You are on page 1of 79

WP/19/74

The Return of the Policy That Shall Not Be Named:


Principles of Industrial Policy

by Reda Cherif and Fuad Hasanov

IMF Working Papers describe research in progress by the author(s) and are published
to elicit comments and to encourage debate. The views expressed in IMF Working Papers
are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily represent the views of the IMF, its
Executive Board, or IMF management.
© 2019 International Monetary Fund 2 WP/19/74

IMF Working Paper

Institute for Capacity Development

The Return of the Policy That Shall Not Be Named: Principles of Industrial Policy

Prepared by Reda Cherif and Fuad Hasanov1

Authorized for distribution by Ralph Chami

March 2019

IMF Working Papers describe research in progress by the author(s) and are published to
elicit comments and to encourage debate. The views expressed in IMF Working Papers are
those of the author(s) and do not necessarily represent the views of the IMF, its Executive Board,
or IMF management.

Abstract

Industrial policy is tainted with bad reputation among policymakers and academics and is
often viewed as the road to perdition for developing economies. Yet the success of the
Asian Miracles with industrial policy stands as an uncomfortable story that many ignore or
claim it cannot be replicated. Using a theory and empirical evidence, we argue that one can
learn more from miracles than failures. We suggest three key principles behind their
success: (i) the support of domestic producers in sophisticated industries, beyond the initial
comparative advantage; (ii) export orientation; and (iii) the pursuit of fierce competition
with strict accountability.

JEL Classification Numbers: O25, O47, O57

Keywords: Industrial policy; technology; innovation; growth; diversification

Authors’ E-Mail Addresses: acherif@imf.org; fhasanov@imf.org

1
We are grateful to Ralph Chami and Alfred Kammer for valuable suggestions and discussions. We would also like to thank
Bergljot Barkbu, Andrew Berg, Claudia Berg, Sascha Buetzer, Chris Colford, Dennis Essers, Jean-Marc Fournier, Chris
Papageorgiou, Jiro Podpiera, Cyril Rebillard, Sidra Rehman, Alasdair Scott, Nikola Spatafora, Andrew Warner, and IMF
seminar participants for helpful comments and discussions. We are grateful to Lopo De Castro Neto for assistance with some
data and figures and to Claudia Cohen and Ravaka Prevost for help with formatting the paper. All errors are our own.
Contents Page

I. Introduction ............................................................................................................................5

II. Rashomon’s Witnesses of The Asian Miracles .....................................................................7

III. Learning from Miracles vs. Failures ..................................................................................10


50 Years of Development: Catching Up, Forging Ahead, and Falling Behind ......10
Can We Learn from Miracles? ................................................................................13
When Leo Tolstoy Meets Wassily Leontief: A Stylized Model of Long-Run Growth
......................................................................................................................................17

IV. Technology and Innovation Policy as “True Industrial Policy” ........................................21


It is All About Productivity Gains: Innovation and Export Sophistication ............21
TIP: The Moonshot Approach to Development ......................................................22
The Three Gears of TIP ...........................................................................................24

V. The Economics of TIP ........................................................................................................26


The Standard Growth Recipe is Not Enough ..........................................................26
Building Sophisticated Products .............................................................................31
Beyond Comparative Advantage: Vegetables, Sewing Machines, or Microcircuits?
......................................................................................................................................36
Not Manufacturing vs. Services, Rather Sophisticated Manufacturing and Services
......................................................................................................................................40
Creating Domestic Innovators: From Convergence to Growth at the Frontier .......45

VI. TIP Through History..........................................................................................................51


TIP Has Always Failed in the Past…Because It Was Not Tried ............................51
ISI in India: The State as a Micromanager ..............................................................57
Export Orientation, not Tariffs, is the Secret Ingredient .........................................59
Can Laissez-Faire be Worse than Import Substitution?..........................................61
Earlier Miracles in Advanced Economies and the Forgotten Hand of the State .....62

VII. Concluding Remarks ........................................................................................................63

Figures
1. GDP Per Capita Relative to the U.S. (2011 PPP $), 1960 vs. 2014 ....................................11
2. GDP per capita relative to the U.S. (2011 PPP $), 1970 vs. 2014 .......................................12
3. Average Investment Rate vs. Average TFP Growth (1970–90) ..........................................15
4. The Power Law Distribution of Gross Relative Growth Rates, 1964–2014........................17
5. TFP Growth in Select Countries (1970–2014) ....................................................................25
6. Doing Business and Competitiveness Indicators in Oil Exporters ......................................29
7. Goods Export Sophistication ...............................................................................................29
8. Value-Added per Worker in U.S. Industries (2016) ............................................................34
9. R&D Intensity (Percent of GDP), OECD (2015) ................................................................34
10. R&D Intensity and Personnel, USA (2015) .......................................................................35
11. Patents Issued by Different Industries, USA (2012)..........................................................36
12. Manufacturing Economy-wide Productivity Growth in Select Countries .........................40
4

13. The Output Structure: Bahrain vs. Singapore ....................................................................42


14. The Export Structure: Bahrain vs. Singapore ....................................................................42
15. Export Sophistication in Malaysia, Korea, and Taiwan Province of China ......................46
16. Missing TIP: Patents Granted in the U.S. ..........................................................................46
17. R&D Spending in Malaysia and Korea, 1996 vs. 2012 .....................................................47
18. Patents Granted in the U.S.: When Korea Overtook Other Countries ...............................49
19. Patents Granted in the U.S.: Korea vs. Other Countries (1990–2014) ..............................49
20. Who Creates Technology? .................................................................................................50
21. The Rise and Fall of Import Substitution Led Growth ......................................................52
22. Kernel Distribution of Structural Break Years ..................................................................53
23. Short-term Relationship Between Manufacturing Exports and Output .............................54
24. Export Performance (Korea vs. the World) .......................................................................55
25. Manufacturing Export Market Share Change ....................................................................57

References ................................................................................................................................66

Appendix I ...............................................................................................................................75
Appendix II ..............................................................................................................................77
I. INTRODUCTION

How to achieve high and sustained growth is one of the most critical topics in
macroeconomics, but it has remained an elusive holy grail. Over the past half a century,
developing economies have treaded quite different paths, with a few like the “Asian
Miracles”—Hong Kong (China), Korea, Singapore, and Taiwan Province of China—catching
up, some forging ahead, and many falling behind, to use the description of Abramovitz
(1986). Lucas (1988), observing cross-country growth experiences and their implications on
social welfare, famously wrote that “once one starts to think about them, it is hard to think
about anything else.” The empirical evidence shows that the odds for poor or middle-income
countries to reach high-income status within a couple of generations are very low. Over 1960–
2014, less than 10 percent of economies (16 out of 182) have reached high-income status. In
contrast to the Asian miracles, the others that made it either discovered large quantities of oil
or benefitted from joining the European Union.

The contrasting views on the interpretation of the Asian miracles’ success are akin to
Kurosawa’s Rashomon plot. In this masterpiece of Japanese cinema, every witness of a
samurai’s murder (that is, a peasant, a bandit, the samurai’s wife, and lastly a soothsayer) has
its own version of the same event. Similarly, many economists and policymakers call for a
different mixture of the same standard growth policy recipe that includes financial deepening,
openness to trade, ease of doing business, good infrastructure and institutions, macro-stability,
good education, and capital accumulation. We argue for a distinct perspective on the success
of the Asian Miracles (and perhaps play the role of the soothsayer in Rashomon).

Based on theoretical, empirical, and historical evidence (in the tradition of Friedrich List,
Alice Amsden, Robert Wade, James Fallows, and Ha-Joon Chang), we argue that the
development paths of the Asian Miracles as well as Japan, Germany, and the U.S. before
them, provide us with important clues to their success. We contend that standard growth
policy prescriptions are not sufficient. We find strong commonalities in policies pursued by
the Asian Miracles, and one cannot ignore the preeminent role of industrial policy in their
development. 2 Not only did they succeed at catching up with the advanced world, the Asian
miracles’ economic model resulted in much lower market income inequality than that in most
advanced countries. 3

Distilling useful lessons from country experiences is a daunting task, not least because of the
difficulty of disentangling the role of policies from luck in the absence of natural experiments.
We contribute to this debate by arguing that many things could go wrong in the countries that
diverged and there is a lot of valuable information in the countries that truly succeeded. First,
we use a stylized model to show that it is not easy to distinguish between luck and policies in
the countries that have diverged, adding more noise than signal to the uncovering of the

2
In the paper, we do not examine China’s policies (although there are many similarities to policies pursued by
the Asian miracles) since China has not yet achieved the high-income status.
3
See Luxembourg Income Study database.
6

growth determinants. Second, we show that long-term growth follows a power law
distribution suggesting that crucial information such as the experience of the Asian Miracles
lies in the tail rather than the average. This approach contrasts with the standard approach in
economics emphasizing averages such as growth regressions. In other words, according to the
Nobel laureate in physics Phil Anderson, “Much of the real world is controlled as much by the
tails of distributions as [by] means or averages…by the exceptional not the common place; by
the catastrophe, not the steady drip…we need to free ourselves from ‘average’ thinking”
(Ramalingam 2013).

