You are on page 1of 8

Special articles

Globalisation and Inequality


An Analytical Perspective
With the possible exception of the east Asian countries, increased foreign trade and investment
have increased wage inequality in almost all parts of the globe during the last two decades of
the 20th century. Theoretically as well as empirically Heckscher-Ohlin-Samuelson model of
trade, with the Stolper-Samuelson result at its core, fails to explain such widening of wage
gap between skilled and unskilled labour particularly in the south. This paper discusses
alternative variants of the specific factor model accounting for the diverse trade pattern,
informal factor markets and existence of non-traded goods, that can help our
understanding of the wage gap phenomenon.
RAJAT ACHARYYA, SUGATA MARJIT

T
o have the world at your doorstep research work has been devoted to this poor. There are plenty of such examples
is quite exciting. The most visible aspect [Bhagwati 1995; Davis 1998; that prove that the issue of inequality is
part of such a contact is the over- Feenstra and Hanson 1995; Jones and far more complex than the standardisation
whelming proliferation of cable channels Engerman 1996; Leamer 1995; Wood 1997]. of the problem in terms of the relative wage
in our TV sets. Our access to world news, Inequality is a complex phenomenon of the unskilled. However, it is also im-
information regarding the consumption and trade and labour economists have portant to recognise that the absolute real
standards worldwide, our exposure to reduced it to the minimum dimension of income of the unskilled should be a crucial
technological changes, encounter with the abstraction by focusing on the ratio of category along with their relative position
websites, etc, get increasingly interwoven unskilled to skilled wage rate and/or in the economy. Substantial improvement
with our lifestyle. Virtual distance between employment. Also the issue of poverty and in the real income of poor workers can
us and any point in the globe has been inequality is far more important for the definitely compensate for the rise in in-
drastically reduced with far-reaching im- developing countries both because of the equality. One purpose of this paper is to
plications for international trade, invest- alarming and overwhelming proportion of deal with these two categories in terms of
ment, income, employment and growth. the population living below the poverty analytical structures that substantially alter
These in turn have effects on more desir- line (however measured) in these nations the standard trade theoretic results.
able yardstick of development, poverty and also because inequality by halting As it always happens, inequality had to
and inequality. We think that the term growth usually leads to the self-perpetu- grow in the developed world to make trade
globalisation, as is popularly used, defines ation of a low-level equilibrium [Banerji and inequality a hot topic of research.
a process of integration with the rest of and Newman 1993; Gal-Or and Zeira Historically the argument favouring free
the world. Such integration is routed 1993]. The agony of being stuck at a low trade has always been packaged with the
through increasing volume of foreign trade level equilibrium is what distinguishes the idea of compensation and redistribution to
and investment. The major task of an south from the north. Having only an old make everyone better off through trade.
economist is to work out the welfare car in a world where everyone else owns Theoretically, exposure to international
implications of such a transformation both a top-of-the-line Mercedes may be psycho- trade benefits factors used intensively in
from aggregate and distributive perspec- logically as painful as starving to death the export sector. If these factors are at the
tives. In regard to the distributive effect, while everyone else enjoys a lavish dinner. lower end of inequality, degree of inequal-
in particular, economists in the However, in the latter example someone ity must get reduced through trade. This
industrialised world are worried over a dies whereas in the former the choice to is the cornerstone of the neoclassical trade
noticeable empirical phenomenon that survive physically is always there. It is also theory, technically known as the Stolper-
suggests a considerable decline in the possible that a marginal increase in real Samuelson (SS) result. If the US or Europe
income of unskilled labour and/or a de- income from the subsistence level does a have abundance of physical capital and/
cline in their employment relative to the lot of good even when a richer person or skilled workers and their trade pattern
more skilled segment of the workforce. increases her income far more substan- with the rest of the world follows
This has happened in the US and in Europe tially. An alternative scenario, with lower Heckscher-Ohlin, we can expect concen-
over the last 20 years and has roughly income for the rich and no change in income tration of unskilled workers in their im-
coincided with the buoyant phase of inter- for the poor, may improve the Gini coef- port-competing sectors and consequently
national trade and investment. Substantial ficient but does not do anything for the freer trade must make these workers worse

