals 0.0585 0.0658
Tobacco processing 0.0574 0.0828
Nonmetallic minerals 0.0560 0.0756
Food manufacturing 0.0548 0.0784
Smelting and pressing of ferrous metals 0.0544 0.0910
Food processing 0.0507 0.0869
Medical and pharmaceutical products 0.0468 0.0638
Beverage manufacturing 0.0450 0.0778
a
Analysis based on data from Chinese provincial yearbooks.
#9905—ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY—VOL. 79 NO. 3—79304-Fan_Scott
VOL. 79 NO. 3 INDUSTRIAL AGGLOMERATION AND DEVELOPMENT 305
China), thus causing a spurious increment In an attempt to flesh out these first
to apparent agglomeration when the employ- impressions, we examined the relations
ment measure is used. It is spurious, at least, between various measures of industrial struc-
in the sense in which the term agglomera- ture and the H-indexes presented in Table
tion is used in this investigation (i.e., to desig- 1. Given the small number of two-digit
nate a dense geographic clustering of func- sectors (which constitute the observations
tionally interrelated producers or in this analysis) and the paucity of available
establishments, in contrast to large concen- data, this exercise proved to be of limited
trations of employment that are due simply value, but one set of simple regressions
to the existence of one or two giant plants). emerged as being of particular interest. The
However, the simple correlation between relevant information is displayed in Table 2,
the indexes for establishments and employ- where H-indexes for establishments and
ment is 0.73, which means that each can employment are regressed against an inde-
be approximately substituted for the other. pendent variable (K/L), defined opera-
The information in Table 1 provides the tionally as total gross investment per worker,
first analytical glimpse of the geography of measured in units of 100 million yuan. All
manufacturing industries in China. At the variables are transformed into natural loga-
top of the list are sectors that are relatively rithms. The regression coefficient attached
agglomerated; at the bottom are industries to K/L is negative and highly significant. This
that are much more dispersed. A rough first finding confirms the idea that labor-inten-
assessment of the main structural features sive producers tend to be relatively agglom-
of these two groups suggests that the former erated (despite the anomalous cases of food
comprises relatively labor-intensive small- manufacturing and food processing), while
plant industries with a proclivity to form capital-intensive producers are relatively
vertically disintegrated networks (electronics, dispersed in their overall locational struc-
furniture, garments, and so on); the latter ture. From what we know of industrial organi-
seems to be much more focused on capital- zation processes in general, we speculate
intensive, large-plant sectors, often with a that there is some likelihood in principle that
market- or resource-oriented locational logic producers in the former group are charac-
and with significant levels of state owner- terized by tighter, more variable, and more
ship (smelting and pressing of ferrous metals, finely grained interindustrial networks
nonmetallic minerals, beverages, and so on). than are those in the latter group. As it
Note, however, that food manufacturing and happens, both H-indexes are also negatively
food processing, which have relatively low and significantly correlated with average size
H-indexes, are actually labor intensive in of establishment, though the weight of this
terms of their actual capital-labor ratios. variable is entirely swamped when we also
Presumably these industries are at least add K/L to the analysis as an independent
oriented, to some degree, to more dispersed, variable. Clearly, there are likely to be many
rural locations. other forces at play in structuring locational

Table 2
Regression Analysis of H-Indexes for Two-Digit Industries in Chinese Provinces
Values of Regression Statistics

H (Establishments) H (Employment)

Constant –2.6192 –0.3584


Coefficient of K/L –0.2214** –0.2619**
Adjusted R2 0.2323 0.2256

Note: Dependent variables are the H-indexes.


** p < .01.
#9905—ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY—VOL. 79 NO. 3—79304-Fan_Scott
306 ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY JULY 2003
outcomes in these industries (including, in industries become increasingly clustered. If
China, forms of ownership), but what is of we add average size of establishment to these
interest at this point is that our results so far two regressions, we find that the associated
suggest that in a general sense, differential coefficient is positive but not significant.
patterns of agglomeration and dispersal may, However, the simple correlation between
indeed, have some fundamental relationship average size of establishment and K/L is
to the shape and form of industrial activity 0.61, a finding that encourages us to infer
as we proposed earlier. We now need to that agglomerated industries are marked by
inquire more explicitly whether there are comparatively smaller plant sizes on average
productivity effects that flow from the than are more dispersed industries. In other
locational structure of Chinese industry as words, despite the admittedly crude and
expressed in the H-indexes. Productivity is aggregate nature of the analysis thus far, we
measured as value added per worker, and suggest that agglomerated industrial clus-
the hypothesis to be tested is that agglom- ters in China tend to be made up of small,
eration (for all the complex reasons discussed labor-intensive establishments and that it
earlier) has a significantly positive impact on is these kinds of industries whose produc-
this variable. tivity is enhanced by the convergence of
To begin with, we conducted a statistical producers around their own centers of
analysis based on a simple production-func- gravity.
tion approach (with two-digit industries as
observations), as indicated in Table 3. The
A More Disaggregated Analysis
dependent variable is defined as VA/L
(i.e., value added divided by employment), The regressions presented in Table 3
and the independent variables are K/L and represent an extremely aggregated level of
the H-index. In Regression 1, the H-index investigation. It is therefore important to
is defined for establishments; in Regression inquire whether similar relationships can be
2, it is defined for employment. Again, all found using a more spatially disaggregated
variables are transformed into natural loga- approach. To do so, we evaluated models
rithms. As in Table 2, both regressions run based on a production-function approach for
more or less parallel to one another. In each two-digit sectors with the observations
case, there is a (perhaps suspiciously) low defined in terms of individual provinces.
but positive and extremely significant coef- A synoptic view of the results of this
ficient attached to K/L. The H-indexes approach is presented in Table 4 for 29 two-
perform as expected. They indicate that digit manufacturing sectors. The dependent
significant productivity effects emerge as variable is VA/L as previously defined. The