We argue that the success of the Asian Miracles is based on three key principles that
constitute “True Industrial Policy,” which we describe as Technology and Innovation Policy
(TIP). Although our paper is yet another attempt among many to discover the key ingredients
for success in development, we are the first, to our knowledge, to articulate them into the
following three key principles, which were applied at the onset by the Asian miracles: (i) state
intervention to fix market failures that preclude the emergence of domestic producers in
sophisticated industries early on, beyond the initial comparative advantage; (ii) export
orientation, in contrast to the typical failed “industrial policy” of the 1960s–1970s, which was
mostly import substitution industrialization (ISI); and (iii) the pursuit of fierce competition
both abroad and domestically with strict accountability.

In addition, the extent of the technological leap to sophisticated industries early on and the
extent of the technology creation by domestic firms would determine how successful the long-
term growth outcome could be. Success depends on policies emphasizing innovation and
technology at every stage of the development process. Those countries that manage this
process would have a high chance of making it to the club of high-income countries in a
relatively brief period. We contend that the Asian miracles implemented these principles,
offering clues as to what other countries could do to follow in their footsteps. Indeed, “If we
know what an economic miracle is, we ought to be able to make one” (Lucas 1993).

Economic diversification, which is on agenda of many developing countries, especially


commodity exporters, is another outcome of TIP. It is consistent with the thesis of Breaking
the Oil Spell, in which Cherif, Hasanov, and Zhu (2016) argue that to promote sustained
growth, diversifying the tradable sector and increasing its sophistication are crucial for
commodity exporters.

Both the state and the market have their roles to play in implementing TIP. The “Leading
Hand of the State” has a role in steering labor and capital into activities the market would not
necessarily undertake (Cherif, Hasanov, and Kammer 2016), but market-signal-based
decision-making and an autonomous private sector are also crucial. Bill Gates, describing his
and Mark Zuckerberg’s efforts to finance green investments, said “the public led; we
7

followed” (Rumbelow 2017). 4 It is not the state against the market; rather “when the public
takes the lead and is ambitious, not just facilitating or being meek, it can push the frontier”
(Mariana Mazzucato in Rumbelow 2017).

We characterize a three-gear approach to implementing TIP. The state has to set the level of
ambition of its goal, and then implement the right policies while imposing accountability and
being able to adapt fast as conditions change—Ambition, Accountability, and Adaptability
(AAA), or a triple A, of the “leading hand of the state.” Mediocre growth is not necessarily a
fatality; rather it depends on the right policies and the level of the gear selected. The Asian
miracles—the highest gear—are the outcome of TIP in its moonshot approach version. The
middle gear is a leapfrog approach and it may provide decent growth leading to the middle-
income status, while the lowest gear is a snail crawl approach that results in relatively lower
growth.

The three gears correspond to different sets of policies. We argue that a standard growth
recipe such as improving business environment, institutions, and infrastructure, preserving
macro-stability, investing in education, and minimizing government interventions is not
sufficient to sustain high long-term growth and to a large extent, constitutes the lowest gear of
TIP, or the snail crawl approach. These policies mostly fix “government failures” but not
necessarily “market failures,” especially in the development of sophisticated sectors. The
standard policies to attract FDI in addition to state intervention to develop industries around
comparative advantage sectors may result in leapfrogging and steady growth. By and large,
however, these policies might not generate miracles. By intervening to fix market failures to
develop sophisticated sectors and domestic or homegrown technology, the state could create
conditions for high and sustained long-term growth. These ambitious policies pursued by the
Asian miracles represent the moonshot approach.

The rest of the paper is divided into the following main parts: (i) a brief overview of the
different sides of the debate on the nature of the Asian miracles’ success; (ii) empirical
evidence and theory showing why there is more information in the Asian miracles than in the
“failures”; (iii) an outline of the principles of TIP; (iv) a justification of the principles of TIP
from an economic perspective; (v) TIP in an historical perspective; and (vi) conclusion. A
reader mainly interested in the principles of TIP can skip the second and third sections without
loss of continuity.

II. RASHOMON’S WITNESSES OF THE ASIAN MIRACLES

The discussion of the Asian Miracles brings us to the taboo topic of the usefulness of
industrial policy for development and growth. In one of the earliest work on the topic, the
World Bank (1993), espousing the views of many economists, argues that the standard growth

4
See, for example, Kavlak, McNerney and Trancik (2018) who show the importance of government funded
R&D and policies that stimulate market growth in the dramatic cost reduction of photovoltaic modules.
8

recipe such as enhancing macroeconomic stability, improving legal and regulatory structure
and business climate, securing an effective financial system, liberalizing trade, and
accumulating physical and human capital, was key to sustained growth of the East Asian
countries. 5 Although the World Bank (1993) acknowledges that state intervention to spur
specific industries was successful in some cases, it suggests that in general industrial policy
did not work and advises governments against using it. Many countries that tried have failed
and a few that succeeded have pursued good fundamental policies and have been good at
evaluating and monitoring the support provided. Nonetheless, the World Bank (1993) states
that export-push strategies using standard growth policies hold the most promise. In other
words, this view corresponds to the low gear of TIP or snail-crawl approach in our
classification.

The example of Hong Kong illustrates well the contrasting views on what made the Asian
miracles. Many argue that its success was due to free-market policies (e.g., Monnery 2017)
rather than industrial policy. Chen (1987) and Weiss (2005) point to the prominent
contribution of manufacturing exports to growth in the earlier period without state
intervention in contrast to activist policies of Korea and Taiwan Province of China. However,
the Trade and Industry Department of Hong Kong indicates that it provided various forms of
support to industry, which can be classified as “soft” industrial policy. Hong Kong
Productivity Council created in 1967 played an instrumental role in promoting technology and
innovation, TIP in our definition (Boulton 1997).

The empirical growth literature suggests that many of the standard growth factors, by and
large, are causal while at the same time considering the Asian miracles as mere statistical
accidents. A few others, based on growth accounting exercises (e.g., Young 1995) believe the
high growth of the Asian miracles is attributed to high investment rates in physical and human
capital, increased labor force participation and higher working hours, or “perspiration” rather
than high productivity gains or “inspiration.” Others see in the Asian miracles the product of
cultural traits and geography, which can neither be changed nor exported.

Yet many scholars have argued that a certain form of industrial policy in East Asia was
instrumental in its rapid growth and catch up. Amsden (1989), Wade (1990), Woo (1992) and
Chang (2002) have attributed this catch up to “the developmental state”. Ricardo Hausmann,
Jose-Antonio Ocampo, Dani Rodrik, and Joseph Stiglitz, among others, have also shown that
policies play an important role in the structural transformation of developing economies. 6 The
state’s priorities included high investment rates, promotion of some sectors either through
creating state-owned enterprises (SOEs) or directing private firms to enter the sectors they
would not otherwise enter, and strong export orientation (Wade 2018). Interestingly, some

5
In addition, Bloom and Williamson (1997) argue that the demographic dividend contributed to the success of
the Asian miracles.
6
See for example Rodrik (2005), Ocampo, Taylor, and Rada (2009), Stiglitz and Greenwald (2014), and
Hausmann, Espinoza, and Santos (2015).
9

elements such as export orientation and high investment rates are common across the
contrasting views on industrial policy in the earlier work.

The debate on industrial policy has been relatively confrontational in the recent past. Perhaps
the consensus view among many economists is that industrial policy usually fails, so any
resurrection of these ideas is taken with great skepticism. Wade (2018) mentions an
interesting anecdote about the World Bank’s view on industrial policy. In his account, only
when Justin Lin arrived at the World Bank as Chief Economist in 2008, was there an attempt
to bring back the banished phrase “industrial policy.” In his speech in Pretoria, Vice President
of the World Bank, Janamitra Devan citing The Economist’s “Industrial policy is back in
fashion,” argues that “promoting industrial competitiveness is not back in fashion—because it
never went out of fashion” (2011). 7 Yet the term went underground after Lin left and the
pilots “Competitive Industries Program” that were created were wound down. There are
relatively few empirical studies on the causal effects of industrial policy, and some recent
papers find a positive effect (e.g. Criscuolo et. al. 2019, Juhasz 2018, Kalouptsidi 2018, and
Lane 2017).

