You are on page 1of 20

Futures Hedge Ratios: A Review*

74
Sheng-Syan Chen, Cheng-Few Lee, and Keshab Shrestha

Abstract
This paper presents a review of different theoretical approaches to the optimal futures
hedge ratios. These approaches are based on minimum variance, mean-variance, expected
utility, mean extended-Gini coefficient, semivariance and Value-at-Risk. Various ways of
estimating these hedge ratios are also discussed, ranging from simple ordinary least squares
to complicated heteroscedastic cointegration methods. Under martingale and joint-
normality conditions, different hedge ratios are the same as the minimum variance hedge
ratio. Otherwise, the optimal hedge ratios based on the different approaches are in general
different and there is no single optimal hedge ratio that is distinctly superior to the
remaining ones.

Keywords
Cointegration  Gini coefficient  Hedge ratio  Minimum variance  Semi variance

74.1 Introduction

One of the best uses of derivative securities such as futures


contracts is in hedging. In the past, both academicians and
practitioners have shown great interest in the issue of hedg-
ing with futures. This is quite evident from the large number
*
This article is an updated version of the article entitled “Futures hedge of articles written in this area.
ratios: a review” published in the Quarterly Review of Economics and One of the main theoretical issues in hedging involves the
Finance (Sheng-Syan Chen, Cheng-few Lee, and Keshab Shrestha,
Vol. 43, 2003, pp. 433–465). We would like to thank the editor of the
determination of the optimal hedge ratio. However, the
Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance, Professor H.S. Esfahani, optimal hedge ratio depends on the particular objective
and Elsevier for permission to reprint the paper. function to be optimized. Many different objective functions
S.-S. Chen (*) are currently being used. For example, one of the most
Department of Finance, College of Management, National widely-used hedging strategies is based on the minimization
Taiwan University, No. 85, Sec. 4, Roosevelt Road, Taipei, of the variance of the hedged portfolio (e.g., see Johnson,
Taiwan, China
e-mail: fnschen@management.ntu.edu.tw
1960; Ederington, 1979; Myers and Thompson, 1989). This -
so-called minimum-variance (MV) hedge ratio is simple to
C.-F. Lee
Rutgers Business School, Rutgers University, New Brunswick, USA
understand and estimate. However, the MV hedge ratio
completely ignores the expected return of the hedged port-
Graduate Institute of Finance, National Chiao Tung University,
Taiwan, China
folio. Therefore, this strategy is in general inconsistent with
e-mail: lee@rbs.rutgers.edu the mean-variance framework unless the individuals are
K. Shrestha
infinitely risk-averse or the futures price follows a pure
Risk Management Institute, National University of Singapore, 21 Heng martingale process (i.e., expected futures price change is
Mui Keng Terrace, I3 Building, Singapore 119613, Singapore zero).
e-mail: rmikms@nus.edu.sg

C.-F. Lee and A.C. Lee (eds.), Encyclopedia of Finance, DOI 10.1007/978-1-4614-5360-4_74, 871
# Springer Science+Business Media New York 2013
872 S.-S. Chen et al.

Other strategies that incorporate both the expected return securities are incorporated in the model. Using a CARA
and risk (variance) of the hedged portfolio have been utility function, Lence finds that under certain circumstances
recently proposed (e.g., see Howard and D’Antonio, 1984; the optimal hedge ratio is zero; i.e., the optimal hedging
Cecchetti et al., 1988; Hsin et al., 1994). These strategies are strategy is not to hedge at all.
consistent with the mean-variance framework. However, it In addition to the use of different objective functions in
can be shown that if the futures price follows a pure martin- the derivation of the optimal hedge ratio, previous studies
gale process, then the optimal mean-variance hedge ratio also differ in terms of the dynamic nature of the hedge ratio.
will be the same as the MV hedge ratio. For example, some studies assume that the hedge ratio is
Another aspect of the mean-variance based strategies is constant over time. Consequently, these static hedge ratios
that even though they are an improvement over the MV are estimated using unconditional probability distributions
strategy, for them to be consistent with the expected utility (e.g., see Ederington, 1979; Howard and D’Antonio, 1984;
maximization principle, either the utility function needs to Benet, 1992; Kolb and Okunev, 1992, 1993; Ghosh, 1993).
be quadratic or the returns should be jointly normal. If On the other hand, several studies allow the hedge ratio to
neither of these assumptions is valid, then the hedge ratio change over time. In some cases, these dynamic hedge ratios
may not be optimal with respect to the expected utility are estimated using conditional distributions associated with
maximization principle. Some researchers have solved this models such as ARCH and GARCH (e.g., see Cecchetti
problem by deriving the optimal hedge ratio based on the et al., 1988; Baillie and Myers, 1991; Kroner and Sultan,
maximization of the expected utility (e.g., see Cecchetti 1993; Sephton, 1993a). The GARCH based method has
et al., 1988; Lence, 1995, 1996). However, this approach recently been extended by Lee and Yoder (2007) where
requires the use of specific utility function and specific regime-switching model is used. Alternatively, the hedge
return distribution. ratios can be made dynamic by considering a multi-period
Attempts have been made to eliminate these specific model where the hedge ratios are allowed to vary for differ-
assumptions regarding the utility function and return ent periods. This is the method used by Lien and Luo
distributions. Some of them involve the minimization of (1993b).
the mean extended-Gini (MEG) coefficient, which is consis- When it comes to estimating the hedge ratios, many
tent with the concept of stochastic dominance (e.g., see different techniques are currently being employed, ranging
Cheung et al., 1990; Kolb and Okunev, 1992, 1993; Lien from simple to complex ones. For example, some of them
and Luo, 1993a; Shalit, 1995; Lien and Shaffer, 1999). Shalit use such a simple method as the ordinary least squares
(1995) shows that if the prices are normally distributed, (OLS) technique (e.g., see Ederington, 1979; Malliaris and
then the MEG-based hedge ratio will be the same as the Urrutia, 1991; Benet, 1992). However, others use more
MV hedge ratio. complex methods such as the conditional heteroscedastic
Recently, hedge ratios based on the generalized (ARCH or GARCH) method (e.g., see Cecchetti et al., 1988;
semivariance (GSV) or lower partial moments have been Baillie and Myers, 1991; Sephton, 1993a), the random coeffi-
proposed (e.g., see De Jong et al., 1997; Lien and Tse, cient method (e.g., see Grammatikos and Saunders, 1983), the
1998, 2000; Chen et al., 2001). These hedge ratios are also cointegration method (e.g., see Ghosh, 1993; Lien and Luo,
consistent with the concept of stochastic dominance. Fur- 1993b; Chou et al., 1996), or the cointegration-heteroscedastic
thermore, these GSV-based hedge ratios have another attrac- method (e.g., see Kroner and Sultan, 1993). Recently, Lien
tive feature whereby they measure portfolio risk by the GSV, and Shrestha (2007) has suggested the use of wavelet analysis
which is consistent with the risk perceived by managers, to match the data frequency with the hedging horizon. Finally,
because of its emphasis on the returns below the target return Lien and Shrestha (2010) also suggests the use of multivariate
(see Crum et al., 1981; Lien and Tse, 2000). Lien and Tse skew-normal distribution in estimating the minimum variance
(1998) show that if the futures and spot returns are jointly hedge ratio.
normally distributed and if the futures price follows a pure It is quite clear that there are several different ways of
martingale process, then the minimum-GSV hedge ratio will deriving and estimating hedge ratios. In the paper we review
be equal to the MV hedge ratio. Finally, Hung et al. (2006) these different techniques and approaches and examine their
has proposed a related hedge ratio that minimizes the Value- relations.
at-Risk associated with the hedged portfolio when choosing The paper is divided into five sections. In Section 74.2
hedge ratio. This hedge ratio will also be equal to MV hedge alternative theories for deriving the optimal hedge ratios are
ratio if the futures price follows a pure martingale process. reviewed. Various estimation methods are discussed in Sec-
Most of the studies mentioned above (except Lence, tion 74.3. Section 74.4 presents a discussion on the relation-
1995, 1996) ignore transaction costs as well as investments ship among lengths of hedging horizon, maturity of futures
in other securities. Lence (1995, 1996) derives the optimal contract, data frequency, and hedging effectiveness. Finally,
hedge ratio where transaction costs and investments in other in Section 74.5 we provide a summary and conclusion.
74 Futures Hedge Ratios: A Review 873

Table 74.1 A list of different static hedge ratios


74.2 Alternative Theories for Deriving Hedge ratio Objective function
the Optimal Hedge Ratio Minimum-variance (MV) hedge ratio Minimize variance of
Rh
The basic concept of hedging is to combine investments in Optimum mean-variance hedge Ratio Maximize
the spot market and futures market to form a portfolio that EðRh Þ  A2 Var ðRh Þ
EðRh ÞRF
will eliminate (or reduce) fluctuations in its value. Specifi- Sharpe hedge ratio Maximize p ffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi
Var ðRh Þ
cally, consider a portfolio consisting of Cs units of a long Maximum expected utility hedge ratio Maximize E½U ðW 1 Þ
spot position and Cf units of a short futures position.1 Let St Minimum mean extended-Gini (MEG) Minimize Gv ðRh vÞ
and Ft denote the spot and futures prices at time t, respec- coefficient hedge ratio
tively. Since the futures contracts are used to reduce the Optimum mean-MEG hedge ratio Maximize
fluctuations in spot positions, the resulting portfolio is E½Rh   Gv ðRh vÞ
known as the hedged portfolio. The return on the hedged Minimum generalized semivariance (GSV) Minimize V d;a ðRh Þ
hedge ratio
portfolio, Rh , is given by:
Maximum mean-GSV hedge ratio Maximize
E½Rh   V d;a ðRh Þ
Cs St Rs  Cf Ft Rf
Rh ¼ ¼ Rs  hRf ; (74.1a) Minimum VaR hedge ratio over a given time Minimize
pffiffiffi
C s St period t Z a sh t  E½Rh t
Notes
Cf F t Stþ1 St 1. Rh ¼ return on the hedged portfolio
where h ¼ Cs St is the so-called hedge ratio, and Rs ¼ St
Ftþ1 Ft
EðRh Þ ¼ expected return on the hedged portfolio
and Rf ¼ Ft are so-called one-period returns on the spot Var ðRh Þ ¼ variance of return on the hedged portfolio
and futures positions, respectively. Sometimes, the hedge sh ¼ standard deviation of return on the hedged portfolio
Z a ¼ negative of left percentile at afor the standard normal distribution
ratio is discussed in terms of price changes (profits) instead A ¼ risk aversion parameter
of returns. In this case the profit on the hedged portfolio, RF ¼ return on the risk-free security
DV H , and the hedge ratio, H, are respectively given by: EðU ðW 1 ÞÞ ¼ expected utility of end-of-period wealth
Gv ðRh vÞ ¼ mean extended-Gini coefficient of Rh
V d;a ðRh Þ ¼ generalized semivariance of Rh
Cf
DV H ¼ Cs DSt  Cf DFt and H ¼ (74.1b) 2. With W 1 given by Equation 74.17, the maximum expected utility
Cs hedge ratio includes the hedge ratio considered by Lence (1995, 1996)

where DSt ¼ Stþ1  St and DFt ¼ Ftþ1  Ft .


