You are on page 1of 20

KURT A. CARLSON, JARED WOLFE, SIMON J. BLANCHARD, JOEL C.

HUBER,

and DAN ARIELY*

How do consumers adjust their spending when their budget changes?


A common view is that the allocation of one’s current budget should not
depend on previous budget allocations. Contrary to this, the authors find
that when the budget contracts to a particular level, consumers select
less variety (as measured by the number of different items with some of
the budget allocated to them) than when their budget expands to that
same level. This budget contraction effect stems from a reduction in
variety under the contracting budget, not from variety expansion under
the expanding budget. Evidence from five experiments indicates that the
effect is driven by a desire to avoid feelings of loss associated with
spreading allocation cuts (relative to reference quantities from previous
allocations) across many items.
Keywords: budget contraction, allocation variety, loss aversion, reference
quantities
Online Supplement: http://dx.doi.org/10.1509/jmr.10.0243

The Budget Contraction Effect: How


Contracting Budgets Lead to Less Varied
Choice

In stable economic times, approximately 300,000 new pay cut, a reduction in hours, or an involuntary transition to
unemployment claims are filed in the United States each part -time work (Taylor et al. 2010). More than half those
month. People who have lost their jobs typically experience an surveyed (62%) also reported reducing their household
spending in response to the economic contraction.
income loss of 25%–40% in the 12 months following the loss In addition to income contractions from economic hard-
(Ruhm 1991; Stephens 2001), either because they fail to find a ship, many other life events can cause consumers to reduce
new job or because the new job pays less than the lost job their disposable budgets. Two of the most significant and
(Stephens 1997) . Matters are even worse when the economy common events are paying for college (Souleles 2000) and
retirement (Banks, Blundell, and Tanner 1998; Bernheim,
experiences a significant contraction. For exam-ple, a recent
Skinner, and Weinberg 2001). For example, Bernheim,
Pew survey found that during a recession (e.g., the one that Skinner, and Weinberg (2001) find that retirement
began in 2007), 55% of adult U.S. workers experienced a coincided with a drop in U.S. food budgets of 24% for
work-related financial contraction due to a households in the first income quartile, 15% for those in the
*Kurt A. Carlson is Associate Professor of Marketing, McDonough School
second, and 9% for those in the third and fourth quartiles.
of Business, Georgetown University (e - mail: kurt.carlson@georgetown. edu).
The prevalence of budget contractions in everyday con-
Jared Wolfe is Assistant Professor of Marketing, LIU Post (e-mail: jared. sumer life raises the important question of how consumers
wolfe@liu.edu). Simon J. Blanchard is Assistant Professor of Marke-ting, adjust their spending under a budget contraction compared
McDonough School of Business, Georgetown University (e-mail: simon. with a budget expansion. The standard economic view is that
blanchard@georgetown.edu). Joel C. Huber is Schwartz Professor of
consumers move up and down their utility surface to whatever
Marketing, Fuqua School of Business, Duke University (e-mail: joel.
huber@duke.edu). Dan Ariely is Duke Professor of Marketing, Fuqua School allocation provides the highest utility for the cur-rent budget.
of Business, Duke University (e-mail: dandan@duke.edu). Stephen Nowlis A basic assumption is that the trajectory of a person’s budget
served as associate editor for this article. does not change the shape of his or her util-

© 2015, American Marketing Association Journal of Marketing Research

ISSN: 0022-2437 (print), 1547-7193 (electronic) 337 Vol. LII (June 2015), 337–348
338 JOURNAL OF MARKETING RESEARCH, JUNE
ity surface. This means that if all other factors are held con- 2015 increase (decrease) spending on essential goods that
stant (e.g., tastes, prices, liquidity), the path down the are consumed in less (more) visible circumstances,
utility surface will be the same as the path up the surface.
For bud-get allocations, this means that consumers will compared with when the economy is expanding.
allocate their budget to the same set of goods in the same In contrast with prior research, which has focused mainly
a on
proportions for budget of $ X, regardless of whether their aggregate income changes and their effects on aggregate
was
previous budget greater than or less than $X. spending, we examine the effects of budget changes on allo-
In this research, we contend that this single path assump- cations for individual consumers. We do so for three main
tion and the implications derived from it are not warranted reasons. First, it is difficult to analyze income effects with-out
when consumers allocate a sequence of budgets. We pro- first specifying consumer expectations. Specifically, the study
pose that when a consumer allocates an initial budget of income effects requires specification of whether an income
across an assortment of items, the amount allocated to each shock was anticipated or unanticipated and whether it was
item serves as a reference point for subsequent allocations. expected to be permanent or transitory (Jappelli and Pistaferri
2010) . Second, by focusing on budgets instead of income, we
If a new budget is lower than the prior budget, the
can avoid the complex issue of expenditure smoothing through
consumer must allocate less to some items than the saving or borrowing against future income. Third, examining
reference level established under the previous allocation. In the effect of budget changes on allocations enables us to
accordance with loss aversion, we predict that consumers control for consumer myopia and liquidity constraints, the two
will anticipate psychological loss for every item for which hypotheses most typically advanced for asymmetric income
their new allo-cation is less than its reference allocation. To effects (Shea 1995a).
minimize the sum of these anticipated psychological losses, In addition to the focus on discretionary budgets, the cur-
consumers will allocate cuts to a relatively small subset of rent work departs from prior work in two other important
items. As a consequence, the number of different items to ways. First, in general prior research has used either panel
which a given budget (e.g., $100) is allocated (which we
data or aggregate -level consumption data to explore the
refer to as “allo-cation variety”) will be fewer when the
budget sequence is contracting (i.e., if the previous budget effect of income changes on expenditures as a whole. Such
was higher at, for example, $ 150) than when it is settings are quite different from individual- level experi-
expanding (i.e., if the previ-ous budget was lower at, for ments that examine how a specific consumer reacts to a
example, $50). We refer to this effect of budget trajectory budget change. Consequently, prior research lacks the
on allocation variety as the “bud-get contraction effect.” strong internal validity and the concomitant causal infer-
In the remainder of this article, we review the relevant lit- ence that experimental designs provide. Second, whereas
erature and develop our research hypothesis that allocations of prior research has examined aggregate expenditures or how
a given budget will be less varied when that budget was part of spending shifts from certain types of items to other types of
a contracting sequence than when the same budget was part of items, we examine how the variety in the allocation basket
an expanding sequence. We then present five choice fluctuates in response to budget changes. This enables us to
experiments that show choice patterns consistent with the make direct statements not about substitution effects across
budget contraction effect; with these experiments, we trace the products but about the shape of the income expansion path.
budget contraction effect’s origins to loss aver-sion, in which The Consumer’s Budget Allocation Problem
consumers use previous budget allocations as a reference point When allocating a budget across a set of items, the con-
when contemplating future allocations. sumer’s budget allocation problem can be stated as follows:
THEORETICAL DEVELOPMENT “to identify and commit to the affordable assortment of items
that is expected to provide the greatest utility.” In this
Consumption in the Face of Changing Budgets
statement, the identification with and commitment to an
It is well established that changes in income have a sig-
assortment define a choice (Russo and Carlson 2002).
nificant influence on aggregate consumption patterns (e.g., Assortment refers to the set of items to which a nonzero
Hall 1979; Hall and Mishkin 1982). It is also known that amount of the budget is allocated. The term “affordable”
consumers do not always react symmetrically to increasing simply means that the consumer has sufficient resources to
and decreasing income. For example, Shea (1995a, b) ana- cover the total cost of the assortment. The phrase “expected to
lyzes quarterly U.S. consumption data and finds that drops in provide the greatest utility” means that the consumer’s
consumer income lead to more changes in consumption than objective is to maximize expected utility, given an evalua-tion
equal income increases. Likewise, Bowman, Minehart, and of the alternatives. Importantly, when making such choices,
Rabin (1993) find asymmetry in how total consumption consumers do not necessarily maximize actual util-ity but
changes in the face of news regarding future income (expected instead maximize expected utility (Coombs, Dawes, and
to decrease or expected to increase). They find that when Tversky 1970) . This means that consumers can make choices
consumers expect income to increase, they are more likely to that turn out to be suboptimal if their expectations are wrong,
immediately alter their total consumption than when they as has been well documented in literature on affective
expect their income to decrease. Dargay (2001) finds that forecasting (e.g., Kahneman and Thaler 2006; Loewenstein,
income effects on car ownership are not symmetric, with O’Donoghue, and Rabin 2003) . The discon-nect between
consumers being less likely to cut car spending when income expected and actual utility often occurs because expected
declines than to expand car spend-ing when income expands. utility depends on how consumers evalu-ate alternatives, and
More recently, Kamakura and Du (2012) observe that during a evaluations often depend on the context in which the
recession, consumers alternatives are considered (e.g., Johnson and
The Budget Contraction Effect 339