Chang (2009, 2013) proposes to go beyond the confrontation and see what we can learn from
this debate. He stresses the importance of export orientation as a common ground. He further
argues that even such crucial problems as the lack of capabilities and political economy issues
that tend to translate into advice for inaction, should not let “the best become the enemy of the
good.” In the same vein of surmounting the ideological confrontation, Benhassine and
Raballand (2009) suggest that industrial policy may be most needed in low-income countries
with undiversified industrial base. They argue that even if conditions for interventions are
very weak, examples show that interventions can still succeed. Harrison and Rodriguez-Clare
(2010) discuss theoretical and empirical work on industrial policy and suggest that there is an
important role for a “soft” industrial policy, in which government and the private sector
collaborate on interventions to increase productivity. 8 IDB (2014) argues along the same lines
based on the Latin American experience. Justin Lin (2012) suggests that the state could
provide a facilitating role in identifying and helping develop industries around comparative
advantage along with markets and firms leading the technological innovation.

Stiglitz and Greenwald (2014) argue that what separates advanced countries from developing
countries is the gap in knowledge. They start with Arrow’s (1962) seminal paper “Learning by
Doing” and contend that markets will underprovide the production and diffusion of
knowledge. Closing the knowledge gap would require a well-crafted industrial policy to
encourage learning and create a learning society. Mazzucato (2013) shows how important the
state’s role is in promoting innovation and growth in advanced countries.

7
We thank Chris Colford for bringing this speech to our attention.
8
The OECD’s Warwick (2013) also suggests “soft” industrial policy rather than heavy product market
interventions. Chang and Andreoni (2016) discuss industrial policy in a changing world. Mazzucato (2013),
World Bank’s Hallegatte, Fay, and Vogt-Schilb (2013) and Harrison, Martin, and Nataraj (2017) propose green
industrial policy.
10

While academics have been debating about the practicalities and merits of industrial policy,
most countries, whether intentionally or not, have been engaged in some form of industrial
policy. Ha-Joon Chang has been arguing this point that by choosing to build a certain type of
infrastructure (e.g., a railroad vs. a road or broadband internet) or encouraging a certain type
of education (e.g., engineering schools vs. business schools), policies favor a certain type of
industries. Moreover, many countries have been trying to promote explicitly tourism, finance,
and logistics, and even if policies to promote these industries are not called industrial policies,
effectively these policies have been industrial in nature. In many cases international financial
institutions seem to have been less worried by this type of industrial policy. The key question
is if many countries have been conducting industrial policy anyway, what should the right
way to do this be.

III. LEARNING FROM MIRACLES VS. FAILURES

50 Years of Development: Catching Up, Forging Ahead, and Falling Behind

A half-century of cross-country development experience indicates that the odds of reaching


high-income status are low. Since high-income countries have also grown for the past
50 years, an important metric for assessing income convergence is relative growth. The
standard methods to define low, middle, or high-income status using absolute levels of income
need to be updated regularly to incorporate growth of other countries. Since the goal of
economic development is to reach the living standards of the most advanced countries, the
thresholds based on relative income capture how far an economy is from reaching that goal.

We use the distribution of GDP per capita in 2011 purchasing power parity (PPP) dollars
relative to the U.S. in 2005 to compute the thresholds. 9 We calculate this distribution’s median
and the seventy-fifth percentile, which help determine the thresholds for upper-middle-income
and high-income countries, respectively. 10 We set the upper-middle income threshold at
20 percent of the U.S. income per capita and the high-income threshold at 50 percent
(Figure 1). The thresholds are applied through time since they are expressed in relative
income terms. In 2014, the upper-middle income threshold was about $10,400, while the high-
income threshold was about $26,000. 11 These figures raise the bar for the countries to reach
high-income status.

9
We use data from Penn World Tables 9.0. The thresholds computed from the 2005 data are not substantially
different from those computed using the data in the 2000s. In addition, these thresholds are not different from
those in the earlier version of Penn World Tables 8.0. However, the thresholds based on the relative income
distribution in earlier decades are much lower in PWT 9.0 than in PWT 8.0.
10
The median is about 18 percent while the 75th percentile is about 47 percent in the relative income
distribution.
11
In 1960, these thresholds were about $3500 and $8800, while in 1970, they were about $4700 and $11,700,
respectively.
11

Figure 1. GDP Per Capita Relative to the U.S. (2011 PPP $), 1960 vs. 2014

1.5
NOR

GDP per capita relative to US in 2014


SGP LUX
CHE
1

IRL USA
NLD
HKG DEU
AUT DNK AUS
TPC SWECAN
GNQ BELFRA ISL
GBR
FIN
KOR JPN ITA
ESP NZL
ISR TTO
PRT
.5

MLT CYP GRCSYC


MYS
ROMPAN CHL
ARG TUR URY
MUS
BWA BRA IRN MEXVEN
GAB
THA
CHN ECU COLCRI ZAF
DOM DZA
EGYTUN JOR
NAM
PER
LKA
IDN BRB
SLV PRY
MARGTMFJI JAM
CPV
INDPHL
BOL NGA
PAK
COG GHA NIC
HND
ZMBSYR
MRT
NPL CIV
KEN
BGD
LSO
CMR
TZASEN
BEN
TCD
ZWE
UGA
RWA
BFA
ETH GMB
HTI
COM
MLI
TGO
GNB
MOZ
MDG
MWI
BDI
NERGIN
CAFCOD
0

0 .5 1 1.5
GDP per capita relative to US in 1960
Source: Penn World Tables 9.0 (Feenstra, Inklaar, and Timmer 2015).

Some interesting patterns emerge. Many industrialized nations remained rich, with a few
economies growing rapidly in the 1960s and passing the high-income threshold by 1970
(Israel, Italy, and Japan). Many oil-exporting countries witnessed a large fall in relative
income over 1970–2014 despite the rise in oil prices in the 2000s (Cherif and Hasanov 2016).
Low- and lower-middle income countries (with relative income of less than 20 percent of the
U.S. GDP per capita) mostly stayed in the same relative positions. Only did a few countries
rise to the upper-middle income status from the low-income status 12 (Botswana, Egypt, China,
Grenada, Mongolia, and Thailand). A few more countries rose to the upper-middle income
level from the lower-middle income level (e.g., Brazil, Malaysia, and Romania). Many others
lagged and fell in relative rankings (e.g., Jamaica and South Africa). 13

12
The threshold for the low-income status is set at 10 percent of U.S. GDP per capita.
13
For a survey, see Johnson and Papageorgiou (forthcoming).
12

Figure 2. GDP Per Capita Relative to the U.S. (2011 PPP $), 1970 vs. 2014

1
IRL USA

NLD
HKG AUTDEU
GDP per capita relative to US in 2014 DNKAUS
SWECAN
.8 TPC
GNQ BEL ISL BHR
OMN FINGBR
FRA
ABW
KOR JPN
ITA
NZL
ESP
ISR TTO
.6

PRT
SYC
CYP GRC VGB
MLT POL
HUN
MYS CHL BHS
.4

ROMKNA
ARG PAN TURURYAIA
MUS MSR
MDV BGR
BWA BRASURATG LBN IRNMEX VEN
THA GAB
CHN DOM IRQ COL CRIDZA ZAF
MNG JOR
ECU
ALB NAM
EGY PER
LKA
.2

IDNGRDTUN LCA BRB


DMA
VCTAGO
SLVSWZPRYBLZ
MAR
BTN
CPV GTMFJI
PHL JAM
LAO
MMR
VNM
INDBOL NGA
PAK
COG
PSEHND SYR NIC
LSOSDNZMB
KHM
KEN
BGD GHA
STP
MRT
CIV DJI
TCA CMR
NPL
UGA TZA
SEN
BEN
TCD
ZWE
GMB
MOZHTI
RWA
BFA
MLI
ETH GIN
TGO
SLE
GNB
MDG
MWI
LBR
BDINERCOM
COD
CAF
0

0 .2 .4 .6 .8 1
GDP per capita relative to US in 1970
Source: Penn World Tables 9.0.

