You are on page 1of 9

Journal of Transport Geography xxx (xxxx) xxx–xxx

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Journal of Transport Geography


journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/jtrangeo

Theorising informality and social embeddedness for the study of informal


transport. Lessons from the marshrutka mobility phenomenon

Lela Rekhviashvili , Wladimir Sgibnev
Leibniz Institute for Regional Geography, Schongauerstraße 9, 04328 Leipzig, Germany

A R T I C LE I N FO A B S T R A C T

Keywords: This paper builds upon recent post-structuralist writings on informal economic practices, using most importantly
Informality a Polanyian institutionalist framework, to discuss formal/informal and market/non-market practices in the
Social embeddedness transport sector. The article proposes a critical reading of the literary canon of informal transport, which largely
Marshrutka assumes a naturalness and omnipresence of markets. We illustrate how reductionist definitions of informal
Marketisation
transport marginalise analytically important empirical detail, and furthermore, lead to misleading theoretical
Polanyi
Ride-sharing
conclusions. In contrast, we analytically de-couple informality and markets, showing that formal and informal
economic practices can be embedded in diverse social-cultural institutions. Such a theoretical framework allows
for consistent evaluation and empirical examination of transport options, as substantiated by evidence from the
marshrutka mobility phenomenon in Bishkek and Tbilisi. We observe marketisation, dis- or re-embedding, for-
malisation and informalisation as dynamic, inter-dependent and conflictual processes. On these grounds, the
article argues for a critical re-appraisal of other forms of informal transport, old and emerging, both in the Global
South and the Global North.

1. Introduction argue in this article, that the existing dominant definitions of informal
transport are thin, reductionist, and detached from recent academic
While urban transportation challenges are intensifying across the debates on informal economic practices as well as urban mobilities. We
globe (Pojani and Stead, 2015) millions of urban dwellers, often pre- rely on feminist post-structuralist writings on informal and diverse
dominantly poor and marginalised communities, depend on informal economies (Cameron and Gibson, 2005; Gibson-Graham, 2008; Gibson
transport for daily mobility in many cities of the Global South. There is et al., 2010), and a Polanyian institutionalist framework (Polanyi,
a growing academic recognition of the need “to make informal urban 1957, 1968) to rework informal transport theorisation. Empirically
transport and the kinds of mobility it enables more visible within de- drawing on the example of post-Soviet paratransit, the so-called
bates concerning the future of cities” (Evans et al., 2018, p. 1). Recent marshrutkas, we challenge the dominant association of informal trans-
transformations in urban mobility sector put informal transport under port with laissez-faire transport, and insist on taking the socially em-
pressure. On the one hand, informal transport is associated with traffic bedded character of informal transport seriously.
congestion, health and safety risks, and environmental degradation. The dominant share of informal transport literature (Cervero, 2000;
Public authorities tend to further marginalise informal transport due to Cervero and Golub, 2007; Golub et al., 2009; Kumar et al., 2016;
their noncompliance to the ideals of ‘modern’ and ‘smart’ cities, offer Wilson, 2011) defines informal transport as unlicensed or not endorsed
alternatives to informal transport (such as BRT systems), and try to by the state, and reduces it to market forces. Naturalising both, in-
formalise and regulate the sector (Paget-Seekins, 2015). On the other formality and markets, the literature equates the two without asking
hand, digitalisation, particularly the spread of taxi aggregators is which processes lead to informalisation and/or marketisation of urban
transforming informal transport. Both of these processes prompt re- transport.1 The reductionist and economistic definition of informality in
sistance and labour contentions (Bundhun, 2018), amplifying the need informal transport literature is challenging for a few interrelated rea-
of a thorough conceptualisation of informal transport. However, we sons. For one, the literature is detached from recent debates in critical


Corresponding author.
E-mail addresses: l_rekhviashvili@ifl-leipzig.de (L. Rekhviashvili), w_sgibnev@ifl-leipzig.de (W. Sgibnev).
1
Some authors argue for using the term paratransit instead of informal transport, “as these services are not necessarily provided by informal businesses or
unregulated” (Ferro and Behrens, 2015, p. 123). Yet this ‘informal-versus-paratransit’ distinction is made possible precisely because of the endorsement of a narrow
definition of informal transport as a commercial transport not licensed by state.

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jtrangeo.2019.01.006
Received 13 October 2017; Received in revised form 18 October 2018; Accepted 7 January 2019
0966-6923/ © 2019 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

Please cite this article as: Rekhviashvili, L., Journal of Transport Geography, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jtrangeo.2019.01.006
L. Rekhviashvili, W. Sgibnev Journal of Transport Geography xxx (xxxx) xxx–xxx