Table 3
Regression Analysis of the Relations between Productivity and Locational Structure for
Two-Digit Industries in Chinese Provinces
Values of Regression Statistics

Regression 1 Regression 2

Constant 2.6729 3.1164


Coefficient of K/L 0.3231** 0.5067**
Coefficient of H 0.3828* 0.5691**
Adjusted R2 0.4131 0.5123

Note: VA/L is the dependant variable in both regressions.


* p < .05, ** p < .01.
#9905—ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY—VOL. 79 NO. 3—79304-Fan_Scott
VOL. 79 NO. 3 INDUSTRIAL AGGLOMERATION AND DEVELOPMENT 307
Table 4
Industrial Productivity in Chinese Provinces by Two-Digit Sectors, 2000: Regression
Resultsa
Average Number
Capital- Size of Population of
Constant Labor Establish- Location of Largest Adjusted Observa-
Sector Value Ratio ment Quotient City R2 tions

Food processing –0.3239 0.1327 –0.1425 0.1283 0.3608* 0.2075 20


Food manufacturing –1.8230** 0.2767 0.1838 –0.0003 0.2439** 0.6513 20
Beverage manufacturing –1.6009 0.8387 0.0372 0.3124 0.2173 0.7622 20
Tobacco processing 3.6634 1.1595** –0.4419* 0.0817 –0.2363 0.7257 18
Textiles –2.7573 1.1235** 0.0649 0.5400** 0.1296 0.7842 20
Garments and other fiber –5.3746** 0.9050* 0.4770 0.2540 0.4296** 0.5221 20
products
Leather, furs, down, and related –4.4040 0.9757 0.5464 0.6901* 0.1522 0.2071 20
products
Timber processing, bamboo cane, –4.6338 1.3171 0.6262 –0.0211 –0.1275 –0.0565 18
palm fiber, and straw products
Furniture manufacturing –4.5040* 1.1043** 0.5099* –0.1337 0.1440 0.2775 20
Papermaking and paper products 1.6282 0.6970** –0.3589* 0.2133 –0.0599 0.6112 19
Printing and record pressing –3.4975** 0.9663** 0.3086 –0.0659 0.1752** 0.6779 20
Stationery, education, and 1.0806 0.0355 –0.3524 0.5355* 0.2576 0.1973 19
sporting goods
Petroleum processing and coking 0.4736 1.1248** –0.2590* –0.1424 –0.1176 0.8791 19
products
Chemical raw materials and 1.7837 0.4556 –0.3370* 0.0618 0.0039 0.3185 20
chemical products
Medical and pharmaceutical 3.1377* 0.7768* –0.5881** 0.4320* 0.0036 0.5644 20
products
Chemical fibers 2.1169 0.4993** –0.3672 –0.2420 0.0074 0.6052 18
Rubber products –2.4372 1.8424** 0.3138 0.1720 –0.4425 0.6650 19
Plastic products –7.0235** 1.8577** 0.7580** 0.2615 0.0462 0.8247 20
Nonmetallic minerals –0.5699 0.9257** –0.1631 0.2159 0.0268 0.4548 19
Smelting and pressing of ferrous –2.9597* 0.6599* 0.0844 0.2504 0.2979 0.4663 20
metals
Smelting and pressing of 4.9269 0.3853 –0.4360** –0.0598 –0.3699 0.4779 19
nonferrous metals
Metal products –1.7505 1.0496* –0.0840 –0.0953 0.1861 0.2076 19
Ordinary machinery 1.5330 0.7400 –0.1452 0.5390 –0.2971 0.0965 20
manufacturing
Special purpose equipment –2.4027 0.8387 0.0372 0.3124 0.2173 –0.0016 19
Transportation equipment –2.8779 1.3677** –0.0652 0.1103 0.1969 0.7255 20
manufacturing
Electric equipment and –3.9346 1.6158** 0.4266 0.7617** –0.1162 0.8191 19
machinery
Electronics and 2.5839 0.6029 –0.2988 0.4982* –0.0942 0.5411 18
telecommunications
Instruments, meters, educational 7.8152** –0.4436 –0.2513 1.1143* –0.7878 0.3578 19
and office machinery
Other manufacturing –2.3789 0.6215** 0.1657 –0.0023 0.2678 0.6484 19
All manufacturing 0.0268 1.0047** 0.0290 2.4893* –0.2223 0.4932 20
a
Analysis based on data from Chinese provincial yearbooks.
* p < .05, ** p < .01.
#9905—ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY—VOL. 79 NO. 3—79304-Fan_Scott
308 ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY JULY 2003
independent variables are the capital-labor able (even when the inefficiencies of state-
ratio (K/L, as before), the average size of owned and collective-owned industries are
establishments, the location quotient, and taken into account). These low values may
the population of the largest city in each stem from measurement errors in the data
province. The location quotient for any used. In about half the cases, however, the
industry, i, in any province, j, is defined as coefficients have values that range from
πij/Πi, with πij = xij/Σixij and Πi = Xi/ΣXi, where 0.7 to 1.3, and these values seem to be more
x ij is the number of establishments in credible, at least in comparison with
industry i in province j and Xi is the number econometric studies carried out in other
of establishments in industry i in the whole parts of the world. At the same time, most
of China (i.e., X i = Σ j x ij ). The location of the statistically significant coefficients
quotient (which can take on any value attached to the average-size-of-establish-
greater than zero) thus identifies the degree ment variable (which is intended to capture
to which any given province is specialized in internal economies and diseconomies of
any given industry. In view of the specific scale that are due to plant size) are negative,
concept of agglomeration proposed earlier, which may not be unreasonable in more
the location quotients used in this phase of labor-intensive sectors, such as furniture,
the investigation are defined for establish- but seems anomalous in more capital-inten-
ments, rather than for employment. In prin- sive sectors, such as tobacco processing,
ciple, location quotients are supposed to chemical raw materials, or nonferrous
capture the effects (if any) of so-called local- metals. Again, in the absence of further
ization economies. The variable represented investigation, we cannot know whether this
by the population of the largest city in each apparent anomaly is due to data errors, to