Economic and Political Weekly September 23, 2000 3503


off both in absolute and relative terms. we set out to do. It has to do with what trade and regional concentration or diver-
This is precisely the argument of the trade is the most likely outcome of liberalising sifications have not received much atten-
theorists linking Mexico-US trade and the trade if one is concerned with the real tion from trade theorists. However, no
formation of NAFTA with the observed income of the poor workers, particularly such attempt will be made in this paper
widening wage gap. If the poor gets poorer in an economy which exhibits large agri- though this is certainly on our future re-
through trade, inequality is likely to grow. cultural sector, pockets of economic sophi- search agenda.
In fact, one complaint has been that the stication, possibly dualism, large informal This paper has four sections. Section I
blue collared workers in the rich countries labour markets, non-traded activities, capi- summarises the country experiences with
have been increasingly exposed to fierce tal constraint, etc. Such proliferation of trade, wage distribution, poverty and
competition from the Asian and Latin concerns sounds far too complex for an inequality. This part of the analysis is
American exports and therefore it is experiment with the SS type result in a basically informative and is not at all
natural that poverty and inequality will general equilibrium framework. But as we exhaustive partly because no such analysis
grow as an inevitable fallout of the process argue, between the vintage two-sector is available and partly because the focus
of globalisation. Heckscher-Ohlin structure and a multi- of this paper is theoretical. Section II is
The competing view of wage inequality, sector analytically unsolvable general devoted to an overview of the neoclassical
however, tends to contain the backlash on equilibrium model lies the possibility of trade theoretic results at the frontier of
freer trade and argues that technological constructing something meaningful, of research, which may help our understand-
change that depends increasingly on skilled course more transparent to people who ing of the issue of trade and wage gap. In
workforce must reduce the relative de- appreciate theory, but not less interesting Section III we elaborate a theoretical re-
mand for the unskilled. Hence, technology to a wide range of economists. In some of search agenda that explicitly focus on the
and not trade is the real culprit. These our recent work we have tried to make pattern of trade, labour markets and im-
issues are summarised in Wood (1995). serious efforts in this respect and we will perfections in a typical developing
present a bird’s-eye view of these models economy.
Developing Country Scenario [Acharyya and Marjit 1999; Marjit 1997;
Marjit et al 1997, Marjit and Acharyya I
Generally speaking not much attention 2000]. Wage Inequality: Empirical
has been devoted to the analysis of Before going to the next section, it should Evidences
globalisation and inequality in the devel- be mentioned that the regional dimension
oping countries. Of course, we do not of trade and inequality has been a major Despite asymmetries in the extent of
undermine the recent works of Robbins research topic for economists working on changes in relative wages of skilled and
(1994, 1995, 1996a, 1996b) and Wood various aspects of the European Union. A unskilled workers, the experiences of the
(1997) and their empirical findings that different type of research is needed to high and low/middle income countries are
point towards growing wage inequality in assess the impact of globalisation on inter- more or less similar. Except for the east
the southern hemisphere. What bothers us regional disparity in a big country like Asian countries, the general trend that has
is the thin list of theoretical possibilities India. Should we expect that trading ac- been observed is an increase in the ratio
that are grounded in an antiquated dem- cording to comparative advantage would of skilled to unskilled wages, i e, a wid-
onstration of the Stolper-Samuelson re- lead to the convergence of economic well- ening wage gap between skilled and un-
sult. Moreover, an apathy towards having being of the Indian states? Such a dimen- skilled workers, in most part of the globe
a closer look at the labour markets of the sion of inequality is noticeably absent in since 1970s. In Europe, where national
developing countries and a casual treatment countries such as Singapore, Hong Kong institutions have a particularly strong in-
of the trade theory, ignoring the possibili- and Taiwan. In India regional disparity, fluence on wage settings, the deterioration
ties that lie underneath the surface, means imbalances and promotion of backward of the relative position of the relatively
committing the theory to conclusions which states and regions have been highlighted unskilled workers is reflected in rising
are only artefacts of weak theorisation. in the context of the devolution of fiscal unemployment.
This is what this paper tries to avoid and power between the centre and the states. Over the 1970s although the US economy
for this purpose we suggest models that A small but growing literature has been became considerably open, the premium
can be used in the applied work instead dealing with these issues for a while mainly earned by educated workers actually de-
of the straitjacket application of the Stolper- handling the divergence of per capita net clined. The situation has changed drasti-
Samuelson (SS) result. state domestic product (PCNSDP) in the cally from the 1980s onwards as the real
Empirical methodology which illumi- post-independence period [Ghosh et al wages have stagnated and relative wages
nates our view regarding trade and wage 1998; Nagaraj et al 1997]. Little analysis have become more dispersed. These have
inequality is extremely difficult to imple- is available on how different regions have been accompanied by dramatic increase in
ment in an aggregative study because one performed in the post-reform period. One inequality of earnings based on education,
has to control for many variables that intriguing statistical evidence is that the experience and occupation. For example,
determine the degree of inequality. Con- coefficient of variation in PCNSDP does as observed by Bound and Johnson (1992),
trolling for other explanatory factors also have positive correlation with the open- the ratio of the average wage of a college
means that one is more or less certain about ness index for the entire post-indepen- graduate to the average wage of a high
the mechanism, which determines the dence period. Such a correlation increased school graduate rose by 15 per cent. Reich
nature of such partial dependence of in- substantially during the post-reform pe- (1991) put it more strongly: global com-
equality on trade and investment. Explor- riod. Except some recent works by Krugman petition has bifurcated American workers
ing such a mechanism rigorously is what (1997) and Deardorff and Courant (1992), into two groups, the high-earning ‘sym-