urban transport literature. Influenced by the critical mobilities turn, in previously vertically embedded, state-enforced labour regulations of
the past decade transportation research has moved beyond orthodox transport workers are side-lined, causing an informalization, or as ex-
and economistic perspectives, focusing on the social meanings of mo- pressed in popular language, an ‘Uberisation’ of employment relations.
bility, power relations, access inequalities, and mobility (in)justice To illustrate the merits of the proposed theoretical framework, we
(Hannam et al., 2006; Kębłowski and Bassens, 2017; Kwan and look at the marshrutka mobility phenomenon in Eurasian cities. The
Schwanen, 2016). Second, transdisciplinary contributions on informal empirical discussion on marshrutka mobility primarily relies on four
economic practices have theoretically moved away from, and produced months of fieldwork conducted in August–September 2016 and
vast empirical evidence against a reductionist readings of economy. January–March 2017 in Bishkek, the capital of Kyrgyzstan, and Tbilisi,
Feminist geographers forming the ‘diverse economies’ school of thought the capital of Georgia. In both cities, we conducted lengthy informal
have argued that economy is not reducible to commercial and mone- interviews with marshrutka drivers, as well as participant observation
tised exchange, but is comprised of diverse, also non-market production during ride-alongs and at terminal stations. In both cases, we selected
and exchange processes (Cameron and Gibson, 2005; Gibson-Graham, one suburban terminal station as a primary observation site and con-
2008; Gibson et al., 2010). In a similar vein, social science research on tinuously stayed in touch with a few collectives of drivers. However, we
the post-socialist region has emphasized the socially embedded char- also interviewed drivers on other routes, to corroborate findings and
acter of informal practices (Morris and Polese, 2014; Polese et al., 2018; account for spatial differences in working conditions between drivers
Williams and Onoschenko, 2014). Finally, some mobilities scholars are on different routes. We conducted semi-structured interviews with
frustrated with the reductionist definitions, to the point of re- marshrutka operating companies: four in the case of Bishkek, and with
commending to abandon the informality concept altogether. For ex- the only operating company in Tbilisi. We also interviewed re-
ample, Belk suggests that informality obscures rather than reveals the presentatives of city transport authorities, transport workers' unions in
richness of particular mobility practices, which “have been studied Tbilisi, and an association of marshrutka operator companies in Bishkek
primarily as informal paratransit systems without a historical or social (where drivers are not unionised). The fieldwork examined the systems
life” (Belk, 2014, p. 443). governing marshrutka mobility in the two cities, how those systems
Instead of abandoning the informality concept, this article offers a affect drivers' working conditions and the affordability and safety of
reconceptualization of informal transport based on a critical readings of service, and finally, how the system has been transforming throughout
informal economic practices. Informality is an important empirical the past two decades.
entry point to observe relations beyond formal institutions and formal Marshrutkas proliferated in post-Soviet cities in early 1990s. With
economic exchange, as well as a significant and widely shared marker the breakdown of the Soviet Union and the subsequent economic
of socio-economic relations remaining beyond state regulation (Routh, downturn, the once-extensive public transport infrastructure began to
2011), but still interwoven with negotiations of state and citizenship. As rapidly decay, suffering from disinvestment and a broader labour
Roy argues, “informality is inscribed in the ever-shifting relationship shortage. In combination with very low (albeit rapidly rising) private
between what is legal and illegal, legitimate and illegitimate, author- car ownership levels, the collapse of public transport systems severely
ized and unauthorized. This relationship is both, arbitrary and fickle impaired the provision of mobility services. Simultaneously, pre-
and yet is the site of considerable state power and violence” (Roy, 2009, dominantly privately owned minibuses, known locally as marshrutkas,
p. 80). Resonating with the broader call to politicize transportation spread as a substitute to publicly run trams, buses and trolleybuses
research, we propose that informal transport literature learns from the (Sgibnev and Vozyanov, 2016), and have since become an important, or
informal economies and ‘diverse economies’ literature and discusses even prevailing mode of public transport. Over time, the sector grew
informality in relation to marketisation and social embeddedness. We and diversified; marshrutka routes multiplied, overlapped, and stabi-
primarily rework the original Polanyian definition of marketisation and lised once higher market shares were attained. In most cases, Soviet-era
social embeddedness (Polanyi, 1957), and incorporate informality in a legislation, procedures and norms with regard to line operations, safety
Polanyian institutionalist perspective. standards and reporting were formally maintained, but rarely enforced,
Relying on the mentioned theoretical framework, we suggest to de- which allowed the marshrutka sector to flexibly address diversifying
couple informality and markets, currently equated in informal transport mobility needs. The proliferation of this flexible, privately owned and
literature. We argue that informal economic practices in general, and operated, and barely coordinated mode of transport was considered to
informal transport in particular, can be and often are comprised of both, be one of the key signifiers of bottom-up entrepreneurship in a period of
market-like and non-market-like, socially embedded economic ex- economic transition ‘from state to market’.
changes. Importantly, even if they co-exist, there is a tension between Marshrutka sector transformation in past two decades illustrates
markets and social embeddedness, each holding the propensity to how misleading a reductionist definitions of informal transport and
marginalise, and ultimately informalise the other. Neither market- equating informality with markets can be. At a first glance, marshrutkas
likeness nor social embeddedness can be taken for granted, but should would be classified as informal paratransit, privately operating transit
rather be questioned in each empirical setting. Therefore, when re- services existing within weak regulatory frameworks, (Ferro and
searching informality of formalisation processes, we suggest paying Behrens, 2015), and counted as demand-responsive, laissez-faire
attention to both, whether market–relations are formalised, but also transport. A closer look at the sector reveals that the marshrutka phe-
whether social embeddedness is formalised or remains informal. nomenon is much less market driven and more socially embedded then
Further elaborating on the Polanyian framework, we distinguish be- assumed (Sanina, 2011). Even if for-profit, the sector is largely shaped
tween vertical (state-enforced) embedding and horizontal (informal) by non-market norms and institutions, involving reciprocity, mutuality
embedding. The emphasis based on vertical and horizontal embedding and sharing. Relationships at differing scales and between diverse ac-
has grave implications for informal transport literature as well as tors – passengers and drivers, drivers and operating companies, com-
policy-making. Since reductionist definitions exclusively care for panies and city governments – are negotiated informally and are in-
market-based exchange, the focus on market supporting institutions fluenced by a range of socio-political considerations that defy the profit-
(such as property relations, operating rights) prevails when looking into seeking principle as well as private property enforcement
formalisation processes. Such a view dismisses how market-supporting (Rekhviashvili and Sgibnev, 2018a,b). If, however, we applied the ex-
institutions can indeed be formalised, but socially embedding institu- isting definition of informal transport as not endorsed or licensed by
tions might not be: labour relations, sometimes-even customers' rights public authority, (Cervero and Golub, 2007), then marshrutkas could
remain informally negotiated. The spread of digital taxi aggregators is a easily be seen formalised since the mid-2000s. In the two cities ex-
good example at hand. In the Global South, the business side is formal, amined in this article, Bishkek and Tbilisi, marshrutkas are licensed and
but labour relations remain informal. In the Global North, however, taxed by their respective municipal governments, and route operating