Meyer 1984; Payne, Bettman, and Johnson 1993; Slovic,


Griffin, and Tversky 1990). Thus, changes in context can referencementofitems,pointtheforamountsubsequentallocatedbudgetto
alter the utility consumers expect to receive from items and eachallocationitem servesdecisions.asa This
thus alter how budgets are allocated. (2006)ideaunitisbiasconsistentheuristic.withSpecifically,Geier,Rozin,Geier,andRozin,Doros’sand

When
it comes to allocating different budgets over time, optimalDorosfindwhateverthatconsumersreasonabletendquantitytoacceptofanasitemnormalthey andare

one salient contextual feature is how the previous budget was


allocated—in particular, how many of each item the budget cup)given.forInscoopingtheirstudy,itemspeople(e.g.,givenpretzels,alargerM&Ms)scoop took(aquarter(and

was allocated to. We suggest that these quantities (which


range from zero when nothing is spent on an item to the peoplepresumablygivenconsumed)asmaller(tablespoon)moreofthescoop.items Theintheauthorsbowl conthan-

quantity that could be obtained if the entire budget were spent


on the item) serve as reference quantities for the next budget normaltendthatandtheappropriate,scoopcreatedcausingareferenceconsumersquantitytocomplythatseemedwith

allocation decision. As with other reference points


(Kalyanaram and Winer 1995; Lattin and Bucklin 1989; selecteditbyscoopingquantitiesmoregainwhenasimilarthescooperstatus, wasoriginallarger.allocationIfself-

Oliver 1980), these allocation reference quantities can influ-


ence how consumers perceive and evaluate items. We con- normalquantitiesandwouldappropriate.beconsidered reference values that are
tend that consumers will evaluate each item’s new alloca-tion When the new budget is lower than the initial budget, the
level relative to its reference quantity from the previous consumer must allocate less to some items than the refer-ence
allocation, such that they will perceive a reduction in quan-tity level for those items. In other words, when a budget contracts,
as a loss and an increase in quantity as a gain. As a con- a consumer will code the prospective amount of any item that
sequence, contracting budget trajectories will involve refer- had a nonzero prior allocation as either the same or a loss
ence quantities above those available to consumers under the relative to that item’s reference level. Follow-ing loss aversion
new (lower) budget, causing consumers to view new allocation (e.g., Hardie, Johnson, and Fader 1993; Kahneman and
possibilities as losses relative to prior allocation levels. In Tversky 1979; Novemsky and Kahneman 2005), we expect
contrast, an expanding budget trajectory will involve reference that consumers will try to avoid incurring such losses across
quantities below those available at the new budget level, many items. This is because the loss function is convex and
causing consumers to view expanding allocation levels as steepest immediately below the ref-erence level. Therefore, to
gains. As we discuss subsequently, this can have implications minimize the sum total of these anticipated losses, consumers
for how consumers allocate a given budget (e.g., $80) to a set facing a contracting budget trajectory will distribute their
of items (e.g., groceries) under a contracting budget trajectory budget cuts across a relatively narrower subset of items.
(if, for example, the previous budget was $120) versus an Consequently, the number of dif-ferent items to which a given
expanding budget trajectory (if, for example, the previous budget (e.g., $100) is allocated (i.e., allocation variety) will be
budget was $40). fewer when the previous budget was larger (e.g., $150) than
Asymmetry in Allocations when the previous bud-get was smaller (e.g., $50).
The allocation of a specific budget under a contracting
trajectory could differ from an allocation of the same budget We focus on allocation variety because the amount of
when the budget is part of an expanding sequence for sev-eral variety in the choice set is often an important factor that
reasons. First, consumers might have contractual obli-gations consumers contemplate when making purchase decisions
(akin to liquidity constraints) that cause them to focus most (Kahn and Ratner 2005) and because it provides a way to
spending on contracted items and to cut noncon-tract items examine assortment differences across individuals. As noted
when budgets are reduced. For example, con-sumers who buy previously, we refer to the phenomenon of lesser allocation
a car with a loan or a house with a mort-gage will have to cut variety for a given budget under a contracting trajectory than
other expenditures when their income declines. Second, for one under an expanding trajectory as the “budget con-
consumers have more opportunity to learn what they really traction effect.” We test for this in five experiments by com-
like when allocating larger budgets because the larger budgets paring allocation variety for a sequence of budget allocations
allow for greater exploration. For exam-ple, someone who that is expanding with the allocations of the same budgets
wants to join a country club, but will only realize how much when the sequence is contracting. Our experiments control for
utility he or she will receive from it after joining the club, learning about the alternatives and liquidity constraints.
might come to this realization only after allocating a large In general, loss aversion is believed to occur because of the
discretionary entertainment budget, some of which is allocated expectation that the pain of losing something will be greater
to the country club. Later, if the budget declines, he or she
than the pleasure of an equivalent gain (e.g., Ariely, Huber,
might continue with the country club membership and
sacrifice other forms of entertainment. This example reflects and Wertenbroch 2005; Kahneman and Tversky 1984).
consumer learning, such that a higher budget allocation helps Indeed, when gains and losses can be compared in the same
the consumer learn about his or her true preferences, and thus context, the anticipation of greater feelings from a loss (vs. an
responds to a different utility sur-face under budget equivalent gain) influences the choices con-sumers ultimately
contraction than under budget expansion. make (McGraw et al. 2010). Therefore, for the purposes of
Beyond learning asymmetries and contractual commit-
testing and understanding the budget contraction effect, we are
ments, we expect that budget allocations differ for expand- interested in consumers’ expected utility regarding the
decisions they make, rather than the actual experienced utility
ing and contracting budget trajectories for another reason.
that follows after selected items are consumed and
When a consumer allocates an initial budget to an assort- experienced. We are also interested in the
340 JOURNAL OF MARKETING RESEARCH, JUNE 2015
exists, the budget contraction effect will still operate but will
choices consumers actually make, rather than the choices at
they “should” make. do so at the level of goal-derived categories rather than the
If budget trajectory influences allocations as we expect, for level of product categories (Barsalou 1983; Blanchard and
tions DeSarbo 2013; Ratneshwar, Pechmann, and Shocker 1996) .
consumers making a sequence of three budgets alloca-
For example, although frosting and cake mixes are
(low, middle, and high budgets) in either an expanding or a complements in a distinct product category, we argue that
contracting sequence, the allocation variety for the low-est
consumers who want to bake cakes will view them as mem-
budget should differ more than the allocation variety for the
highest budget. This is because the middle budget allo-cation bers of a single goal -derived category (“Items I need to make
provides a set of reference quantities that represent prospective a cake”) and, under budget contraction, will be more likely to
losses for the lowest budget level in the con-tracting budget stop buying items from an entire category (e.g., items to make
condition, but there are no such reference quantities for the a pizza) to preserve other goal- derived cate-gories (e.g.,
lowest budget allocation in the expanding budget sequence. In baking a cake). Thus, it is not immediately clear how inherent
contrast, the middle budget allocation provides a set of complementarity in the consideration set might influence the
reference quantities that signal prospective gains for the budget contraction effect. In some cases, the budget
highest budget level in the expanding budget condition, but contraction effect might lead to the cutting of several items
there are no such reference quantities for the highest budget in that belong to one goal-derived category. In other cases, it
the contracting sequence. Because refer-ence points are likely might lead to a shallow cut of items across all categories. The
to be less salient under gains and the concavity of the value issue is further complicated by the reality that each individual
function for gains is generally mod-est (with quickly consumer constructs his or her own unique goal - derived
diminishing marginal gains in utility), we expect this reference
categories at will. For these reasons, we selected sets of items
allocation effect to have little or no influence on allocations
for the experiments that we believe are unlikely to be deemed
when budgets are expanding. We test for this asymmetry by
comparing the slopes of the allo-cation varieties for each obvious complements of the same goal-derived category.
budget level across expanding and contracting budget
conditions. EXPERIMENT 1: ALLOCATION VARIETY IN
If we are correct, a difference in the budget trajectory by GROCERY ORDERS
itself is insufficient to create the budget contraction effect. Experiment 1 tests whether mean and slope differences
This is because the effect requires that reference allocation exist between budget expansion and budget contraction
levels for the items being considered under the new budget paths. Participants made grocery budget allocations for
reference levels come from the allocation of the previous three budgets that were allocated in either an expanding
budget. Therefore, if the budget declines, but consumers ($40, $80, $120) or a contracting ( $120, $ 80, $ 40) budget
did not allocate the previous budget to specific items, there order. Across these different budget scenarios, we expect
will be no reference allocation levels and no felt loss from lesser allocation variety among participants in the contract-
allocat-ing less to an item. Therefore, if previous budgets ing condition than among those in the expanding condition,
were not allocated, the budget contraction effect should be and we expect this difference to be most pronounced for the
mitigated. Research Overview lowest budget.
The subsequent experiments explore budget allocations Method
for common consumer budgeting decisions, including gro- Participants (N = 451) from a national online panel were
cery store purchases, investments, and cities to visit on a asked to imagine a shopping spree with a given budget to buy
trip. Experiments 1–3b demonstrate the budget contraction groceries at Costco. They were asked to allocate the budget
effect, and Experiments 3b and 4 explore the psychological across nine products that generally come in boxed packages:
mechanism underlying it. We measure allocation variety as
Thomas’ English Muffin Mix & Match ($3.58), Milton’s
the number of different items to which the middle budget is
Multi -Grain Bread ($4.88), M&M’s Milk Choco-late
allocated. This differs from definitions of variety seeking
that involve the pursuit of stimulation through the ($17.97), PowerBar Performance Variety Pack ($21.88),
consump-tion of novel items (Faison 1977), and it differs Mott’s Variety Pack Apple Sauce ($ 8.30), Chef Boyardee
from phe-nomenological definitions of variety seeking that Beef Ravioli ($8.30), Red Baron Deep Dish Singles Pizza
emphasize a preference for lesser- valued and previously Variety ($10.44), DiGiorno Pepperoni Pizza ($ 12.88), and
unselected items over higher-valued and currently selected The Cheesecake Factory Original Cheesecake ($9.45). In the
items (Mitchell, Kahn, and Knasko 1995; Simonson 1990) . budget expansion condition, participants began with a $40
How-ever, allocation variety accords with more general budget and indicated the quantity they would purchase of each
defini-tions of variety seeking, in which evidence of the item on a product order form (e.g., four boxes of Thomas’
pursuit of variety is revealed by a preference for larger
English Muffin Mix & Match, three boxes of Chef Boyardee
portfolios of items over smaller portfolios of items (Kahn
Beef Ravioli, and zero boxes of PowerBar Per-formance
and Ratner 2005; McAlister 1982).
We designed the consideration sets used in the experi- Variety Pack). After allocating the initial budget, participants
were told to imagine that a few weeks had passed and that they
ments to have a substantial amount of utility independence had eaten all the food but now had won an $80 shopping spree
across the items so that participants would be unlikely to at Costco, in which they could spend what they wished on the
same set of nine products. Partici-pants used a new blank
make decisions about one item conditional on the other
product entry form to complete this second allocation. After
items they selected. We expect that when complementarity this, participants imagined the same
The Budget Contraction Effect 341