The main objective of hedging is to choose the optimal 74.2.1.1 Minimum-Variance Hedge Ratio
hedge ratio (either h or H). As mentioned above, the optimal The most widely-used static hedge ratio is the minimum-
hedge ratio will depend on a particular objective function to variance (MV) hedge ratio. Johnson (1960) derives this
be optimized. Furthermore, the hedge ratio can be static or hedge ratio by minimizing the portfolio risk, where the risk
dynamic. In subsections A and B, we will discuss the static is given by the variance of changes in the value of the hedged
hedge ratio and then the dynamic hedge ratio. portfolio as follows:
It is important to note that in the above setup, the cash
position is assumed to be fixed and we only look for the Var ðDV H Þ ¼ C2s Var ðDSÞ þ C2f Var ðDFÞ  2Cs Cf Cov
optimum futures position. Most of the hedging literature  ðDS; DFÞ:
assumes that the cash position is fixed, a setup that is suitable
for financial futures. However, when we are dealing with The MV hedge ratio, in this case, is given by:
commodity futures, the initial cash position becomes an
important decision variable that is tied to the production Cf CovðDS; DFÞ
decision. One such setup considered by Lence (1995, HJ ¼ ¼ : (74.2a)
Cs Var ðDFÞ
1996) will be discussed in subsection C.
Alternatively, if we use definition (74.1a) and use Var ðRh Þ
74.2.1 Static Case to represent the portfolio risk, then the MV hedge ratio is
obtained by minimizing Var ðRh Þ which is given by:
We consider here that the hedge ratio is static if it remains    
the same over time. The static hedge ratios reviewed in this Var ðRh Þ ¼ Var ðRs Þ þ h2 Var Rf  2hCov Rs ; Rf :
paper can be divided into eight categories, as shown in
Table 74.1. We will discuss each of them in the paper. In this case, the MV hedge ratio is given by:
874 S.-S. Chen et al.

 
Cov Rs ; Rf s process, then we do not need to know the risk aversion
hJ ¼   ¼r s; (74.2b) parameter of the investor to find the optimal hedge ratio.
Var Rf sf

where r is the correlation coefficient between Rs and Rf , and 74.2.1.3 Sharpe Hedge Ratio
ss and sf are standard deviations of Rs and Rf , respectively. Another way of incorporating the portfolio return in the
The attractive features of the MV hedge ratio are that it is hedging strategy is to use the risk-return tradeoff (Sharpe
easy to understand and simple to compute. However, in measure) criteria. Howard and D’Antonio (1984) consider
general the MV hedge ratio is not consistent with the the optimal level of futures contracts by maximizing the
mean-variance framework since it ignores the expected ratio of the portfolio’s excess return to its volatility:
return on the hedged portfolio. For the MV hedge ratio to
be consistent with the mean-variance framework, either the Eð Rh Þ  R F
Max y ¼ ; (74.5)
investors need to be infinitely risk-averse or the expected Cf sh
return on the futures contract needs to be zero.
where s2h ¼ Var ðRh Þ and RF represents the risk-free interest
rate. In this case the optimal number of futures positions, Cf ,
74.2.1.2 Optimum Mean-Variance Hedge Ratio
is given by:
Various studies have incorporated both risk and return in the
derivation of the hedge ratio. For example, Hsin et al. (1994)        
derive the optimal hedge ratio that maximizes the following S ss ss E Rf
r
utility function: F sf sf EðRs Þ  RF
Cf ¼ Cs      : (74.6)
ss E Rf r
1
Max V ðEðRh Þ; s; AÞ ¼ EðRh Þ  0:5As2h ; (74.3) sf EðRs Þ  RF
Cf

From the optimal futures position, we can obtain the


where A represents the risk aversion parameter. It is clear
following optimal hedge ratio:
that this utility function incorporates both risk and return.
Therefore, the hedge ratio based on this utility function       
ss ss E Rf
would be consistent with the mean-variance framework. r
sf sf EðRs Þ  RF
The optimal number of futures contract and the optimal h3 ¼       : (74.7)
hedge ratio are respectively given by: ss E Rf r
1
s f E ð Rs Þ  RF
"   #
Cf F E Rf ss  
h2 ¼  ¼ r : (74.4) Again, if E Rf ¼ 0, then h3 reduces to:
Cs S As2f sf
 
ss
One problem associated with this type of hedge ratio is that h3 ¼ r; (74.8)
sf
in order to derive the optimum hedge ratio, we need to know
the individual’s risk aversion parameter. Furthermore, differ-
which is the same as the MV hedge ratio hJ .
ent individuals will choose different optimal hedge ratios,
As pointed out by Chen et al. (2001), the Sharpe ratio is a
depending on the values of their risk aversion parameter.
highly non-linear function of the hedge ratio. Therefore, it is
Since the MV hedge ratio is easy to understand and simple
possible that Equation 74.7, which is derived by equating the
to compute, it will be interesting and useful to know under
first derivative to zero, may lead to the hedge ratio that
what condition the above hedge ratio would be the same as
would minimize, instead of maximizing, the Sharpe ratio.
the MV hedge ratio. It can  be
 seen from Equations 74.2b and This would be true if the second derivative of the Sharpe
74.4 that if A ! 1 or E Rf ¼ 0, then h2 would be equal to
ratio with respect to the hedge ratio is positive instead of
the MV hedge ratio hJ . The first condition is simply a restate-
negative. Furthermore, it is possible that the optimal hedge
ment of the infinitely risk-averse individuals. However, the
ratio may be undefined as in the case encountered by Chen
second condition does not impose any condition on the risk-
et al. (2001), where the Sharpe ratio monotonically increases
averseness, and this is important. It implies that even if
with the hedge ratio.
the individuals are not infinitely risk averse, then the MV
hedge ratio would be the same as the optimal mean-variance
hedge ratio if the expected return on the futures contract is 74.2.1.4 Maximum Expected Utility Hedge Ratio
zero (i.e. futures prices follow a simple martingale process). So far we have discussed the hedge ratios that incorporate
Therefore, if futures prices follow a simple martingale only risk as well as the ones that incorporate both risk and
74 Futures Hedge Ratios: A Review 875

return. The methods, which incorporate both the expected U ðRh Þ ¼ EðRh Þ  Gv ðRh Þ: (74.10)
return and risk in the derivation of the optimal hedge ratio,
are consistent with the mean-variance framework. However, The hedge ratio based on the utility function defined by
these methods may not be consistent with the expected Equation 74.10 is denoted as the M-MEG hedge ratio. The
utility maximization principle unless either the utility func- difference between the MEG and M-MEG hedge ratios is
tion is quadratic or the returns are jointly normally that the MEG hedge ratio ignores the expected return on the
distributed. Therefore, in order to make the hedge ratio hedged portfolio. Again,
consistent with the expected utility maximization principle,  if the futures price follows a mar-
tingale process (i.e., E Rf ¼ 0), then the MEG hedge ratio
we need to derive the hedge ratio that maximizes the would be the same as the M-MEG hedge ratio.
expected utility. However, in order to maximize the
expected utility we need to assume a specific utility function.
For example, Cecchetti et al. (1988) derive the hedge ratio 74.2.1.7 Minimum Generalized Semivariance
that maximizes the expected utility where the utility function Hedge Ratio
is assumed to be the logarithm of terminal wealth. Specifi- In recent years a new approach for determining the hedge
cally, they derive the optimal hedge ratio that maximizes the ratio has been suggested (see De Jong et al., 1997; Lien and
following expected utility function: Tse, 1998, 2000; Chen et al., 2001). This new approach is
ð ð based on the relationship between the generalized

  semivariance (GSV) and expected utility as discussed by
log 1 þ Rs  hRf f Rs ; Rf dRs dRf ;
Fishburn (1977) and Bawa (1978). In this case the optimal
Rs Rf
hedge ratio is obtained by minimizing the GSV given below:
 
where the density function f Rs ; Rf is assumed to be bivar- ðd
iate normal. A third-order linear bivariate ARCH model is V d;a ðRh Þ ¼ ðd  Rh Þa dGðRh Þ; a>0; (74.11)
used to get the conditional variance and covariance matrix, 1
and a numerical procedure is used to maximize the objective
function with respect to the hedge ratio.2 where GðRh Þ is the probability distribution function of the
return on the hedged portfolio Rh . The parameters d and a
(which are both real numbers) represent the target return and
74.2.1.5 Minimum Mean Extended-Gini
risk aversion, respectively. The risk is defined in such a way
Coefficient Hedge Ratio
that the investors consider only the returns below the target
This approach of deriving the optimal hedge ratio is consis-
return (d) to be risky. It can be shown (see Fishburn, 1977)
tent with the concept of stochastic dominance and involves
that a<1 represents a risk-seeking investor and a>1
the use of the mean extended-Gini (MEG) coefficient.
represents a risk-averse investor.
Cheung et al. (1990), Kolb and Okunev (1992), Lien and
The GSV, due to its emphasis on the returns below the
Luo (1993a), Shalit (1995), and Lien and Shaffer (1999) all
target return, is consistent with the risk perceived by
consider this approach. It minimizes the MEG coefficient
managers (see Crum et al., 1981; Lien and Tse, 2000).
Gn ðRh Þ defined as follows:
Furthermore, as shown by Fishburn (1977) and Bawa
(1978), the GSV is consistent with the concept of stochastic
Gn ðRh Þ ¼ nCov Rh ; ð1  GðRh ÞÞn1 ; (74.9) dominance. Lien and Tse (1998) show that the GSV hedge
ratio, which is obtained by minimizing the GSV, would be
the same as the MV hedge ratio if the futures and spot returns
where G is the cumulative probability distribution and n is
are jointly normally distributed and if the futures price
the risk aversion parameter. Note that 0  n<1 implies risk
follows a pure martingale process.
seekers, n ¼ 1 implies risk-neutral investors, and n>1
implies risk-averse investors. Shalit (1995) has shown that
if the futures and spot returns are jointly normally
74.2.1.8 Optimum Mean-Generalized
distributed, then the minimum-MEG hedge ratio would be
Semivariance Hedge Ratio
the same as the MV hedge ratio.
Chen et al. (2001) extend the GSV hedge ratio to a Mean-
GSV (M-GSV) hedge ratio by incorporating the mean return
74.2.1.6 Optimum Mean-MEG Hedge Ratio in the derivation of the optimal hedge ratio. The M-GSV
Instead of minimizing the MEG coefficient, Kolb and hedge ratio is obtained by maximizing the following mean-
Okunev (1993) alternatively consider maximizing the utility risk utility function, which is similar to the conventional
function defined as follows: mean-variance based utility function (see Equation 74.3):
876 S.-S. Chen et al.