3504 Economic and Political Weekly September 23, 2000


bolic analysts’ whose talents are rewarded The studies by Robbins covering Argen- between 1985 and 1987. The wage gap
by globalisation and the mass of ordinary tina, Chile, Colombia, Costa Rica, Mexico between non-production and production
production workers whose earnings are and Uruguay, reveal widening of the skill workers in manufacturing, on the other
dispersed by it. differentials in wages (by the level of edu- hand, widened during 1984-90 [Feenstra
Another influential work in this regard cation) in almost all these countries con- and Hanson 1995].
much cited by economists as well as by trary to conventional wisdom. The indices For east Asia the empirical findings
the media is that of Borjas, Freeman and for wages, the weighted averages across available so far point towards declining
Katz (1992). But their conclusion was not sex and experience, and the ratio of wage inequality. Except in case of Hong Kong,
very encouraging for the supporters of the of workers with secondary level education the wage gap declined in Korea and Taiwan
trade-wage gap nexus. The trade flows are to that of workers with primary level of during the 1960s and in Singapore during
observed to explain at most 15 per cent education as reported by Robbins are clear 1970s. In all these three cases, according
of the 12.4 per cent increase in the earnings indication of the widening wage gap to Wood (1997), changes in trade regime
differential between college educated phenomenon. Pederson (1998) corrobo- were partly responsible. On the other hand,
workers and their high school educated rates the findings of Robbins for Chile by he attributes the widening wage gap in
counterparts between 1980 and 1988. reporting a study that shows that during Hong Kong to the large increase in the
Bhagwati and Dahejia (1998), however, the 1980s the ratio of the wage of the relative supply of unskilled labour instead
challenges this work on a more theoreti- university graduates to high school gradu- of trade policy change. However, the major
cally legitimate ground. Borjas et al, miss ates went up by 56 per cent. On the con- problem with the empirical exercise, as
the central point in their analysis that trary, however, Meller (1998) finds the pointed out by Wood himself, is that the
international trade must affect commodity white-blue wage differentials going down data on relative wages suffers from gaps
prices in the desired direction before between 1984 and 1992. and deficiencies. Moreover, while finding
anything can be inferred about the trade- There are also some empirically observed the relationship between trade and wage
wage gap nexus. But as observed by strong associations between trade gap, only few analyses have attempted to
Bhagwati (1995) and by Lawrence and liberalisation and widening wage gap as control for the internal influences on the
Slaughter (1993), commodity prices have shown in Table 1. Except in cases of second movement of relative wages.
changed in the opposite direction to that phase liberalisation programmes in Ar- Similar to the experience of the three
required for the SS explanation. Leamer gentina and in Chile, the wage gap has tigers, Robbins (1994) finds persistent
(1995), on the other hand, has stressed that widened with reduction of trade barriers. compression of wage differentials by the
some relative prices of US import com- In Chile average tariff rates were reduced level of education in Malaysia from 1973-
peting goods have indeed fallen during from over 100 per cent prior to 1975 to 89 particularly between university gradu-
this period, especially those for textiles 11 per cent by 1979. ates and educated workers. This went on
and apparel. Openness rose from about 20 to 55 per in the early 1990s with the skilled and
The case of Europe is altogether differ- cent during 1970-90. Though during semi-skilled blue collar workers in manu-
ent. With national institutions having a 1976-89, the period of study of Robbins facturing sector gaining relative to others.
strong influence on wage setting there, the (1995), Colombia did not liberalise its However, despite the increasing openness
important issue is the degree to which such trade regime significantly, its currency from a high initial level of 70 per cent in
institutional and regulatory forces repressed was devalued over 60 per cent between 1970 to nearly 100 per cent in 1983 and
wage adjustments and instead raised un- 1985 and 1989. The openness index there then to 150 per cent by 1992, and shift in
employment. The strongest bastion of the hovered around 25 per cent. In almost all demand in favour of less skilled workers
European Monetary Union (EMU), Ger- these cases the relative demand for skilled within industries because of trade related
many, has exhibited significant unemploy- workers has been found to be rising im- changes in product mix, Robbins (1994)
ment rates and the root cause has often plying a possible trade-wage gap nexus. denies the role of trade openness in such
been cited to be rigid labour laws and Mexico is another example where skilled- a decline in the wage gap. The relative
social safety net contributions of the unskilled wage gap increased in parallel growth in the number of highly educated
employer. Whereas the workers out of job with radical trade liberalisation. The tariffs workers is what he ascribed as the pri-
for more than a year accounted for just 6.3 were reduced there by 45 per cent and mary factor behind the compression of the
per cent of total unemployment in the US, import licences by more than 75 per cent wage gap.
the share was typically about 40 per cent
Table 1: Effects of Increased Openness in Latin American Countries
in Germany, France, the UK and Italy.
However, Lawrence (1994) has reported Country and Years Changes in Trade Skill Differentials Relative Demand
that between 1978 and 1988, the ratio of Reform in Wages for Skill

manual to non-manual wages fell by 8.1 Argentina


per cent in Germany and by 3 per cent in 1967-82 Barrier reduction with appreciation Widened Rising
1989-93 Barrier reduction with appreciation Narrowed Falling
Italy whereas they actually increased in Chile
Belgium and Denmark. According to the 1974-79 Barrier reduction with devaluation Widened Rising
OECD Employment Outlook (1993), on 1984-92 Devaluation Fluctuated Rising
Colombia (1985-94) Devaluation till 1989, barrier reduction
the other hand, there was a substantial during 1990-92 Widened Rising
increase in the ratio of earnings of the Costa Rica (1985-93) Barrier reduction and devaluation Widened except
highest to lowest percentiles in the UK. during 1988-90 Rising
Uruguay 1990-95 Barrier reduction Widened Rising
Similar was the finding of Katz, Loveman
and Blanchflower (1992). Source: As reported in Wood (1997).