scenario, but this time with a budget of $ 120. The stimuli Figure 1
for participants in the contracting budget were the same as EXPERIMENT 1: BETWEEN-SUBJECT NUMBER OF GROCERY
in the expansion budget, except that the first budget was
$120, the second budget was $80, and the third budget was ITEMS PURCHASED BY CONDITION
$40. (The experimental stimuli for this and subsequent
experiments can be found in the Web Appendix.) 5.50
Because real prices and products were used in this experi- 5.12
ment, it was not possible to restrict participants to spending
the exact dollar amount of each shopping spree (e.g., 5.00 4.82
exactly $40). Therefore, participants in this experiment 4.62
were not required to spend the exact amount of their shop- 4.50
ping spree budget. Rather, those who overspent their budget 4.17
did so expecting to cover the difference from their own 4.00
pockets, and those who underspent their budget did so 3.57
expecting to forfeit the remainder of the shopping spree 3.50
budget.1
Results 3.00 2.99
After eliminating nine participants with missing values,
we were left with 442 observations (for three budget levels) 2.50 $40 $80 $120
for our analyses. The experimental design included two Budget
budget trajectories (expanding and contracting) across sub-
jects and three budget levels ($ 40, $80, and $120) within Expanding Contracting
subject. We analyzed allocation variety as a function of (1) Linear (expanding)
three budget levels ($40, $80, and $120; within-subject) and Linear (contracting)
(2) two budget trajectories (expanding and contracting;
between-subjects) with a within-subject analysis of variance
(ANOVA). In addition to including individual random contracting than the expanding budget condition (M = .36;
effects, we included the total number of items purchased as F(1, 879) = 6.86, p = .01). This difference in slopes provides
a covariate. We then used planned contrasts to investigate initial support for the budget contraction effect.
our hypotheses. Another approach to test for the budget contraction effect
As Figure 1 shows, higher budgets lead to a greater mean is to examine allocation variety, measured as the number of
number of grocery items chosen. (For reference, Table 1 different products chosen with the middle budget across
reports the sample mean quantities purchased of each item budget trajectories. This approach involves a comparison in
at each budget level.) We found a significant interaction which participants in both conditions have made one prior
between budget levels and the budget trajectory (F(2, 879) = allocation and are facing the same current budget. Contrasts
3.46, p = .03), which is best explained by contrasting the revealed lesser allocation variety for the $80 budget in the
slopes of the budget trajectory. The within-subject differ- contracting condition (M = 4.17) than in the expanding bud-
ence in allocation variety between the lowest budget level get condition (M = 4.62; F(1, 879) = 20.41, p < .01) . At all
and the highest budget level was significantly greater for the budget levels, participants in the contracting condition had
lesser allocation variety than those in the expanding condi-
1 The average total spending at the $40, $80, and $ 120 budget levels did
not significantly differ between the expanding and contracting conditions tion. Specifically, planned contrasts revealed that when the
($40 budget: M exp = 58.96, M con = 58.57; F(1, 450) = .00, p > .90; $80 bud- budget was $40, participants in the contracting condition
get: Mexp = 103.60, M con = 106.70; F(1, 450) = .03, p > .80; $120 budget: had lesser allocation variety in their choice sets (M = 2.99)
Mexp = 149.28, Mcon = 129.06; F(1, 450) = .95, p > .30). than those in the expanding condition (M = 3.57; F(1, 879) =

Table 1
EXPERIMENT 1: MEAN QUANTITY OF GROCERY ITEMS BY BUDGET LEVEL AND TRAJECTORY

Between-Subject Means Within-Subject Differences


$40 Budget $80 Budget $120 Budget $120 Budget – $40 Budget
Grocery Items Expanding Contracting Expanding Contracting Expanding Contracting Expanding Contracting
Thomas’ English Muffin Mix & Match .86 .90 1.48 1.25 2.02 1.65 1.19 .75
Milton’s Multi-Grain Bread 1.29 1.27 2.21 1.60 2.93 1.87 1.68 .61
M&M’s Milk Chocolate .16 .14 .41 .35 .85 .51 .70 .37
PowerBar Performance Variety Pack .25 .27 .33 .41 .56 .74 .33 .47
Mott’s Variety Pack Apple Sauce .73 .52 1.77 1.33 2.11 1.52 1.42 1.01
Chef Boyardee Beef Ravioli 1.47 1.42 2.35 2.12 3.20 2.54 1.79 1.13
Red Baron Deep Dish Singles Pizza Variety .91 .98 1.65 1.95 2.48 2.12 1.61 1.15
DiGiorno Pepperoni Pizza .82 1.03 1.31 2.05 1.89 2.04 1.10 1.02