U ðRh Þ ¼ E½Rh   V d;a ðRh Þ: (74.12) Another way of making the hedge ratio dynamic is by
using the regime switching GARCH model (to be discussed
This approach to the hedge ratio does not use the risk later) as suggested by Lee and Yoder (2007). This model
aversion parameter to multiply the GSV as done in conven- assumes two different regimes where each regime is
tional mean-risk models (see Hsin et al., 1994 and Equa- associated with different set of parameters and the
tion 74.3). This is because the risk aversion parameter is probabilities of regime switching must also be estimated
already included in the definition of the GSV, V d;a ðRh Þ. As when implementing such method. Alternatively, we can
before, the M-GSV hedge ratio would be the same as the allow the hedge ratio to change during the hedging period
GSV hedge ratio if the futures price follows a pure martin- by considering multi-period models, which is the approach
gale process. used by Lien and Luo (1993b).
Lien and Luo (1993b) consider hedging with T periods’
planning horizon and minimize the variance of the wealth at
74.2.1.9 Minimum Value-at-Risk Hedge Ratio the end of the planning horizon, W T . Consider the situation
Hung et al. (2006) suggests a new hedge ratio that minimizes where Cs;t is the spot position at the beginning of period t and
the Value-at-Risk of the hedged portfolio. Specifically, the the corresponding futures position is given by Cf ;t ¼ bt Cs;t .
hedge ratio h is derived by minimizing the following Value- The wealth at the end of the planning horizon, W T , is then
at-Risk of the hedged portfolio over a given time period t: given by:

pffiffiffi X
T1
VaRðRh Þ ¼ Z a sh t  E½Rh t (74.13) WT ¼ W0 þ Cs;t ½Stþ1  St  bt ðFtþ1  Ft Þ (74.15)
t¼0
The resulting optimal hedge ratio, which Hung et al.
X
T1
(2006) refer to as zero-VaR hedge ratio, is given by ¼ W0 þ Cs;t ½DStþ1  bt DFtþ1 :
sffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi t¼0
ss
ss 1  r2
hVaR ¼ r  E Rf
(74.14) The optimal bt ’s are given by the following recursive
sf sf Z 2 s2  E Rf 2
a f
formula:
It is clear that, if the futures price follows martingale CovðDStþ1 ; DFtþ1 Þ
process, the zero-VaR hedge ratio would be the same as bt ¼
Var ðDFtþ1 Þ
the MV hedge ratio.
X 1  
T
Cs;i CovðDFtþ1 ; DSiþ1 þ bi DFtþi Þ
þ : (74.16)
i¼tþ1
Cs;t Var ðDFtþ1 Þ
74.2.2 Dynamic Case
It is clear from Equation 74.16 that the optimal hedge
ratio bt will change over time. The multi-period hedge ratio
We have up to now examined the situations in which the
will differ from the single-period hedge ratio due to the
hedge ratio is fixed at the optimum level and is not revised
second term on the right-hand side of Equation 74.16. How-
during the hedging period. However, it could be beneficial to
ever, it is interesting to note that the multi-period hedge ratio
change the hedge ratio over time. One way to allow the
would be different from the single-period one if the changes
hedge ratio to change is by recalculating the hedge ratio
in current futures prices are correlated with the changes in
based on the current (or conditional) information on the
future futures prices or with the changes in future spot prices.
covariance (ssf ) and variance (s2f ). This involves calculating
the hedge ratio based on conditional information (i.e.,
ssf jOt1 and s2f jOt1 ) instead of unconditional information.
In this case, the MV hedge ratio is given by: 74.2.3 Case with Production and Alternative
Investment Opportunities
ssf jOt1
h1 jOt1 ¼  :
s2f jOt1 All the models considered in subsections A and B assume
that the spot position is fixed or predetermined, and thus
The adjustment to the hedge ratio based on new informa- production is ignored. As mentioned earlier, such an
tion can be implemented using such conditional models as assumption may be appropriate for financial futures. How-
ARCH and GARCH (to be discussed later) or using the ever, when we consider commodity futures, production
moving window estimation method. should be considered in which case the spot position
74 Futures Hedge Ratios: A Review 877

becomes one of the decision variables. In an important the CARA utility function and some simulation results,
paper, Lence (1995) extends the model with a fixed or Lence (1995) finds that the expected-utility maximizing
predetermined spot position to a model where production hedge ratios are substantially different from the minimum-
is included. In his model Lence (1995) also incorporates the variance hedge ratios. He also shows that under certain
possibility of investing in a risk-free asset and other risky conditions, the optimal hedge ratio is zero; i.e., the optimal
assets, borrowing, as well as transaction costs. We will strategy is not to hedge at all.
briefly discuss the model considered by Lence (1995) Similarly, the opportunity cost of the estimation risk
below. (eBayes ) is defined as follows:
Lence (1995) considers a decision maker whose utility is
a function of terminal wealth U ðW 1 Þ, such that U 0 >0 and h n h io i
Er E U W 0 Ropt ðrÞ  eBayes
U 00 <0. At the decision date (t ¼ 0Þ), the decision maker will r
h i
engage in the production of Q commodity units for sale at ¼ Er E U W 0 RBayes ; (74.19)
opt
terminal date (t ¼ 1) at the random cash price P1 . At the
decision date, the decision maker can lend L dollars at the -
risk-free lending rate ðRL  1Þ and borrow B dollars at the where Ropt ðrÞ is the expected-utility maximizing return
borrowing rate ðRB  1Þ, invest I dollars in a different activ- where the agent knows with certainty the value of the corre-
ity that yields a random rate of return ðRI  1Þ and sell X lation between the futures and spot prices (r), RBayes
opt is the
futures at futures price F0 . The transaction cost for the expected-utility maximizing return where the agent only
futures trade is f dollars per unit of the commodity traded knows the distribution of the correlation r, and Er ½: is the
to be paid at the terminal date. The terminal wealth (W 1 ) is expectation with respect to r. Using simulation results,
therefore given by: Lence (1995) finds that the opportunity cost of the estima-
tion risk is negligible and thus the value of the use of
sophisticated estimation methods is negligible.
W 1 ¼ W 0 R ¼ P1 Q þ ðF0  F1 ÞX  f j Xj  RB B þ RL L þ RI I;
(74.17)
74.3 Alternative Methods for Estimating
where R is the return on the diversified portfolio. The deci- the Optimal Hedge Ratio
sion maker will maximize the expected utility subject to the
following restrictions: In Section 74.2 we discussed different approaches to deriv-
ing the optimum hedge ratios. However, in order to apply
W 0 þ B  vðQÞQ þ L þ I; 0  B  kB vðQÞQ; kB  0; these optimum hedge ratios in practice, we need to estimate
these hedge ratios. There are various ways of estimating
L  kL F0 j Xj; kL  0; I  0; them. In this section we briefly discuss these estimation
methods.
where vðQÞ is the average cost function, kB is the maximum
amount (expressed as a proportion of his initial wealth) that
the agent can borrow, and kL is the safety margin for the 74.3.1 Estimation of the Minimum-Variance
futures contract. (MV) Hedge Ratio
Using this framework, Lence (1995) introduces two
opportunity costs: opportunity cost of alternative (sub- 74.3.1.1 OLS Method
optimal) investment (calt ) and opportunity cost of estimation The conventional approach to estimating the MV hedge ratio
risk (eBayes ).3 Let Ropt be the return of the expected-utility involves the regression of the changes in spot prices on the
maximizing strategy and let Ralt be the return on a particular changes in futures price using the OLS technique (e.g., see
alternative (sub-optimal) investment strategy. The oppor- Junkus and Lee, 1985). Specifically, the regression equation
tunity cost of alternative investment strategy calt is then can be written as:
given by:
DSt ¼ a0 þ a1 DFt þ et ; (74.20)
 

E U W 0 Ropt ¼ E½U ðW 0 Ralt þ calt Þ: (74.18) where the estimate of the MV hedge ratio, H j , is given by a1 .
The OLS technique is quite robust and simple to use. How-
In other words, calt is the minimum certain net return ever, for the OLS technique to be valid and efficient,
required by the agent to invest in the alternative (sub-optimal assumptions associated with the OLS regression must be
hedging) strategy rather than in the optimum strategy. Using satisfied. One case where the assumptions are not completely
878 S.-S. Chen et al.

satisfied is that the error term in the regression is Then Y is said to have skew-normal distribution if its proba-
heteroscedastic. This situation will be discussed later. bility density function is given as follows:
Another problem with the OLS method, as pointed out by
Myers and Thompson (1989), is the fact that it uses uncon- f Y ðyÞ ¼ 2’k ðy; OY ÞFðat yÞ (74.22)
ditional sample moments instead of conditional sample
moments, which use currently available information. They where a is a k-dimensional column vector, ’k ðy; OY Þ is the
suggest the use of the conditional covariance and conditional probability density function of a k-dimensional standard
variance in Equation 74.2a. In this case, the conditional normal random variable with zero mean and correlation
version of the optimal hedge ratio (Equation 74.2a) will matrix OY and Fðat yÞ is the probability distribution function
take the following form: of a one-dimensional standard normal random variable
evaluated at at y.
Cf CovðDS; DFÞjOt1
HJ ¼ ¼ : (74.2a*)
Cs Var ðDFÞjOt1
74.3.1.3 ARCH and GARCH Methods
Suppose that the current information (Ot1 ) includes a Ever since the development of ARCH and GARCH models,
vector of variables (Xt1 ) and the spot and futures price the OLS method of estimating the hedge ratio has been
changes are generated by the following equilibrium model: generalized to take into account the heteroscedastic nature
of the error term in Equation 74.20. In this case, rather than
DSt ¼ Xt1 a þ ut ; using the unconditional sample variance and covariance, the
conditional variance and covariance from the GARCH
DFt ¼ Xt1 b þ vt :
model are used in the estimation of the hedge ratio. As
mentioned above, such a technique allows an update of the
In this case the maximum likelihood estimator of the MV
hedge ratio over the hedging period.
hedge ratio is given by (see Myers and Thompson, 1989):
Consider the following bivariate GARCH model (see
Cecchetti et al., 1988; Baillie and Myers, 1991):
^uv
^ t1 ¼ s
hjX ; (74.21)      
^2v
s
DSt m1 e
¼ þ 1t , DY t ¼ m þ et ;
DFt m2 e2t
where s^uv is the sample covariance between the residuals
^2v is the sample variance of the residual vt .
ut and vt , and s  
H 11;t H12;t
In general, the OLS estimator obtained from Equation 74.20 et jOt1 N ð0; H t Þ ; H t ¼ ;
H 12;t H22;t
would be different from the one given by Equation 74.21.
For the two estimators to be the same, the spot and futures 0

prices must be generated by the following model: vecðHt Þ ¼ C þ A vec et1 et1 þ B vecðH t1 Þ:

DSt ¼ a0 þ ut ; DFt ¼ b0 þ vt : The conditional MV hedge ratio at time t is given by


ht1 ¼ H 12;t =H 22;t . This model allows the hedge ratio to
In other words, if the spot and futures prices follow a change over time, resulting in a series of hedge ratios instead
random walk, then with or without drift, the two estimators of a single hedge ratio for the entire hedging horizon.
will be the same. Otherwise, the hedge ratio estimated from The model can be extended to include more than one type
the OLS regression (74.18) will not be optimal. of cash and futures contracts (see Sephton, 1993a). For
example, consider a portfolio that consists of spot wheat
74.3.1.2 Multivariate Skew-Normal Distribution (S1;t ), spot canola (S2t ), wheat futures (F1t ) and canola
Method futures (F2t ). We then have the following multi-variate
An alternative way of estimating the MV hedge ratio GARCH model:
involves the assumption that the spot price and futures 2 3 2 3 2 3
DS1t m1 e1t
price follows a multivariate skew-normal distribution as
6 DS 7 6 m 7 6 e 7
suggested by Lien and Shrestha (2010). The estimate of 6 2t 7 6 2 7 6 2t 7
6 7 ¼ 6 7 þ 6 7 , DY t ¼ m þ et ;
covariance matrix under skew-normal distribution can be 4 DF1t 5 4 m3 5 4 e3t 5
different from the estimate of covariance matrix under the DF2t m4 e4t
usual normal distribution resulting in different estimates of et jOt1 N ð0; H t Þ :
MV hedge ratio. Let Y be a k-dimensional random vector.
74 Futures Hedge Ratios: A Review 879