province is a putative measure of the effects genuine inefficiencies (e.g., in the state-
of urbanization economies. These two vari- owned sector), or to some other cause.
ables are conceptually unsatisfactory, but in We now turn to the specifically geographic
the absence of more adequate data, they are content of the regressions laid out in Table
the best we have to work with. The largest- 4. This content is represented by the effects
city variable used here is especially inade- of the location-quotient variable and the
quate, given that it does not account for largest-city variable on value added per
the full extent of urbanization in each worker. As expected, the location-quotient
province. We experimented with a corre- variable has significant positive impacts on
sponding variable defined as the percentage productivity in a number of sectors where
of the total provincial population living in capital-labor ratios are relatively low and
cities, but this variable performed badly as values of the H-index high, namely, textiles,
an explanation of agglomeration, as we might leather, stationery, electric equipment and
anticipate, given that it does not express a machinery, electronics and telecommuni-
mass but a ratio. Complete sets of data for cations, and instruments. In turn, the largest-
each industry are not always available, and city variable has a significant and positive
hence the number of observations impact on productivity in garments and
(provinces) underlying each regression printing, which is in line with what we know
differs from sector to sector, as shown in about the economic geography of these
Table 4. Unfortunately, the number of two sectors in other countries. The same
degrees of freedom is restricted in all independent variable is significantly and
cases. All variables are measured in terms of positively correlated with productivity in
natural logarithms. food processing and food manufacturing. In
The first thing to note about the results all four cases, the positive impact of the
presented in the table is the wide variation largest-city variable may be explained not
in the values of the coefficients attached to only by the basic organizational features of
the capital-labor ratio; in some cases, these these four industries, but also by the orien-
values are so low as to be close to unbeliev- tation of a significant number of firms within
#9905—ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY—VOL. 79 NO. 3—79304-Fan_Scott
VOL. 79 NO. 3 INDUSTRIAL AGGLOMERATION AND DEVELOPMENT 309
them to market locations. If we now corre- recorded in China’s 1995 Industrial Census.
late K/L for each two-digit sector (at the level These firms accounted for 68.2 percent and
of the Chinese economy as a whole) with the 59.7 percent of the output and employment,
entire set of regression coefficients attached respectively, of all China’s industries. Note
to the location-quotient and largest-city vari- that the locations of a number of firms could
ables, we find that in the former case, the not be ascertained, and when we excluded
simple correlation is –0.18, which has the these and nonmanufacturing firms (in
expected sign but is not significant, and in mining and public utilities), we were left
the latter case, it is –0.50, which is signifi- with a total of 459,108 firms.
cant at the .01 level. This outcome suggests Data on all firms with known locations
strongly that labor-intensive industries, in were aggregated by county. We defined loca-
addition to their inclination to intrasectoral tion quotients as before, except that the
agglomeration, have a particular predilec- index i now runs over 534 four-digit indus-
tion for locations in large cities. trial sectors and j runs over 2,325 coun-
Thus, in a rough way, the analysis indi- ties,2 as opposed to provinces. Again, we
cates that localization and urbanization focus on establishments rather than employ-
economies are indeed at work in the Chinese ment. With a full set of location quotients in
space-economy and that they have statistical hand, we computed correlation coeffi-
profiles that conform broadly to theoretical cients representing the spatial association
expectations. That said, we are sharply aware between pairs of four-digit sectors. Then,
that the analyses presented here are char- we used simple cluster analysis in an attempt
acterized by many statistical shortcomings
to identify spatial complexes of industrial
and interpretative ambiguities and that
activity.
further probing of the issues is obviously in
The correlation matrix we worked with
order. In the next section, therefore, we
is large, defined as over 543 different four-
attempt to explore further many of the ideas
digit sectors, and a great many different
we developed earlier with the aid of much
more detailed information on industrial industrial clusters can be extracted from it.
production. This exploration involves, first, In what follows, we focus on one large and
a shift from a provincial geographic base to multifaceted cluster, which dominates the
a more finely grained county base and entire analysis and provides important repre-
second, a search for statistical correlations sentation of both sectoral and spatial
between spatially and functionally related trends in the new Chinese economy (see
sectors. Figure 1). In fact, this dominant cluster
breaks down into two overlapping