Cheesecake Factory Cheesecake .32 .14 .49 .39 .63 .71 .31 .58
342 JOURNAL OF MARKETING RESEARCH, JUNE
2015 as they wished. Each participant received and
36.78, p < .001). Finally, at the highest budget level ($120),
allocation variety also significantly differed between par- allocated three retirement budgets in either an expanding
in sequence ($500, $1,000, $ 1,500) or a contracting sequence
ticipants in the contracting condition (M = 4.82) and those
the expanding condition (M = 5.12; F(1, 879) = 5.46, p = ($1,500, $1,000, $500).
.02). These effects hold when we control for the number of For
each of the three sequential budget allocation deci-
items purchased, in line with allocation variety (F(1, 879) =
sions, participants reported how much of the current budget
50.34, p < .01). (in dollars) they wished to allocate to each of the four
Discussion investment vehicles. We deemed vehicles that received a
The budget contraction effect we found is consistent with nonzero investment amount as having been invested in for
the notion that consumers try to avoid spreading losses shal-
that budget. Thus, a participant’s allocation variety for a
given budget could range from a low of one (i.e., the entire
lowly across many items and instead constrict them to a nar- budget allocated to one vehicle) to a high of four (i.e., some
rower set of items. Our explanation for the budget contrac-tion portion of the budget allocated to each of the four vehicles).
effect stems from the idea that the allocation of the initial As in Experiment 1, the key test was whether the mean and
budget provides a reference quantity for each item in the slopes for the allocations of a given budget were less varied
allocation set. Experiment 2 explores the generalizabil-ity of (i.e., applied to fewer vehicles) in the contracting sequence
the budget contraction effect by examining a setting in which than in the expanding sequence.
money is allocated to investments. In this case, the budget is Unlike in the grocery purchases, participants in this
not allocated to different products, but to an assortment of experiment were not led to believe that the previous alloca-
financial investment vehicles. Furthermore, the use of tion had been consumed, but rather that each new allocation
investments instead of groceries helps eliminate potential would be added to the previous month’s (e.g., “The govern-
variation due to any possibility of dependence among the ment has decided to up the allocation amount for this
available items; participants do not have any information to month. This month they are giving people $1,000 to
potentially attempt to make inferences about complementarity invest”). Thus, if the budget contraction effect only occurs
of the available alternatives. when people cannot pursue interperiod allocation
EXPERIMENT 2: ALLOCATION VARIETY IN strategies, it should not occur in this experiment.
FINANCIAL DIVERSIFICATION Results
It is common for people to have retirement accounts to As in Experiment 1, the experimental design had two
which they contribute each month. Such accounts generally budget trajectories (expanding and contracting; between-
allow investors to adjust how their balance is allocated subjects) and three budget levels ($500, $1,000, and
across various investments. In this experiment, we explore $1,500; within - subject), and we analyzed allocation
how people allocate investment contributions to various variety as a function of budget trajectories, budget level,
investment vehicles under either increasing or decreasing and their inter-action with a within-subject ANOVA. Three
investment allocation budgets. This experiment enables us measures of allocation variety were thus obtained for each
to examine whether the budget contraction effect general- of the 588 participants.
izes to a setting in which the budget and the items to which First, we found a significant interaction between budget
the allocations are made are both monetary. By limiting the allocation and budget trajectory (F(2, 1772) = 28.53, p <
number of investment vehicles to four and by sizing the .01). Figure 2 displays the (between- subject) number of
budgets so that there is sufficient money to allocate to all investments to which participants in the expanding and con-
four vehicles, we can mute any possible effects of differen- tracting conditions allocated each of the three budgets
tial consideration of costly alternatives in the initial alloca- (between-subject means). As in Experiment 1, planned bud-get
level budget trajectory within-subject planned contrast
tions of the declining and expanding budget conditions
revealed that the slope (difference in allocation variety)
(i.e., participants first faced with the largest budget and
between the largest and smallest budgets (within - subject) was
those first faced with the smallest budget) that could have
significantly greater in the expanding than the contract-ing
poten-tially existed in Experiment 1. In addition, because
condition (M = .44, F(1, 1772) = 54.78, p < .001). This again
there are no prices for the items in this setting and all items provides support for the budget contraction effect.
had posi-tive expected value, we could require participants
Second, we found, as expected, that allocation variety
to allo-cate the exact amount of each budget.
was lesser for the $1,000 budget under the contracting tra-
Method
jectory (M = 2.95) than for that under the expanding trajec-
Participants were 588 adults from a national online panel.
tory (M = 3.26; F(1, 1172) = 52.17, p < .001). Comparison
Each participant was asked to imagine that the U.S. govern-
of the allocation variety for the other budget levels revealed
ment was implementing a new retirement plan that gave
a pattern similar to that in Experiment 1. Specifically, at the
people money each month to allocate to four investment
lowest budget level ( $500), participants in the contracting
vehicles that differed in their risk and likely return: “very safe, condition had less allocation variety in their choice sets (M
guaranteed low returns”; “safe, almost always with modest = 2.57) than those in the expanding condition (M = 3.17;
returns”; “somewhat risky, normally with above average F(1, 1172) = 204.66, p < .001). In addition, at the highest
returns”; and “very risky, with the possibility for high returns.” budget level ($ 1,500), the difference was smaller but sig-
The plan allowed people to spread their monthly investment nificant (Mcontracting = 3.14, Mexpanding = 3.30; F(1, 1172) =
stipend/budget across the four vehicles 14.73, p = .01).
The Budget Contraction Effect 343

Figure 2 thanthatdecliningexpandingbudgetsbudgetsgenerateand,throughlessmeanslopeallocationtests,thatvarietythe
EXPERIMENT 2: BETWEEN-SUBJECT NUMBER OF
INVESTMENTS SELECTED BY CONDITION controlsuccessivechoicesdeclinesthan successivehaveamuchbudgetlargerexpansions.impacton initial

EXPERIMENT 3: ALLOCATION VARIETY IN TRAVEL


ITINERARIES
Experiment 3 assesses allocation variety by the number of
3.40 3.26 3.30
cities to be visited on a trip with differing numbers of days,
3.20 3.17 3.14 thus testing whether the effect extends to time bud-gets. The
question of extension to time budgets is important because
3.00 2.95
time is one of the most significant resources con-sumers have
to allocate (Okada and Hoch 2004). The gener-alization of the
2.80 2.57 budget contraction effect to time budgets is uncertain, though,
2.60 because money and time differ in the length of planning
horizons they encourage (Lynch et al. 2010) , in the
2.40 concreteness of their valuation (Okada and Hoch 2004), in
their tendency to direct attention to posses-sion versus
2.20 experience (Mogilner and Aaker 2009), and in the extent to
which they encourage heuristic versus system-atic processing
2.00 $500 $1,000 $1,500 (Saini and Monga 2008). Thus, anticipated psychological
Budget reactions to changes in time budgets may dif-fer from changes
in monetary budgets.
Expanding Contracting
To examine the allocation of time budgets, Experiment 3a
Linear (expanding)
explores how people allocate travel-day budgets to cities when
Linear (contracting) planning a trip through Western Europe. Experiment 3b uses
Discussion this same travel context to examine whether making many
In this experiment, the budget contraction effect occurs for shallow cuts to a reference allocation indeed involves more
incremental financial investments and, just as in Experi-ment severe feelings of loss than making fewer deep cuts.
1, demonstrates a much larger impact of two contrac-tions Experiment 3a: Impact of a High Initial Budget
against a control than two expansions against a control. Method. All participants (N = 410) from a national online
Because participants in this experiment came from a national panel were asked to imagine winning an all -expenses-paid trip
sample of U.S. adults, it is possible that this sample contains through Western Europe for 21 days. Participants in the
many novice investors. Novices often take information- expanding budget condition were then told that because of
processing shortcuts (e.g., Ratneshwar and Chaiken 1991), and work obligations, they could only travel for 7 of the 21 days.
participants in this experiment might have simply taken the Participants were then shown the list of cities they could visit
shortcut of cutting categories. For this reason, we exam-ined (i.e., Amsterdam, Copenhagen, Edinburgh, Lis-bon, London,
the robustness of the budget contraction effect using people Madrid, Marseilles, Milan, Munich, Naples, Paris, Prague,
with a relatively high knowledge of investing. We ran a follow Rome, and Vienna) and were told to indicate which cities they
-up experiment using 54 middle managers and executives would visit and how many days they would spend in each city.
enrolled in a weekend MBA program at a top business school. After making the initial allocation, participants were told that
The experiment took place two weeks after participants time had freed up in their work schedule and they could now
completed the core finance course, ensuring that all travel instead for 14 days. Par-ticipants completed a new travel
itinerary, indicating how they would allocate their 14 travel
participants were well versed in the topics of finance and
days across the various cities. Finally, participants were told
investing.
that their schedule had freed up completely and they could
The results from this smaller sample of well-versed par- travel instead for all 21 days, and they completed a final travel
ticipants were nearly identical to the results of the larger itinerary. Partici-pants in the contracting travel budget
online sample (between-subject means: M500exp = 3.33, condition followed the same procedure, except that the order
M1,000exp = 3.33, M1,500exp = 3.40, M500con = 2.33, M1,000con = was reversed, begin-ning with 21 days and ending with 7 days,
2.83, M 1,500con = 3.17) . Although the difference in alloca-tion with each con-traction due to an unexpected constraint in their
variety f r the $1,500 budget was not significant across the two schedule.
budget trajectories (F(1, 52) = .98, p > .30), the dif-ference for work . As with the previous experiments, we
analyzed
the $ 1,000 budget was marginally significant (F(1, 52) = 2.92,
Results
p < .10), and the difference for the $ 500 budget was highly the allocation variety as a function of the three budget levels (7
significant (F(1, 52) = 12.82, p < .001). Finally, a slope test days, 14 days, and 21 days; within-subject) and budget
(i.e., a planned budget level budget trajectory linear contrast)
trajectory (expanding or contracting; between-subjects) with a
also revealed a steeper slope in the declining budget
within-subject ANOVA. First, we found a significant
condition (M = .84) than in the expanding budget condition (M
= .07; F(1, 52) = 6.35, p < .05). The first two experiments interaction between budget trajectory and budget level (F(2,
demonstrate in very different contexts 815) = 9.43, p < .01). To illustrate this interaction, Figure 3
344 JOURNAL OF MARKETING RESEARCH, JUNE
2015 Costco and not having received money from the
Figure 3 govern-ment to invest for retirement). Nevertheless, the
effects here replicated those in the previous experiments.
EXPERIMENT 3A: BETWEEN-SUBJECT NUMBER OF CITIES
This indirect evidence suggests that the budget contraction
VISITED BY CONDITION
not
effect does stem from differences in budget trajectory
alone, but rather from differences in reference quantities
that emerge when initial budgets are allocated to items. We
8.00 7.60 7.28 examine this idea directly in Experiment 4.
Thus far, three experiments using groceries, investments,
7.00 and travel itineraries have shown that allocations of con-
tracting budgets have lesser allocation variety than alloca-
6.00 6.47 5.64
tions of expanding budgets. Although at the lowest budgets
there is little opportunity to find differences of extreme
magnitude, the reported experiments consistently find that
5.00 4.44
the largest differences in allocation variety across the bud-
get trajectories come from the lowest budget levels. This is
4.00 consistent with evidence that consumers try to avoid some
3.12 of the feelings of loss from making broad but shallow allo-
3.00 cation cuts to many items, but the evidence is indirect.
The purpose of Experiment 3b is to provide more direct
2.00 7 Days 14 Days 21 Days evidence that the budget contraction effect stems from a
Number of Cities Visited desire to avoid feelings of loss. Specifically, the experiment
Expanding Contracting uses a travel itinerary task to show how a desire to avoid
Linear (expanding) feelings of loss associated with making cuts to many
options may underlie the budget contraction effect.
Linear (contracting) Experiment 3b: Expected Feelings of Loss from Broad
presents the between-subject average allocation variety for Versus Focused Cuts
the three budgets measured by the number of cities each
This experiment examines the expected feelings of loss
participant would visit for the expanding and contracting of two strategies for dealing with a declining budget: a
conditions. As we predicted, a within-subject slope test “broad -cut” strategy, which involves making many small,
(i.e., a planned budget level budget trajectory within- shallow cuts across many items, and a “focused-cut” strat-
subject contrast) revealed that the difference in allocation egy, which involves focusing cuts on a limited set of items.
variety between the highest and lowest budgets was As discussed, choices derive from expected utility (e.g.,
significantly greater for participants in the contracting Mellers and McGraw 2001), not from actual experienced
budget condition than for those in the expanding budget utility after decisions are made, and so we specifically
condition (M = 1.00; F(1, 815) = 18.86, p < .001). focus on expected feelings of loss to better understand why
Second, we also report on the simple effect of budget tra- the budget contraction effect may occur. The loss aversion
jectory conditional on budget level. At the middle budget level account for the budget contraction effect suggests that con-
(14 days), participants in the contracting condition had lesser
allocation variety in their choice sets (M = 5.64) than those in sumers will have less severe feelings of loss when
the expanding condition (M = 6.46; F(1, 815) = 25.97, p < executing a focused-cut strategy than a broad-cut strategy.
.01). The same was true for the 7- day budget, in which Method. Participants were 124 undergraduate students from
participants in the contracting condition had lesser allocation a large eastern university who participated in exchange for
variety in their choice sets (M = 3.11) than those in the monetary compensation ($ 10) . They were given the same 21-
expanding condition (M = 4.43; F(1, 815) = 66.96, p < .001).
At the highest budget level (21 days), there was a smaller but day budget scenario as in the budget contraction conditions of
significant difference in allocation variety between Experiment 3a and were asked to indicate how they would
participants in the contracting condition (M = 7.28) and those allocate their travel budget. Participants were then told to
4.13, p = imagine that they could only travel for 14 days and so had to
in the expanding condition (M = 7.60; F(1, 815) =
eliminate 7 days of travel in a way requested by their travel
.04).
. The data from this experiment replicate the agency. Participants in the focused-cut condi-tion were told
Discussion that they would have to use a focused -cut strategy to adjust
budget contraction effect found previously for time budgets. their travel plans: “For logistical reasons, the travel agency
Specifically, the budget contraction effect replicated in terms with which you booked your trip tells you that you must cut
of both the main effect at the middle budget and the slope your 7 days in a way that preserves the length of your stay in
difference. A noteworthy design feature of this experi-ment as many cities as possible, thus lead-ing you to have to cut out
some of your chosen cities alto-gether .” Participants in the
was that participants were told at the outset to imagine that
broad - cut condition read the same instructions but were told
they had won a trip for 21 days. This is a departure from the that they would have to use a broad- cut strategy to revise their
previous experiments, in which the initial default budget that travel plans. The itali-cized portion in the previous condition
participants brought to each decision context was pre-sumably was replaced with “visiting as many cities as possible, thus
zero (i.e., not having won a shopping spree to leading you to have
The Budget Contraction Effect 345