The MV hedge ratio can be estimated using a similar where the hedge ratio bt ¼ b þ vt is assumed to be random.
technique as described above. For example, the conditional This random coefficient model can, in some cases, improve
MV hedge ratio is given by the conditional covariance the effectiveness of hedging strategy. However, this tech-
between the spot and futures price changes divided by the nique does not allow for the update of the hedge ratio over
conditional variance of the futures price change. time even though the correction for the randomness can be
made in the estimation of the hedge ratio.
74.3.1.4 Regime-Switching GARCH Model
The GARCH model discussed above can be further extended 74.3.1.6 Cointegration and Error Correction
by allowing regime switching as suggested by Lee and Method
Yoder (2007). Under this model, the data generating process The techniques described so far do not take into consideration
can be in one of two states or regime denoted by state the possibility that spot price and futures price series could be
variable st ¼ f1; 2g, which is assumed to follow a first- non-stationary. If these series have unit roots, then this will
order Markov process. The state transition probabilities are raise a different issue. If the two series are cointegrated as
assumed to follow a logistic distribution where the transition defined by Engle and Granger (1987), then the regression
probabilities are given by Equation 74.20 will be mis-specified and an error-correction
term must be included in the equation. Since the arbitrage
ep0 condition ties the spot and futures prices, they cannot drift
Prðst ¼ 1jst1 ¼ 1Þ ¼ & Prðst ¼ 2jst1 ¼ 2Þ
1 þ ep0 far apart in the long run. Therefore, if both series follow a
eq0 random walk, then we expect the two series to be cointegrated
¼ :
1 þ eq0 in which case we need to estimate the error correction model.
This calls for the use of the cointegration analysis.
The conditional covariance matrix is given by The cointegration analysis involves two steps. First, each
    series must be tested for a unit root (e.g., see Dickey and Fuller,
h 0 1 rt;st h1;t;st 0
H t;st ¼ 1;t;st 1981; Phillips and Perron, 1988). Second, if both series are
0 h2;t;st rt;st 1 0 h2;t;st found to have a single unit root, then the cointegration test
must be performed (e.g., see Engle and Granger, 1987;
where
Johansen and Juselius, 1990; Osterwald-Lenum, 1992).
If the spot price and futures price series are found to be
h21;t;st ¼ g1;st þ a1;st e21:t1 þ b1;st h21;t1
cointegrated, then the hedge ratio can be estimated in two
h22;t;st ¼ g2;st þ a2;st e22:t1 þ b2;st h22;t1 steps (see Ghosh, 1993; Chou et al., 1996). The first step
involves the estimation of the following cointegrating
 
rt;st ¼ 1  y1;st  y2;st r þ y1;st rt1 þ y2;st ft1 regression:

P
2 St ¼ a þ bFt þ ut : (74.24)
e1;tj e2;tj
j¼1 ei;t
’t1 ¼ vffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi
! !ffi ; ei;t ¼ h ; y1 ; y2
u The second step involves the estimation of the following
u P 2 P2 it
t e21;tj e22;tj error correction model:
j¼1 j¼1
X
m X
n
 0 & y1 þ y2  1 DSt ¼ rut1 þ bDFt þ di DFti þ yi DStj þ ej ;
i¼1 j¼1

Once the conditional covariance matrix is estimated, the (74.25)


time varying conditional MV hedge ratio is given by the
ratio of the covariance between the spot and futures returns where ut is the residual series from the cointegrating regres-
to the variance of the futures return. sion. The estimate of the hedge ratio is given by the estimate
of b. Some researchers (e.g., see Lien and Luo, 1993b)
74.3.1.5 Random Coefficient Method assume that the long-run cointegrating relationship is
There is another way to deal with heteroscedasticity. This
(St  Ft ), and estimate the following error correction model:
involves use of the random coefficient model as suggested
by Grammatikos and Saunders (1983). This model employs X
m X
n
the following variation of Equation 74.20: DSt ¼ rðSt1  Ft1 Þ þ bDFt þ di DFti þ yi DStj þ ej :
i¼1 j¼1

DSt ¼ b0 þ bt DFt þ et ; (74.23) (74.26)


880 S.-S. Chen et al.

Alternatively, Chou et al. (1996) suggest the estimation such method is described in Cecchetti et al. (1988) where an
of the error correction model as follows: ARCH model is used to estimate the required distributions.

X
m X
n
DSt ¼ a^
ut1 þ bDFt þ di DFti þ yi DStj þ ej ;
i¼1 j¼1 74.3.4 Estimation of Mean Extended-Gini (MEG)
(74.27) Coefficient Based Hedge Ratios

where u^t1 ¼ St1  ða þ bFt1 Þ; i.e., the series u^t is the The MEG hedge ratio involves the minimization of the
estimated residual series from Equation 74.24. The hedge following MEG coefficient:
ratio is given by b in Equation 74.26.
Kroner and Sultan (1993) combine the error-correction Gv ðRh Þ ¼ vCov Rh ; ð1  GðRh ÞÞv1 :
model with the GARCH model considered by Cecchetti
et al. (1988) and Baillie and Myers (1991) in order to
In order to estimate the MEG coefficient, we need to
estimate the optimum hedge ratio. Specifically, they use
estimate the cumulative probability density function GðRh Þ.
the following model:
The cumulative probability density function is usually
      estimated by ranking the observed return on the hedged
Dloge ðSt Þ m1 as ðloge ðSt1 Þ  loge ðFt1 ÞÞ
¼ þ portfolio. A detailed description of the process can be
Dloge ðFt Þ m2 af ðloge ðSt1 Þ  loge ðFt1 ÞÞ found in Kolb and Okunev (1992), and we briefly describe
 
e1t the process here.
þ ;
e2t The cumulative probability distribution is estimated by
(74.28) using the rank as follows:
 
where the error processes follow a GARCH process. As   Rank Rh;i
G Rh;i ¼ ;
before, the hedge ratio at time ðt  1Þ is given by N
ht1 ¼ H 12;t =H 22;t :
where N is the sample size. Once we have the series for the
probability distribution function, the MEG is estimated by
replacing the theoretical covariance by the sample covari-
74.3.2 Estimation of the Optimum
ance as follows:
Mean-Variance and Sharpe Hedge Ratios
v XN     v1
The optimum mean-variance and Sharpe hedge ratios are Gsample
v ðRh Þ ¼  Rh;i  Rh 1  G Rh;i Y ;
given by Equations 74.4 and 74.7 respectively. These hedge N i¼1
ratios can be estimated simply by replacing the theoretical (74.29)
moments by their sample moments. For example, the
expected returns can be replaced by sample average returns, where
the standard deviations can be replaced by the sample stan-
dard deviations, and the correlation can be replaced by 1 XN
1 XN   v1
sample correlation. Rh ¼ Rh;i and Y ¼ 1  G Rh;i :
N i¼1 N i¼1

The optimal hedge ratio is now given by the hedge ratio


74.3.3 Estimation of the Maximum Expected that minimizes the estimated MEG. Since there is no analyt-
Utility Hedge Ratio ical solution, the numerical method needs to be applied in
order to get the optimal hedge ratio. This method is some-
The maximum expected utility hedge ratio involves the times referred to as the empirical distribution method.
maximization of the expected utility. This requires the esti- Alternatively, the instrumental variable (IV) method
mation of distributions of the changes in spot and futures suggested by Shalit (1995) can be used to find the MEG
prices. Once the distributions are estimated, one needs to use hedge ratio. Shalit’s method provides the following analyti-
a numerical technique to get the optimum hedge ratio. One cal solution for the MEG hedge ratio:
74 Futures Hedge Ratios: A Review 881


Cov Stþ1 ; ½1  GðFtþ1 Þu1 hedge ratio. Instead of using the kernel method, one can also
h IV
¼ : employ the conditional heteroscedastic model to estimate
Cov Ftþ1 ; ½1  GðFtþ1 Þu1 the density function. This is the method used by Lien and
Tse (1998).
It is important to note that for the IV method to be valid,
the cumulative distribution function of the terminal wealth
(W tþ1 ) should be similar to the cumulative distribution of the 74.4 Hedging Horizon, Maturity of Futures
futures price (Ftþ1 ); i.e., GðW tþ1 Þ ¼ GðFtþ1 Þ. Lien and Contract, Data Frequency, and
Shaffer (1999) find that the IV-based hedge ratio (hIV ) is Hedging Effectiveness
significantly different from the minimum MEG hedge ratio.
Lien and Luo (1993a) suggest an alternative method of In this section we discuss the relationship among the length
estimating the MEG hedge ratio. This method involves the of hedging horizon (hedging period), maturity of futures
estimation of the cumulative distribution function using a contracts, data frequency (e.g., daily, weekly, monthly, or
non-parametric kernel function instead of using a rank func- quarterly), and hedging effectiveness.
tion as suggested above. Since there are many futures contracts (with different
Regarding the estimation of the M-MEG hedge ratio, one maturities) that can be used in hedging, the question is
can follow either the empirical distribution method or the whether the minimum-variance (MV) hedge ratio depends
non-parametric kernel method to estimate the MEG coeffi- on the time to maturity of the futures contract being used for
cient. A numerical method can then be used to estimate the hedging. Lee et al. (1987) find that the MV hedge ratio
hedge ratio that maximizes the objective function given by increases as the maturity is approached. This means that if
Equation 74.10. we use the nearest to maturity futures contracts to hedge,
then the MV hedge ratio will be larger compared to the one
obtained using futures contracts with a longer maturity.
Aside from using futures contracts with different
74.3.5 Estimation of Generalized Semivariance maturities, we can estimate the MV hedge ratio using data
(GSV) Based Hedge Ratios with different frequencies. For example, the data used in the
estimation of the optimum hedge ratio can be daily, weekly,
The GSV can be estimated from the sample by using the monthly, or quarterly. At the same time, the hedging horizon
following sample counterpart: could be from a few hours to more than a month. The
question is whether a relationship exists between the data
sample 1 XN  a   frequency used and the length of the hedging horizon.
Vd;a ð Rh Þ ¼ d  Rh;i U d  Rh;i ; (74.30)
N i¼1 Malliaris and Urrutia (1991) and Benet (1992) utilize
Equation 74.20 and weekly data to estimate the optimal
where hedge ratio. According to Malliaris and Urrutia (1991), the
ex ante hedging is more effective when the hedging horizon
( is 1 week compared to a hedging horizon of 4 weeks. Benet
  1 for d  Rh;i
U d  Rh;i ¼ : (1992) finds that a shorter hedging horizon (4-weeks) is
0 for d<Rh;i more effective (in ex ante test) compared to a longer hedging
horizon (8-weeks and 12-weeks). These empirical results
Similar to the MEG technique, the optimal GSV hedge seem to be consistent with the argument that when
ratio can be estimated by choosing the hedge ratio that estimating the MV hedge ratio, the hedging horizon’s length
sample
minimizes the sample GSV, Vd;a ðRh Þ. Numerical methods must match the data frequency being used.
can be used to search for the optimum hedge ratio. Similarly, There is a potential problem associated with matching the
the M-GSV hedge ratio can be obtained by minimizing the - length of the hedging horizon and the data frequency. For
mean-risk function given by Equation 74.12, where the example, consider the case where the hedging horizon is 3
expected return on the hedged portfolio is replaced by months (one quarter). In this case we need to use quarterly
the sample average return and the GSV is replaced by the data to match the length of the hedging horizon. In other
sample GSV. words, when estimating Equation 74.20 we must employ
One can instead use the kernel density estimation method quarterly changes in spot and futures prices. Therefore,
suggested by Lien and Tse (2000) to estimate the GSV, and if we have 5 years’ worth of data, then we will have 19
numerical techniques can be used to find the optimum GSV non-overlapping price changes, resulting in a sample size of
882 S.-S. Chen et al.