Economic and Political Weekly September 23, 2000 3505


The case of Philippines is less transparent the impact of a more open trade environ- factor supply or endowment base of the
during its modest liberalisation episode ment since there may be several factors country can be accommodated through
(1978-88). Skill differentials in wages affecting demand and supply of labour. changes only in the composition of out-
widened during severe recession in 1982- But it is a convenient starting point. puts. Thus no changes in factor prices and
86, but then narrowed again [Robbins consequently in factor intensities are needed
1994]. II to clear the domestic factor markets. This
The evidence in south Asia is not very Standard Trade Theory often misunderstood one-to-one correspon-
systematic. Though any comprehensive dence between commodity prices and factor
empirical study is yet to come by, some The wage determination process in a prices, given the state of the technology,
casual empiricism points out widening trading economy is important in under- holds the centre-stage of the HOS model
wage gap in south Asia including India. standing the relationship between trade and the wage gap debate.2 In particular,
The impact of the so-called globalisation liberalisation and the wage gap. As neatly when Pi is the weighted average of all
in this region is studied from a broader summarised in Jones and Engerman (1996), commodity price changes, in absence of
perspective of employment, growth and in any general equilibrium (GE) model any no money illusion, equation 1 boils
poverty by Dev (2000), Khan (1998) and factor prices are influenced by commodity down to
Tendulkar et al (1996). The employment prices, factor endowments and technol-
scenario, according to Dev (2000), is ogy. If Pi, Ei and Ti denote effects of w^ i = Σj βj ^pj ...(2)
encouraging enough at the aggregate level changes in commodity prices, in endow- Therefore, for a trading economy, the wages
though not so much at a more disaggregate ment or factor supply base and in technol- are uniquely determined from outside, no
level in the post-liberalisation era. On the ogy respectively, then the relative change matter how small or large the volume of
other hand, Khan (1998) finds that the in price of factor i is given as, trade is, given the technology. Recently,
process of expansion in foreign trade and ^ =P + E + T Leamer (1995) has put it in a different way:
wi i i i ...(1)
investment in south Asian countries is even though trade dependence, volume of
consistent with rising incidence of poverty where wi denotes proportional change in trade as a proportion of GDP, is low in
in these nations. Typically, if poverty is money wage. the US, the existence of the apparel indus-
really on the rise then it must worsen the The important point to understand in this try means that wage of the unskilled worker
inequality situation. context is that any other factors, such as in the US is determined in Shanghai.
Although no systematic study on wage trade deficit or surplus, volumes of trade Another important characteristic of the
dispersion caused by trade liberalisation and the like, cannot affect factor prices wage-price relationship in equation 2 is the
in India is available, there is one interest- independent of Pi, Ei and Ti.1 magnification effect as we will demon-
ing piece of evidence that points to grow- The effects of these three terms in equa- strate later in the context of a 2x2 HOS
ing wage inequality in the post-reform tion 1 on wages, however, depend on the model with no joint production. This is the
period. In Table 2 we look at the range of number of goods versus the number of essence of the much celebrated Stolper-
wages for the lowest daily paid unskilled factors. An economy consuming m goods Samuelson (SS) theorem and is reflected
workers in the organised sectors for the and having n factors of production, will in the fact that at least one βj is greater
periods 1985-86 and 1993-94. Since the produce only n goods, when m > n, at a than unity and another is negative [Jones
process of economic reforms started in given set of world commodity prices. The and Engerman 1996:36]. Thus the factor
1991-92, we use these two periods as pre- (m – n) remaining goods will be imported price changes are more than proportionate
reform and post-reform data points respec- entirely. The even case, number of goods to commodity price changes.
tively. Note that for all states there is equal to number of factors, describe the Does the unique relationship in equa-
substantial difference between the maxi- HOS scenario whereas m < n describes the tion 2 mean that any increase in the ratio
mum and minimum value for both periods. specific factor model a la Jones (1971). In of skilled and unskilled workers in the
If we assume perfect labour mobility within both the even and the m > n cases, the economy over time, for example, through
the states, this looks a bit awkward. The unique result is that Ei = 0. That is, at given education and training, has no impact on
only meaningful explanation is that the commodity prices, factor prices are the wage gap? The answer depends on the
data is available at some level of aggre- uniquely determined and any change in importance of the economy in the world
gation and part of the differential possibly
Table 2: Range of Minimum Wages for Lowest Daily Paid Unskilled Workers in
captures productivity or skill gap even Organised Sectors
among the unskilled. Of course, there may (in Rupees)
be cost of living differences as well. 1985-86 1993-94
Whatever be the case, what is striking is Central/ Minimum Maximum Range/ Minimum Maximum Range/
the difference in the extent of the gap State Government Min Wage Min Wage
between the maximum and minimum wage Central 8.50 12.75 0.50 19.82 37.37 0.88
over the two periods. This difference or Andhra Pradesh 7.00 18.00 1.57 11.00 40.00 2.60
range as a proportion of minimum wage Bihar 8.50 8.50 0.00 16.00 26.24 0.64
has increased by more than seven times for Kerala 12.00 15.00 0.25 19.50 75.40 2.86
Maharashtra 6.00 10.00 0.66 11.00 64.00 4.80
Maharashtra, 15 times for Tamil Nadu and Punjab 14.00 16.44 0.17 41.50 41.50 0.00
uniformly for other states except Punjab. Tamil Nadu 8.00 11.00 0.38 8.00 49.20 5.15
The average was about 0.48 in 1985-86 Uttar Pradesh 8.00 9.50 0.18 18.00 42.00 1.33
West Bengal 7.29 10.15 0.39 7.76 45.00 4.79
and more than 2 in 1993-94. Such wid-
ening of the gap does not necessarily reflect Source: Annual Report 1993-94, Ministry of Labour, Government of India.