2
L. Rekhviashvili, W. Sgibnev Journal of Transport Geography xxx (xxxx) xxx–xxx

rights are assigned based on competitive tendering. Nevertheless, in endeavour: “...informal transport involves commercial transactions
both contexts, marshrutkas systematically bypass traffic regulations and which distinguishes them, as transportation services, from the provision
informally negotiate lower fines for rule evasion. A significant share of of free lifts (…) It is this more limited definition of informal transport,
money circulation in the sector is informal, as are the relationships namely ones involving pay−for−services, that is adopted in this study”
between transport workers and the company, and among transport (Cervero, 2000, p. 3). Indeed, some approaches to informality, pri-
workers. Acknowledgement of the constitutive role of informal, socially marily the legalist-institutionalist ones, assume that informal economic
embedding practices enabled by a Polanyian reading allows drawing a practices are predominantly market-like (Chersi, 1997; De Soto, 1989,
more comprehensive picture of the sector. Even more importantly, such 2000; Olaya et al., 2007; Schneider et al., 2010). The informal transport
a reading allows to account for socio-cultural situatedness of informal literature, however, explicitly defines informality as a market-based
transport, and possibly equips the research for comprehending grie- exchange. In doing so, it dismisses a range of economic exchanges that
vances and contentions that go along with modernisation and for- take place beyond state attention as irrelevant for the analysis. This
malisation efforts. literature then directly characterises informal transport as a perfect
In what follows, we first critically review the conceptual toolkit example of a self-regulating market at work: “Informal transport is
offered by the informal transport literature. Second, we move on to about as close to laissez-faire transportation as can be found. Through
overview broader debates in informality literature to identify theore- the invisible hand of the marketplace, those who are willing−to−pay
tical and conceptual innovations that can potentially overcome the for transport services make deals for lifts with those who are will-
limits of existing informal transport literature. Third, we attempt to ing−to−provide” (Cervero, 2000, p. 3). Hence, the criteria for the
consolidate a Polanyian framework to define informality, markets and laissez-faire transportation are that transport provision depends on
embeddedness. Finally, we come back to demonstrating the implica- deals between free rational individuals, or the demand-and-supply
tions of concept definitions for an empirical examination of urban principle.
transport, using the example of the marshrutka mobility phenomenon The portrayal of informal transport as laissez-faire leads to the
on the post-Soviet periphery. In the concluding part, we summarise the second challenge, the conclusion that whenever there is no state,
contribution and draw implications for low-tech as well as high-tech markets fill up the void. This literature is not concerned with the
flexible urban transport research. question of how and why the process of informalisation takes place,
since the absence of a state is always the explanation at hand.
Furthermore, this literature naturalises state absence by implicitly or
2. Informality: the blind spot of informal transport literature
explicitly articulating the inferiority of state-run transport and idea-
lising the spontaneity of informal transport: “The rich mix of en-
Despite its significance to the lives of millions of citizens, particu-
trepreneurial services found in the third world evolved spontaneously,
larly in the Global South (Pojani and Stead, 2015), informal transport
without central control or direction (...) Rather, it is largely a product of
remains under-theorised and detached from wider debates about in-
marketplaces allowed to run their own courses” (Cervero, 2000, p. 16).
formality. The existing literature offers invaluable empirical material
Informalisation is explained by the deficiencies of municipal transport:
but suffers from several conceptual challenges. First, it relies on a thin,
“The most important factors behind the growth of the [informal] sector
formalist understanding of informality, assuming a universalised
were thought to be the declining quality of transit service, poor or
market-likeness of informal transport. Hence, it focuses on the ration-
outdated route connections, low levels of comfort and safety, rising
ality of actors, and the costs and benefits of economic exchange, at the
transit fares in real terms, and long and increasing waiting and travel
expense of examining the social-historical situatedness of informal
times” (Golub et al., 2009, p. 603). As a tendency, the reasons behind
transport. Second, informality, in this strand of literature, is a de-
the decline of formal transit service are not sought after.
scriptive term or a condition, and is rarely explored as a process with
It needs to be emphasized, that the existing informal transport lit-
own enabling causes and effects. Finally, these inter-related challenges
erature offers unique, comparative and empirically rich material con-
stem from a disengagement of informal transport literature with trans-
cerning urban mobility across different world regions. In contradiction
disciplinary debates around the informality concept on one hand, and
to own theoretic convictions, informality literature also shows how
debates about the development and role of markets and the state for
unregulated competition can undermine service quality and passenger
social well-being on the other.
safety, and can worsen transport workers' employment conditions, and
The literature on informal transport, in the formalist tradition,2
notes how transport workers' efforts at coordinating and self-organising
reduces it to an exchange of free and rational individuals selling and
are directed at mitigating the adverse consequences of marketisation
buying services according to de-personalised demand and supply
(Cervero and Golub, 2007). Moreover, this literature often hints on the
principles. The key and defining publications on informal transport in
fundamentally political character of mobility governance, showing how
different global regions, by Cervero and Golub, broadly define informal
monopolies and rent-seeking agents create conditions for informalisa-
transport as transport that is unlicensed or not officially endorsed
tion (Golub et al., 2009). Nevertheless, due to a restrictive theoretical
(Cervero and Golub, 2007). Cervero's publications also identify a more
framework and a lack of conceptual elaboration, the rich empirical
specific definition of informal transport as a commercial, market-like
material is not reflected in theoretical arguments. Due to this challenge,
social and economic exchange beyond states and markets remain un-
2
The formalist reading of economic exchange refers back to debates in eco- named and marginal to the analysis. Importantly, non-market-like in-
nomic anthropology in the 1970s between the so-called formalists and sub- formal practices that shape informal transport are empirically described
stantivists. The former current largely consists of scholars who have accepted but not theorised.
and defended classical and neoclassical economists' assumptions about the Beyond mainstream informal transport literature, some research
universal rationality of economic actors, and their primarily profit-motivated offers critical and substantivist discussion of informal transport. A
action. The substantivist current, on the other hand, was influenced by the number of anthropologists (Bürge, 2011; Sopranzetti, 2014), mobility
works of Hungarian political-economist and economic historian, Karl Polanyi,
scholars (Rahman and Assadekjaman, 2013) human geographers (Diaz
who argued that economic exchange can rarely be reduced to economistic
Olvera et al., 2016), and development economists (Rizzo, 2011), write
reasoning. Instead, it should be examined in relation to its embeddedness in
non-economic institutions, whether they are small-scale, such as family and on the topic without sharing Cervero's and his colleagues' assumptions
kinship networks, or large-scale cultural and political institutions. While purely on informal transport. In some cases, the primacy of profit-seeking is
formalist readings of economic exchange might have become a rarity in such directly contested. However, these dispersed efforts are, to our best
fields as anthropology, they still prevail in many other fields and sub-fields of knowledge, not mobilised to systematically oppose and re-examine the
social sciences. dominant thin definition of informal transport. Thus, authors do not

3
L. Rekhviashvili, W. Sgibnev Journal of Transport Geography xxx (xxxx) xxx–xxx

directly refer to or engage with informal transport literature. In rare Stenning et al., 2010) and underlines the relational character of in-
cases, authors reject existing definitions of informal transport, sug- formality (Sassen, 1997). Moreover, it strives to deconstruct the nega-
gesting that such descriptions might be reductionist and detach mobi- tive prejudices associated with the informal economy, and proposes
lity practices from their respective social-historical context. Such cri- that a diversity of economic practices can inform our thinking on al-
tical appreciation prompts authors to argue against the usage of the ternative modes of production (Williams and Onoschenko, 2014). One
term altogether, and to bring in alternative concepts such as subaltern of the key recent contributions of informality literature has been its
mobilities (Best, 2016). Then the question is: can further research rely introduction of the concept of social embeddedness. Suggesting that
on existing formalist readings of informality to study urban transport? If economic exchanges are “embedded in concrete, ongoing systems of
this reading seems insufficient, should the concept of informality be set social relations” (Granovetter, 1985, p. 487), scholars show that in-
aside? formality is not reducible either to survival or to profit-seeking, but
instead is shaped by historically and culturally contingent, as well as
3. The difficult trade-off between informality and social newly emerging, shared norms and understandings (Morris and Polese,
embeddedness 2014, 2015; Rodgers and Williams, 2009; Smith and Rochovská, 2007).
While the informality literature has come a long way in under-
The assumptions of the informal transport literature – equating in- mining the assumption of the market-likeness of informal practices, the
formal transport with the market, and seeing its emergence as sponta- existing prevalent definition of social embeddedness faces a significant
neous – are problematic. Writings on informal economic practices in the challenge. This mainly refers to the concept's inability to capture
past few decades have introduced a sea of qualitative and quantitative marketisation and social embedding as processes rather than static
evidence that contradicts these assumptions. These writings indicate conditions. The existing definition of embeddedness in informality lit-
that informal practices are not necessarily market-like. Instead, they are erature is borrowed from new economic sociology, primarily from
immersed in the social and cultural institutions of the respective so- Granovetter, which proposes that no economic action is entirely de-
cieties (Gibson-Graham, 2008; Morris, 2011; Morris and Polese, 2015; personalised and dis-embedded. Hence, any economy, at any time, is
Williams, 2004). While informal transport literature has, until now, both market-like (to a degree), and socially embedded (Granovetter,
largely disregarded these existing approaches to informal economic 1985).
practices, and has barely addressed the complex relations alongside the Depicting all economies as socially embedded creates two chal-
formal-informal spectrum and the reasons behind the spread of in- lenges for thinking of informality, markets and embeddedness. First, if
formal practices, the informality literature is now in its fourth or fifth all economic action is embedded, then the embeddedness of informal
decade of theorising on such questions. economic practices seems to be no novelty, and the relevance of a
Four important schools of thought have shaped the thinking on formal-informal distinction disappears. Second, and perhaps more im-
informality since the coining of the concept by anthropologist Keith portantly, if we do not draw a line between economic exchanges that
Hart in the early 1970s (Hart, 1973). The first, dualist/modernisation are governed by market logic and those that are not, lumping all of
perspective on informality viewed the informal economy as a separate them together, then the omnipresence of markets is rather reinforced.
and marginal sector, comprised of small-scale subsistence activities, in If, for example, a taxi sector in which labour relations are regulated by
contrast to a formal market economy. In the following decades, this the state and a ride-sourcing sector where labour relations are informal
approach was critically appreciated, up to the point that the notion of are both assumed to be similarly socially embedded by default, then
the ‘informal sector’ was replaced in favour of ‘informal economy’, in how do we account for divergent labour conditions?
acknowledgment of the close interconnectedness of formal and in-
formal economic exchanges (Guha-Khasnobis et al., 2006). 4. A Polanyian framework for studying informality, markets and
In the late 1980s and 1990s, the structuralist and the legalist/in- social embeddedness
stitutionalist perspectives started conceptualising informality. Both
perspectives emphasized the interconnectedness of formal and informal In order to overcome the static description of social-economic life,
economies, but approached the issue from very different theoretical be it formal or informal, as simultaneously market-like and socially
starting points. The structuralists saw the spread of informality, as no embedded, we elaborate upon a Polanyian institutionalist perspective.
longer confined to marginal actors and spaces, but affecting core in- In contrast to existing dominant approaches, it sees neither markets nor
dustries in advanced capitalist economies (Portes et al., 1989; Slavnic, social embeddedness as natural, static or given. Rather, both markets
2010). The dawn of neoliberalism, subsequent processes of de-regula- and social embeddedness are conceived as purposefully constructed by
tion, and worldwide liberalisation of capital mobility intensified com- state and non-state actors. From a Polanyian perspective, markets and
petitive pressures on firms. These, in turn, tried to cut down labour social embeddedness can indeed co-exist. This approach stands in
costs through strategies of sub-contracting, outsourcing, and evasion of contrast to both the formalist perspective, which assumes the omni-
labour protection legislation. In contrast to the structuralists, the leg- presence of markets, and the new economic sociology, which assumes
alist/institutionalists current, assumed that the reason behind the the omnipresence of social embeddedness. Instead, it suggests first that
spread of informality was a lacking formal institutionalisation of mar- the relationship between market and embeddedness is far from har-
kets (De Soto, 1989; North, 1995). The informal transport literature monious and stable, but rather conflictual and tension-ridden, and
comes close to this perspective, believing that informal practices are second, that the balance between the two is continuously changing and
already market-like. However, even such liberal readers of informality producing divergent consequences and implications for social-economic
as the legalist/institutionalists, unlike informal transport scholars, ac- life (Bohle and Greskovits, 2009, 2012; Dalton, 1968; Polanyi, 1957).
knowledged the important role of states in establishing and enforcing In order to explicate the Polanyian perspective on markets and
market-supporting institutions, security of private property and rule of embeddedness and the role of informality in such a framework, a little
law. theoretical detour is necessary. Polanyi distinguishes between different
The grand theories gave way to a fourth perspective: the post- types of social-economic organisation, that is market, reciprocal, re-
structuralist writings on informality since the late 1990s/early 2000s. distributive and household economies. Relying on historical and an-
These writings offer interpretative readings of informal economic thropological material, he demonstrates that prior to the emergence of
practices, forming a ‘diverse economies’ school of thought (Cameron capitalism, most economies were operating on the principles of re-
and Gibson, 2005; Gibson-Graham, 2008; Gibson et al., 2010). This ciprocity, redistribution and the household. Such modes of social in-
literature apprehends and underlines the non-capitalist character of tegration are socially embedded, that is, subjected to the social-political
informal economic practices (Gibson-Graham, 2006; Routh, 2011; and cultural institutions of various societies. A market economy, in