19. However, if the hedging horizon is 1 week, instead of the time series into different frequencies as suggested by
3 months, then we will end up with approximately 260 non- Lien and Shrestha (2007). The decomposition can be done
overlapping price changes (sample size of 260) for the same without the loss of sample size (see Lien and Shrestha, 2007
5 years’ worth of data. Therefore, the matching method is for detail). For example, the daily spot and future returns
associated with a reduction in sample size for a longer series can be decomposed using the maximal overlap dis-
hedging horizon. crete wavelet transform (MODWT) as follows:
One way to get around this problem is to use overlapping
price changes. For example, Geppert (1995) utilizes k-period Rs;t ¼ BsJ;t þ DsJ;t þ DsJ1;t þ


þ Ds1;t
differencing for a k-period hedging horizon in estimating the
regression-based MV hedge ratio. Since Geppert (1995) uses Rf ;t ¼ BfJ;t þ DfJ;t þ DfJ1;t þ


þ Df1;t
approximately 13 months of data for estimating the hedge
ratio, he employs overlapping differencing in order to elimi- where Dsj;t and Dfj;t are the spot and futures returns series with
nate the reduction in sample size caused by differencing.
changes on the time scale of length 2j1 days respectively.4
However, this will lead to correlated observations instead of Similarly, BsJ;t and B2J;t represents spot and futures returns
independent observations and will require the use of a series corresponding to time scale of 2J days and longer.
regression with autocorrelated errors in the estimation of
Now, we can run the following regression to find the hedge
the hedge ratio. ratio corresponding to hedging horizon equal to 2j1 days:
In order to eliminate the autocorrelated errors problem,
Geppert (1995) suggests a method based on cointegration
Dsj;t ¼ yj;0 þ yj;1 Dfj;t þ ej (74.33)
and unit-root processes. We will briefly describe his method.
Suppose that the spot and futures prices, which are both unit-
root processes, are cointegrated. In this case the futures and where the estimate of the hedge ratio is given by the estimate
spot prices can be described by the following processes (see of yj;1 .
Stock and Watson, 1988; Hylleberg and Mizon, 1989):

S t ¼ A 1 Pt þ A 2 t t ; (74.31a) 74.5 Summary and Conclusions


F t ¼ B 1 Pt þ B2 t t ; (74.31b) In this paper we have reviewed various approaches to deriv-
Pt ¼ Pt1 þ wt ; (74.31c) ing the optimal hedge ratio, as summarized in Appendix A.
These approaches can be divided into the mean-variance
tt ¼ a1 tt1 þ vt ; 0  ja1 j<1; (74.31d) based approach, the expected utility maximizing approach,
the mean extended-Gini coefficient-based approach, and
where Pt and tt are permanent and transitory factors that the generalized semivariance-based approach. All these
drive the spot and futures prices and wt and vt are white noise approaches will lead to the same hedge ratio as the conven-
processes. Note that Pt follows a pure random walk process tional minimum-variance (MV) hedge ratio if the futures
and tt follows a stationary process. The MV hedge ratio for a price follows a pure martingale process and if the futures
k-period hedging horizon is then given by (see Geppert, and spot prices are jointly normal. However, if these
1995): conditions do not hold, then the hedge ratios based on the
various approaches will be different.
 
ð1ak Þ The MV hedge ratio is the most understood and most
A1 B1 ks2w þ 2A2 B2 1a2 s2v
widely-used hedge ratio. Since the statistical properties of
HJ ¼ : (74.32) the MV hedge ratio are well known, statistical hypothesis
B21 ks2w þ 2B22 ð1a
1ak Þ
2 s2v
testing can be performed with the MV hedge ratio. For
example, we can test whether the optimal MV hedge ratio
One advantage of using Equation 74.32 instead of a is the same as the naı̈ve hedge ratio. Since the MV hedge
regression with non-overlapping price changes is that it ratio ignores the expected return, it will not be consistent
avoids the problem of a reduction in sample size associated with the mean-variance analysis unless the futures price
with non-overlapping differencing. follows a pure martingale process. Furthermore, if the mar-
An alternative way of matching the data frequency with tingale and normality condition do not hold, then the MV
the hedging horizon is by using the wavelet to decompose hedge ratio will not be consistent with the expected utility
74 Futures Hedge Ratios: A Review 883

maximization principle. Following the MV hedge ratio is the of methods that have been proposed in the literature.
mean-variance hedge ratio. Even if this hedge ratio These methods range from a simple regression method to
incorporates the expected return in the derivation of the complex cointegrated heteroscedastic methods with regime-
optimal hedge ratio, it will not be consistent with the switching, and some of the estimation methods include a
expected maximization principle unless either the normality kernel density function method as well as an empirical
condition holds or the utility function is quadratic. distribution method. Except for many of mean-variance
In order to make the hedge ratio consistent with the based hedge ratios, the estimation involves the use of a
expected utility maximization principle, we can derive the numerical technique. This has to do with the fact that most
optimal hedge ratio by maximizing the expected utility. of the optimal hedge ratio formulae do not have a closed-
However, to implement such approach, we need to assume form analytic expression. Again, it is important to mention
a specific utility function and we need to make an assump- that based on his specific model, Lence (1995) finds that the
tion regarding the return distribution. Therefore, different value of complicated and sophisticated estimation methods
utility functions will lead to different optimal hedge ratios. is negligible. It remains to be seen if such a result holds for
Furthermore, analytic solutions for such hedge ratios are not the mean extended-Gini coefficient-based as well as
known and numerical methods need to be applied. semivariance-based hedge ratios.
New approaches have recently been suggested in deriving In this paper, we have also discussed about the relation-
optimal hedge ratios. These include the mean-Gini ship between the optimal MV hedge ratio and the hedging
coefficient-based hedge ratio, semivariance-based hedge horizon. We feel that this relationship has not been fully
ratios and Value-at-Risk based hedge ratios. These hedge explored and can be further developed in the future. For
ratios are consistent with the second-order stochastic domi- example, we would like to know if the optimal hedge ratio
nance principle. Therefore, such hedge ratios are very gen- approaches the naı̈ve hedge ratio when the hedging horizon
eral in the sense that they are consistent with the expected becomes longer.
utility maximization principle and make very few The main thing we learn from this review is that if the
assumptions on the utility function. The only requirement futures price follows a pure martingale process and if the
is that the marginal utility be positive and the second deriva- returns are jointly normally distributed, then all different
tive of the utility function be negative. However, both of hedge ratios are the same as the conventional MV hedge
these hedge ratios do not lead to a unique hedge ratio. For ratio, which is simple to compute and easy to understand.
example, the mean-Gini coefficient-based hedge ratio However, if these two conditions do not hold, then there
depends on the risk aversion parameter (n) and the are many optimal hedge ratios (depending on which
semivariance-based hedge ratio depends on the risk aversion objective function one is trying to optimize) and there is
parameter (a) and target return (d). It is important to note, no single optimal hedge ratio that is distinctly superior to
however, that the semivariance-based hedge ratio has some the remaining ones. Therefore, further research needs
appeal in the sense that the semivariance as a measure of risk to be done to unify these different approaches to the
is consistent with the risk perceived by individuals. The hedge ratio.
same argument can be applied to Value-at-Risk based For those who are interested in research in this area, we
hedge ratio. would like to finally point out that one requires a good
So far as the derivation of the optimal hedge ratio is understanding of financial economic theories and economet-
concerned, almost all of the derivations do not incorporate ric methodologies. In addition, a good background in data
transaction costs. Furthermore, these derivations do not analysis and computer programming would also be helpful.
allow investments in securities other than the spot and
corresponding futures contracts. As shown by Lence
(1995), once we relax these conventional assumptions, the Notes
resulting optimal hedge ratio can be quite different from 1. Without loss of generality, we assume that the size of the
the ones obtained under the conventional assumptions. futures contract is one.
Lence’s (1995) results are based on a specific utility function 2. Lence (1995) also derives the hedge ratio based on the
and some other assumption regarding the return expected utility. We will discuss it later in subsection C.
distributions. It remains to be seen if such results hold for 3. Our discussion of the opportunity costs is very brief. We
the mean extended-Gini coefficient-based as well as would like to refer interested readers to Lence (1995) for
semivariance-based hedge ratios. a detailed discussion. We would also like to point to the
In this paper we have also reviewed various ways of fact that production can be allowed to be random as is
estimating the optimum hedge ratio, as summarized in done in Lence (1996).
Appendix B. As far as the estimation of the conventional 4. For example, Ds1;t represents daily time scale and Ds4;t
MV hedge ratio is concerned, there are a large number represents 8-day time scale.
884 Appendix A: Theoretical Models

Return
Appendix A: Theoretical Models definition
and
objective
References function Summary
commodity, investment in a risk-free asset,
Return investment in a risky asset, as well as borrowing.
definition It also incorporates the transaction costs
and De Jong Ret2 The paper derives the optimal hedge ratio that
objective et al. O7 (also minimizes the generalized semivariance
References function Summary (1997) uses O1 (GSV). The paper compares the GSV hedge
Johnson Ret1 The paper derives the minimum-variance and O3) ratio with the minimum-variance (MV) hedge
(1960) O1 hedge ratio. The hedging effectiveness is ratio as well as the Sharpe hedge ratio. The
defined as E1, but no empirical analysis is done paper uses E1 (for the MV hedge ratio), E3
Hsin et al. Ret2 The paper derives the utility function-based (for the Sharpe hedge ratio) and E4 (for the
(1994) O2 hedge ratio. A new measure of hedging GSV hedge ratio) as the measures of hedging
effectiveness E2 based on a certainty effectiveness
equivalent is proposed. The new measure of Chen et al. Ret1 The paper derives the optimal hedge ratio that
hedging effectiveness is used to compare the (2001) O8 maximizes the risk-return function given by
effectiveness of futures and options as U ðRh Þ ¼ E½Rh   V d;a ðRh Þ. The method can
hedging instruments be considered as an extension of the GSV
Howard Ret2 The paper derives the optimal hedge ratio method used by De Jong et al. (1997)
and O3 based on maximizing the Sharpe ratio. The Hung et al. Ret2 The paper derives the optimal hedge ratio that
D’Antonio proposed hedging effectiveness E3 is based on (2006) O10 minimizes the Value-at-Risk for p a hedging
ffiffiffi
(1984) the Sharpe ratio horizon of length tgiven by Z a sh t  E½Rh t
Cecchetti Ret2 The paper derives the optimal hedge ratio that
et al. O4 maximizes
Ð Ð the expected utility
function:
 