3506 Economic and Political Weekly September 23, 2000


market. With full sectoral factor mobility, contracting Y sector. Hence, the unskilled both the counts we have seen that the
such changes in factor endowment must money wage increases whereas the skilled standard HOS model or its variants fail to
affect the world commodity prices first in money wage declines. corroborate the empirical findings. One
order to influence the wages. If the country However, we can expect something more important property of the HOS model as
is small enough to affect the commodity than just these changes in the absolute explained above is the independence of
prices, there would certainly be no changes prices. An appeal to the SS theorem in- wages from endowments of skilled and
in wages. Otherwise, with the output dicates that freer trade causes the real unskilled workers. Any changes in such
composition changing, the world relative wage to increase and the real return to factor supplies can affect wages only
price of skill-intensive commodity will fall capital fall [Caves et al 1996]: through changes in world commodity prices
through consequent excess supply. Ac- ^ ^ ^ ^ and that too when the country is an im-
cordingly, given equation 2, the relative w > PX > 0 > PY > wS ...(4) portant trader in the world market. In terms
wages change. This is essentially a restatement of the of our discussion in Section II above this
But changes in factor supplies will have price magnification effect implied by means for a small open economy (or as a
a direct influence on factor returns when equation 2. It is to be noted that unskilled matter fact, for given world prices), Ei = 0.
the number of factors is greater than the workers gain through trade. But the findings of Robbins (1996a) of
number of goods (m < n). Thus, in a Conversely, in the foreign country a strong domestic supply impact on relative
specific factor model, Ei ≠ 0. similar argument leads to, wages in Colombia suggest forces incon-
Having such understanding of wage ^ ^ ^ ^ sistent with this property of the HOS model.
determination process in the standard trade wS* > PY* > 0 > PX* > w* ...(5) As pointed out earlier, in the specific
theoretic general equilibrium models, let That is, free trade makes foreign skilled factor model of trade where the number
us now turn to the explanation of the wage workers better off and unskilled workers of factors of production is greater than the
gap phenomenon. The cornerstone of the worse off. number of traded goods, the endowment
trade theorists’ argument on the link be- What the above price magnification base of the economy has direct influence
tween trade liberalisation and widening effects or the (generalised) SS theorem on wages. It may appear obvious then to
wage gap is the HOS model and the Stolper- indicate is that trade liberalisation causes presuppose better applicability of such a
Samuelson theorem. But the problem with the wage gap to change asymmetrically in model on the basis of the findings of
such an argument is that simultaneous the two countries. Therefore, the HOS Robbins (1996a). But the specific factor
widening of wage gap in the trading na- model with the SS theorem at its core does model too, unless modified, cannot explain
tions cannot be justified theoretically not take us very far in explaining the more the symmetric changes, in the wage gap
though observed empirically. To fix idea, or less similar income distributional ef- in the trading nations. The main problem
suppose in a two country, two commodity fects of free trade observed in the north with these standard theories is their failure
framework the home country exports good and in the south. to capture the diverse trade pattern that the
X, i e, it has a comparative advantage in There is one exception, however, of the developing nations are showing up in their
good X, indicated by the lower relative above asymmetric effect when production export baskets of late, and the institutional
price of good X: technology exhibits factor intensity rever- characteristics specific to them. Our on-
sal (FIR). But this is an exception rather going theoretical research indicates that
pa < pa* ...(3)
than a rule. Another plausible case is where inclusion of trade in intermediate goods
Whatever may be the source of such countries produce similar as well as dif- in a variant of the specific factor model
comparative advantage or price differences, ferent goods such that the relatively skill- may generate symmetric changes in factor
through arbitrage (buying cheap and sell- intensive good in one country is not so prices. On the other hand, pecularities such
ing dear) and consequent physical move- skill-intensive in the other. In a three as exporting both skill-intensive manufac-
ments of goods across national borders, commodity setting, for example, if coun- turing and unskilled labour intensive ag-
the domestic prices will eventually be tries completely specialise in the most and ricultural products, coexistence of
equalised thereby stopping any further least skill-intensive commodities with the organised and informal labour markets and
movements of goods. Thus, the relative moderately skill-intensive commodity the production of goods that are not (or
price of good X rises in the home country produced in common, symmetric changes cannot be) traded, are capable of explain-
and falls in the foreign country. in wage gap can be obtained.3 ing the relationship between openness and
How are the factor prices expected to wage-gap in the south. In the rest of the
change consequent upon such commodity III paper we sketch a theoretical structure
price movements? Suppose the home Alternative Theoretical incorporating these features to highlight
exportables are relatively unskilled labour- Framework the trade and widening wage gap nexus.
intensive. As the relative price of ex-
portables increases, the production of the Trade Pattern
From the empirical evidence cited in
import-competing good Y contracts and Section I it is immediate that for the trade Of late, the trade pattern of the devel-
that of the exportable good X increases. theorists the task at hand is twofold. The oping countries as reflected in their export
The consequent resource reallocation leads first is to generate more or less symmetric baskets has become more diversified than
to an excess demand for unskilled labour changes in the wage gap in the trading it was a decade ago. Such diverse trade
and an excess supply of skilled labour nations. The second is to explain widening patterns cannot effectively be captured
because the expanding X sector requires wage gap through increased trade in the through an aggregative index of skill-in-
more unskilled labour and can absorb fewer south or the developing countries having tensity of exports. India’s export pattern
skilled labourers than are released by the an abundance of unskilled workers. On is one such example revealing the draw-