to reduce the number of days you spend traveling in at least ception of losses in budget contraction by showing a mod-
some of your chosen cities.”
All participants then reported the expected psychological anyerationpreviousofthe budget.effectwhen specific items are not allocated in
experience of making these cuts on nine-point scales (“How
much loss do you expect to feel as a result of adjusting your EXPERIMENT 4: ALLOCATION VARIETY WITHOUT
travel schedule by cutting out some of your chosen cities PRIOR ALLOCATIONS
altogether?” and “How psychologically painful do you expect The results of Experiment 3b show that consumers faced
your decision to cut out some of your chosen cities altogether with allocating a reduced budget anticipate that making broad,
will be?”) . On the same scale, participants assessed the shallow cuts to many alternatives will involve greater feelings
expected general difficulty of making the cuts (“How difficult of loss than making focused, deep cuts to a few alternatives.
do you expect your decision of which of your chosen cities to We claim that the basis of these concerns about loss is the
cut out altogether will be?”). We explore expectations of reference quantities established by the previous budget
difficulty and psychological experi-ence because, according to allocation. If so, the budget contraction effect should not occur
loss aversion, expectations of the psychological experience if participants do not allocate their initial budget because,
drive allocation decisions (e.g., the strategies taken by without an allocation of the budget, reference quantities will
participants in Experiments 1– 3a) , not the expected not emerge. To test this, we ask some partici-pants to examine
difficulty, actual difficulty, or actual psychological experience an initial set of alternatives with a budget in mind but not to
that results from the use of a par-ticular allocation strategy. actually allocate their initial budget.
Method. Participants were 416 adults from a national online
The first two questions enable us to assess whether expected panel. The experimental design was similar to that in
psychological experiences differ for the two strate-gies. The Experiment 1 involving grocery orders. However, this
general difficulty question enables us to determine whether experiment employed a 2 (budget trajectory: expanding or
participants perceive the two strategies as differen-tially contracting; between- subjects) 2 (prior allocation: yes or no;
effortful to apply, a potential alternative explanation for the between - subjects) design. All participants allocated an $80
budget contraction effect. We asked this question because if
grocery budget after facing either a $40 budget (expanding
participants expect the focused -cut strategy to be easier to
execute, the budget contraction effect might stem from a condition) or a $120 (contracting condition) and after either
perceived difference in effort needed to execute spe-cific allocating the initial budget (prior allocation) or not allocating
reduction strategies, rather than the difference in expected the initial budget (no prior allocation).
strategies. Results. Because the only budget allocated by all partici-
psychological experiences of executing different . pants was the $80 budget, the analysis in this experiment
The results reveal that participants in the broad- centers on the allocation variety of the $80 budgets. The
Results focus was on exploring whether the budget trajectory’s
cut condition expected to experience greater feelings of loss influence on allocation variety is moderated by whether
(M = 5.26) than those in the focused -cut strategy condition par-ticipants’ previous budget was allocated to items in
(M = 4.47; F(1, 122) = 4.79, p < .05). This same pattern their consideration set. If so, allocation variety for the $80
occurred for the psychological pain question, with partici- budget should be lesser in the prior allocation contracting
pants using the broad - cut strategy anticipating condition than in the other three conditions. We analyzed
directionally greater psychological pain (M = 3.66) than the alloca-tion variety with linear regression, with budget
those using the focused-cut strategy (M = 3.08; F(1, 122) = trajectory (1: contracting; 0: expanding), prior allocation (1:
2.28, p = .13). An equally weighted linear combination of yes; 0: no), and their interaction as predictors.
these two mea-sures produced the same result; those in the We found a marginally significant interaction between
broad -cut con-dition anticipated greater feelings of loss (M budget trajectory and prior allocation ( = –.7220, t(412) = –
= 4.46) than those in the focused -cut strategy (M = 3.77; 1.68, p < .10) . This interaction (depicted in Figure 4) can be
F(1, 122) = 4.50, p < .05). Finally, the anticipated difficulty decomposed by contrasting the simple effect of the bud-get
of imple-menting the two strategies did not differ (for both trajectory between prior allocation conditions. We found a
condi-tions, M = 4.29; F(1, 122) = .00, p > .50). significant effect of budget trajectory on allocation variety
Discussion. These data provide process evidence for the when the initial budget had been allocated, but no such effect
budget contraction effect, showing that consumers faced when it had not been allocated. Specifically, when the initial
with allocating a reduced budget anticipated that making budget was allocated, there was less allocation vari-ety in the
broad, shallow cuts to many alternatives would involve contracting condition (M = 4.00) than in the expanding
greater feelings of loss than making focused, deep cuts to a condition (M = 4.65; = –.65, t(412) = –2.10, p =
few alternatives. However, there was no difference in .04). However, when the initial budget had not been allo-
expected general difficulty of implementing the two strate- cated, allocation variety in the contracting budget condition
gies. This suggests that the budget contraction effect stems (M = 4.84) was not directionally lower than allocation vari-
not from a difference in expected effort of executing the ety in the expanding condition (M = 4.77; = .07, t(412) =
two strategies but from a difference in the expected .24, p = .81). In addition, for those experiencing an expand-
negative psychological experience of implementing them,
ing budget trajectory, allocation variety in the no prior allo-
in line with a loss aversion account.
Experiment 4 examines directly whether reference quan- cation condition (M = 4.77) did not differ from that in the prior
allocation condition (M = 4.65; = –.12, t(412) = –.39, p = .69).
tities are necessary to produce the budget contraction effect.
However, in the contractingcondition, there was a significant
Specifically, the experiment tests the critical role of the per- difference between the no prior allocation condi-
346 JOURNAL OF MARKETING RESEARCH, JUNE
2015 (but shallowly) across many items. Support for this
Figure 4 avoid-ance of anticipated losses comes from Experiments
EXPERIMENT 4: NUMBER OF GROCERY ITEMS PURCHASED We
3b and 4. show that the budget contraction effect is a
BY CONDITION AT $80 BUDGET causal influence of budget trajectory on the amount of
variety in one’s allocation set. We can make this strong
causal claim because of our experimental designs, in which
participants were randomly assigned to experience either an
4.90 4.84
4.77 expanding or a contracting budget trajectory.
It is important to understand the influence of budget tra-
4.70 4.65
jectory because even in stable economic times, millions of
U.S. households experience a negative budget shock in any
4.50 given year. The role of budget trajectory (as opposed to
income trajectory) on allocation variety might seem a bit
4.30 academic at first, but we believe that allocation variety is the
right place to start for two reasons. First, demand mod-els
4.10 4.00 typically presume that income effects on demand are
symmetric for budget expansions and contractions. Our results
3.90 instead imply that they are not symmetric. That is, our results
suggest that income elasticities for particular products are
3.70 likely to be different when budgets expand than when they
contract. Second, the effect of budget trajectory may also
3.50
influence the exact composition of consumer choice sets. For
Yes Prior Allocation No example, under budget contraction, multi-pack cereals may be
less popular at breakfast, and cities containing multiple
Budget expanding Budget contracting activity options may be less popular on tours. Speculating on
and exploring the nature of this influ-ence is likely to be a
tion (M = 4.00) and the prior allocation condition (M = 4.84; = fruitful avenue for research.
–.84, t(412) = –2.71, p < .01), confirming that the bud-get
contraction effect stems from the contracting budget In an attempt to test and understand the budget contrac-
condition. tion effect, we relied on consumers’ expected utility (e.g.,
. These data show that the budget contraction Loewenstein, O’Donoghue, and Rabin 2003) regarding the
Discussion decisions they make, rather than the actual experienced
effect depends on whether allocations to a given set of alter- util-ity that follows from consumption. Similarly, we
natives were made with a prior reference allocation level in explored the choices consumers actually make, rather than
mind, adding support to the notion that the budget contrac-tion the choices they should make. To better understand the
effect stems at least in part from feelings of loss of reducing down-stream consequences of the budget contraction effect
items. When a set of items was not previously selected, on consumer welfare, future studies might explore the
allocation variety was insensitive to budget trajec-tory. This actual experienced utility in contexts similar to those we
result indicates that feelings of loss are not associ-ated with present herein. Doing so could contribute to a better
making cuts to those items, and so there is no need to focus understanding of what decisions would help consumers
cuts narrowly. The data in this experiment also help us rule out maximize their experienced utility.
a possible drive to simplification (and, thus, less variety) in All the experiments used tightly controlled between-
response to worsening prospects, because alloca-tion variety subject designs, which measure changes in allocation
did not drop under worsening prospects when there was no variety across adjacent allocations. It remains to be seen if
the contraction effect is strong enough to compel a given
initial allocation from which to adjust.
consumer to opt for a less varied assortment at time t + 2
GENERAL DISCUSSION with a budget B than at time t with the same budget (having
Theoretical and Managerial Implications had a larger budget at time t + 1) . For example, if a
The experiments demonstrate an asymmetry in budget consumer allocates $40 across a product set, then allocates
expansion and contraction paths, with consumers arriving at a $80 across the same set, and then allocates $ 40 again
across the same set, will the original $40 allocation have
particular budget from a higher initial budget selecting fewer
greater variety than the final $40 allocation?
different types of items than those arriving at the same budget In addition to its theoretical importance, understanding
from a lower initial budget. We found this bud-get contraction
the budget contraction effect might help companies market
effect in grocery item purchases, investment allocations, and
their products. For example, during times of economic
travel budgeting decisions. The results from our experiments
downturn, companies such as Amazon.com may prefer to
suggest that the effect originates from a decrease in allocation
emphasize albums by artists whose other songs consumers
variety when budgets contract rather than from an increase in
allocation variety when budgets expand. The results also already own or focus on specific genres that a particular
reveal that the budget contraction effect stems from a desire to consumer has most likely purchased music from in the past.
avoid the anticipated psycho-logical losses associated with Doing so should be beneficial because such recommenda-
spreading budget cuts broadly tions help consumers in an economic downturn keep their
The Budget Contraction Effect 347