(1988) log 1 þ Rs ðtÞ  hðtÞRf ðtÞ f t Rs ; Rf
Rs Rf
Notes
dRs dRf , where the density function is assumed A. Return model
to be bivariate normal. A third-order linear (Ret1)
bivariate ARCH model is used to get the C
DV H ¼ Cs DPs þ Cf DPf ) hedge ratio = H ¼ Cfs ; Cs ¼ units of
conditional variance and covariance matrix.
A numerical procedure is used to maximize spot commodity and Cf = units of futures contract
the objective function with respect to hedge (Ret2) Rh ¼ Rs þ hRf ; Rs ¼ St SS t1
t1
(a) Rf ¼ FtFF
Cf Ft1
ratio. Due to ARCH, the hedge ratio changes t1
t1
) hedge ratio: h ¼ Cs St1
over time. The paper uses certainty equivalent (b) Rf ¼ Ft SF
C
t1
t1
) hedge ratio: h ¼ Cfs .
(E2) to measure the hedging effectiveness
Cheung Ret2 The paper uses mean-Gini (v ¼ 2, not mean B. Objective function
et al. O5 extended-Gini coefficient) and mean-variance (O1) Minimize
(1990) approaches to analyze the effectiveness of Var ðRh Þ ¼ C2s s2s þ C2f s2f þ 2Cs Cf ssf or Var ðRh Þ ¼ s2s þh2 s2f þ 2hssf
options and futures as hedging instruments (O2) Maximize EðRh Þ  A2 Var ðRh Þ
ðRh ÞRF
Kolb and Ret2 The paper uses mean extended-Gini (O3) Maximize EVar ðRh Þ ð Sharpe ratio), RF ¼ risk  freeinterestrate
Okunev O5 coefficient in the derivation of the optimal (O4) Maximize E½UðWÞ; Uð:Þ = utility function, W ¼ terminal wealth
(1992) hedge ratio. Therefore, it can be considered as
a generalization of the mean-Gini coefficient (O5) Minimize Gv ðRh Þ; Gv ðRh Þ ¼ vCov Rh ; ð1  FðRh ÞÞv1
method used by Cheung et al. (1990) (O6) Maximize E½Rh   Gv ðRh vÞ
Ðd
Kolb and Ret2 The paper defines the objective function as O6, (O7) Minimize V d;a ðRh Þ ¼ 1 ðd  Rh Þa dGðRh Þ; a>0
Okunev O6 but in terms of wealth (W) UðWÞ ¼ E½W   (O8) Maximize U ðRh Þ ¼ E½Rh   V d;a ðRh Þ
(1993) Gv ðWÞ and compares with the quadratic utility T 
P
function UðWÞ ¼ E½W   ms2 . The paper (O9) Minimize Var ðW t Þ ¼ Var Cst DSt þ Cft DFt .
plots the EMG efficient frontier in W and pffiffiffi t¼1
(O10) Minimize Z a sh t  E½Rh t
Gv ðWÞ space for various values of risk
aversion parameters (v) C. Hedging effectiveness

Lien and Ret1 The paper derives the multi-period hedge ðRh Þ
(E1) e ¼ 1  Var
Var ðRs Þ
Luo O9 ratios where the hedge ratios are allowed to
(1993b) change over the hedging period. The method (E2) e ¼ Rce
h  Rss ; Rh ðRs Þ ¼ certainty equivalent return of
ce ce ce

suggested in the paper still falls under the hedgedðunhedgedÞportfolio


minimum-variance hedge ratio ðE½Rh   RF Þ
Lence O4 This paper derives the expected utility Var ðRh Þ ðE½Rh   RF Þ ðE½Rs   RF Þ
(E3) e ¼ or e ¼ 
(1995) maximizing hedge ratio where the terminal ðE½Rs   RF Þ Var ðRh Þ Var ðRs Þ
wealth depends on the return on a diversified Var ðRs Þ
portfolio that consists of the production of a spot V d;a ðRh Þ
(E4) e ¼ 1  .
(continued) V d;a ðRs Þ
Appendix A: Theoretical Models 885

References Commodity Summary


Appendix B: Empirical Models
Lee et al. S&P 500, NYSE, The paper tests for the temporal
(1987) Value Line stability of the minimum-variance
(1983) [daily hedge ratio. It is found that the
References Commodity Summary data] hedge ratio increases as maturity of
Ederington GNMA futures The paper uses the Ret1 definition the futures contract nears. The
(1979) (1/1976–12/ of return and estimates the paper also performs a functional
1977), Wheat minimum- variance hedge ratio form test and finds support for the
(1/1976–12/ (O1). E1 is used as a hedging regression of rate of change for
1977), Corn effectiveness measure. The paper discrete as well as continuous rates
(1/1976–12/ uses nearby contracts (3–6 months, of change in prices
1977), T-bill 6–9 months and 9–12 months) and Cecchetti Treasury bond, The paper derives the hedge ratio
futures a hedging period of 2 weeks and et al. (1988) Treasury bond by maximizing the expected utility.
(3/1976–12/ 4 weeks. OLS (M1) is used to futures (1/ A third-order linear bivariate
1977) [weekly estimate the parameters. Some of 1978–5/1986) ARCH model is used to get the
data] the hedge ratios are found not to be [monthly data] conditional variance and
different from zero and the hedging covariance matrix. A numerical
effectiveness increases with the procedure is used to maximize the
length of hedging period. The objective function with respect to
hedge ratio also increases (closer to the hedge ratio. Due to ARCH, the
unity) with the length of hedging hedge ratio changes over time. It is
period found that the hedge ratio changes
Grammatikos Swiss franc, The paper estimates the hedge ratio over time and is significantly less
and Saunders Canadian dollar, for the whole period and moving (in absolute value) than the
(1983) British pound, window (2-year data). It is found minimum-variance (MV) hedge
DM, Yen that the hedge ratio changes over ratio (which also changes over
(1/1974–6/1980) time. Dummy variables for various time). E2 (certainty equivalent) is
[weekly data] sub-periods are used, and shifts are used to measure the performance
found. The paper uses a random effectiveness. The proposed utility-
coefficient (M3) model to estimate maximizing hedge ratio performs
the hedge ratio. The hedge ratio for better than the MV hedge ratio
Swiss franc is found to follow a Cheung et al. Swiss franc, The paper uses mean-Gini
random coefficient model. (1990) Canadian dollar, coefficient (v ¼ 2) and mean-
However, there is no improvement British pound, variance approaches to analyze the
in effectiveness when the hedge German mark, effectiveness of options and futures
ratio is calculated by correcting for Japanese yen as hedging instruments. It
the randomness (9/1983–12/ considers both mean-variance and
Junkus and Three stock index The paper tests the applicability of 1984) [daily data] expected-return mean-Gini
Lee (1985) futures for four futures hedging models: a coefficient frontiers. It also
Kansas City variance-minimizing model considers the minimum-variance
Board of Trade, introduced by Johnson (1960), the (MV) and minimum mean-Gini
New York traditional one to one hedge, a coefficient hedge ratios. The MV
Futures utility maximization model and minimum mean-Gini
Exchange, and developed by Rutledge (1972), and approaches indicate that futures is a
Chicago a basis arbitrage model suggested better hedging instrument.
Mercantile by Working (1953). An optimal However, the mean-variance
Exchange ratio or decision rule is estimated frontier indicates futures to be a
(5/82–3/83) for each model, and measures for better hedging instrument whereas
[daily data] the effectiveness of each hedge are the mean-Gini frontier indicates
devised. Each hedge strategy options to be a better hedging
performed best according to its instrument
own criterion. The Working Baillie and Beef, Coffee, The paper uses a bivariate GARCH
decision rule appeared to be easy to Myers (1991) Corn, Cotton, model (M2) in estimating the
use and satisfactory in most cases. Gold, Soybean minimum-variance (MV) hedge
Although the maturity of the (contracts ratios. Since the models used are
futures contract used affected the maturing in 1982 conditional models, the time series
size of the optimal hedge ratio, and 1986) [daily of hedge ratios are estimated. The
there was no consistent maturity data] MV hedge ratios are found to
effect on performance. Use of a follow a unit root process. The
particular ratio depends on how hedge ratio for beef is found to be
closely the assumptions underlying centered around zero. E1 is used as
the model approach a hedger’s real a hedging effectiveness measure.
situation Both in-sample and out-of-sample
(continued) effectiveness of the GARCH-based
(continued)
886 Appendix A: Theoretical Models

References Commodity Summary References Commodity Summary


hedge ratios is compared with a Kolb and Cocoa The paper estimates the Mean-
constant hedge ratio. The GARCH- Okunev (3/1952–1976) MEG (M-MEG) hedge ratio (M12).
based hedge ratios are found to be (1993) for four cocoa- The paper compares the M-MEG
significantly better compared to the producing hedge ratio, minimum-variance
constant hedge ratio countries (Ghana, hedge ratio, and optimum mean-
Malliaris and British pound, The paper uses regression Nigeria, Ivory variance hedge ratio for various
Urrutia German mark, autocorrelated errors model to Coast, and Brazil) values of risk aversion parameters.
(1991) Japanese yen, estimate the minimum-variance [March and The paper finds that the M-MEG
Swill franc, (MV) hedge ratio for the five September data] hedge ratio leads to reverse
Canadian dollar currencies. Using overlapping hedging (buy futures instead of
(3/1980–12/ moving windows, the time series of selling) for v less than 1.24 (Ghana
1988) [weekly the MV hedge ratio and hedging case). For high-risk aversion
data] effectiveness are estimated for both parameter values (high v) all hedge
ex post (in-sample) and ex ante ratios are found to converge to the
(out-of-sample) cases. E1 is used to same value
measure the hedging effectiveness Lien and Luo S&P 500 The paper points out that the mean
for the ex post case whereas (1993a) (1/1984–12/ extended-Gini (MEG) hedge ratio
average return is used to measure 1988) [weekly can be calculated either by
the hedging effectiveness. data] numerically optimizing the MEG
Specifically, the average return coefficient or by numerically
close to zero is used to indicate a solving the first-order condition.
better performing hedging strategy. For v ¼ 9 the hedge ratio of
In the ex post case, the 4-week 0.8182 is close to the minimum-
hedging horizon is more effective variance (MV) hedge ratio of
compared to the 1-week hedging 0.8171. Using the first-order
horizon. However, for the ex ante condition, the paper shows that for
case the opposite is found to be true a large v the MEG hedge ratio
Benet (1992) Australian dollar, This paper considers direct and converges to a constant. The
Brazilian cross hedging, using multiple empirical result shows that the
cruzeiro, futures contracts. For minor hedge ratio decreases with the risk
Mexican peso, currencies, the cross hedging aversion parameter v. The paper
South African exhibits a significant decrease in finds that the MV and MEG hedge
rand, Chinese performance from ex post to ex ratio (for low v) series (obtained by
yuan, Finish ante. The minimum-variance using a moving window) are more
markka, Irish hedge ratios are found to change stable compared to the MEG hedge
pound, Japanese from one period to the other except ratio for a large v. The paper also
yen (8/1973–12/ for the direct hedging of Japanese uses a non-parametric Kernel
1985) [weekly yen. On the ex ante case, the estimator to estimate the
data] hedging effectiveness does not cumulative density function.
appear to be related to the However, the kernel estimator does
estimation period length. However, not change the result significantly
the effectiveness decreases as the Lien and Luo British pound, This paper proposes a multi-period
hedging period length increases (1993b) Canadian dollar, model to estimate the optimal
Kolb and Corn, Copper, The paper estimates the mean German mark, hedge ratio. The hedge ratios are
Okunev Gold, German extended-Gini (MEG) hedge ratio Japanese yen, estimated using an error-correction
(1992) mark, S&P 500 (M9) with v ranging from 2 to 200. Swiss franc model. The spot and futures prices
(1989) [daily The MEG hedge ratios are found to (3/1980–12/ are found to be cointegrated. The
data] be close to the minimum-variance 1988), MMI, optimal multi-period hedge ratios
hedge ratios for a lower level of NYSE, S&P are found to exhibit a cyclical
risk parameter v (for v from 2 to 5). (1/1984–12/ pattern with a tendency for the
For higher values of v, the two 1988) [weekly amplitude of the cycles to decrease.
hedge ratios are found to be quite data] Finally, the possibility of spreading
different. The hedge ratios are among different market contracts is
found to increase with the risk analyzed. It is shown that hedging
aversion parameter for S&P 500, in a single market may be much
Corn, and Gold. However, for less effective than the optimal
Copper and German mark, the spreading strategy
hedge ratios are found to decrease Ghosh (1993) S&P futures, All the variables are found to have
with the risk aversion parameter. S&P index, Dow a unit root. For all three indices the
The hedge ratio tends to be more Jones Industrial same S&P 500 futures contracts are
stable for higher levels of risk average, NYSE used (cross hedging). Using the
(continued) composite index Engle-Granger two-step test, the
S&P 500 futures price is found to
(continued)
Appendix A: Theoretical Models 887