Economic and Political Weekly September 23, 2000 3507


back of the aggregative measure. From Of course, we have the input choice con- land being fixed in supply and specific to
exporters of primary products at large, ditions described by the input coefficients, this sector, return to land must increase.
India has emerged as a large exporter of aij. Note that these seven equations are This implies that the increase in the un-
softwares which is highly skill-intensive. sufficient to determine the seven variables skilled money wage must be less than pro-
Gems and jewelleries, another major ex- – four factor prices and three output levels. portionate to the increase in PX. Hence, the
port item during 1990s, also involve a However, being a variant of the specific real wage for the unskilled workers mea-
good deal of skilled labour. Thus despite factor model, factor endowments do have sured in terms of agricultural output falls.
several agricultural goods being exported, perceptible influence on factor prices unlike
it would not only be unfair but also per- in an HOS model.
Non-traded Production
verse to assume India’s exports as rela- Now suppose booming global trade As well documented by Agenor (1996),
tively unskilled labour-intensive while prospects increases the world price of Z. Cole and Sanders (1985), Fields (1990),
analysing the effect of terms of trade For a given value of agricultural output (X) Mazumdar (1983, 1993), informal sectors
changes on the wage gap. Examples of and hence demand for unskilled labour, provide most of the employment in most
other southern countries are not hard to the Y-Z subsystem defined by eqs 7-11 of the developing countries. The 1991
find. Consequently, it is quite obvious that gives us the standard 2 x 3 specific factor census report in India also tells the same
labelling the south as exporters of un- set up with skilled and unskilled labour as story: share of informal sectors in total
skilled labour-intensive goods with too the two specific factors and capital as the employment is almost 90 per cent and this
much analytical dependence on the SS mobile factor. Thus, as demonstrated in has been the scenario during the 1980s and
theorem produce theoretical results largely Jones (1971), increase in PZ raises WS and 1990s. In fact, as documented in Dev
at variance with observed wage move- reduces W. However, as W goes down, (2000), during 1973-93, in almost all sectors
ments in the south. unskilled labour moves to agriculture the share of informal segments has either
As pointed out by Jones et al (1999), reducing the output of Y and expanding remained the same or increased. This has
production and trade pattern of a country that of X. This arrests the fall in W to some been the highest in agriculture around 99
must match the specific composition of extent but not fully because in the final per cent, followed by around 90 and 81
resources. Every country should produce equilibrium production of Y must contract per cents respectively in construction and
and export goods consistent with its factor since capital leaves this sector for the manufacturing. Accordingly, these char-
endowments no doubt, but this does not expanding Z sector. Therefore, wage gap acteristics of the labour markets in the
and should not mean that an unskilled widens indicating the importance of pat- LDCs must be accounted for in the expla-
labour abundant country will export only tern of exports. nation of the wage gap phenomenon. Of
unskilled labour intensive goods. In case What happens when world price of late, we have made an attempt in this
of India, exports of rice and softwares are agricultural exports goes up? With un- regard in Marjit and Acharyya (2000).
indeed consistent with the available prod- skilled labour drawn into agriculture con- It is also well known by now that the
uct-specific factors. In the following we sequent upon this, the unskilled wage existence of the non-traded goods, the
consider a variant of the specific-factor increases and this pushes down the return market for which must clear domestically,
model incorporating such diverse trade to capital to maintain the zero profit con- significantly alter many standard results of
pattern as discussed in Marjit and Acharyya dition in the Y sector as its price has not the trade models. Since most of the non-
(2000). changed. By the same token WS must rise. traded production in the LDCs uses un-
Consider a small open economy produc- The change in wage gap is, therefore, skilled labour intensively, any discussion
ing three goods: an agricultural good (X) ambiguous. Formally, of widening wage gap in the unskilled
that uses unskilled labour (L) and land (T); ^ ^ ^ labour abundant LDCs through trade
and two manufacturing goods – Y, using WS – W = –r (θKZ – θKY)/θSZθLY ...(13) liberalisation cannot be complete without
unskilled labour and capital (K), and Z that where θijs are the factor income shares. such non-traded goods being taken into
combines capital with skilled labour (S). Therefore, an improvement in the terms of account.
Goods Z and X are exported whereas Y trade through an increase in the price of As argued in Acharyya and Marjit (1999),
is imported by this country. The markets agricultural exports will widen the wage gap however, the more important issue is the
are perfectly competitive and production if θKZ > θKY. With the decline in the return nature of such non-traded sectors. In
technology exhibits constant returns to to capital, the cost saving is more in the particular, whether non-traded production
scale. Z sector than in the Y sector if capital cost is organised in the informal or in the formal
Given the world prices of the final goods, share is higher in this sector. This, in turn, sector may appear to be crucial. Essentially
the zero profit conditions are described as: necessitates greater increase in the skilled the way formal and informal sectors are
PX = aLXW + aTXR ...(6) wage than the unskilled money wage to modelled in the literature, the issue at hand
maintain zero profit conditions in these can be rephrased as examining the role of
PY = aLYW + aKYr ...(7)
sectors at given world prices, PZ and PY. non-traded production under alternative
PZ = aSZWS + aKZr ...(8) Hence the wage gap widens notwithstand- wage formation assumption: (higher)
Factor price flexibility, on the other hand ing the fact that it is agriculture, which does contractual unskilled wage or fully flex-
ensures full employment of all factors: not use skilled labour, that has expanded. ible market-determined unskilled wage.
S = aSZZ ...(9) The latent complementarity between ag- Since the traded sectors compete with the
riculture and skilled manufacturing leads non-traded sectors for the scarce resources
K = aKYY + aKZZ ...(10)
to increasing inequality in this case. they use in commonly and the non-traded
L = aLYY + aLXX ...(11) Moreover, as agricultural output expands production by definition must match its
T = aTXX ...(12) consequent upon the increase in its price, domestic demand, trade liberalisation in-