In the past one-half of a century (1960-2014), only a handful of economies, 16 out of 182
economies in the sample in 2014—Aruba, Czech Republic, Equatorial Guinea, Estonia, Hong
Kong (China), Ireland, Israel, Italy, Japan, Korea, Oman, Portugal, Singapore, Slovenia,
Spain, and Taiwan Province of China—have crossed the threshold of 50 percent of the U.S.
GDP per capita. Examining a bit over 40 years of data (1970–2014), Israel, Italy, and Japan
drop out from this sample as they reached the high-income status by 1970. Over the past
44 years, 7 economies out of 13 reaching the high-income status were European countries,
which were already upper-middle income economies to begin with, and later became part of
the European Union, including a small Dutch Caribbean island of Aruba. It is not surprising
that these economies grew relatively fast. Other countries such as Equatorial Guinea, Oman,
and in fact Aruba, grew fast due to oil discoveries. However, history may repeat itself as other
oil exporters such as Kuwait and Saudi Arabia got rich with oil discoveries but then lost their
relative income ranking over time.

The four economies reaching the high-income status without the proximity to advanced
Europe or natural resource discoveries are the Asian Tigers—Hong Kong (China), Korea,
Singapore, and Taiwan Province of China. Korea, Singapore, and Taiwan Province of China
were below the upper-middle income threshold in 1960 (Figure 1). In 1970, only Korea was
below the 10 percent threshold for low-middle income countries, while Taiwan Province of
China was slightly below 20 percent threshold (Figure 2). Given the historic record of long-
term growth and income convergence, reaching high-income status in 40–50 years constitutes
an economic “miracle” as Lucas (1993) observed. For instance, what took Malaysia more than
13

50 years to reach about 40 percent of U.S. GDP per capita in 2014 (starting at around
15 percent of U.S. GDP per capita), took Korea only about 20 years. And for current and
forthcoming generations, fast convergence is what matters.

Can We Learn from Miracles?

Our summary of 50 years of development showed that only a few countries made it from
relative or absolute poverty to advanced economy status. While countries like Ireland and
Spain do provide valuable lessons, their relatively high starting levels of income, the
geographic proximity to the advanced economies of Europe and the substantial aid and
development programs of the EU cannot be ignored as contributing factors. Meanwhile, the
Asian miracles could be considered as the most relevant group and arguably the only true
“miracles”. One would naturally expect the Asian miracles to constitute a focal point for the
students of development. Instead, and until recently, the experiences of the Asian miracles
have been mostly considered as “accidents” that cannot and should not be emulated, at least
from the point of view of standard development economics. 14 A few exceptions are Murphy
et. al. (1989) and Lucas (1993) who gave elegant and insightful views of the mechanism
behind the Asian miracles but not necessarily the policies that led to them. As we will argue
below, the success of the Asian miracles cannot be disentangled from that of their industrial
policies.

As for why development economics in general ignored the Asian miracles, or rather the
industrial policies behind them, there are roughly two schools. In the first school, the tendency
is to interpret History so that it fits preconceptions about the role of policies and the type of
institutions or projectionism in the words of Johnson (1982). Some consider the Asian
miracles in their recent form, when it would be difficult to distinguish them from other
advanced economies in terms of institutions, human and physical capital as well as policies,
and in particular in terms of the extent of state intervention. Others document state
intervention and sectoral policies during the fast growth periods but conclude that they had a
minor effect and that the miracle would have happened without them (see World Bank 1993).
In other words, there is no particular value extracted from their experiences beyond the usual
prescription: financial deepening, openness to trade, infrastructure, institutions, macro-
stability, education, etc. 15 This approach of course ignores History in the sense that it ignores
the different metamorphoses performed by the Asian miracles and in particular the role of
their ever-changing policies to take them from one stage of development to the next.

The second broad school is based on empirical studies, which either “de-mystify” the Asian
miracles as the result of a rapid accumulation of labor and capital (see Krugman 1994) or
consider them as statistical accidents or outliers with no meaningful information within the

14
There are many studies emphasizing the role of unorthodox policies in the economic development of the Asian
miracles, but their conclusions are not viewed as part of the standard economics textbook or the consensus
among policy experts (e.g., Amsden 1989, Wade 1990, Woo 1991, Chang 2002, among others).
15
See World Bank (1993) and Jomo (1997).
14

context of growth regressions (see Easterly 1995). In a seminal paper, Young (1995)
performed a careful and painstaking growth accounting exercise based on the data of Korea,
Hong Kong, Singapore and Taiwan Province of China. His conclusion was that the
contribution of productivity gains, i.e. Total Factor Productivity (TFP), had been exaggerated
and once physical and human capital were correctly measured, TFP’s contribution to growth
decreased significantly. 16 For some, this was the proof that the Asian miracles were the result
of “perspiration”, sheer hard work and sacrifices in the form of high saving and investment
rates, rather than “inspiration”. What needs to be done to imitate the Asian successes is to
follow policies encouraging the accumulation of both physical and human capital ultimately
meaning going back to the standard prescription.

Several facts contradict the theory that the secret of the Asian miracles is simply
“perspiration”. The main implication of this growth accounting exercise based on the
neoclassical production function is that the end of the Asian miracles’ era of sustained high
growth should have been around the corner (see Krugman 1994). 17 Young (1995) showed that
TFP contribution was low for the period roughly between the 1950s and late 1980s. However,
Singapore continued growing fast afterward and became one of the richest countries in the
world by 2017. Meanwhile Korea and Taiwan Province of China have been following a
similar path, essentially unaffected by the laws of diminishing returns.

Many countries had high rates of investment over 1970–90, that were in many cases
comparable to those in the Asian miracles, while simultaneously displaying much lower
average TFP growth rates (see Figure 3). Korea for example had an impressive average
investment rate of about 30 percent between 1970 and 1990 but this was not exceptional. A
diverse group of countries had similar or greater investment rates such as China, Iran, Jordan,
Portugal, and Saudi Arabia over the same period and average TFP growth was negative in all
these countries. Many of these countries did not succeed in achieving sustained high growth
despite their high rates of accumulation of both physical and human capital (see Cherif,
Hasanov and Zhu 2016 for some examples). Something fundamental must distinguish the
experience of these countries over that period from the Asian miracles beyond the rate of
accumulation of capital. 18

Moreover, if one accepts that TFP contribution was low in the Asian miracles, one would
have to put it in a cross-country perspective. The same method used by Young (1995) of
“chipping away” the contribution of TFP by a more precise measurement of the quality of
capital, human capital, labor participation, hours, etc. would also apply to many other

16
Hsieh (2002) showed that the contribution of TFP growth could be significantly greater for Taiwan Province of
China and Singapore.
17
If one assumes a neoclassical production function, in the absence of sustained technological progress, the
accumulation of physical and human capital alone would lead to stagnation.
18
Interestingly, over the subsequent period 1990–2010, China’s investment rate increased substantially and its
TFP started growing much faster which corresponds to a move from a period of import substitution policies to
policies more closely resembling TIP (see Appendix Figure 3).
15

developing economies yielding even smaller, if not negative, TFP contributions to growth. 19
In this case, the sustained growth of TFP over long periods of time in the Asian miracles
would remain an oddity compared to most other countries. Senhadji (2000) shows that even
though a country’s TFP growth could be lower due to different assumptions and
mismeasurement, the differences in TFP growth are robust across countries suggesting that
many countries had lower TFP growth than that of the Asian miracles. More important,
patents granted in the U.S. show that firms in the Asian miracles were already very active in
terms of innovation at an early stage of development. In other words, something else than
“perspiration” must have happened in these countries that led them to high and sustained
growth.

Figure 3. Average Investment Rate vs. Average TFP Growth (1970–90)

MLT
.02

HKG
BGR KOR
DEU NOR
BELESP CYP
FRA ISL
NLD
LUX FIN
GBR
Annual TFP growth, 1970-1990
.01

KENDNKIRL
ECU USA TUN
HND AUT
COL ITA
TUR IND EGY THA MYS SGP
SDN IDN CMR NZL
ISR AUSCHE
SEN CAN TZAROM
LKA
0

POLBRA CHN
SWEPRT
PAN
BFA JPN
ZAF SAU
MAR GRC
GTM
MOZ
BOL DOM
-.01

BRBCHL
URY
MEX
CIV CRI
JAMPHL

NER
-.02

NGA ARG
TTO
VEN JOR
PER
-.03

0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50
Average investment rate, 1970-1990
Source: Penn World Tables 9.0 and World Development Indicators (WDI).