Industrial Clusters in Chinese firms identified as being below the township level,
Counties such as those established by villages. In addition,
firms registered at or above the township level
The data set we explored in this phase of include the bulk, if not all, of state-owned and
the investigation consisted of information share-holding enterprises and joint ventures
for 510,381 firms that are defined as inde- between Chinese and overseas investors.
pendent accounting units registered at or Collective-owned enterprises and private- and
above the township level of authority,1 as individual-owned enterprises are less highly
represented in the data set. As such, the data
set is probably biased toward larger firms. In total,
1
The definitional criteria are specific to the the 510,381 firms in the data set accounted for
Chinese industrial statistics system. Firms that 86.2 percent of all firms at or above the township
are independent accounting units are not level.
financed by or ancillary to any other institu- 2
County-level units include counties, county-
tions. Firms are also identified in terms of the level cities, and urban districts of prefecture-level
administrative rank of the places in which they and provincial-level cities. In this article, we refer
are registered. The data set used here excludes to all county-level units as counties.
#9905—ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY—VOL. 79 NO. 3—79304-Fan_Scott
310 ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY JULY 2003

Figure 1. Cluster analysis of establishments in the consumer electronics and garments industries
and the computers, electronic equipment and instruments industries, China, 1995. Figure based on
four-digit data by county from the 1995 Industrial Census provided by the State Statistical Bureau,
People’s Republic of China.

subgroups. The first subgroup is comprised nation, but there is strong prima facie
of consumer electronics and garments evidence, based on our general knowledge
(including cotton knitting) industries, with of how these industries work, that at least
the former breaking further down into some of them are both transactionally inter-
sectors like radios, television sets, cameras, connected and strongly associated with
toys, and clocks; these are among the most one another in geographic terms. In Figures
prominent export-oriented industries in 2 and 3 we map out values of the number of
China. The second subgroup consists of establishments and location quotients for
computers, electronic equipment and instru- establishments in the two subgroups. The
ments industries, including semiconductors agglomerative tendencies of these industries
and medical equipment. Unfortunately, our are clearly evident.
data do not allow us to identify functional The consumer electronics and garments
linkages between the sectors under exami- group is concentrated in the Pearl River
#9905—ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY—VOL. 79 NO. 3—79304-Fan_Scott—Pg. 311

Number of
Establishments Location Quotient
1001-1500 ≥ 4.50
501—1000 3.00—4.49
251—500 1.50—2.99
1—250

Beijing

Tianjin

JIANGSU

Shanghai

ZHEJIANG

FUJIAN

GUANGDONG

Shenzhen
ta

l
De
v er
P e a rl Ri

0 600 km

0 600 mi

Figure 2. Distribution of establishments in the consumer electronics and garments industries by


county, China, 1995. Figure based on four-digit data from the 1995 Industrial Census provided by
the State Statistical Bureau, People’s Republic of China. Note: Counties in which the number of
establishments is less than 0.04 percent of all consumer electronics and garments establishments in
China are excluded.
#9905—ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY—VOL. 79 NO. 3—79304-Fan_Scott—Pg. 312

Number of
Establishments Location Quotient
201-500 ≥ 4.50

101—200 3.00—4.49
51—100 1.50—2.99
1—50

Shenyang

Beijing
Tianjin

Jinan

Xian

Hongyuan
Shanghai

Wuhan
Chongqing

Shenzhen

0 600 km

0 600 mi

Figure 3. Distribution of establishments in the computers, electronic equipment and instruments