3508 Economic and Political Weekly September 23, 2000


duced expansion of activities in the traded tion that α proportion of total urban in- If non-traded production falls, some
sectors will be possible only through a fall come is spent on the non-traded good and unskilled labour will be released from this
in the demand for non-tradeables. This that the rural population does not have sector as well along with that from the
necessitates an increase in the price of non- access to this output: import competing sector and accordingly
traded goods and consequent changes in the unskilled wage must fall to absorb
PNN = a[(aLYY + aLNN)W
domestic income distribution. Herein them in informal agriculture. But if non-
comes the role of the nature of the non- + WSS + rK] ...(15) traded production increases, not signifi-
trade sector. If it is a formal sector with These two equations are added to the basic cantly though, some of the released un-
a contractual wage, the non-traded price structure described earlier and the full skilled labour will be absorbed in the non-
may be determined solely by the cost of employment condition for unskilled labour, traded sector thereby necessitating much
production independent of the demand for eq 11, now contains an additional term, smaller wage fall in the informal agricul-
non-traded good. In such a case demand aLNN. tural sector. In either case, the wage gap
variation consequent upon trade The important point to note is that the widens. It is only when non-traded pro-
liberalisation induced real income changes formal sectors form an independent sub- duction increases significantly, requiring
alters only non-traded production. Accord- system of the economy. The output and more unskilled labour than is released by
ingly any change in the wage gap is trig- prices of the factors used in production of the contracting import competing sector,
gered by the consequent resource reallo- Z, Y and N are all determined independent the unskilled wage will go up and the wage
cation across the non-traded and traded of the informal agricultural sector.4 But gap may decline consequent upon such
sectors. But if the non-traded sector is an the wage rate, the return to land and the (net) excess demand for unskilled labour
informal sector, variations in the demand agricultural output level crucially depend in the formal sector as a whole.
for non-traded good is followed by changes on the equilibrium values in the formal Import liberalisation through tariff re-
in both production and price of the sectors of the economy. This is exactly duction, however, can be shown to widen
non-traded good. Accordingly, trade what we can expect. Since only those the wage gap unambiguously. On the other
liberalisation will have quite different unskilled workers who are not employed hand, when the non-traded good is
implications on the wage gap between in the formal import competing and non- produced in the informal sector, PN is
skilled and unskilled workers. traded sectors at the higher contracted wage no longer independent of domestic de-
To fix ideas, we extend the earlier equa- moves to informal agriculture, it is obvi- mand. In such a case, as shown in Acharyya
tion system by incorporating a non-traded ous that its production activities will be and Marjit (1999), the wage gap is more
sector. First consider the case where rural constrained by the outputs and hence by pronounced under import liberalisation
labour market is informal whereas the urban the demand for unskilled labour in the compared to the above case of formal
labour market is organised. It is important formal sectors. Herein comes the role of sector production of non-traded good.
to note that unskilled workers who cannot the non-traded good. Had all goods been That is, the informal non-traded sector
find any job in the urban organised sector(s) traded, production of agricultural exports by itself appears to be source of the
at high institutionally given money wage would not necessarily be constrained by deteriorating position of the unskilled
move to the rural sectors to work at even the demand for non-traded good and the workers.
lower market-determined money wage. In consequent demand for unskilled labour. With the possible exception of the east
this regard we deviate from the standard Any excess demand would have been met Asian countries, increased foreign trade
Harris-Todaro type assumption and instead through imports. and investment have increased wage in-
follow the available empirical evidences In such a set-up let us examine how an equality in almost all parts of the globe
cited in Agenor (1996), Agenor and Montiel increase in the price of manufacturing during the last two decades of the 20th
(1996) and Mazumdar (1993) that low- exports affects the wage gap. The imme- century. Theoretically as well as empiri-
skilled workers cannot afford to remain diate impact will be an increase in the cally HOS model of trade with the Stolper-
unemployed. Therefore, in a way unskilled skilled wage and with the rate of return Samuelson result at its core fails to explain
labour is fully employed in our extended to capital held fixed by the given world such widening of wage gap between skilled
model as well although there are two distinct price of importable and the ad valorem and unskilled labour particularly in the
wage rates. tariff rate, such increase will be more than south. The main problem with these stan-
Now from our assumption regarding the proportionate. Consequently input substi- dard theories is their failure to capture the
nature of rural and urban labour markets, tution effect will raise production of manu- diverse trade pattern that the developing
it follows that the manufacturing Y sector facturing exports. This causes output of nations are showing in their export baskets
hires unskilled labour at a given money the import competing good to fall since of late, and the institutional characteristics
wage, W, whereas the agricultural workers some capital is withdrawn to support the specific to them. Instead of straightjacket
offer their work at the market-determined additional production of the Z good. application of the HOS model and too
lower money wage, W. To begin with, But the change in urban income, at the much emphasis on the Stolper-Samuelson
suppose the non-traded good (N) is pro- initial non-traded output, is ambiguous as theorem, one needs to focus on these
duced in the urban formal sector. If only evident from equation 15: whereas the aspects. In this paper we have discussed
labour is used to produce this good, which income of the capitalists remain unchanged, alternative variants of the specific factor
is of course just a simplifying assumption, that of the skilled workers increase and the model accounting for the diverse trade
the non-traded price is cost-determined: wage income of the workers in the Y sector pattern, informal factor markets and ex-
PN = aLNW ...(14) decrease. Consequently, the demand for istence of non-traded goods, that can
Output is, on the other hand, demand- non-traded good and hence its output level explain to a large extent the wage gap
determined given the simplifying assump- may go either way. phenomenon. EPW