4
L. Rekhviashvili, W. Sgibnev Journal of Transport Geography xxx (xxxx) xxx–xxx

turn, is the only mode of social-economic integration which dis-embeds institutionalist take on informality (De Soto, 2000).
economy and subjects it to a self-regulating demand and supply prin- Based on an extended Polanyian framework, we can propose a
ciple. The uniqueness of a market economy resides in the fact that number of possible ideal-type scenarios on the interplay between in-
beyond exchanging commodities produced for sale, fictitious com- formality, markets, and embeddedness (see Table 1). In the first sce-
modities (that is, resources not produced for sale such as land, labour nario, both markets and socially embedded forms of social integration
and money) are being commodified, and thus subjected to being sold on (be it household, reciprocal or redistributive) operate informally. In the
demand- and supply-driven markets. The creation of conditions to second scenario, markets are institutionalised by the state, leading to
commodify such productive resources is far from spontaneous or nat- the emergence of a market economy. This, according to Polanyi, will
ural. A purposeful institutionalisation of market economies by the state, cause the dismantling of previous social embedded institutions, which
and an enforcement of private property rights enables the marketisation will reconfigure themselves or new informal practices and institutions
process (Polanyi, 1957, 1968). can emerge to re-embed the economy and address the risks and social
Social embedding, much like marketisation, is not a default and insecurities imposed by marketisation. In the third scenario, social
omnipresent condition. The need for re-embedding stems from the so- embedding is institutionalised by public authorities in the form of state-
cial and ecological consequences of marketisation. Marketisation ad- based, vertical regulation and protection. In the fourth scenario, reg-
vances at the expense of dismantling pre-existing social and cultural ulation leads to the emergence of informal markets that subvert existing
institutions. To understand the costs of such dismantling, there is no social norms. Each scenario can have its own transitory and temporary
need to idealise or romanticise pre-existing embedded institutions, grey zones, where formal marketisation is not yet re-embedded for-
which historically might have been egalitarian or repressive. The social mally or informally, or where formalised reciprocal or redistributive
cost of marketisation is nevertheless significant, as markets fail to systems leave little space for formal or informal markets.
provide what embedded economies, as a tendency, are able to – social Indeed, we need to dwell on the limits and possible distortions of
safety and protection. Then, an attempt of re-embedding markets is such an exercise. Clearly, empirical realities in different circumstances
rather a response to the risks and insecurities imposed by marketisation. (Table 2) can and will be more complicated than accounted for in an
Importantly, however, re-embedding can constrain markets to the de- ideal type scenario. Each dimension of categorisation has its own
gree that they lose efficiency, again threatening social reproduction. spectrum, and its own context-based diversity. While these categorisa-
Polanyi calls this tension between marketization and embedding pro- tions might enable broad, cross-space mapping of configurations of
cesses a ‘double movement’ (Polanyi, 1957). Marketisation imposes informality over time, markets and embeddedness, degrees and forms of
social costs, while re-embedding imposes economic costs, unless, of the phenomena will not be reducible to the parsimonious scheme.
course, there is a formally institutionalised political-economic system With these limitations in mind, the contribution of the proposed
other than a market economy in place.3 framework is twofold. The first one is conceptual, with major metho-
In what follows, we develop the Polanyian theory on markets and dological implications for the research of informal transport in parti-
embeddedness, include informality in the theoretical framework, and cular and informal economic practices in general. This approach en-
draw implications for informal transport and urban mobility research. ables an analytical decoupling of markets and informality (which are
First, given that establishing a market economy requires third-party often equated in existing writings on informal transport), and in some
enforcement (be it the state or some other sub-or supranational political cases, on informal economic practices in a broad sense. It also enables
entity), it is highly doubtful that informal markets can function as the decoupling of social embeddedness between vertical (state-en-
laissez-faire markets. Instead of being entirely dependent on the de- forced) embedding and horizontal (informal) embedding. This shar-
mand and supply principle, informal markets can be subjected to social- pened conceptual toolkit requires alternative methodological ap-
cultural norms and institutions. Therefore, academic research cannot proaches to studying informality. It emphasises the continual need for
assume market-likeness of informal economic exchange, but rather empirical verification of the presence/absence of markets and em-
empirically investigate which norms regulate such exchange. Second, in beddedness, rather than assuming by default the presence of markets or
the context of formalised or institutionalised markets, the need for re- embeddedness when encountering informality. The inverse is also true:
embedding will emerge due to the aforementioned social costs of detailed empirical investigation is due when encountering formalised
marketisation. This re-embedding can take a formal or an informal markets to learn whether, informally, non-market norms and institu-
character, which we respectively name as vertical (state-based) and tions exist, or even prevail.
horizontal (informal) embedding. On the one hand, the state (or an- Secondly, the proposed framework offers a theoretical contribution,
other political entity) can vertically embed – regulating markets to pro- primarily by identifying causal connections between markets and em-
tect productive resources by enforcing labour regulations and con- bedded forms of social-economic orders, and formal and informal re-
straining the commodification of resources. On the other hand, in the embedding processes. The major theoretical contribution proposed here
absence of state-based embedding, horizontal re-embedding can take is the articulation of a tension between markets and social embedded-
place by drawing either on pre-existing or newly elaborated norms and ness, the propensity of each to marginalise, and ultimately informalise
institutions that counterbalance marketisation's risks and insecurities. the other. A thorough verification of this theoretical proposition using
Much like marketisation, re-embedding is a process; it requires collec- the example of flexible paratransit is far beyond the scope of this article.
tive efforts and mobilisation on different scales. Third, as markets de- However, given numerous successful applications of a Polanyian-in-
pend on dismantling embedding institutions, and socially embedding spired framework in the fields of anthropology (Burawoy, 1999, 2010;
institutions depend on constraining markets, the progression of one can Hann and Hart, 2009), human geography (Peck, 2013), and political
enable the informalisation of the other. In a context where both market economy (Bohle and Greskovits, 2009, 2012; Streeck, 2011), these
supporting and socially embedding institutions are present, the pro- theoretical propositions deserve serious consideration in further em-
gression of marketisation will inevitably mean the demise of social pirical investigations. In what follows, we briefly demonstrate the re-
regulations (for example, in the form of informalised labour relations), levance of the proposed framework on empirical examples from the
as often articulated by a structuralist reading of informality (Slavnic, post-Soviet marshrutka mobility phenomenon.
2010). In turn, excessive regulation can also lead to the emergence of
informal markets, a process often emphasized by a legalist/ 5. Post-Soviet marshrutkas