allocations narrow. During times of economic prosperity, Banks, James, Richard Blundell, and Sarah Tanner (1998), “Is
however, it might be beneficial to expand recommendations There
a Retirement- Savings Puzzle?” American Economic
to provide easier access to items that would maximize allo- Review, 88 (4), 769–88.
cation variety. Barsalou, Lawrence W. (1983), “Ad Hoc Categories,” Memory &
An understanding of how the phenomenon can affect Cognition, 11 (3), 211–27.
decision making can also help consumers predict their own Bernheim, B. Douglas, Jonathan Skinner, and Steven Weinberg
(2001), “What Accounts for the Variation in Retirement Wealth
future behavior and perhaps prevent times when, for exam-
Among U.S. Households?” American Economic Review, 91 (4),
ple, choosing a lesser allocation variety during budget con- 832–57.
tractions could have damaging consequences. Diversifying Blanchard, Simon J. and Wayne S. DeSarbo (2013), “A New
an investment portfolio is considered a fundamental rule of Zero-Inflated Negative Binomial Methodology for Latent
prudent investing. During downturns in the economy, how- Category Identification,” Psychometrika, 78 (2), 322–40.
ever, investors may allocate their money to a smaller num- Bowman, David, Debby Minehart, and Matthew Rabin (1993),
ber of investments, ironically creating a less diversified “Loss Aversion in a Savings Model,” Working Paper No. 93-
and, therefore, more risky portfolio. However, such 212, Department of Economics, University of California at
Berkeley.
potentially problematic situations may be overcome by an Coombs, Clyde H., Robyn M. Dawes, and Amos Tversky (1970),
understand-ing of how budget contractions affect decisions. Mathematical Psychology. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall.
There are undoubtedly many more contexts in which the Dargay, Joyce M. (2001), “The Effect of Income on Car Owner-
budget con-traction effect plays a role in decision making, ship: Evidence of Asymmetry,” Transportation Research Part
and we hope that clarifying this effect can help explain how A: Policy and Practice, 35 (9), 807–821.
people can best deal with harsh economic circumstances. Faison, Edmund W.J. (1977), “The Neglected Variety Drive,”
Conclusion Journal of Consumer Research, 4 (3), 172–75.
Geier, Andrew B., Paul Rozin, and Gheorghe Doros (2006), “Unit
The budget contraction effect introduced in this article is Bias a New Heuristic That Helps Explain the Effect of Portion
relevant for understanding the expenditure decisions of con- Size on Food Intake,” Psychological Science, 17 (6), 521–25.
sumers whose budgets undergo a contraction, whether due to Hall, Robert E. (1979), “Stochastic Implications of the Life Cycle-
an income shock, a substantial price increase, or a drop in the Permanent Income Hypothesis: Theory and Evidence,” NBER
discretionary budget as a result of an increase in expen-ditures Working Paper No. R0015.
elsewhere. Because individual budget contractions are more ——— and Frederic S. Mishkin (1982), “The Sensitivity of Con-
common during economic downturns, the budget contraction sumption to Transitory Income: Estimates from Panel Data on
effect is particularly helpful for understanding how consumers Households,” NBER Working Paper No. 505.
adjust their spending during economic con-tractions. We offer Hardie, Bruce G.S., Eric J. Johnson, and Peter S. Fader (1993),
evidence that economic downturns cause consumers to be “Modeling Loss Aversion and Reference Dependence Effects
on Brand Choice,” Marketing Science, 12 (4), 378–94.
narrower in their choice sets and to allocate their budgets to
Jappelli, Tullio and Luigi Pistaferri (2010), “The Consumption
fewer categories, suggesting that economic downturns are a Response to Income Changes,” NBER Working Paper No.
particularly important time for brands to reinforce 15739.
relationships with consumers who must narrow their Johnson, Eric J. and Robert J. Meyer (1984), “Compensatory
consumption. Choice Models of Noncompensatory Processes: The Effect of
We argue that the budget contraction effect occurs Varying Context,” Journal of Consumer Research, 11 (1), 528–
because consumers make choices by considering not only 41.
the utility they expect to receive from the items they select Kahn, Barbara E. and Rebecca Ratner (2005), “Variety for the
but also the psychological costs they expect to incur from Sake of Variety? Diversification Motives in Consumer Choice,”
in Inside Consumption: Frontiers of Research on Consumer
consuming these items at levels below a prior reference Motives, Goals, and Desires, S. Ratneshwar and David Glen
level. The idea that consumers make choices by focusing Mick, eds. London: Routledge, 1–34.
on expected utility, rather than actual experienced utility, is Kahneman, Daniel and Richard Thaler (2006), “Utility Maximiza-
not a unique contribution of this work, as that idea can be tion and Experienced Utility,” Journal of Economic Perspec-
traced as far back as Bernoulli in 1738 and more recently to tives, 20 (1), 221–34.
Fech-ner in 1860, who established quantitative ——— and Amos Tversky (1979), “Prospect Theory: An Analysis of
psychophysics using a subjective utility scale (see Coombs, Decision Under Risk,” Econometrica, 47 (2), 263–91.
Dawes, and Tversky 1970) . Rather, our main contribution ——— and ——— (1984), “Choices, Values, and Frames,”
Ameri-can Psychologist, 39 (4), 341–50.
is showing that prior budget allocations create allocation
Kalyanaram, Gurumurthy and Russell S. Winer (1995),
quantities that act as important reference points for future “Empirical Generalizations from Reference Price Research,”
budget alloca-tion decisions. We also show that part of the Marketing Science, 14 (3), G161–69.
utility con-sumers anticipate, and therefore part of the Kamakura, Wagner A. and Rex Yuxing Du (2012), “How Eco-
utility that influ-ences their choices, comes from the losses nomic Contractions and Expansions Affect Expenditure Pat-
or gains they anticipate relative to the reference quantities terns,” Journal of Consumer Research, 39 (2), 229–47.
obtained from their previous budget allocations. Lattin, James M. and Randolph E. Bucklin (1989), “Reference
REFERENCES Effects of Price and Promotion on Brand Choice Behavior,”
Journal of Marketing Research, 26 (August), 299–310.
Ariely, Dan, Joel Huber, and Klaus Wertenbroch (2005), “When Loewenstein, George, Ted O’Donoghue, and Matthew Rabin