Economic and Political Weekly September 23, 2000 3509


Notes Political Economy, February, 198-210. Mazumdar, D (1983): ‘Segmented Labour Markets
Cole, W E and R D Sanders (1985): ‘Internal in LDCs’, American Economic Review,
[This paper has grown out of our ongoing work Migration and Urban Employment in the Third 73:254-59.
on Trade and Inequality. We would like to thank World’, American Economic Review, 75:481- – (1993): ‘Labour Markets and Adjustment in
Amiya K Bagchi, Satya P Das, Ananya Ghosh 94. Open Asian Economies: The Republic of Korea
Dastidar, Ronald Jones, Utsa Patnaik, Dipak Davis, D (1998): ‘Does European Unemployment and Malaysia’, World Bank Economic Review,
Nayyar, and seminar and conference participants Prop Up American Wages? National Labour 7:349-80.
at the CSSS, Calcutta, Copenhagen Business Markets and Global Trade’, American Meller, P (1998): ‘Trade and Employment in Latin
School, IGIDR, Mumbai, JNU, Delhi and the Economic Review. America’ in O Memedovic et al (eds),
University of Mumbai for stimulating discussions.] Dev, M (2000): ‘Economic Liberalisation and Globalisation of Labour Markets: Challenges,
Employment in South Asia’, Economic and Adjustments and Policy Response in the
1 Another factor that has no direct influence, of Political Weekly, January 8:40-51. European Union and Less Developed
course, in absence of any non-traded good, is Feenstra, R and G Hanson (1995): ‘Foreign Countries, Kluwer Academic Publishers.
the devaluation or revaluation of the nominal Investment, Outsourcing and Relative Wages’ Murphy, K M and F Welch (1991): ‘The Role of
exchange rates. Exchange rate changes in R Feenstra, G Grossman and D Irwin (eds), International Trade in Wage Differentials’ in
proportionately raises all commodity prices and Political Economy of Trade Policies: Essays Kosters (ed), Workers and their Wages:
money wages leaving relative wages unchanged. in Honour of J N Bhagwati, MIT Press. Changing Pattern in the United States, The
Thus, as correctly pointed out by Robbins Fields, G (1990): ‘Labour Market Modelling and American Enterprise Institute Press,
(1995a), the work on trade and wages by Murphy the Urban Informal Sector: Theory and Washington, DC.
and Welch (1991) that emphasised on Evidence’ in D Turnham (ed), The Informal Nagaraj, R, A Varaudakis and M A Veganzones
revaluation of US dollar was based on a false Sector and Evidence Revisited, OECD, Paris. (1997): ‘Long Run Growth Trends and
premise. Gal-Or, O and J Zeira (1993): ‘Income Distribution Convergence Across Indian States’, technical
2 Such one-to-one correspondence fails to hold and Macroeconomics’, Review of Economic paper, Development Centre.
when domestic factors of production are not Studies, 60:35-52. Pedersen, K (1998): ‘Comment on ‘Trade and
sectorally mobile or the production technologies Ghosh, B, S Marjit, C Neogi (1998): ‘Economic Employment in Latin America’ ’ in
exhibit factor intensity reversals. Growth and Regional Divergence in India, O Memedovic et al (eds), Globalisation of
3 We are indebted to Ron Jones for pointing this 1960 to 1995’, Economic and Political Weekly, Labour Markets: Challenges, Adjustments and
out. June 27. Policy Response in the European Union and
4 If we assume that a fraction of the rural income Jones, R W (1971): ‘A Three Factor Model in Less Developed Countries, Kluwer Academic
is spent on the non-traded good, the formal non- Trade, Theory and History’ in J N Bhagwati Publishers.
et al (eds), Trade, Balance of Payments and Reich, R B (1991): The Work of Nations, Alfred
traded sector is no longer a part of the
Growth, North Holland. A Knopf, New York.
independent subsystem.
Jones, R W, H Beladi and S Marjit (1999): ‘Three Robbins, D (1994): ‘Malaysian Wage Structure
References Faces of Factor Intensities’, Journal of and Its Causes’, Harvard Institute for
International Economics, 48 (2):413-20. International Development.
Acharyya, R and S Marjit (1999): ‘Trade Jones, R W and S L Engerman (1996): ‘Trade, – (1995): ‘Trade, Trade Liberalisation and
Liberalisation and Wage-gap in the Developing Technology and Wages: A Tale of Two Inequality in Latin America and East Asia:
Countries: The Role of the Informal Non- Countries’, American Economic Review, 86: Synthesis of Seven Country Studies’, Harvard
traded Sector’, Working Paper No 112, Chinese 35-40. Institute of International Development.
University of Hong Kong. Katz, L F, G W Loveman and D G Blanchflower – (1996a): ‘Stolper-Samuelson Lost in the Topics
Agenor, P R (1996): ‘The Labour Market and (1992): ‘A Comparison of Changes in the – Trade Liberalisation and Wages in Columbia’,
Economic Adjustment’, IMF Staff Paper 32, Structure of Wages in Four OECD Countries’, Harvard Institute of International Development.
261-335. NBER. – (1996b): ‘HOS Hits Facts: Facts Win – Evidence
Agenor, P R and P Montiel (1996): Development Khan, A R (1998): ‘The Impact of Globalisation on Trade and Wages in Developing World’,
Macroeconomics, Princeton University Press, in South Asia’ in A S Bhalla (ed), Globalisation, Harvard Institute of International Development.
Princeton. Growth and Marginalisation, Macmillan. Tendulkar, S, D K Sundaram and L R Jain (1996):
Banerjee, A V and A Newman (1993): Krugman, P (1997): Development, Geography ‘Macroeconomic Policies and Poverty in India
‘Occupational Choice and the Process of and Economic Theory, MIT Press. 1966-67 to 1993-94’, manuscript, ILO,
Development’, Journal of Political Economy, Lawrence, R Z (1994): ‘Trade, Multinationals and New Delhi.
101:274-98. Labour’, NBER, WP No 4836. Wood, A (1995): ‘How Trade Hurt Unskilled
Bhagwati, J N (1995): ‘Trade and Wages: A Malign Lawrence, R Z and M Slaughter (1993): ‘Trade Workers’, Journal of Economic Perspectives,
Relationship?’, unpublished manuscript, and US Wages in the 1980s: Giant Sucking 9(3): 57-80.
Columbia University. Sound or Small Hiccup?’ Brookings Papers – (1997): ‘Openness and Wage Inequality in
Bhagwati, J N and V H Dahejia (1997): ‘Free on Economic Activity: Macroeconomics. Developing Countries: The Latin American
Trade and Wages of the Unskilled – Is Marx Leamer, E (1995): ‘A Trade Economist’s View Challenge to East Asian Conventional
Striking Again?’ in V N Balasubramanyam of US Wages and Globalisation’ in Collins Wisdom’, World Bank Research Observer,
(ed), Writings on International Economics by (ed), Imports, Exports and American Worker, 11(1):33-57.
J N Bhagwati, Oxford University Press, Delhi. Washington, DC.
Borjas, G J, R Freeman and L F Katz (1991): ‘On Marjit, S (1997): ‘Terms of Trade and Wage Gap
the Labour Market Effects of Immigration and in the Developing Countries’, mimeo, Centre
Trade’, Harvard Institute of Economic Research for Studies in Social Sciences, Calcutta. Economic and Political Weekly
Discussion Paper No 1556, Harvard University. Marjit, S and R Acharyya (2000): ‘Trade and
Bound, J and G Johnson (1992): ‘Changes in Wage-Inequality in the Developing Nations:
Structure of Wages in the 1980s: An Evaluation A Simple General Equilibrium Approach’,
available at
of Alternative Explanations’, American mimeo, CSSSC. A K Nayak
Economic Review, vol 82, 371-92. Marjit, S, U Broll and S Sengupta (1997): ‘Trade
Caves, R E, J A Frankel and R W Jones (1996): and Wage Gap in Poor Countries: The Role Bus Stand Book Stall
World Trade and Payments: An Introduction, of Informal Sector’, forthcoming in A Bose Bhubaneswar - 751 009
Seventh Edition, Harper Collins. et al (eds), Macro, Trade and Institutions: Orissa
Deardorff, A and P N Courant (1992): ‘International Essays in Honour of M K Rakshit, Oxford
Trade with Lumpy Countries’, Journal of University Press, Delhi.

3510 Economic and Political Weekly September 23, 2000

You might also like