The emergence and transformation of marshrutkas in Tbilisi and


3
Socialist systems including the Soviet Union, with largely redistributive, Bishkek illustrates the limits of a formalist definition of informal
subsistence-provisioning economies, can be seen as such. transport, and the merits of a more complex and refined framework.

5
L. Rekhviashvili, W. Sgibnev Journal of Transport Geography xxx (xxxx) xxx–xxx

Table 1 put in place, such as the institution of private property. However, these
Ideal type configurations of informality, markets, and embeddedness. basics do not amount to the creation of a market economy if the state is
incapable of enforcing property rights and other contractual relations
(Bohle and Greskovits, 2012; North, 1995). The redistributive economy
collapsed, but instead of free laissez-faire markets, the countries wit-
nessed the emergence of informal markets tightly interwoven with pre-
existing and evolving informal networks and institutions (Morris,
2011).
If we applied the reductionist definition of informality prevalent in
informal transport literature, marshrutkas, privately owned for-profit
small buses, could be seen as market-like. That would imply the eco-
nomic exchange to be defined by demand and supply of free profit-
seeking individuals, not mediated by non-economistic social con-
siderations. If we apply a Polanyian framework and empirically ex-
amine different aspects and levels of economic exchanges in the sector,
the significance of personalised, non-economistic considerations, or
social embeddedness becomes apparent. First, the relationships be-
tween drivers and passengers were mediated by a range of non-econ-
omistic considerations. Drivers often served their own residential
neighbourhoods, or developed relationships with passengers over time.
This implied a negotiability of prices and types of services based on
personal connections, as well as broader social considerations such as
waiving or reducing fees for needier passengers. Relations between
drivers and vehicle or route owners were also mediated by informal
norms and institutions, with kinship and friendship networks affecting
access to jobs. The relationship among owners was hardly market-like
Table 2
either. The ownership rights to vehicles, as well as ownership of newly
Locating the case studies in the ideal-type raster.
established routes, were rather inconsistent and usually reliant on the
enactment of informal institutions. In Tbilisi, the rights to route own-
ership or operation were not legally assigned by the state. Thus, mafia-
like groupings, the so-called ‘thieves in law’ (Slade, 2012), ensured
owners' rights informally, and settled conflicting ownership claims.
Finally, the relationships between route operators and the state were
personalised, and dependent on a delicate interconnectedness and
overlapping of criminal and political circles. In this period, marshrutkas
in both cities were operating as informal markets and were informally
embedded.
By the mid-to-late 1990s, both Georgia and Kyrgyzstan began
creating a more formalised framework to institutionalise the quickly
growing marshrutka sector (Finn, 2012). The enactment of the Pola-
nyian distinction between market-supporting and market-constraining
institutions is once more important. Local governments in both coun-
tries attempted to formalise informal markets by initiating competitive
tendering for access rights to marshrutka routes, coupled with licensing
and taxation. Public authorities were not concerned with labour rela-
tions, working conditions or the environmental impacts of the sector.
The only regulation imposed that can be seen as social embedding was
the Bishkek city authorities' insistence on affordable transit fares. In-
terestingly, the institutionalisation of market-supporting conditions
such as tendering took place with the support and pressure of inter-
national organisations (Gwilliam, 2001). This is no surprise given the
The Soviet public transport system in itself can be seen as a type of drive towards privatisation of urban transport in the cities of the Global
socially embedded, state-run system that drew on the redistributive South fostered by the World Bank and other globalised institutions
Soviet economy. Transport allocation was decided according to cen- (Rizzo, 2002). To put it another way, steps towards the in-
trally determined mobility needs. Given the prevalence of informal stitutionalisation of markets were not spontaneous, but rather based on
markets of services and commodities throughout the Soviet period a transnational knowledge transfer aimed at enabling the transforma-
(Ledeneva, 2006; Mars and Altman, 1983), marginal levels of informal tion of former Soviet republics into functioning market economies.
provisioning of mobility services were present even prior to the collapse If we were to apply a thin formalist definition of informal transport,
of the Union. In the early 1990s, marshrutkas in both cities operated de marshrutkas would now appear as formal, market-based, private
jure within, but de facto largely outside of the regulatory framework, transport service providers. However, neither formality nor market-
and were assumed to be an example of bottom-up market-like en- likeness stand up to the empirical proof of the complexity of licensing
trepreneurship. However, if one looks at this process from a Polanyian and tendering arrangements. To this day in Bishkek, tendering and li-
framework, the notion of informally-operating marshrutkas being censing processes are rather fictitious, masking the informal distribu-
market-like easily dissolves. In both Georgia and Kyrgyzstan in the tion of political loyalties and rent-collection practices. Virtually no
early 1990s, some very basic preconditions of market economy were drivers are denied licences, while the assignment or renewal of licences
is often ensured through the payment of bribes. As for access to routes,