References Commodity Summary References Commodity Summary


(1/1990–12/ be cointegrated with each of the hedging effectiveness of options
1991) [daily data] three spot prices: S&P 500, DJIA, and futures contracts. It is found
and NYSE. The hedge ratio is that the futures contracts perform
estimated using the error- better than the options contracts
correction model (ECM) (M4). Shalit (1995) Gold, silver, The paper shows that if the prices
Out-of-sample performance is copper, are jointly normally distributed, the
better for the hedge ratio from the aluminum mean extended-Gini (MEG) hedge
ECM compared to the Ederington (1/1977–12/ ratio will be same as the minimum-
model 1990) [daily data] variance (MV) hedge ratio. The
Sephton Feed wheat, The paper finds unit roots on each MEG hedge ratio is estimated
(1993a) Canola futures of the cash and futures (log) prices, using the instrumental variable
(1981–82 crop but no cointegration between method. The paper performs
year) [daily data] futures and spot (log) prices. The normality tests as well as the tests
hedge ratios are computed using a to see if the MEG hedge ratios are
four-variable GARCH(1,1) model. different from the MV hedge ratios.
The time series of hedge ratios are The paper finds that for a
found to be stationary. Reduction significant number of futures
in portfolio variance is used as a contracts the normality does not
measure of hedging effectiveness. hold and the MEG hedge ratios are
It is found that the GARCH-based different from the MV hedge ratios
hedge ratio performs better Geppert German mark, The paper estimates the minimum-
compared to the conventional (1995) Swiss franc, variance hedge ratio using the OLS
minimum-variance hedge ratio Japanese yen, as well as the cointegration
Sephton Feed wheat, Feed The paper finds unit roots on each S&P 500, methods for various lengths of
(1993b) barley, Canola of the cash and futures (log) prices, Municipal Bond hedging horizon. The in-sample
futures (1988/89) but no cointegration between Index (1/1990–1/ results indicate that for both
[daily data] futures and spot (log) prices. A 1993) [weekly methods the hedging effectiveness
univariate GARCH model shows data] increases with the length of the
that the mean returns on the futures hedging horizon. The out-of-
are not significantly different from sample results indicate that in
zero. However, from the bivariate general the effectiveness (based on
GARCH canola is found to have a the method suggested by Malliaris
significant mean return. For canola and Urrutia (1991)) decreases as
the mean variance utility function the length of the hedging horizon
is used to find the optimal hedge decreases. This is true for both the
ratio for various values of the risk regression method and the
aversion parameter. The time series decomposition method proposed in
of the hedge ratio (based on the paper. However, the
bivariate GARCH model) is found decomposition method seems to
to be stationary. The benefit in perform better than the regression
terms of utility gained from using a method in terms of both mean and
multivariate GARCH decreases as variance
the degree of risk aversion De Jong et al. British pound The paper compares the minimum-
increases (1997) (12/1976–10/ variance, generalized semivariance
Kroner and British pound, The paper uses the error-correction 1993), German and Sharpe hedge ratios for the
Sultan (1993) Canadian dollar, model with a GARCH error (M5) to mark three currencies. The paper
German mark, estimate the minimum-variance (12/1976–10/ computes the out-of-sample
Japanese yen, (MV) hedge ratio for the five 1993), Japanese hedging effectiveness using non-
Swiss franc currencies. Due to the use of yen (4/1977–10/ overlapping 90-day periods where
(2/1985–2/1990) conditional models, the time series 1993) [daily data] the first 60 days are used to
[weekly data] of the MV hedge ratios are estimate the hedge ratio and the
estimated. Both within-sample and remaining 30 days are used to
out-of-sample evidence shows that compute the out-of-sample
the hedging strategy proposed in hedging effectiveness. The paper
the paper is potentially superior to finds that the naı̈ve hedge ratio
the conventional strategies performs better than the model
Hsin et al. British pound, The paper derives the optimum based hedge ratios
(1994) German mark, mean-variance hedge ratio by Lien and Tse Nikkei stock The paper shows that if the rates of
Yen, Swiss franc maximizing the objective function (1998) average change in spot and futures prices
(1/1986–12/ O2. The hedging horizons of 14, (1/1989–8/1996) are bivariate normal and if the
1989) [daily data] 30, 60, 90, and 120 calendar days [daily data] futures price follows a martingale
are considered to compare the process, then the generalized
(continued) (continued)
888 Appendix A: Theoretical Models

References Commodity Summary References Commodity Summary


semivariance (GSV) (referred to as Furthermore, the expected value of
lower partial moment) hedge ratio the futures price change is found to
will be same as the minimum- be significantly different from zero.
variance (MV) hedge ratio. A It is also found that for a high level
version of the bivariate asymmetric of risk aversion, the M-MEG hedge
power ARCH model is used to ratio converges to the MV hedge
estimate the conditional joint ratio whereas the M-GSV hedge
distribution, which is then used to ratio converges to a lower value
estimate the time varying GSV Hung et al. S&P 500 The paper proposes minimization
hedge ratios. The paper finds that (2006) (01/1997–12/ of Value-at-Risk in deriving the
the GSV hedge ratio significantly 1999) [daily data] optimum hedge ratio. The paper
varies over time and is different finds cointegrating relationship
from the MV hedge ratio between the spot and futures
Lien and Nikkei (9/86–9/ This paper empirically tests the returns and uses bivariate constant
Shaffer 89), S&P ranking assumption used by Shalit correlation GARCH(1,1) model
(1999) (4/82–4/85), (1995). The ranking assumption with error correction term. The
TOPIX (4/90–12/ assumes that the ranking of futures paper compares the proposed
93), KOSPI (5/ prices is the same as the ranking of hedge ratio with MV hedge ratio
96–12/96), Hang the wealth. The paper estimates the and hedge ratio (HKL hedge ratio)
Seng mean extended-Gini (MEG) hedge proposed by Hsin et al. (1994). The
(1/87–12189), ratio based on the instrumental paper finds the performance of the
IBEX (4/93–3/ variable (IV) method used by proposed hedge ratio to be similar
95) [daily data] Shalit (1995) and the true MEG to the HKL hedge ratio. Finally, the
hedge ratio. The true MEG hedge proposed hedge ratio converges to
ratio is computed using the the MV hedge ratio for high risk-
cumulative probability distribution averse levels
estimated employing the kernel Lee and Nikkei 225 and The paper proposes regime-
method instead of the rank method. Yoder (2007) Hang Send index switching time varying correlation
The paper finds that the MEG futures GARCH model and compares the
hedge ratio obtained from the IV (01/1989–12/ resulting hedge ratio with constant
method to be different from the 2003) [weekly correlation GARCH and time-
true MEG hedge ratio. data] varying correlation GARCH. The
Furthermore, the true MEG hedge proposed model is found to
ratio leads to a significantly smaller outperforms the other two hedge
MEG coefficient compared to the ratio in both in-sample and out-of-
IV-based MEG hedge ratio sample for both contracts
Lien and Tse Nikkei stock The paper estimates the Lien and 23 different This paper proposes wavelet base
(2000) average generalized semivariance (GSV) Shrestha futures contracts hedge ratio to compute the hedge
(1/1988–8/996) hedge ratios for different values of (2007) (sample period ratios for different hedging
[daily data] parameters using a non-parametric depends on horizons (1-day, 2-day, 4-day, 8-
kernel estimation method. The contracts) day, 16 day, 32-day, 64-day, 128-
kernel method is compared with [daily data] day; and 256-day and longer). It is
the empirical distribution method. found that the wavelet based hedge
It is found that the hedge ratio from ratio and the error-correction based
one method is not different from hedge ratio are larger than MV
the hedge ratio from another. The hedge ratio. The performance of
Jarque-Bera (1987) test indicates wavelet based hedge ratio
that the changes in spot and futures improves with the length of
prices do not follow normal hedging horizon
distribution Lien and 22 different The paper proposes the hedge ratio
Chen et al. S&P 500 The paper proposes the use of the Shrestha futures contracts based on skew-normal distribution
(2001) (4/1982–12/ M-GSV hedge ratio. The paper (2010) (sample period (SKN hedge ratio). The paper also
1991) estimates the minimum-variance depends on estimates the semi-variance (lower
[weekly data] (MV), optimum mean-variance, contracts) partial moment (LPM)) hedge ratio
Sharpe, mean extended-Gini [daily data] and MV hedge ratio among other
(MEG), generalized semivariance hedge ratios. SKN hedge ratios are
(GSV), mean-MEG (M-MEG), and found to be different from the MV
mean-GSV (M-GSV) hedge ratios. hedge ratio based on normal
The Jarque-Bera (1987) Test and distribution. SKN hedge ratio
D’Agostino (1971) D statistic performs better than LPM hedge
indicate that the price changes are (continued)
not normally distributed.
(continued)
Appendix A: Theoretical Models 889

h i
ss ss ð Þ
E Rf
r
References Commodity Summary sf sf EðRs Þi
(M10): Hedge ratio ¼ h3 ¼  h i , where the moments
ratio for long hedger especially for 1sss
ð Þr
E Rf

f EðRs Þi
the out-of-sample cases
and correlation are estimated by their sample counterparts
D. Mean-Gini coefficient based hedge ratios
(M11): The hedge ratio is estimated by numerically minimizing the
Notes following mean extended-Gini coefficient, where the cumulative prob-
A. Minimum-variance hedge ratio ability distribution function
P is estimatedPusing the rank function
A.1. OLS DSt ¼ rut1 þ bDFt þ m i¼1 iDF t1 þ n
j¼1 f i DStj þ ej ; EC Hedge
(M1): DSt ¼ a0 þ a1 DFt þ et : Hedge ratio ¼ a1 ratio = b
Rs ¼ a0 þ a1 Rf þ et : Hedge ratio ¼ a1 (M12): The hedge ratio is estimated by numerically solving the first-
A.2.Multivariate skew-normal   order condition, where the cumulative probability distribution function
Rs
(M2): The return vector Y ¼ is assumed to have skew-normal is estimated using the rank function
Rf
(M13): The hedge ratio is estimated by numerically solving the first-
distribution with covariance matrix V:
order condition, where the cumulative probability distribution function
Hedge ration ¼H skn ¼ VV ðð1;2 Þ
2;2Þ is estimated using the kernel-based estimates
A.3. ARCH/GARCH
(M14): The hedge ratio is estimated by numerically maximizing the
     