The Asian miracles were also ignored on methodological grounds in growth regressions.
There is a large and rich literature based on cross-country growth regressions, but the common
approach is to regress average growth rates (over 5 years, a decade or longer horizons) on a
set of independent variables (e.g., measures of the quality of institutions, initial income per
capita, and other economic variables). In this literature, the Asian miracles are in general
considered outliers or statistical accidents with no relevant information to be gained from (see
Easterly 1995). It is even recommended to exclude obvious outliers from the sample as they
would bias the results. The implicit assumption in standard growth regressions is that the

19
See Cherif and Hasanov (2016) showing that many oil exporting countries had negative TFP growth rates over
past several decades.
16

variable of interest should be well behaved. In particular, the error term of the linear model
should follow a distribution with finite mean and variance. Although this could seem as a
plausible assumption, we argue that in the case of growth regressions, at least over longer
horizons, this critical assumption could be challenged. There is a myriad of criticisms against
growth regressions including the endogeneity issue (see Bazzi and Clemens 2013), the
difficulty of extracting policy recommendations from growth regressions (see Rodrik 2012),
or the unreasonable assumption that all countries follow the same linear model (see Hausmann
et al. 2005).

To our knowledge, the argument we develop below, namely that growth over the long term
follows a Power Law constitutes a novel contribution to the literature. Our goal is not to
discredit growth regressions; rather it is to argue that the Asian miracles should not be
sidelined as mere anomalies with no informational content.

To illustrate our argument, we study the distribution of cross-country relative gross growth
rates, which is the ratio of GDP per capita relative to the U.S. in 2014 to that in 1964. This
measure is in fact the same as the one we used in Figure 1 to summarize 50 years of
development. Our conjecture is that the relative gross growth rates follow a power law. Power
law distributions exhibit fat tails such that extreme events (multiples of standard deviations)
are much more likely than with normal distributions. 20 Empirical studies have been
uncovering such power laws in a wide spectrum of fields. The distribution of wealth, the sizes
of cities in a country, and stock market returns are a few examples (see Gabaix 2009). The
peculiarity of these distributions is that they could exhibit infinite means or variances
depending on the exponent of the distribution. In the case of power laws, observations which
are considered outliers under other distributions become an important source of information, if
not most of the information.

We follow Clauset et. al. (2009) to test whether gross relative growth rates follow a power
law. Figure 4 below illustrates the result. It shows the cumulative distribution function (CDF)
of the variable of interest x expressed on a logarithmic scale. The test detects the minimum
threshold for x as being around one, implying that only countries that have grown at least as
fast as the U.S. over the period should be considered. The straight line represents the CDF of a
power law with exponent equal to about 2.5 (estimated from the data). The distribution of the
gross relative growth rates follows closely that of a power law with exponent 2.5 for
observations greater or equal to one (Figure 4). The formal test confirms this observation as
the null hypothesis cannot be rejected. We also use Kolmogorov-Smirnoff test to check if
other distributions such as log-normal and exponential are good approximations to the data.
The tests suggest that these distributions are not a good approximation to our data. We also
use log-likelihood ratio tests, where the null hypothesis is that x follows a power law against
these distributions. These tests indicate that one cannot reject that the distribution of gross
relative growth rates follows a power law (although in the case of log-normal and Weibull

20
See Gabaix (2009) for a detailed survey about power laws.
17

distributions, the tests do not reject these distributions, either). Overall, power law seems to be
a good approximation to long-run gross relative growth rates.

If cross-country gross relative growth rates follow a power law with exponent 2.5, then it
would mean that the Asian miracles should not be dismissed and instead they would constitute
an important source of information. It Figure 4. The Power Law Distribution of Gross
would also mean that the mean of Relative Growth Rates, 1964–2014
gross relative growth is finite while 10
0

its variance is infinite (see Gabaix


2009). In turn, this would imply that
statistical inference may not be -1
10
applied to long-term cross-country

Pr(X ≥ x)
growth regressions.
-2
Estimating the exponent for shorter 10
panels such as for 40, 30, 20, 10
years, ending in 2014, we note that
-3
the estimate increases in value. For 10 -1 0 1 2
the 20- and 10-year panels, it is above 10 10 10 10
x
three, suggesting that variance is Source: Penn World Tables 9.0.
finite, and that inference may be valid
in short panels. However, since in short panels we estimate the effects of variables on growth
in the short to medium term, we could potentially miss what is key to long run sustained
growth.

When Leo Tolstoy Meets Wassily Leontief: A Stylized Model of Long-Run Growth

Can We Learn from Failures: Luck or Policies?

For growth to happen, it is plausible to assume that a relatively large number of conditions
must be satisfied simultaneously. For simplicity let us assume that the growth outcome takes
the form of:

𝑔𝑔 = 𝐺𝐺(𝑃𝑃, 𝑋𝑋) (1)

Where P represents an index of policy decisions and X is an index summarizing exogenous


factors lying outside the control of the government. Growth is the result of an interaction
between policy and exogenous factors, i.e. policy decisions could magnify or mitigate luck
(good or bad). In turn, let’s assume that X is defined as follows:
18

𝑋𝑋 = min(𝑥𝑥1 , 𝑥𝑥2 , … , 𝑥𝑥𝑛𝑛 ) (2)

where 𝑥𝑥1 , 𝑥𝑥2 , … , 𝑥𝑥𝑛𝑛 are the exogenous factors. In other words, the binding constraint on
growth could come from any of the exogenous factors (e.g., natural disaster, civil war,
commodity prices, etc.). For simplicity, we assume that these factors lie in [0,1], which means
that at best a country would get the full benefit of its policies over a certain period, but its luck
cannot make it grow beyond what its policies would yield over an extended period of time.
We also assume that the exogenous factors are random variables. To simplify, let’s assume
that they are all randomly drawn from the same probability distribution, the CDF of which is
F. It is straightforward to show that for any value y:

𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃(𝑋𝑋 > 𝑦𝑦) = (1 − 𝐹𝐹(𝑦𝑦))𝑛𝑛 (3)

If the number of exogenous factors is large, the probability of being greater than y becomes
small. Back to equation (1), we assume a simple multiplicative form for the interaction
between policy and exogenous factors. We can rewrite equation (1) as

𝑔𝑔 = 𝐺𝐺(𝑃𝑃) ∗ 𝑋𝑋 (4)

We order P on a continuum [0, +∞) corresponding to the ordering of the quality of the policy
decisions, from worst to best respectively. G is assumed to be an increasing function of P.
Conditional on a policy decision P, the probability that growth, g, is greater than a certain
value z is:

𝑧𝑧
𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃(𝑔𝑔 > 𝑧𝑧|𝑃𝑃) = (1 − 𝐹𝐹 �𝐺𝐺(𝑃𝑃)�)𝑛𝑛 (5)

If G is an increasing function, then the probability that g is greater than a certain threshold z
increases when P increases such as better policies increase the chances of greater growth. To
study the effects of policies on growth, we examine how 𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃(𝑔𝑔 > 𝑧𝑧|𝑃𝑃) is affected when P
changes that is:

𝜕𝜕𝜕𝜕𝜕𝜕(𝑔𝑔>𝑧𝑧|𝑃𝑃) 𝐺𝐺′(𝑃𝑃)𝑧𝑧𝑧𝑧(𝑧𝑧/𝐺𝐺(𝑃𝑃)) 𝑧𝑧
= 𝑛𝑛 𝐺𝐺(𝑃𝑃)2
(1 − 𝐹𝐹 �𝐺𝐺(𝑃𝑃)�)𝑛𝑛−1 (6)
𝜕𝜕𝜕𝜕

In turn, deriving with respect to z yields:

𝜕𝜕2 𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃(𝑔𝑔>𝑧𝑧|𝑃𝑃) 𝑧𝑧 𝑧𝑧 𝑧𝑧 𝑧𝑧 𝑧𝑧 𝑧𝑧 𝑧𝑧
∝ 𝑓𝑓 �𝐺𝐺(𝑃𝑃)� + 𝐺𝐺(𝑃𝑃) 𝑓𝑓′ �𝐺𝐺(𝑃𝑃)� − (𝑛𝑛 − 1) 𝐺𝐺(𝑃𝑃) 𝑓𝑓 �𝐺𝐺(𝑃𝑃)� 𝑓𝑓′ �𝐺𝐺(𝑃𝑃)� (1 − 𝐹𝐹 �𝐺𝐺(𝑃𝑃)�)−1 (7)
𝜕𝜕𝜕𝜕𝜕𝜕𝜕𝜕

Given that each factor x is in [0,1], we assume that they follow a uniform distribution. The
equation above becomes (for z/G(P) in [0,1] and given a positive factor of proportionality):

𝜕𝜕2 𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃(𝑔𝑔>𝑧𝑧|𝑃𝑃)
∝1 (8)
𝜕𝜕𝜕𝜕𝜕𝜕𝜕𝜕
19

This means that the marginal effect of policies is smaller when the threshold on growth is
smaller. When the sample includes a lot of low-income countries, the marginal effect of
policies is less distinguishable from the effect of luck.