6
L. Rekhviashvili, W. Sgibnev Journal of Transport Geography xxx (xxxx) xxx–xxx

this is formally based on competitive route tenders for 3 to 5 year terms. to thirty drivers continue pooling and sharing resources (be it labour,
Officially, the city government leases routes for free, and the best and money, or property) to cope with vehicle maintenance costs, share the
most experienced operating companies are supposedly selected. In burden of unexpected accidents, build and equip shelters at terminal
practice, however, 43 operating companies own access to 118 routes. stations, and also to support each other in more personal, family-related
During tendering periods, they are expected to pay informal contribu- matters. Even if drivers lease the vehicles, the company sometimes in-
tions to ensure their access to the routes (which in turn are collected formally allows them to use vehicles for personal purposes off-duty, like
from drivers). Yet informal rents alone would not suffice: operating driving to funerals or weddings of the driver's family and kin.
companies are expected to have so-called ‘roofs’ (krysha) – that is, Feeding back into our theoretical framework, the Tbilisi marshrutka
political patrons enabling their access to the routes. In other words, it is sector experienced formal marketisation but remains, to a degree, in-
a political and often clan-based competition, rather than a market- formally embedded. It is worth noting that in both the cases of the city
based one, which shapes Bishkek's marshrutka sector. Despite the government and the managerial company, the persistence of informal
process of professionalisation and de-personalisation since the 1990s, networks can come in handy: in the absence of formalised social pro-
marshrutka services remain socially embedded, retaining vast informal tection, drivers themselves informally team up to handle risks and in-
negotiation space between drivers, passengers, companies, and state securities. In this sense, markets do not simply co-exist with informal
bureaucracy. embedding but draw on it as a resource, owing their very survival to
Tbilisi marshrutkas operated similarly to Bishkek prior to informal embeddedness as it reproduces labour – in this case the key
2011–2012. Despite a formal tendering of routes, informal entitlements resource for the functioning of the sector. Furthermore, markets are also
and means of enforcing rights over routes prevailed. Complex and indebted to inexistent or limited formal protections: they reproduce and
convoluted class and property relations shaped the drivers' working draw profits at the expense of the severe exploitation of labour and
conditions. Route owners sub-rented route access to vehicle owners, environment.
who, in turn, rented vehicles to drivers. In some cases, drivers would
further sub-rent vehicles which they did not own. Such drivers, oper- 6. Discussion and implications
ating sub-rented vehicles, were called ‘slaves of slaves’, denoting their
extreme precariousness and powerlessness. Another vivid signifier of As this article demonstrates, even if the formal-informal divide is
the lack of marketisation is the sustained multiplicity of actors, pri- not clear-cut, informality still retains its importance in studying urban
marily of operating companies, denoting the lack of a firm consolida- transport in the Global South and North. First, the (non-)usage of the
tion tendency. In summary, despite superficial formalisation attempts, concept of informality shapes methodological choices. Informality re-
Bishkek today and Tbilisi until 2012 may be classified as informal mains a key entry point for observing exchange rules, the circulation of
markets, all while retaining their informal embeddedness. resources, and power dynamics beyond the observation of formal and
Tbilisi's marshrutka sector experienced full-fledged marketisation in institutionalised rules and practices. Secondly, informality is analyti-
2011–2012. The city government announced a tender which required cally important for signifying a lack of vertical embeddedness, or the
operating companies to enter the market with an entirely new vehicle lack of state involvement in regulating social-economic relations.
fleet, and in turn promised an exclusive and extended 20-year franchise. However, if the concept is to maintain its methodological and analytical
These criteria forced out the previously prevalent small operators and importance, we need to move beyond reductionist and formalist read-
enabled the entry of large investors. Four of the winning enterprises ings of informality. This is what this article has attempted to do, sug-
established a united managerial company, called ‘Tbilisi Microbus’. gesting building upon a Polanyian perspective to understand in-
They purchased up to 2500 new vehicles and set up a centralised co- formality, markets and embeddedness.
ordination structure for the sector. This clarified property and access Reading marshrutkas in a substantivist manner reveals a very dif-
rights virtually overnight, and made them easily enforceable by the ferent picture then a formalist perspective would allow. For one, in-
state, removing the need for involvement of non-state extra-legal actors. formal markets do not function like laissez-faire markets, as the existing
This also de-personalised the relations between the operating company informal transport literature would assume. Moreover, as the Tbilisi
and drivers, and established formal contractual relations between them. case shows, even institutionalised markets can be informally embedded.
The standardisation of the fleet, alongside new tools of managerial The goal of drawing a more nuanced picture of informal transport is not
control (including GPS tracking) substantially de-personalised driver- only to reveal empirical complexity. Altering the conceptual lenses
passenger relations, reduced the leeway to negotiate fares, and most through which we see informal transport, or urban transport in general,
importantly, ruled out the previous practice of flexibly manoeuvring has further implications. This empirical nuance, or the lack thereof,
routes upon passengers' request. This essentially marked the dis-em- defines what kind of theoretical arguments and causal links are being
bedding of marshrutkas at different levels of economic exchange, and inferred. Moreover, theoretical generalisations define what lessons are
the consolidation of the sector into the hands of a clearly identifiable learned from the research, and which policy solutions are suggested.
and taxable private profit-seeking company. Numerous scholars have suggested learning from the informal
The formalisation of the once-informal marshrutka sector did not transport experience to make public transit more flexible and efficient
involve the simultaneous institutionalisation of social embeddedness, elsewhere (Cervero, 2000; Finn, 2012; Neumann, 2014). Such cross-
and it drew on exploiting a legally unprotected labour force. The di- learning propositions stress the demand-responsiveness of transport
verse body of transport workers, which in some cases included former operating within market-based competition. In sharp contrast to this
vehicle or route owners, transformed into a body of drivers leasing account, an analysis of the marshrutka sector from a Polanyian lens
vehicles from the company. The drivers' incomes now depend entirely articulates the role of social (dis)embeddedness, and thus radically al-
on their work for the managerial company, all while they own neither ters basic theoretical assumptions about informal transport. The de-
shares in the company nor even the vehicles they operate. Nevertheless, mand-responsiveness of marshrutkas comes not from the operation of
they are contracted as ‘self-employed entrepreneurs’. This allows the the invisible hand, but from their very visible and tangible local social
company to duck away from employment regulations and social con- embeddedness. Moreover, the reproduction of the sector depends on
tributions (mostly income tax) as well as from vehicle insurance and exploitation and self-exploitation of transport workers. In both Bishkek
maintenance, which are being socialised onto drivers. However, the and Tbilisi, local and national governments attempt to formalise
Tbilisi Microbus company did not fully disturb one key set of relations: marshrutkas as businesses, but avoid formalising labour relations. In
the drivers' informal social safety net. By the time of its entry into the such a context, informal horizontal social embeddedness serves as the
sector, the company allowed pre-existing transport workers' collectives only venue for enabling the reproduction of worker's livelihoods, and as
to remain in their previous work locations. At present, collectives of ten a way to cope with market-related risks and insecurities.