industries by county, China, 1995. Figure based on four-digit data from the 1995 Industrial Census
provided by the State Statistical Bureau, People’s Republic of China. Note: Counties in which the
number of establishments is less than 0.04 percent of all computers, electronic equipment and
instruments establishments in China are excluded.
#9905—ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY—VOL. 79 NO. 3—79304-Fan_Scott
VOL. 79 NO. 3 INDUSTRIAL AGGLOMERATION AND DEVELOPMENT 313
Delta, eastern coastal Guangdong and tional policies of the Chinese government
coastal Fujian, Shanghai and nearby areas in promoting the growth of inland cities. In
in southern Jiangsu and northern Zhejiang, addition, the work of Wang and Wang (1998)
and in Beijing and Tianjin and adjacent on the Zhong’guancun high-technology
areas. Industries in this subgroup are char- district adjacent to Beijing University under-
acterized by relatively low capital-labor lines the significance of institutions of higher
ratios, which as we have already shown is a education in helping to anchor agglomera-
sign of the tendency toward locational tions of industries in the second subgroup.
agglomeration. In addition, these industries Beijing’s large number of establishments and
are among the largest export industries in high location quotient again point to the
China, and the Chinese government has important role of institutions of higher
actively reinforced their concentration in the education. This factor appears to be related
Pearl River Delta. These industries are much also to the large number of establishments
favored by overseas Chinese investors, whose in Tianjin and Shanghai.
social ties and networks have helped to boost As we indicated in Table 1, the garments
economic development in the area and electronics and telecommunications
(Chisterson and Lever-Tracy 1997). The industries (at the two-digit level and with
Pearl River Delta has benefited from both provinces as units of observation) are highly
governmental policy and strong social ties concentrated in spatial terms. On the basis
to overseas Chinese investors. The large of our county-level data, we recomputed the
number of adjacent counties with high loca- H-indexes for all industries and again found
tion quotients and/or a large number of that garments and electronics and telecom-
establishments in that area suggests not only munications are close to the top of the
that the industries are spatially concentrated, sectoral rankings. The analysis presented
but also that institutional forces have effec- in Table 4 also suggested that the clustering
tively fostered functional linkages and of these two industries has statistically signif-
agglomeration economies. Similar processes icant effects on their productivity.
appear to have begun in and near Beijing, Specifically, we found that urbanization has
Tianjin, and Shanghai. a positive impact on productivity in the
The computer, electronic equipment and garments sector, and localization has a posi-
instruments subgroup also displays a degree tive impact in electronics and telecommu-
of clustering in the Pearl River Delta, nications. The Chinese space-economy is a
especially in and near Shenzhen, and in areas highly complex one, however, and for
near Shanghai, Beijing, and Tianjin, but some industries spatial concentration does
there are a number of other clusters scat- not necessarily or always lead to unusually
tered throughout the country. In a few high levels of productivity. This seems to be
isolated cases, the high location quotients especially the case in transportation-equip-
observed for this subgroup are a statistical ment manufacturing, which is marked by
artifact resulting from the small total number dense spatial concentration, especially in
of industrial establishments in certain coun- areas around Shiyan in central China,
ties. Hongyuan county in western China, for Changchun in the northeast, and Chongqing
example, has a high location quotient of 10.1 in the southwest, as shown in Figure 4.
but is the location of only six industrial estab- There are undoubtedly some productivity
lishments in total. More important, the many effects in these areas that are due to agglom-
different agglomerations of establishments eration, but these industries were initially
in this subgroup reflect their affinity for large located in these relatively inaccessible places
cities, which, in addition to the cities of the during the Maoist period for political
coastal areas, include Chongqing, Xian, reasons. During the 1950s, the First Auto
Wuhan, Jinan, and Shenyang. This pattern Works was located in Changchun so as to be
can be related, in part, to the combined close to the former Soviet Union (Sit and
effects of market forces and the past loca- Liu 2000). After the Sino-Soviet split and
#9905—ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY—VOL. 79 NO. 3—79304-Fan_Scott—Pg. 314

Number of
Establishments Location Quotient
101-200 ≥ 4.50
Changchun

51—100 3.00—4.49
21—50 1.50—2.99
1—20

Beijing

Tianjin

Shiyan

Wuhan
Chongqing

0 600 km

0 600 mi

Figure 4. Distribution of establishments in the transportation-equipment manufacturing industry by