According to this model, and for a fairly large n, conditional on a set of policies, fast and
sustained growth is difficult to obtain even with the correct policies. More important, it also
implies that an empirical investigator, curious about the effect of policies, should be mindful
of the tradeoff between a larger sample containing more information and the noise introduced
by low growth countries. The reason is that if the threshold z in our notation is too low then it
becomes very difficult to discriminate between bad policies and bad luck, which could spring
from any of the exogenous factors.

Based on this model, one can build a narrative of the stylized facts shown in Figure 1. The
group of countries which fell back (or grew less than the U.S.), can be characterized by bad
luck and/or bad policies. Even if countries have tried to implement the right policies, bad luck
could result in poor growth outcomes. The group of countries which maintained their relative
income per capita (along the 45-degree line) probably did not encounter bad luck but most
likely followed the snail-crawl approach to policy. The countries that grew a bit faster than the
U.S. followed a leapfrog approach. Some countries that grew faster than the U.S., followed
leapfrog policies and benefitted from good luck in the form of natural resources or proximity
and support of the EU. Lastly, the Asian miracles, which did not encounter bad luck, had
adopted the moonshot approach.

Paraphrasing Tolstoy, we argue that all rich countries are the same and every poor country is
poor in its own way. For a large enough n, every low performing country could be considered
unique in the sense that the sources of its bad luck are unique to it. The probability that the
realization of exogenous variables x is the same for all these countries, is very low. In other
words, the experiences of bad performers may not hold useful information. Meanwhile, good
performers could be said to be the same in the sense that they were not hit hard with bad luck
and they adopted the best policies. As our stylized model suggests, and as argued in the
following section, there are common patterns in policies among successful economies. 21 These
common patterns further reinforce the case that their successes are the result of policies rather
than good luck (the probability of which is very small with large n), and therefore they can be
replicated. 22

21
One could argue that other non-policy factors could set aside the Asian miracles and that by focusing on the
successes, one may risk concluding that policies pursued were key to success. We argue that the Asian miracles
were spared bad luck and thus managed to achieve success, and what was important for success was not
necessarily the specific tools used or particular factors (e.g. geography, size, culture, political structure); rather,
the principles of TIP were implemented in the relentless pursuit of achieving high income.
22
See for example Henry and Miller (2009) for the importance of policies vs. geography, culture, and other
similar characteristics. Acemoglu and Robinson (2012) argue that “inclusive” political and economic institutions
are important for development. Although we agree that certain institutions are necessary, we argue that they are
not sufficient and policies to solve market failures are crucial, as the cases of the Asian miracles and rich Gulf oil
exporters illustrate.
20

The Power of Compounding

We show that if the effect of policies is compounded over time, it can lead to a power law
distribution of growth in the cross-section, the coefficient of which decreases with time. First,
we assume that G(P) is the compounding of the effects of P over T periods such that:

𝐺𝐺(𝑃𝑃) = 𝑃𝑃𝑇𝑇 (9)

We further assume that P follows a broken Power Law with coefficient 𝛼𝛼′ over [0,1] and 𝛼𝛼′′
for P>1. The p.d.f. of G(P) denoted 𝑓𝑓𝐺𝐺(𝑃𝑃) (y) is therefore:

𝑓𝑓 (𝑦𝑦 1/𝑇𝑇 )
𝑓𝑓𝐺𝐺(𝑃𝑃) (y) = 𝑇𝑇(𝑦𝑦𝑃𝑃1/𝑇𝑇 )𝑇𝑇−1 (10)

which by definition is proportional to:

𝛼𝛼′′ +𝑇𝑇−1
𝑦𝑦 − 𝑇𝑇 for y in [0,1] (11)

𝛼𝛼′ +𝑇𝑇−1

𝑦𝑦 𝑇𝑇 for y>1 (12)

We turn to the unconditional distribution of g denoted h(g). Given (1), it can be written as:
+∞ 1
ℎ(𝑔𝑔) = ∫−∞ 𝑥𝑥 𝑓𝑓𝐺𝐺(𝑃𝑃) ( 𝑔𝑔/𝑥𝑥)𝑓𝑓𝑋𝑋 (𝑥𝑥)𝑑𝑑𝑑𝑑 (13)

Given that x is in [0,1], for g greater than one:

𝛼𝛼′ +𝑇𝑇−1 ′
11 1 𝛼𝛼 −1
ℎ(𝑔𝑔) = ∫0 𝑥𝑥 𝑓𝑓𝐺𝐺(𝑃𝑃) ( 𝑔𝑔/𝑥𝑥)𝑓𝑓𝑋𝑋 (𝑥𝑥)𝑑𝑑𝑑𝑑 ∝ 𝑔𝑔− 𝑇𝑇 ∫0 𝑥𝑥 𝑇𝑇 𝑓𝑓𝑋𝑋 (𝑥𝑥)𝑑𝑑𝑑𝑑 (14)

and if g is in [0,1]:

11 𝛼𝛼′ +𝑇𝑇−1 𝑔𝑔 𝛼𝛼′ −1 𝛼𝛼′′ +𝑇𝑇−1 1 𝛼𝛼′′ −1


ℎ(𝑔𝑔) = ∫0 𝑥𝑥 𝑓𝑓𝐺𝐺(𝑃𝑃) ( 𝑔𝑔/𝑥𝑥)𝑓𝑓𝑋𝑋 (𝑥𝑥)𝑑𝑑𝑑𝑑 ∝ 𝑔𝑔− 𝑇𝑇 ∫0 𝑥𝑥 𝑇𝑇 𝑓𝑓𝑋𝑋 (𝑥𝑥)𝑑𝑑𝑑𝑑 + 𝑔𝑔− 𝑇𝑇 ∫𝑔𝑔 𝑥𝑥 𝑇𝑇 𝑓𝑓𝑋𝑋 (𝑥𝑥)𝑑𝑑𝑑𝑑
(15)

For g greater than one, the distribution of g follows a power law with a coefficient (minus
exponent):

𝛼𝛼′ +𝑇𝑇−1
𝑇𝑇
(16)

which decreases with T provided 𝛼𝛼 ′ > 1. This pattern of decline in the exponent with time
horizon is consistent with what we observed in the data in the previous section. For the
exponent found for the long horizon (50 years), the distribution is capable of producing black
swans (see Newman et al. 2005). The coefficient declines with T (converging to one) which is
the lower bound to have a defined mean. With an increasing horizon, the dispersion increases
21

and the probability of observing “miracles” increases. Focusing on short term growth is not
helpful in detecting policies that lead to the miracle growth outcome.

IV. TECHNOLOGY AND INNOVATION POLICY AS “TRUE INDUSTRIAL POLICY”

It is All About Productivity Gains: Innovation and Export Sophistication

A theoretical explanation for the lack of sustained growth, especially in the “middle-income
trap,” relates to productivity slowdowns as gains from low-cost labor and foreign technology
imitation diminish in moving through the stages of development. As a low-income country
becomes a middle-income country, it needs to find new sources of growth as benefits of low-
cost labor and productivity gains from sectoral reallocation from agriculture to manufacturing
and easy foreign technology adoption fade away. Wages rise, and competitiveness is eroded.
Moving away from labor-intensive manufacturing to sustain increases in productivity and per
capita income requires innovation—the use of new ideas, methods, processes, and
technologies in production—rather than imitation (Romer 1990, Aghion and Howitt 1992).

Innovation-driven growth is key to sustaining productivity gains and achieving high-income


status. Acemoglu, Aghion, and Zilibotti (2006) argue that if countries do not switch from an
investment-based strategy to an innovation-based strategy when approaching the frontier, they
may get stuck in a “non-convergence trap” without reaching the world technology frontier.
Similar to Gerschenkron (1962), the authors suggest that government intervention to increase
investment and adopt existing technologies is desirable at the early stage of development to
increase growth, but ironically, this policy may be costly in the long run and result in a “non-
convergence trap.” To move to an innovation-based strategy, competition policy and checks
and balances on political interests are needed to ensure convergence to the frontier.

To sustain growth, a country needs to constantly introduce new goods and adopt and develop
new technologies. Constantly introducing new goods rather than learning only on a fixed set
of goods is what is needed to generate productivity gains for a sustained growth miracle
(Lucas 1993). Learning-by-doing or learning-on-the-job is one of the most important channels
of accumulating knowledge and human capital in this process. Producing the same set of
goods or doing the same set of tasks would rapidly lead to stagnation in productivity. In
contrast, introducing new goods and tasks would allow managers and workers to continually
learn and move up the “quality ladder” (Aghion and Howitt 1992).