Do Losses Loom Larger Than Gains?” Journal of Marketing (2003), “Projection Bias in Predicting Future Utility,”

Research, 42 (May), 134–38. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118 (4), 1209–1248.


348 JOURNAL OF MARKETING RESEARCH, JUNE 2015

Lynch, John G., Jr., Richard G. Netemeyer, Stephen A. Spiller, and by


Alessandra Zammit (2010), “A Generalizable Scale of Propen-sity Ruhm, Christopher J. (1991), “Are Workers Permanently Scarred
to Plan: The Long and the Short of Planning for Time and for Job Displacements?” American Economic Review, 81 (1), 319–24.
Money,” Journal of Consumer Research, 37 (1), 108–128. Russo, J. Edward and Kurt A. Carlson (2002), “Individual Deci-
McAlister, Leigh (1982), “A Dynamic Attribute Satiation Model of sion Making,” in Handbook of Marketing, Barton A. Weitz and
Variety- Seeking Behavior,” Journal of Consumer Research , 9 Robin Wensley, eds. London: Sage Publications, 371–408.
(2), 141–50. Saini, Ritesh and Ashwani Monga (2008), “How I Decide Depends on
McGraw, A. Peter, Jeff T. Larsen, Daniel Kahneman, and David What I Spend: Use of Heuristics Is Greater for Time Than for
Schkade (2010), “Comparing Gains and Losses,” Psychological Money,” Journal of Consumer Research, 34 (6), 914–22.
Science, 21 (10), 1438–45. gate
Shea, John (1995a), “Myopia, Liquidity Constraints, and Aggre-
Mellers, Barbara A. and A. Peter McGraw (2001), “Anticipated Consumption: A Simple Test,” Journal of Money, Credit and
Emotions as Guides to Choice,” Current Directions in Psycho- Banking, 27 (3), 798–805.
logical Science, 10 (6), 210–14. ——— (1995b), “Union Contracts and the Life-Cycle/Permanent-
Mitchell, Deborah J., Barbara E. Kahn, and Susan C. Knasko Income Hypothesis,” American Economic Review, 85 (1), 186–
(1995), “There’s Something in the Air: Effects of Congruent or 200.
Incongruent Ambient Odor on Consumer Decision Making,” Simonson, Itamar (1990), “The Effect of Purchase Quantity and
Journal of Consumer Research, 22 (2), 229–38. Timing on Variety-Seeking Behavior,” Journal of Marketing
Mogilner, Cassie and Jennifer Aaker (2009), “The Time vs. Research, 27 (May), 150–62.
Money Effect: Shifting Product Attitudes and Decisions Slovic, Paul, Dale Griffin, and Amos Tversky (1990), “Compati-
Through Per-sonal Connection,” Journal of Consumer bility Effects in Judgment and Choice,” in Insights in Decision
Research, 36 (2), 277– 91. Making, Robin M. Hogarth, ed. Chicago: University of Chicago
Novemsky, Nathan and Daniel Kahneman (2005), “The Bound- Press, 5–27.
aries of Loss Aversion,” Journal of Marketing Research, 42 Souleles, Nicholas S. (2000), “College Tuition and Household
(May), 119–28. Savings and Consumption,” Journal of Public Economics, 77
Okada, Erica M. and Stephen J. Hoch (2004), “Spending Time (2), 185–207.
Versus Spending Money,” Journal of Consumer Research, 31 Stephens, Ann H. (1997), “Persistent Effects of Job Displacement:
(3), 313–23. The Importance of Multiple Job Losses,” Journal of Labor Eco-
Oliver, Richard L. (1980), “A Cognitive Model of the nomics, 15 (1), 165–88.
Antecedents and Consequences of Satisfaction Decisions,” Stephens, Melvin (2001), “The Long-Run Consumption Effects of
Journal of Mar-keting Research, 17 (November), 460–69. Earnings Shocks,” Review of Economics and Statistics, 83 (1),
Payne, John W., James R. Bettman, and Eric J. Johnson (1993), 28–36.
The Adaptive Decision Maker. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge Taylor, Paul, Rich Morin, Rakesh Kochhar, Kim Parker, D’Vera
University Press.
Ratneshwar, S. and Shelly Chaiken (1991), “Comprehension’s Cohn, Mark Hugo Lopez, et al. (2010), “A Balance Sheet at 30
Role in Persuasion: The Case of Its Moderating Effect on the Months: How the Great Recession Has Changed Life in Amer-
Persuasive Impact of Source Cues,” Journal of Consumer
Research, 18 (1), 52–62. ica,” Pew Research Center, A Social and Demographic Trends
———, Cornelia Pechmann, and Allan D. Shocker (1996), “Goal- Report (June 30).

Derived Categories and the Antecedents of Across-Category

Consideration,” Journal of Consumer Research, 23 (3), 240–50.


KURT A. CARLSON, JARED WOLFE, SIMON J. BLANCHARD, JOEL C. HUBER,
and DAN ARIELY

The Budget Contraction Effect: How Contracting Budgets


Lead to Less Varied Choice
STIMULI APPENDIX

Experiment 1: Budget Contraction Grocery Stimuli

Expanding (Contracting) Condition

Imagine that you won a $40 ($120) shopping spree at Costco. It couldn’t have come at a

better time because you have very little to eat in the house. Suppose you could spend the money

on the items below. How would you spend it? Use the lines to the left of each item to indicate

how many of each product you would buy. If you would not buy a product, leave the line empty.

__ Thomas’ English Muffins Mix & Match (2 pk. 12 oz.) — $3.58


__ Milton’s Multi-Grain Bread (2 loaves) — $4.88
__ M&M’s Milk Chocolate (48/1.69 oz. pk.) — $17.97
__ PowerBar Variety Pack (24 bars) — $21.88
__ Mott’s Variety Pack Apple Sauce (36 cups) — $8.30 __
Chef Boyardee Beef Ravioli (10/15 oz. cans) — $8.30
__ Red Baron Deep Dish Singles Pizza Variety Pack (12 pk.) —
$10.44 __ DiGiorno Pepperoni Pizza (3 pk.) — $12.88
__ Cheesecake Factory Original Cheesecake (4 lb. cake) — $9.45

— Page Break —

Now imagine that a month has passed and you won another Costco shopping spree from

work. All the food you bought last time is all gone. This time the spree is for $80 ($80). Again it

comes at a good time because you have almost no food in the house. How would you spend the
$80? Use the lines to the left of each item to indicate how many of each product you would buy.

If you would not buy a product, leave the box empty.