7
L. Rekhviashvili, W. Sgibnev Journal of Transport Geography xxx (xxxx) xxx–xxx

In past few years, digitally empowered ride-sourcing companies are Cervero, R., Golub, A., 2007. Informal transport: a global perspective. Transp. Policy 14
transforming informal sharing mobility practices in the region. App- (6), 445–457. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.tranpol.2007.04.011.
Chersi, E., 1997. The informal economy in Latin America. Gate J. 17 (1), 99–108.
based taxi services such as Taxify, Maxim, or Yandex Taxi, are entering Dalton, G., 1968. Introduction. In: Polanyi, K. (Ed.), Primitive, Archaic, and Modern
the market with so far unclear consequences for mobility provision and Economies: Essays of KarlPolanyi. Doubleday, Garden City, NY, pp. ix–xlvi.
employment relations. The proliferation of app-based mobility options De Soto, H., 1989. The Other Path: The Invisible Revolution in the Third World. 1st ed).
Harper & Row, New York.
in contexts where formal labour protection is almost inexistent could De Soto, H., 2000. The Mystery of Capital: Why Capitalism Triumphs in the West and Fails
possibly undermine even the informal social embeddedness. If the Everywhere Else. Basic Books, New York.
marshrutka and the pre-existing taxi sector's informal embeddedness is Diaz Olvera, L., Guézéré, A., Plat, D., Pochet, P., 2016. Earning a living, but at what price?
Being a motorcycle taxi driver in a Sub-Saharan African city. J. Transp. Geogr. 55,
enabled by the solidarisation of transport workers and their attachment 165–174. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jtrangeo.2015.11.010.
to specific locations, ride-sourcing companies could undermine drivers' Evans, J., O'Brien, J., Ch Ng, B., 2018. Towards a geography of informal transport:
capacity to collectively mobilise – along the same line as we have seen Mobility, infrastructure and urban sustainability from the back of a motorbike. Trans.
Inst. Br. Geogr. https://doi.org/10.1111/tran.12239.
in the Global North where ride-sourcing companies attempt to prevent
Ferro, P.S., Behrens, R., 2015. From direct to trunk-and-feeder public transport services in
the collective mobilisations of drivers (Hawkins, 2017). the Urban South: Territorial implications. J. Transport Land Use 8 (1), 123–136.
Indeed, thinking of new ride-sourcing companies from a Polanyian https://doi.org/10.5198/jtlu.2015.389.
perspective also alters the prevalent picture of this emerging and Finn, B., 2012. Towards large-scale flexible transport services: a practical perspective
from the domain of paratransit. Res. Transport. Business Manag. 3, 39–49. https://
quickly expanding sector. Such companies build their business on the doi.org/10.1016/j.rtbm.2012.06.010.
avoidance of pre-existing social regulations (of the taxi sector, for in- Gibson, K., Cahill, A., McKay, D., 2010. Rethinking the dynamics of rural transformation:
stance), and the informalisation of labour relations. Contrary to performing different development pathways in a Philippine municipality. Trans. Inst.
Br. Geogr. 35 (2), 237–255. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1475-5661.2009.00378.x.
marshrutkas, however, it is doubtful whether the sector enables hor- Gibson-Graham, J.K., 2006. A Postcapitalist Politics. 1 edition. Univ Of Minnesota Press,
izontal informal embeddedness, while undermining formal socially Minneapolis.
embedding institutions. In this case, the expansion of markets generates Gibson-Graham, J.K., 2008. Diverse economies: performative practices for `other worlds.
Prog. Hum. Geogr. 32 (5), 613–632. https://doi.org/10.1177/0309132508090821.
an informalisation of labour relations, but impedes local informal la- Golub, A., Balassiano, R., Araújo, A., Ferreira, E., 2009. Regulation of the informal
bour protection, given the de-territorialised and impersonal recruit- transport sector in Rio de Janeiro, Brazil: welfare impacts and policy analysis.
ment strategies and digitally fuelled modes of operation (Rekhviashvili Transportation 36 (5), 601–616. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11116-009-9215-y.
Granovetter, M., 1985. Economic action and social structure: the problem of embedd-
and Sgibnev, 2018a,b). Unlike existing readings, a Polanyian stance edness. Am. J. Sociol. 91 (3), 481–510.
would see such informalisation of labour relations not as a sad side- Guha-Khasnobis, B., Kanbur, R., Ostrom, E., 2006. Beyond formality and informality. In:
effect, but as a consequence and direct enabler of the sector's fast ex- Guha-Khasnobis, B., Kanbur, R., Ostrom, E. (Eds.), Linking the Formal and Informal
Economy. Oxford University Press, pp. 1–29. Retrieved from. http://www.
pansion. Learning from informal transport is vital here as well, but in
oxfordscholarship.com/view/10.1093/0199204764.001.0001/acprof-
terms of acknowledging the structural precariousness of the labour 9780199204762.
force in the absence of social regulations which come to counterbalance Gwilliam, K.M., 2001. Competition in urban passenger transport in the developing world.
marketisation (Rizzo, 2011; Spooner, 2011). J. Transport Econ. Policy 35 (1), 99–118.
Hann, C.M., Hart, K. (Eds.), 2009. Market and Society: the Great Transformation Today.
Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK; New York.
Acknowledgements Hannam, K., Sheller, M., Urry, J., 2006. Editorial: mobilities, immobilities and moorings.
Mobilities 1 (1), 1–22. https://doi.org/10.1080/17450100500489189.
Hart, K., 1973. Informal income opportunities and urban employment in Ghana. J. Mod.
We are immensely grateful to Professor Bela Greskovits for his ex- Afr. Stud. 11 (1), 61–89.
tensive support, feedback and insights while elaborating the theoretical Hawkins, A.J., 2017, February 6. Uber Sues Seattle over Law Allowing Drivers to
linkages between marketisation, social embeddedness and informality. Unionize. Retrieved June 5, 2017, from. https://www.theverge.com/2017/2/6/
14524792/uber-lawsuit-seattle-law-drivers-unionize.
We thank the Volkswagen Foundation for providing generous funding Kębłowski, W., Bassens, D., 2017. “All transport problems are essentially mathematical”:
(project number 89 816) for the research project “Fluid mobilities for the uneven resonance of academic transport and mobility knowledge in Brussels.
cities in transformation: spatial dynamics of marshrutkas in Central Urban Geogr. 0 (0), 1–25. https://doi.org/10.1080/02723638.2017.1336320.
Kumar, M., Singh, S., Ghate, A.T., Pal, S., Wilson, S.A., 2016. Informal public transport
Asia and the Caucasus” at the Leibniz Institute for Regional Geography.
modes in India: a case study of five city regions. IATSS Res. 39 (2), 102–109. https://
We also extend our thanks the anonymous reviewers for providing in- doi.org/10.1016/j.iatssr.2016.01.001.
sightful feedback to an early draft of this paper. Kwan, M.-P., Schwanen, T., 2016. Geographies of Mobility. Ann. Am. Assoc. Geogr. 106
(2), 243–256. https://doi.org/10.1080/24694452.2015.1123067.
Ledeneva, A., 2006. How Russia Really Works: The Informal Practices that Shaped Post-
References Soviet Politics and Business. Cornell University Press, Ithaca.
Mars, G., Altman, Y., 1983. The cultural bases of Soviet Georgia's second economy. Sov.
Belk, R., 2014. You are what you can access: sharing and collaborative consumption Stud. 35 (4), 546–560.
online. J. Bus. Res. 67 (8), 1595–1600. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbusres.2013.10. Morris, J., 2011. Socially embedded workers at the nexus of diverse work in Russia. Int. J.
001. Sociol. Soc. Policy 31 (11/12), 619–631. https://doi.org/10.1108/
Best, A., 2016. The Way They Blow the Horn: Caribbean Dollar Cabs and Subaltern 01443331111177832.
Mobilities. Ann. Am. Assoc. Geogr. 106 (2), 442–449. https://doi.org/10.1080/ Morris, J., Polese, A. (Eds.), 2014. The Informal Post-Socialist Economy: Embedded
00045608.2015.1120148. Practices and Livelihoods. Routledge, New York.
Bohle, D., Greskovits, B., 2009. Varieties of capitalism and capitalism « tout court ». Eur. Morris, J., Polese, A. (Eds.), 2015. Informal Economies in Post-Socialist Spaces: Practices,
J. Sociol. Arch. 50 (03), 355–386. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0003975609990178. Institutions and Networks. Palgrave Macmillan, New York.
Bohle, D., Greskovits, B., 2012. Capitalist Diversity on Europe's Periphery. Cornell Neumann, A., 2014. A paratransit-inspired evolutionary process for public transit net-
University Press, Ithaca. work design (PhD thesis). In: Retrieved from. Berlin Technical University, Berlin.
Bundhun, R., 2018, March 24. Uber and rival Ola drivers under pressure in India as battle https://depositonce.tu-berlin.de/handle/11303/4393.
heats up. Retrieved September 30, 2018, from. https://www.thenational.ae/ North, D.C., 1995. Institutions, Institutional Change, and Economic Performance.
business/uber-and-rival-ola-drivers-under-pressure-in-india-as-battle-heats-up-1. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.
715655. Olaya, C., Díaz, F., Caicedo, S., 2007. Towards a system dynamics model of De Soto's
Burawoy, M., 1999. The Great Involution: Russia's Response to the Market. Retrieved theory on informal economy. In: Proceedings of the 26th International Conference of
from. http://burawoy.berkeley.edu/Russia/involution.pdf. the System Dynamics Society. System Dynamics Society, Athens, Greece, pp. 1–20.
Burawoy, M., 2010. From polanyi to pollyanna: the false optimism of global labor studies. Paget-Seekins, L., 2015. Bus rapid transit as a neoliberal contradiction. J. Transp. Geogr.
Global Labour J. 1 (2), 301–313. https://doi.org/10.15173/glj.v1i2.1079. 48, 115–120. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jtrangeo.2015.08.015.
Bürge, M., 2011. Riding the narrow tracks of moral life: commercial motorbike riders in Peck, J., 2013. Disembedding Polanyi: Exploring Polanyian Economic Geographies.
Makeni, Sierra Leone. Africa Today 58 (2), 58–95. Environ Plan A 45 (7), 1536–1544. https://doi.org/10.1068/a46253.
Cameron, J., Gibson, K., 2005. Alternative pathways to community and economic de- Pojani, D., Stead, D., 2015. Sustainable urban transport in the developing world: beyond
velopment: the latrobe valley community partnering project. Geogr. Res. 43 (3), megacities. Sustainability 7 (6), 7784–7805. https://doi.org/10.3390/su7067784.
274–285. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1745-5871.2005.00327.x. Polanyi, K., 1957. The Great Transformation. Beacon Press, Boston.
Cervero, R., 2000. Informal Transport in the Developing World. United Nations Centre for Polanyi, K., 1968. In: Dalton, G. (Ed.), Primitive, archaic, and modern economies: essays
Human Settlements (Habitat), Nairobi. of KarlPolanyi. Doubleday, Garden City, NY.
Polese, A., Rekhviashvili, L., Kovács, B., Morris, J., 2018. Post-Socialist Informalities:

8
L. Rekhviashvili, W. Sgibnev Journal of Transport Geography xxx (xxxx) xxx–xxx

Power, Agency and the Construction of Extra-Legalities from Bosnia to China. Taylor Series No. 5356). The World Bank Retrieved from. https://ideas.repec.org/p/wbk/
and Francis, London Retrieved from. http://www.tandfebooks.com/isbn/ wbrwps/5356.html.
9781351585194. Sgibnev, W., Vozyanov, A., 2016. Assemblages of mobility: the marshrutkas of Central
Portes, A., Castells, M., Benton, L.A. (Eds.), 1989. The Informal Economy: Studies in Asia. Central Asian Survey 35 (2), 276–291. https://doi.org/10.1080/02634937.
Advanced and Less Developed Countries. Johns Hopkins University Press, 2016.1145381.
Baltimore, Md. Slade, G., 2012. No country for made men: the decline of the Mafia in Post-Soviet Georgia.
Rahman, M.M., Assadekjaman, M., 2013. Rickshaw pullers and the cycle of unsustain- Law Soc. Rev. 46 (3), 623–649. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-5893.2012.00508.x.
ability in Dhaka City. Transfers 3 (3), 99–118. https://doi.org/10.3167/TRANS. Slavnic, Z., 2010. Political economy of informalization. Eur. Soc. 12 (1), 3–23. https://
2013.030307. doi.org/10.1080/14616690903042724.
Rekhviashvili, L., Sgibnev, W., 2018a. Placing transport workers on the agenda: the Smith, A., Rochovská, A., 2007. Domesticating neo-liberalism: everyday lives and the
conflicting logics of governing mobility on Bishkek's Marshrutkas. Antipode 50 (5), geographies of post-socialist transformations. Geoforum 38 (6), 1163–1178. https://
1376–1395. https://doi.org/10.1111/anti.12402. doi.org/10.1016/j.geoforum.2007.03.003.
Rekhviashvili, L., Sgibnev, W., 2018b. Uber, Marshrutkas and socially (dis-)embedded Sopranzetti, C., 2014. Owners of the map: mobility and mobilization among motorcycle
mobilities. J. Transp. Hist. https://doi.org/10.1177/0022526618757203. taxi drivers in Bangkok. City Soc. 26 (1), 120–143. https://doi.org/10.1111/ciso.
0022526618757203. 12030.
Rizzo, M., 2002. Being taken for a ride: privatisation of the Dar Es Salaam transport Spooner, D., 2011. Transport Workers in the Urban Informal Economy: Livelihood Profile.
system 1983–1998. J. Mod. Afr. Stud. 40 (1), 133–157. Retrieved February 12, 2017, from. http://wiego.org/informal-economy/
Rizzo, M., 2011. “Life isWar”: informal transport workers and neoliberalism in Tanzania occupational-groups/transport-workers.
1998–2009. Dev. Chang. 42 (5), 1179–1205. Stenning, A., Smith, A., Rochovská, A., Świątek, D., 2010. Domesticating Neo-Liberalism:
Rodgers, P., Williams, C., 2009. Guest editors' introduction. Int. J. Sociol. 39 (2), 3–11. Spaces of Economic Practice and Social Reproduction in Post-Socialist Cities, 1 edi-
https://doi.org/10.2753/IJS0020-7659390200. tion. Wiley-Blackwell, Malden, MA.
Routh, S., 2011. Building informal workers agenda: imagining “informal employment” in Streeck, W., 2011. Taking capitalism seriously: towards an institutionalist approach to
conceptual resolution of “informality”. Global Labour J. 2 (3). https://doi.org/10. contemporary political economy. Soc. Econ. Rev. 9 (1), 137–167. https://doi.org/10.
15173/glj.v2i3.1106. 1093/ser/mwq028.
Roy, A., 2009. Why india cannot plan its cities: informality, insurgence and the idiom of Williams, C., 2004. The myth of marketization: an evaluation of the persistence of non-
urbanization. Planning Theory 8 (1), 76–87. https://doi.org/10.1177/ market activities in advanced economies. Int. Sociol. 19 (4), 437–449. https://doi.
1473095208099299. org/10.1177/0268580904047366.
Sanina, A., 2011. The marshrutka as a socio-cultural phenomenon of a Russian megacity. Williams, C., Onoschenko, O., 2014. The diverse livelihood practices of health-care
City Cult. Soc. 2 (4), 211–218. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ccs.2011.12.002. workers in Ukraine: the case of Sasha and Natasha. In: Morris, J., Polese, A. (Eds.),
Sassen, Saskia, 1997. Informalization in Advanced Market Economies (Working Paper). The Informal Post-Socialist Economy: Embedded Practices and Livelihoods.
International Labour Office Development and Technical Cooperation Dept., Geneva, Routledge, New York, pp. 21–34.
pp. 29. Retrieved from. http://www.ilo.org/employment/Whatwedo/Publications/ Wilson, H.F., 2011. Passing propinquities in the Multicultural City: the everyday en-
WCMS_123590/lang–en/index.htm. counters of bus passengering. Environ. Plan. A Econ. Space 43 (3), 634–649. https://
Schneider, F., Buehn, A., Montenegro, C.E., 2010. Shadow Economies All Over the World: doi.org/10.1068/a43354.
New Estimates for 162 Countries From 1999 to 2007 (Policy Research Working Paper

You might also like