To introduce new goods and tasks, the country must be a large exporter (Lucas 1993), and
empirically, export sophistication is one of the major determinants of growth. Hausmann,
Hwang, and Rodrik (2007) and Cherif, Hasanov, and Wang (2018) in cross-country panel
growth regressions show that export sophistication is an important explanatory variable while
accounting for initial conditions, institutions, education, financial development, and trade
openness. Eichengreen, Park, and Shin (2013) show that countries with a high share of
population with secondary and tertiary education as well as a large share of high-technology
exports are less likely to experience growth slowdowns. The authors emphasize the
importance of moving up the “quality ladder” to sustain growth. Bulman, Eden, and Nguyen
22

(2012) suggest that escapees from the middle-income trap experienced rapid structural
transformation from agriculture to industry, higher human capital and innovation, and greater
export orientation while preserving macroeconomic stability with inflation of less than
10 percent and experiencing small increases in inequality. Berg, Ostry and Zettelmeyer
(2012), using an unknown-structural-break methodology to identify growth spells (periods of
high growth), also find that growth duration is correlated with export orientation—a
manufacturing focus, openness to FDI, and avoidance of exchange rate overvaluation—in
addition to macroeconomic stability, democratic institutions, and lower inequality.

Examining empirically growth acceleration episodes, Hausmann, Pritchett and Rodrik (2005)
find that most accelerations (with growth sustained for at least 8 years) are highly
unpredictable and are not preceded or accompanied by improvements in standard
determinants of growth and economic reform. Most instances of economic reform do not
produce growth accelerations although positive political changes and economic reform are
statistically significant predictors of sustained accelerations, that is, those persisting beyond
the 8-year horizon. Positive terms of trade shocks and financial liberalization tend to be
related to accelerations that are not sustained. The authors find that growth accelerations
episodes are not a rare occurrence (with an unconditional probability of 25 percent in a
decade) and that accelerations tend to be correlated with increases in investment and trade and
real exchange rate depreciations. Despite finding that positive economic and political changes
have some predictive power in identifying growth accelerations, the authors conclude that
most growth accelerations are caused by idiosyncratic changes.

TIP: The Moonshot Approach to Development

We argue that TIP had helped the Asian miracles achieve sustained growth, thanks to its
effect on export sophistication and innovation. Based on their experiences, we attempt to
uncover what constitutes TIP. In defining a policy, it is best to start by defining its main goal.
There is a striking pattern among the Asian miracles as well as Germany and Japan before
them. At the onset of the acceleration of their growth, the governments set for themselves an
extremely ambitious goal—to catch-up swiftly with the advanced world technologically and
economically. In their eyes, development was not an abstract concept vaguely referring to the
improvement in the standards of living. It was about joining the select club of industrialized
nations, or the First World in the words of Lee Kuan Yew, the founder of Singapore. To do
so, they had the models of Germany and Japan to follow.

The leaders of the Asian miracles stated explicitly this ambition on many occasions. In an
emblematic episode in 1964, General Park Chung Hee, who became president of South Korea
a year before, gave an emotional speech in Duisburg, West Germany. He addressed a group of
400 Korean miners who came to work as “Gastarbeiter”:

“Looking at your tanned faces, my heart is broken. All of you are risking your lives
every day as you go down thousands of meters underground to make ends
meet…What poor people you are! You go through these trying times just because
Korea is so impoverished…Although we are undergoing this trying time, we are not
23

supposed to pass poverty onto our descendants. We must do our part to end poverty in
Korea so that the next generation doesn't experience what we are going through
now…About 150 years ago, the industrial revolution was in full swing in Germany,
whereas Koreans had no idea of how the world outside was changing. Koreans stuck
to their traditional way of life without knowing what was going on outside the country.
We were like frogs in a well. How can a country like Korea, which was not fully
prepared for the upcoming era, be as rich as Germany now?” 23

It is striking that General Park did not only aim at eradicating poverty within one generation
(which Korea succeeded at) or becoming a “good” middle-income country but sought to
discover how to make his country, one of the poorest in the world at the time, an equal to
Germany.

One could cite many examples of speeches and political announcements to back the
description above. However, the concrete decisions taken at the time by the state (or the
private sector under the encouragement or coercion of the state) show clearly how Korea of
the early 1970s was serious about these objectives. At the time, the country had no meaningful
experience, skills (abroad or at home) or physical capital in industries such as steel,
shipbuilding and automotive. Yet, it set up in each of these industries a large-scale production,
leaving no doubt about the importance of exporting. Korea went from no experience in
running an integrated steel mill to building one of the biggest mills in the world in Pohang;
despite having no experience in modern shipbuilding, Hyundai (which was a construction
company at the time) built the largest shipyard in the world (and simultaneously its first ship);
and finally, the same company moved to the auto industry with no prior experience, and early
on decided to build a factory the annual capacity of which would exceed the total annual sales
of the whole country and set up its own networks of dealerships in the U.S., the largest and
most competitive market in the world.

The ambitious policy goal to catch up was directly translated into precise objectives to
develop select industries. This is the “leading hand of the state” at work (Cherif, Hasanov, and
Kammer 2016) with its triple-A principles of ambition, accountability, and adaptability. The
political leadership at the highest level decided that to catch-up it must compete with the
richest nations on its own turf, i.e., export markets of manufacturing industries. To do so, the
state played an active role, although the type and extent of the intervention depended on the
circumstances.

23
As recollected by one of the miners in attendance, Kwon Yi-chong, who became a professor of education at
the Korea National University of Education. See
http://www.koreatimes.co.kr/www/news/nation/2013/12/116_147609.html.
24

The strategy of the Asian miracles’ industrial policy/state intervention can be summed up as
follows:

• Intervene to create new capabilities in sophisticated industries: Pursue policies to steer


the factors of production into technologically sophisticated tradable industries beyond
the current capabilities to swiftly catch up with the technological frontier.

• Export, export, export: A focus on export orientation as any new industrial product
was expected to be exported right away with the use of market signals from the export
market as a feedback for accountability. As conditions changed, both the state and the
firms adapted fast.

• Cutthroat competition (at home and abroad) and strict accountability: No support was
given unconditionally although performance assessment was not necessarily based on
short term profits. While specific industries may get support, intense competition
among domestic firms was highly encouraged in domestic and international markets.

The Three Gears of TIP

In creating lasting productivity gains, solving market failures is key. We classify the approach
to fixing market failures into three types or gears—snail crawl, leapfrog, and moonshot. A
snail crawl, or gradual, approach to solving market failures—or “evolution by creeps”
(Ramalingam 2013, 219)—would not implement radical changes and would involve, for
example, fixing skill imbalances, providing incentives to private firms to locate in certain
areas, setting up export promotion agencies, etc. Many standard policies may fall under this
category.

A leapfrog approach—or “evolution by jerks” (Ramalingam 2013, 220)—may go beyond


standard intervention measures such as Malaysia’s intervention to support rubber, palm oil
(both natural comparative advantages) and electronic assembly industries (comparative
advantage in terms of availability of cheap labor in the Heckscher-Ohlin sense). It may also
step a little outside comparative advantage sectors, which the state would attempt to promote.
Hausmann’s (2015b) arguments on building on productive capabilities in existing industries to
move to technologically similar industries is indicative of the gradual approach, while
identifying new diversification opportunities, is closer to the leapfrogging approach.

A moonshot approach would pursue ambitious goals and radical changes. It would call for
creating industries and providing all the necessary ingredients to help domestic firms grow
and export way beyond existing comparative advantage sectors. It would require adopting a
long-term view and the ability to take risks. The industries or sectors would be “wicked hard”
to enter, as Pritchett (2017) called it, and much of the required skills and infrastructure might
not even exist. This approach implies that the state would play a “leading hand” in
development rather than leave the market to an invisible hand or a visible but slow-moving
hand (Callen, Cherif, and Hasanov 2016). The moonshot approach relates to the “mission-
oriented” approach of Mazzucato (2013). She challenges the state to go beyond fixing market
failures and to create and shape markets in addressing technological and societal challenges—
25

from putting a man on the moon in the past to addressing climate change or tackling plastic
pollution in the oceans today. Whether in developing or advanced economies, the state that
pursues ambitious goals, has to pull the necessary resources to lift binding constraints to attain
socially beneficial goals such as helping develop a new sector or pursuing cross-sectoral
“missions.” 24

These three approaches to solving market failures may explain how the Asian Tigers managed
to reach the high-income status relatively fast while many other countries improved only
marginally, if any. The three key parameters in identifying the gears of TIP are productivity
growth, export sophistication, and innovation. For instance, despite converging toward high-
income status, Chile has had stagnant productivity and export sophistication. Its approach can
be described as a snail crawl. Many oil exporters would most likely fall into this category as
well. Malaysia, instead, has witnessed positive productivity growth and improved export
sophistication but limited innovation. Its approach could be described as leapfrogging. Lastly,
high productivity growth, increasing export sophistication, and high innovation define the
moonshot approach of the Asian miracles (Figure 5).