county, China, 1995. Figure based on four-digit data from the 1995 Industrial Census provided by
the State Statistical Bureau, People’s Republic of China. Note: Counties in which the number of
establishments is less than 0.04 percent of all transportation-equipment manufacturing establish-
ments in China are excluded.
#9905—ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY—VOL. 79 NO. 3—79304-Fan_Scott
VOL. 79 NO. 3 INDUSTRIAL AGGLOMERATION AND DEVELOPMENT 315
because of efforts to build key industries in economies that were formerly dominated by
inland “third front” locations (Naughton central planning, and it highlights, above all,
1988), Shiyan—a remote and inaccessible sectors and spaces that are undergoing
county—was selected as the site of the economic liberalization as those most prone
Second Auto Works and the nation’s first to the formation of agglomeration
independent auto manufacturing complex. economies. China has a mixed economy in
Our statistical analyses (see Table 4) show which socialist legacies exist side by side with
that productivity in the transportation-equip- new developmental forces as a result of
ment sector is statistically related to the market-opening measures and both formal
capital-labor ratio but not to localization or and informal institutions continue to play
urbanization. In fact, new car-manufacturing important roles in shaping the space-
clusters in coastal areas around Shanghai, economy. China’s economic geography
Beijing, and Tianjin have emerged since the was formerly heavily shaped by a socialist
reforms and as market forces have increas- ideology that downplayed agglomeration
ingly driven locational outcomes in this economies. Our empirical analysis identified
industry (Sit and Liu 2000). Similarly, market transportation-equipment manufacturing as
forces underlie the recent trend to diffuse a sector that exhibits a degree of spatial clus-
transportation-equipment manufacturing tering but little in the way of agglomera-
from Shiyan toward Wuhan and other more tion economies and suggests that this situa-
accessible locations. tion may be a legacy of former state
planning. Recent economic liberalization in
China, however, seems to have fostered both
Conclusion the macroeconomic and local conditions
In this article, we have sought to explore under which viable industrial agglomerations
the interconnections between geography and can emerge. During the past two decades,
economic development in the less-devel- the Chinese government has promoted
oped countries of East Asia, paying special labor-intensive industries, mostly for export,
attention to the role of dense industrial and has developed economic zones in which
regions as conduits of productivity effects these industries can flourish. Our empir-
and developmental impulses. We have ical investigations point to a strong rela-
carried out this exploration on the basis of tionship between industrial clustering and
theoretical speculation, appeals to the productivity, especially in industries like
literature, and a series of empirical investi- consumer electronics and garments and
gations focused on the Chinese case. Once computers that have gained prominence
again, we stress that the quality of the data since the government’s drive toward
on which the latter investigations are based economic liberalization, and especially in the
leaves much to be desired. That said, our coastal provinces and large cities. In addi-
multifaceted approach to the central ques- tion to showing that the relationship between
tion appears to point with some plausibility agglomeration and productivity is mediated
to a real connection between agglomeration, in peculiar ways by governmental policies,
on the one side, and economic development both old and new, we have argued that the
and growth, on the other. This outcome is informal social networks that have tradi-
of special interest because it concerns situ- tionally played such a strong role in the
ations that are very different indeed from Chinese economy are also helping to rein-
the usual case-study material found in the force regional patterns of economic devel-
literature, which is generally focused on opment.
developed Western economies. Of course, much additional work is neces-
Our empirical analysis of Chinese indus- sary, not only for its own sake, but also as a
tries supports the argument that a positive prelude to effective policymaking in the
relationship can be found between indus- many and vastly different regional economic
trial agglomeration and productivity in systems (at various levels of development)
#9905—ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY—VOL. 79 NO. 3—79304-Fan_Scott
316 ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY JULY 2003
that are to be found in East Asia in general, Chen, Y. 1996. Impact of regional factors on
and China in particular. The analysis productivity in China. Journal of Regional
presented here, despite its shortcomings, Science 36:417–36.
provides a reasonably convincing precedent Christerson, B., and Lever-Tracy, C. 1997. The
Third China? Emerging industrial districts in
for probing more deeply into the questions
rural China. International Journal of Urban
raised. As we have indicated, there is a strong and Regional Research 21:569–88.
conceptual and empirical case for claiming Cooke, P., and Morgan, K. 1998. The associa-
that locational clustering and economic tional economy: Firms, regions, and innova-
performance are intertwined in complex but tion. Oxford, U.K.: Oxford University Press.
important ways. This research agenda is not Eng, I. 1997. Flexible production in late indus-
only of considerable importance and interest trialization: The case of Hong Kong. Economic
in its own right, but is all the more pressing Geography 73:26–43.
because the insights to be gained offer the Fan, C. C. 1995. Of belts and ladders: State policy
possibility of greatly enhanced policymaking and uneven regional development in post-Mao
China. Annals of the Association of American
and hence of significant economic gains to
Geographers 85:421–49.
particular regions and countries. The stakes ———. 1997. Uneven development and
are especially high in those parts of East Asia beyond: Regional development theory in post-
that are still struggling to attain to world stan- Mao China. International Journal of Urban
dards of industrial production and compet- and Regional Research 21:620–39.