DSt m1 e following function
(M3): ¼ þ 1t , et jOt1 N ð0; H t Þ ; U ðRh Þ ¼ EðRh Þ  Gv ðRh Þ;
DFt m2 e2t
  where the expected values and the mean extended-Gini coeffi-
H 11;t H 12;t
Ht ¼ , Hedge ratio ¼ H 12;t =H 22;t cient are replaced by their sample counterparts and the cumulative
H 12;t H 22;t
probability distribution function is estimated using the rank function
A.4. Regime-switching GARCH
E. Generalized semivariance based hedge ratios
(M4): The transition probabilities are given by
ep0 eq 0 (M15): The hedge ratio is estimated by numerically minimizing the
Prðst ¼ 1jst1 ¼ 1Þ ¼ 1þe p0 & Prðst ¼ 2jst1 ¼ 2Þ ¼ 1þe q0
following sample generalized hedge ratio
The GARCH model: Two-series GARCH model with first series PN  a  
sample
as return on futures.    Vd;a ðRh Þ ¼ N1 d  Rh;i U d  Rh;i , where
h 0 1 rt;st h1;t;st 0 i¼1
H t;st ¼ 1;t;st   1 for d  Rh;i
0 h2;t;st rt;st 1 0 h2;t;st U d  Rh;i ¼
0 for d<Rh;i
h21;t;st ¼ g1;st þ a1;st e21:t1 þ b1;st h21;t1 ,
(M16): The hedge ratio is estimated by numerically maximizing the
h22;t;st ¼ g2;st þ a2;st e22:t1 þ b2;st h22;t1
  following function
rt;st ¼ 1  y1;st  y2;st r þ y1;st rt1 þ y2;st ’t1 sample
P2 U ðRh Þ ¼ Rh  Vd;a ðRh Þ:
e1;tj e2;tj
E. Minimum Value-at-Risk hedge ratio
ffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi
ft1 ¼ s
ei;t
 ; ei;t ¼ ; y1 ; y2  0
j¼1
 hit (M17): The hedge ratio is estimated by minimizing the following
P2 P 2
2 2 Value-at-Risk
e1;tj e2;tj
pffiffiffi
j¼1 j¼1
VaRðRh Þ ¼ Z a sh t  E½Rh t
H ð1;2Þ
& y1 þ y2  1, Hedge ratio ¼ Ht;st;st ð2;2Þ The resulting hedge ratio is given by
t

rffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi
1r2
A.5. Random coefficient hVaR ¼ r ssfs  E Rf ssfs
Za2 s2f E½Rf 
2
(M5): DSt ¼ b0 þ bt DFt þ et
bt ¼ b  þ vt , Hedge ratio ¼ b 
A.6. Cointegration and error-correction
(M6): St ¼ a þ bFt þ ut Pm Pn
DSt ¼ rut1 þ bDFt þ di DFti þ yi DStj þ ej ,
EC Hedge ratio ¼b i¼1 j¼1

A.7. Error-correction with GARCH


References
(M7):
       
Dloge ðSt Þ m1 a ðloge ðSt1 Þ  loge ðFt1 ÞÞ e Baillie, R.T., & Myers, R.J. (1991). Bivariate Garch estimation of the
¼ þ s þ 1t , optimal commodity futures hedge. Journal of Applied Economet-
Dloge ðFt Þ m2 af ðloge ðSt1 Þ  loge ðFt1 ÞÞ e2t
  rics, 6, 109–124.
H 11;t H 12;t
et jOt1 N ð0; H t Þ ; H t ¼ Bawa, V.S. (1978). Safety-first, stochastic dominance, and optimal
H 12;t H 22;t
portfolio choice. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis,
Hedge ratio ¼ ht1 ¼ H 12;t =H 22;t
13, 255–271.
A.8. Common stochastic trend
Benet, B.A. (1992). Hedge period length and ex-ante futures hedging
(M8): St ¼ A1 Pt þ A2 tt , Ft ¼ B1 Pt þ B2 tt , Pt ¼ Pt1 þ wt ,
effectiveness: the case of foreign-exchange risk cross hedges. Jour-
tt ¼ a1 tt1 þvt ; 0  ja1 j<1;
nal of Futures Markets, 12, 163–175.
Hedge ratio for k-period investment horizon ¼ Cecchetti, S.G., Cumby, R.E., & Figlewski, S. (1988). Estimation of the
ð1ak Þ
A1 B1 ks2w þ2A2 B2 s2v optimal futures hedge. Review of Economics and Statistics, 70,
HJ ¼ 1a2
:
ð1ak Þ 623–630.
B21 ks2w þ2B22 s2v
1a2 Chen, S.S., Lee, C.F., & Shrestha, K. (2001). On a mean-generalized
B. Optimum mean-variance hedge ratio   semivariance approach to determining the hedge ratio. Journal of
C F EðRf Þ Futures Markets, 21, 581–598.
(M9): Hedge ratio ¼ h2 ¼  Cfs S ¼  As2  r ssfs , where the

f Cheung, C.S., Kwan, C.C.Y., & Yip, P.C.Y. (1990). The hedging
moments E Rf ; ss and sf are estimated by sample moments effectiveness of options and futures: a mean-Gini approach. Journal
C. Sharpe hedge ratio of Futures Markets, 10, 61–74.
890 Appendix A: Theoretical Models

Chou, W.L., Fan, K.K., & Lee, C.F. (1996). Hedging with the Nikkei Kroner, K.F., & Sultan, J. (1993). Time-varying distributions and
index futures: the conventional model versus the error correction dynamic hedging with foreign currency futures. Journal of Finan-
model. Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance, 36, 495–505. cial and Quantitative Analysis, 28, 535–551.
Crum, R.L., Laughhunn, D.L., & Payne, J.W. (1981). Risk-seeking Lee, C.F., Bubnys, E.L., & Lin, Y. (1987). Stock index futures hedge
behavior and its implications for financial models. Financial Man- ratios: test on horizon effects and functional form. Advances in
agement, 10, 20–27. Futures and Options Research, 2, 291–311.
D’Agostino, R.B. (1971). An omnibus test of normality for moderate Lee, H.T. & Yoder J. (2007). Optimal hedging with a regime-switching
and large size samples. Biometrika, 58, 341–348. time-varying correlation GARCH model. Journal of Futures
De Jong, A., De Roon, F., & Veld, C. (1997). Out-of-sample hedging Markets, 27, 495–516.
effectiveness of currency futures for alternative models and hedging Lence, S. H. (1995). The economic value of minimum-variance hedges.
strategies. Journal of Futures Markets, 17, 817–837. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 77, 353–364.
Dickey, D.A., & Fuller, W.A. (1981). Likelihood ratio statistics for Lence, S. H. (1996). Relaxing the assumptions of minimum variance
autoregressive time series with a unit root. Econometrica, 49, hedging. Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics, 21,
1057–1072. 39–55.
Ederington, L.H. (1979). The hedging performance of the new futures Lien, D., & Luo, X. (1993a). Estimating the extended mean-Gini
markets. Journal of Finance, 34, 157–170. coefficient for futures hedging. Journal of Futures Markets, 13,
Engle, R.F., & Granger, C.W. (1987). Co-integration and error correc- 665–676.
tion: representation, estimation and testing. Econometrica, 55, Lien, D., & Luo, X. (1993b). Estimating multiperiod hedge ratios in
251–276. cointegrated markets. Journal of Futures Markets, 13, 909–920.
Fishburn, P.C. (1977). Mean-risk analysis with risk associated with Lien, D., & Shaffer, D.R. (1999). Note on estimating the minimum
below-target returns. American Economic Review, 67, 116–126. extended Gini hedge ratio. Journal of Futures Markets, 19, 101–113.
Geppert, J.M. (1995). A statistical model for the relationship between Lien, D. & Shrestha, K. (2007). An empirical analysis of the relation-
futures contract hedging effectiveness and investment horizon ship between hedge ratio and hedging horizon using wavelet analy-
length. Journal of Futures Markets, 15, 507–536. sis. Journal of Futures Markets, 27, 127–150.
Ghosh, A. (1993). Hedging with stock index futures: estimation and Lien, D. & Shrestha, K. (2010). Estimating optimal hedge ratio: a
forecasting with error correction model. Journal of Futures multivariate skew-normal distribution. Applied Financial Econom-
Markets, 13, 743–752. ics, 20, 627–636.
Grammatikos, T., & Saunders, A. (1983). Stability and the hedging Lien, D., & Tse, Y.K. (1998). Hedging time-varying downside risk.
performance of foreign currency futures. Journal of Futures Journal of Futures Markets, 18, 705–722.
Markets, 3, 295–305. Lien, D., & Tse, Y.K. (2000). Hedging downside risk with futures
Howard, C.T., & D’Antonio, L.J. (1984). A risk-return measure of contracts. Applied Financial Economics, 10, 163–170.
hedging effectiveness. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Anal- Malliaris, A.G., & Urrutia, J.L. (1991). The impact of the lengths of
ysis, 19, 101–112. estimation periods and hedging horizons on the effectiveness of a
Hsin, C.W., Kuo, J., & Lee, C.F. (1994). A new measure to compare the hedge: evidence from foreign currency futures. Journal of Futures
hedging effectiveness of foreign currency futures versus options. Markets, 3, 271–289.
Journal of Futures Markets, 14, 685–707. Myers, R.J., & Thompson, S.R. (1989) Generalized optimal hedge ratio
Hung, J.C., Chiu, C.L. & Lee, M.C. (2006). Hedging with zero-value at estimation. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 71,
risk hedge ratio, Applied Financial Economics, 16, 259–269. 858–868.
Hylleberg, S., & Mizon, G.E. (1989). Cointegration and error correc- Osterwald-Lenum, M. (1992). A note with quantiles of the asymptotic
tion mechanisms. Economic Journal, 99, 113–125. distribution of the maximum likelihood cointegration rank test
Jarque, C.M., & Bera, A.K. (1987). A test for normality of observations statistics. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 54, 461–471.
and regression residuals. International Statistical Review, 55, Phillips, P.C.B., & Perron, P. (1988). Testing unit roots in time series
163–172. regression. Biometrika, 75, 335–46.
Johansen, S., & Juselius, K. (1990). Maximum likelihood estimation Rutledge, D.J.S. (1972). Hedgers’ demand for futures contracts: a
and inference on cointegration—with applications to the demand for theoretical framework with applications to the United States soy-
money. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 52, 169–210. bean complex. Food Research Institute Studies, 11, 237–256.
Johnson, L.L. (1960). The theory of hedging and speculation in com- Sephton, P.S. (1993a). Hedging wheat and canola at the Winnipeg
modity futures. Review of Economic Studies, 27, 139–151. commodity exchange. Applied Financial Economics, 3, 67–72.
Junkus, J.C., & Lee, C.F. (1985). Use of three index futures in hedging Sephton, P.S. (1993b). Optimal hedge ratios at the Winnipeg commod-
decisions. Journal of Futures Markets, 5, 201–222. ity exchange. Canadian Journal of Economics, 26, 175–193.
Kolb, R.W., & Okunev, J. (1992). An empirical evaluation of the Shalit, H. (1995). Mean-Gini hedging in futures markets. Journal of
extended mean-Gini coefficient for futures hedging. Journal of Futures Markets, 15, 617–635.
Futures Markets, 12, 177–186. Stock, J.H., & Watson, M.W. (1988). Testing for common trends.
Kolb, R.W., & Okunev, J. (1993). Utility maximizing hedge ratios in Journal of the American Statistical Association, 83, 1097–1107.
the extended mean Gini framework. Journal of Futures Markets, Working, H. (1953). Hedging reconsidered. Journal of Farm Economics,
13, 597–609. 35, 544–561.

You might also like