__ Thomas’ English Muffins Mix & Match (2 pk. 12 oz.) — $3.58


__ Milton’s Multi-Grain Bread (2 loaves) — $4.88
__ M&M’s Milk Chocolate (48/1.69 oz. pk.) — $17.97
__ PowerBar Variety Pack (24 bars) — $21.88
__ Mott’s Variety Pack Apple Sauce (36 cups) — $8.30 __
Chef Boyardee Beef Ravioli (10/15 oz. cans) — $8.30
__ Red Baron Deep Dish Singles Pizza Variety Pack (12 pk.) —
$10.44 __ DiGiorno Pepperoni Pizza (3 pk.) — $12.88
__ Cheesecake Factory Original Cheesecake (4 lb. cake) — $9.45

— Page Break —

Imagine that you won a $120 ($40) shopping spree at Costco. It couldn’t have come at a

better time because you have very little to eat in the house. Suppose you could spend the money

on the items below. How would you spend it? Use the lines to the left of each item to indicate

how many of each product you would buy. If you would not buy a product, leave the box empty.

__ Thomas’ English Muffins Mix & Match (2 pk. 12 oz.) — $3.58


__ Milton’s Multi-Grain Bread (2 loaves) — $4.88
__ M&M’s Milk Chocolate (48/1.69 oz. pk.) — $17.97
__ PowerBar Variety Pack (24 bars) — $21.88
__ Mott’s Variety Pack Apple Sauce (36 cups) — $8.30 __
Chef Boyardee Beef Ravioli (10/15 oz. cans) — $8.30
__ Red Baron Deep Dish Singles Pizza Variety Pack (12 pk.) —
$10.44 __ DiGiorno Pepperoni Pizza (3 pk.) — $12.88
__ Cheesecake Factory Original Cheesecake (4 lb. cake) — $9.45

Experiment 2: Budget Contraction Investment Stimuli


Expanding (Contracting) Condition
Suppose that the Federal Government has decided to change the rules on saving for

retirement. The new plan involves giving people money to invest as they wish for retirement.

Each month you will be given an amount of money by the government and you can invest it

across four different classes of investments (very safe, safe, somewhat risky, very risky). If you

wish, you can put it all in one investment or you can spread it around as you wish. In the first

month of the plan, the government is allocating you $500 ($1,500) to invest. How would you

allocate this money to the four investments below?

___ Very safe, guaranteed low returns


___ Safe, almost always with modest returns
___ Somewhat risky, normally with above average returns
___ Very risky, with the possibility for high returns

— Page Break —

The government has decided to up (drop) the allocation amount for this month. This

month they are giving people $1,000 ($1,000) to invest. How would you allocate this money

across the investments?

___ Very safe, guaranteed low returns


___ Safe, almost always with modest returns
___ Somewhat risky, normally with above average returns
___ Very risky, with the possibility for high returns

— Page Break —

The government has decided to up (drop) the allocation amount again this month. This

month they are giving people $1,500 ($500) to invest. How would you allocate this money

across the investments?

___ Very safe, guaranteed low returns


___ Safe, almost always with modest returns
___ Somewhat risky, normally with above average returns
___ Very risky, with the possibility for high returns

Experiment 3: Budget Contraction Investment Stimuli


Expanding (Contracting) Condition

Suppose that you have won a trip to Western Europe. The trip will pay for your travel for

up to three weeks. Given your commitments here, you only have time to travel for one week.

Indicate how you would allocate your 7 (21) days of travel across the cities below. Note that to

visit a city, you must allocate at least one day to that city.

[0] Amsterdam, [0] Lisbon, [0] London, [0] Madrid, [0] Marseilles, [0] Milan, [0]

Munich, [0] Naples, [0] Paris, [0] Prague, [0] Rome, [0] Vienna

— Page Break —

Now suppose that some of your commitments here have freed up, allowing you to

travel for two weeks (require that you limit your travel to just two weeks). Indicate how you

would allocate your 14 (14) days of travel across the cities below. Note that to visit a city, you

must allocate at least one day to that city.

[0] Amsterdam, [0] Lisbon, [0] London, [0] Madrid, [0] Marseilles, [0] Milan, [0]

Munich, [0] Naples, [0] Paris, [0] Prague, [0] Rome, [0] Vienna

— Page Break —

Now suppose that all of your commitments here have freed up, allowing you to travel for

the full three weeks (require that you limit your travel to just one week). Indicate how you would

allocate your 21 days of travel across the cities below. Note that to visit a city, you must allocate

at least one day to that city.

[0] Amsterdam, [0] Lisbon, [0] London, [0] Madrid, [0] Marseilles, [0] Milan, [0]

Munich, [0] Naples, [0] Paris, [0] Prague, [0] Rome, [0] Vienna
Experiment 4: Budget Contraction Grocery Stimuli, No Allocation on First Budget
Expanding (Contracting) Condition/with Allocation

Imagine that you won a $40 ($120) shopping spree at Costco. It couldn’t have come at a

better time because you have very little to eat in the house. Suppose you could spend the money

on the items below. How would you spend it? Use the lines to the left of each item to indicate

how many of each product you would buy. If you would not buy a product, leave the box empty.

__ Thomas’ English Muffins Mix & Match (2 pk. 12 oz.) — $3.58


__ Milton’s Multi-Grain Bread (2 loaves) — $4.88
__ M&M’s Milk Chocolate (48/1.69 oz. pk.) — $17.97
__ PowerBar Variety Pack (24 bars) — $21.88
__ Mott’s Variety Pack Apple Sauce (36 cups) — $8.30 __
Chef Boyardee Beef Ravioli (10/15 oz. cans) — $8.30
__ Red Baron Deep Dish Singles Pizza Variety Pack (12 pk.) —
$10.44 __ DiGiorno Pepperoni Pizza (3 pk.) — $12.88
__ Cheesecake Factory Original Cheesecake (4 lb. cake) — $9.45

— Page Break —

Now imagine that a month has passed and you won another Costco shopping spree from

work. All the food you bought last time is all gone. This time the spree is for $80 ($80). Again it

comes at a good time because you have almost no food in the house. How would you spend the

$80? Use the lines to the left of each item to indicate how many of each product you would buy.

If you would not buy a product, leave the box empty.

__ Thomas’ English Muffins Mix & Match (2 pk. 12 oz.) — $3.58


__ Milton’s Multi-Grain Bread (2 loaves) — $4.88
__ M&M’s Milk Chocolate (48/1.69 oz. pk.) — $17.97
__ PowerBar Variety Pack (24 bars) — $21.88
__ Mott’s Variety Pack Apple Sauce (36 cups) — $8.30 __

Chef Boyardee Beef Ravioli (10/15 oz. cans) — $8.30


__ Red Baron Deep Dish Singles Pizza Variety Pack (12 pk.) —
$10.44 __ DiGiorno Pepperoni Pizza (3 pk.) — $12.88
__ Cheesecake Factory Original Cheesecake (4 lb. cake) — $9.45

Expanding (Contracting) Condition/No Allocation

Imagine that you won a $40 ($120) shopping spree at Costco. It couldn’t have come at a

better time because you have very little to eat in the house. Suppose you could spend the money

on the items below. Take a moment to read the items and their prices. When you have done so,

please click the red arrow below.

__ Thomas’ English Muffins Mix & Match (2 pk. 12 oz.) — $3.58


__ Milton’s Multi-Grain Bread (2 loaves) — $4.88
__ M&M’s Milk Chocolate (48/1.69 oz. pk.) — $17.97
__ PowerBar Variety Pack (24 bars) — $21.88
__ Mott’s Variety Pack Apple Sauce (36 cups) — $8.30 __
Chef Boyardee Beef Ravioli (10/15 oz. cans) — $8.30
__ Red Baron Deep Dish Singles Pizza Variety Pack (12 pk.) —
$10.44 __ DiGiorno Pepperoni Pizza (3 pk.) — $12.88
__ Cheesecake Factory Original Cheesecake (4 lb. cake) — $9.45

— Page Break —

Now imagine that a month has passed and you won another Costco shopping spree from

work. All the food you bought last time is all gone. This time the spree is for $80 ($80). Again it

comes at a good time because you have almost no food in the house. How would you spend the

$80? Use the lines to the left of each item to indicate how many of each product you would buy.

If you would not buy a product, leave the box empty.

__ Thomas’ English Muffins Mix & Match (2 pk. 12 oz.) — $3.58


__ Milton’s Multi-Grain Bread (2 loaves) — $4.88
__ M&M’s Milk Chocolate (48/1.69 oz. pk.) — $17.97
__ PowerBar Variety Pack (24 bars) — $21.88
__ Mott’s Variety Pack Apple Sauce (36 cups) — $8.30 __
Chef Boyardee Beef Ravioli (10/15 oz. cans) — $8.30
__ Red Baron Deep Dish Singles Pizza Variety Pack (12 pk.) —
$10.44 __ DiGiorno Pepperoni Pizza (3 pk.) — $12.88
__ Cheesecake Factory Original Cheesecake (4 lb. cake) — $9.45
Copyright of Journal of Marketing Research (JMR) is the property of American Marketing
Association and its content may not be copied or emailed to multiple sites or posted to a
listserv without the copyright holder's express written permission. However, users may
print, download, or email articles for individual use.

You might also like