itive advantage and to establish a durable ———. 2001. Migration and labor market
position for themselves on global markets. returns in urban China: Results from a
recent survey in Guangzhou. Environment and
Planning A 33:479–508.
References ———. 2002. The elite, the natives, and the
outsiders: Migration and labor market segmen-
Amin, A. 1999. An institutionalist perspective on
tation in urban China. Annals of the
regional economic development. International
Association of American Geographers
Journal of Urban and Regional Research
92:103–24.
23:365–78.
Fujita, M., and Tabuchi, T. 1997. Regional growth
Amin, A., and Thrift, N. 1995. Institutional issues
in postwar Japan. Regional Science and Urban
for the European regions: From markets and
plans to socioeconomics and powers of asso- Economics 27:643–70.
ciation. Economy and Society 24:41–66. Granovetter, M. 1985. Economic action and social
Beardsell, M., and Henderson, V. 1999. Spatial structure: The problem of embeddedness.
evolution of the computer industry in the USA. American Journal of Sociology 91:481–510.
European Economic Review 43:431–56. Guo, H., and Cai, C. 2000. Network structure:
Bell, M., and Albu, M. 1999. Knowledge systems The organizational model of the sock-making
and technological dynamism in industrial clus- industry in Datang [in Chinese]. Zhejiang
ters in developing countries. World Economy (Zhejiang Jingji) 9:16–17.
Development 27:1715–34. Hamilton, G. 1991. Business networks and
Bonacich, E., and Appelbaum, R. 2000. Behind economic development in East and Southeast
the label: Inequality in the Los Angeles apparel Asia. Hong Kong: Center of Asia Studies.
industry. Berkeley: University of California Harrison, B. 1992. Industrial districts: Old wine
Press. in new bottles. Regional Studies 26:469–83.
Carlino, G. A. 1979. Increasing returns to scale Henderson, J. V. 1986. Efficiency of resource
in metropolitan manufacturing. Journal of usage and city size. Journal of Urban
Regional Science 19:363–73. Economics 19:47–70.
Chang, P.-L., and Hsu, C.-W. 1998. The devel- ———. 1988. Urban development: Theory, fact,
opment strategies for Taiwan’s semiconductor and illusion. New York: Oxford University
industry. IEEE Transactions on Engineering Press.
Management 45:349–56. Hirschman, A. O. 1958. The strategy of economic
Chen, W.-H. 1999. Manufacturing strategies of development. New Haven, Conn.: Yale
network-based small firms: Observations on University Press.
the textile industry in Taiwan. Journal of Small Ho, K. C. 1994. Industrial restructuring, the
Business Management 37:46–62. Singapore city-state, and the regional divi-
#9905—ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY—VOL. 79 NO. 3—79304-Fan_Scott
VOL. 79 NO. 3 INDUSTRIAL AGGLOMERATION AND DEVELOPMENT 317
sion of labour. Environment and Planning A turing in the Pearl River Delta, China.
26:33–51. Urban Studies 38:383–406.
Hodgson, G. M. 1988. Economics and institu- Lipton, M. 1977. Why poor people stay poor: A
tions. Cambridge, U.K.: Polity Press. study of urban bias in world development.
Hsing, Y. 1995. Taiwanese guerilla investors in London: Temple Smith.
southern China. Review of Urban and Regional Liu, S.-J. 1998. Industrial development and struc-
Studies 7:24–34. tural adaptation in Taiwan: Some issues of
———. 1996. Blood thicker than water: learned entrepreneurship. IEEE Transactions
Interpersonal relation and Taiwanese invest- on Engineering Management 45:338–48.
ment in southern China. Environment and Markusen, A. R.; Lee, Y.-S.; and DiGiovanna, S.,
Planning A 28:2241–61. eds. 1999. Second tier cities: Rapid growth
———. 1998. Making capitalism in China: The beyond the metropolis. Minneapolis: University
Taiwan connection. New York: Oxford of Minnesota Press.
University Press. Markusen, A., and Park, S. O. 1993. The state
Huang, Y. 1999. Shiyan: A factory in the wilder- as industrial locator and district builder: The
ness, 1968 false alarm. Time International case of Changwon, South Korea. Economic
154:78. Geography 69:157–81.
Jacobs, J. 1969. The economy of cities. New York: Marshall, A. 1890. Principles of economics.
Random House. London: Macmillan.
Johansson, H., and Nilsson, L. 1997. Export ———. 1919. Industry and trade: A study of
processing zones as catalysts. World industrial technique and business organiza-
Development 25:2115–28. tion. London: Macmillan.
Kaldor, N. 1970. The case for regional policies. McGee, T. G. 1991. The emergence of desakota
Scottish Journal of Political Economy regions in Asia: Expanding a hypothesis. In
17:337–48. The extended metropolis: Settlement transition
Kanemoto, Y.; Ohkawara, T.; and Suzuki, T. 1996. in Asia, ed. N. Ginsburg, B. Koppel, and T. G.
Agglomeration economies and a test for McGee, 3–25. Honolulu: University of Hawaii
optimal city sizes in Japan. Journal of the Press.
Japanese and International Economies Myrdal, G. 1959. Economic theory and under-
10:379–98. developed regions. London: Gerald
Kawashima, T. 1975. Urban agglomeration Duckworth.
economies in manufacturing industries. Papers Nadvi, K., and Schmitz, H. 1994. Industrial clus-
of the Regional Science Association 34:157–75. ters in less developed countries: Review of expe-
Krugman, P. 1991. Geography and trade, Gaston riences and research agenda. Discussion Paper
Eyskens lecture series. Leuven, Belgium: No. 339. Brighton, U.K.: Institute of
Leuven University Press. Development Studies, University of Sussex.
Lampard, E. E. 1955. The history of cities in Nakamura, R. 1985. Agglomeration economies
economically advanced areas. Economic in urban manufacturing industries: A case of
Development and Cultural Change 3:81–102. Japanese cities. Journal of Urban Economics
Lee, Y. J., and Zang, H. 1998. Urbanization and 17:108–24.
regional productivity in Korean manufacturing. Naughton, B. 1988. The third front: Defense
Urban Studies 35:2085–99. industrialization in the Chinese interior. China
Leung, C. K. 1993. Personal contacts, subcon- Quarterly 115:351–86.
tracting linkages, and development in the Olds, K. 2001. Globalization and urban change:
Hong Kong-Zhujiang Delta region. Annals of Capital, culture, and Pacific Rim mega-
the Association of American Geographers projects. Oxford, U.K.: Oxford University
83:272–302. Press.
———. 1996. Foreign manufacturing invest- Park, S. O. 1991. High-technology industries in
ment and regional industrial growth in Korea: Spatial linkages and policy implications.
Guangdong Province, China. Environment and Geoforum 22:421–31.
Planning A 28:513–36. ———. 1993. Industrial restructuring and
Levy, B. 1991. Transactions costs, the size of firms spatial division of labor: The case of the
and industrial policy. Journal of Development Seoul metropolitan region, the Republic of
Economics 34:151–78. Korea. Environment and Planning A 25:81–93.
Lin, G. C. S. 2001. Metropolitan development in ———. 1994. Industrial restructuring in the
a transitional socialist economy: Spatial restruc- Seoul metropolitan region: Major triggers and
#9905—ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY—VOL. 79 NO. 3—79304-Fan_Scott
318 ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY JULY 2003
consequences. Environment and Planning A income countries. Third World Quarterly
26:527–41. 23:137–61.
———. 1996. Networks and embeddedness in Shefer, D. 1973. Localization economies in
the dynamic types of new industrial districts. SMSAs: A production function analysis.
Progress in Human Geography 20:476–93. Journal of Regional Science 13:55–64.
Patchell, J. 1993. Composing robot production Shieh, G. S. 1990. Manufacturing “bosses”:
systems: Japan as a flexible manufacturing Subcontracting network under dependent capi-
system. Environment and Planning A talism in Taiwan. Unpublished Ph.D. disser-
25:923–44. tation, University of California, Berkeley.
Peck, J. 1992. Labor and agglomeration: Control Shukla, V. 1996. Urbanization and economic
and flexibility in local labor markets. Economic growth. Delhi: Oxford University Press.
Geography 68:325–47. Sit, V. F. S., and Liu, W. 2000. Restructuring and
Perroux, F. 1961. L’Economie du XXe siecle. Paris: spatial change of China’s auto industry under
Presses Universitaires de France. institutional reform and globalization. Annals
Poot, H.; Kuyvenhoven, A.; and Jansen, J. 1990. of the Association of American Geographers
Industrialization and trade in Indonesia. 90:653–73.
Yogyakarta, Indonesia: Gadjah Mada Smart, A. 2000. The emergence of local capi-
University Press. talisms in China: Overseas Chinese investment
Porter, M. E. 2001. Regions and the new and patterns of development. In China’s
economics of competition. In Global city regions, polity, and economy: A study of spatial
regions: Trends, theory, policy, ed. A. J. Scott, transformation in the post-reform era, ed. S.
139–57. Oxford, U.K.: Oxford University Press. Li and W. Tang, 65–95. Hong Kong: Chinese
Rasiah, R. 1994. Flexible production systems and University Press.
local machine-tool subcontracting: Electronics Smyth, I. 1992. Collective efficiency and selec-
components transnationals in Malaysia. tive benefits: The growth of the rattan industry
Cambridge Journal of Economics 18:279–98. of Tegalwangi (Indonesia). IDS Bulletin
Sandee, H. 1995. Innovation adoption in rural 23:51–56.
industry: Technological change in roof tile clus- Storper, M. 1997. The regional world: Territorial
ters in Central Java, Indonesia. Unpublished development in a global economy. New York:
doctoral dissertation, Vrije Universiteit, Guilford Press.
Amsterdam. Storper, M., and Scott, A. J. 1995. The wealth
Sandee, H., and Rietveld, P. 2001. Upgrading of regions. Futures 27:505–26.
traditional technologies in small-scale industry Sunley, P. 1996. Context in economic geography:
clusters: Collaboration and innovation adop- The relevance of pragmatism. Progress in
tion in Indonesia. Journal of Development Human Geography 20:338–55.
Studies 37:150–172. Sveikauskas, L. 1975. The productivity of cities.
Sandee, H.; Rietveld, P.; Supratikno, H.; and Quarterly Journal of Economics 89:393–413.
Yowono, P. 1994. Promoting small scale and Tang, H. K. 1996. Hollowing-out or international
cottage industries in Indonesia: An impact division of labour? Perspective from the
analysis for Central Java. Research consumer electronics industry and Singapore.
Memorandum 1994-10, Amsterdam: International Journal of Technology
Department of Economics and Econometrics, Management 12:231–41.
Vrije Universiteit. Tong, X., and Wang, J. 2002. Global-local
Scott, A. J. 1987. The semiconductor industry networking of PC manufacturing in Dongguan,
in South-East Asia: Organization, location and China. In Knowledge, industry and environ-
the international division of labour. Regional ment: Institutions and innovation in territo-
Studies 21:143–60. rial perspective, ed. R. Hayter and R. Le Heron,
———. 1988. Metropolis: From the division of 67–86. London: Ashgate.
labor to urban form. Berkeley: University of Tsay, C.-L. 1993. Industrial restructuring and
California Press. international competition in Taiwan.
———. 1994. Variations on the theme of Environment and Planning A 25:111–20.
agglomeration and growth: The gem and Wang, J. 2001. Innovative spaces: Enterprise clus-
jewelry industry in Los Angeles and Bangkok. ters and regional development [in Chinese].
Geoforum 25:249–63. Beijing: Peking University Press.
———. 2002. Regional push: The geography of Wang, J., and Wang, J. 1998. An analysis of
development and growth in low- and middle- new-tech agglomeration in Beijing: A new
#9905—ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY—VOL. 79 NO. 3—79304-Fan_Scott
VOL. 79 NO. 3 INDUSTRIAL AGGLOMERATION AND DEVELOPMENT 319
industrial district in the making? Environment Yeung, H. W., and Olds, K. 2000. Globalizing
and Planning A 30:681–701. Chinese business firms: Where are they
Weijland, H. 1999. Microenterprise clusters in coming from, where are they heading? In
rural Indonesia: Industrial seedbed and policy
target. World Development 27:1515–30. Globalization of Chinese business firms, ed.
Wong, T.-C., and Goldblum, C. 2000. The China- H. W.-c. Yeung and K. Olds, 1–28. London:
Singapore Suzhou Industrial Park: A turnkey Macmillan.
product of Singapore? Geographical Review Yuan, J., and Eden, L. 1992. Export processing
90:112–22. zones in Asia: A comparative study. Asian
Xue, L. 1997. Promoting industrial R&D and
Survey 32:1026–45.
high-tech development through science parks:
The Taiwan experience and its implications Yuen, B. 1991. Planning and development of
for developing countries. International Journal industrial estates in Singapore. Third World
of Technology Management 13:744–61. Planning Review 13:47–68.
Conditions of use: This article may be downloaded from the
Economic Geography website for personal research by
members of subscribing organizations. This PDF may not
be placed on any website without permission of the
publisher, Clark University.

You might also like