Figure 5. TFP Growth in Select Countries (1970–2014)


200

Korea Malaysia
Taiwan Province of China Chile
TFP at constant national prices, 1970=100

Mexico
100 50 150

1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015
Year
Source: Penn World Tables 9.0.

One could argue that the snail crawl and leapfrogging approach to keep sustained growth is a
less risky strategy than the moonshot approach. Surely, Malaysia and Chile’s growth

24
Going beyond market failures to create and shape markets as Mazzucato argues is not necessarily inconsistent
with fixing market failures. In general, market failures also relate to positive externalities such as learning-by-
doing and spillovers or coordination failures related to firms not entering a market. The market would thus
underprovide the optimum allocation or might not even exist. In this sense, fixing a market failure would imply
creating new markets and new sectors.
26

performance reaching the upper-middle-income status over several decades is better than slow
or no convergence observed in many developing countries (see Johnson and Papageorgiou,
forthcoming). But Malaysia and Chile, at their current trend of growth, are still many decades
away from the levels of income in the Asian miracles although these countries started at
relatively similar levels of development one-half century ago. In addition, the strategies
implemented by Chile and Malaysia have not been risk-free, which relied on commodities and
entailed a vulnerability to commodity price volatility. It is difficult to argue that tackling
market failures to develop industries beyond existing comparative advantage sectors is much
riskier than accepting the fatality that the price of a country’s main export could collapse by
say 30 percent in a matter of weeks. A passive management of commodity price volatility,
through well managed sovereign wealth funds for example, would entail huge savings without
necessarily achieving sustained growth, as shown by Cherif and Hasanov (2013).

To desire much higher welfare for a country’s citizens by reaching high-income status in a
relatively short period of time should be the ultimate goal of inclusive development. From the
experience of the Asian miracles, the moonshot approach has been a key ingredient to their
success. However, different countries can pick their gear depending on their circumstances
such as political and social conditions. Moreover, these three approaches or gears are not
necessarily mutually exclusive and could be applied simultaneously to various sectors, around
existing industries or comparative advantage sectors and those beyond the comparative
advantage sectors. What is important is that the other conditions of TIP, that is, export
orientation and enforcement of competition, are ensured.

V. THE ECONOMICS OF TIP

The Standard Growth Recipe is Not Enough

Although theoretical and empirical growth literature has not yet found the “holy grail” of
economic development, sustained productivity gains are key to catch-up high growth. Moving
from an investment-based growth strategy to an innovation-led one, adopting and developing
new technologies, introducing new products, promoting competition and reducing
misallocation of resources, improving education and research capabilities, and increasing
sophistication of production and exports are identified paths to spur productivity gains. All
that is needed then is the design of relevant policies and their implementation. And yet as the
history of the past one-half century shows that only a handful of countries have caught up
with the advanced world. The typical explanation is that many developing countries have not
followed through the growth policy advice prescribed. First, what is the right growth policy?
Second, have countries failed implementing this policy? Or, has there been another big
obstacle in preventing developing countries to catch up with the advanced world? We argue
that there is a missing element in many growth policy discussions. This missing element is
tackling “market failures.”

The standard growth recipe mainly tackles “government failures” but does not alleviate much
“market failures.” Implementing structural reforms in product and labor markets, improving
27

institutions and business environment, maintaining macroeconomic stability, investing in


infrastructure and human capital, privatizing state assets, and reducing business regulations
are the main ingredients of the standard growth policy prescriptions. These prescriptions
tackle mostly what is described as “government failures” (Rodrik 2005). Such failures could
arise from high inflation, excessive government spending, unprofitable state-owned
enterprises, monopolies, investment impediments such as red tape and corruption, uncertainty
about property rights, unwarranted rules and regulations on labor, and other types of
government-driven distortions. The state should not intervene in the workings of the market
and should fix these problems, leaving the rest to lassies-faire.

Although many developing countries have a room to improve their business environment and
regulatory regimes, can the lack of progress in catching up with high-income countries be
attributed to government failures alone? Tackling government failures, that is, the standard
growth recipe, may not be enough to spur sustained growth.

We argue that the binding constraint to high sustained growth in many countries is market
failures. 25 Economies could be trapped in a suboptimal or low-productivity state not only as a
result of distortions arising from government failures but also as a result of market failures
due to learning externalities or coordination failures (Rodrik 2005).

The market failure based on a learning externality implies that firms do not internalize
productivity gains, leading to a lower allocation of resources into high-productivity sectors.
As argued by Matsuyama (1992), some activities, typically manufacturing, entail higher
productivity gains for an economy compared to other traditional activities such as non-
tradable services or agriculture. Firms may not be fully aware of these productivity gains,
which lead to lower output in high-productivity sectors and lower relative incomes over time.
The learning externality could also involve spillover effects in which productivity in other
sectors increase, while firms are unable to extract the pecuniary benefit from the spillover
effect (e.g., manufacturing’s spillover effect on agriculture). In this case, the resource
allocation into the traditional sector would also be higher than the socially optimal level
(Rodrik 2005). Moving from an investment-based strategy to an innovation-led one may not
be straightforward even if all other distortions, due to heavy or no government intervention,
are minimal.

The coordination failure is based on the idea that a critical size of the modern
(e.g., manufacturing) sector is needed for a firm to enter it. It would be profitable for a firm to
invest in a modern sector only if there are enough firms investing simultaneously in other
modern sectors. The mechanisms proposed to explain spillovers in the literature differ
(e.g., demand spillovers) but could be summed up as related to reaching a critical market size
to justify investment in complex technologies (e.g., automotive and aircraft). If many firms

25
We acknowledge the importance of political economy factors in tackling market failures (e.g., Pritchett, Sen,
and Werker 2018). This discussion is left for the follow-up paper (Cherif and Hasanov, forthcoming).
28

invest together in modern sectors, described as the “big push,” economy reaches a higher level
of productivity and development (Rodrik 2005).

The example of Chiapas in Mexico shows how market failures result in a lagging economy.
Despite a similar macroeconomic and institutional environment, income per capita of
Mexico’s regions has evolved quite differently (Hausmann 2015a). The major reasons are the
lack of productive capabilities and dynamic export industries (Hausmann 2015b). In the case
of Chiapas that has the lowest income per capita in Mexico, its growth rate was the lowest in
the 2000s. This is a dismal performance, especially since the gap within Mexico in years of
schooling, infrastructure, and access to credit improved and Mexico experienced relative
macroeconomic and institutional stability in the 2000s. Chiapas mostly exports agricultural
commodities. It is effectively stuck in the low-productivity trap. The modern production has
not emerged due to coordination failures—a chicken-and-egg problem. Private investment is
low and many complementary inputs for modern production are missing. It is highly likely the
market and the private sector would not be able to create high sustained growth. To correct
these market failures and promote the development of more complex industries, the state
needs to intervene to act as a catalyst (Hausmann, Espinoza, and Santos 2015).

The oil-exporting Gulf Cooperation Council (GCC) countries such as the United Arab
Emirates (UAE) do not have significant government failures, and yet largely lack the non-oil
tradable sector. The GCC countries, especially the UAE, have achieved high scores in the
measures of infrastructure quality and business environment. In comparison, oil exporters
such as Indonesia and Mexico, which lagged in regulation and business indicators, have
performed better in developing non-oil tradables and promoting export sophistication
(Figures 6–7). This observation suggests that to develop the tradable sector, countries do not
have to have institutions and business indicators at the level of advanced countries. Malaysia’s
bureaucratic quality index (from the International Country Risk Guide) did not change much
in the 1980s-1990s as it was developing its more sophisticated tradable sector, and this
indicator was similar to that of Saudi Arabia (Cherif and Hasanov 2016).

The argument that market failures preclude the development of the non-oil tradable sector in
the GCC oil exporters is further illustrated by the business activities of large conglomerates.
These activities are mostly in the nontradable sector such as construction and services
including finance and tourism (most of the activities in these service sectors are nontradable).
The conglomerates have access to land, financing, government bureaucracy, and world
markets, and the ability to import skills if needed. Most forms of government failures and
some forms of market failures such as coordination failures should not have significant impact
on the operations of these firms. Yet most conglomerates have not diversified into the non-oil
tradable sector unlike their Korean counterparts, chaebols, or Japanese zaibatsus, a few
decades ago.
29

Figure 6. Doing Business and Competitiveness Indicators in Oil Exporters

Quality of Infrastructure, 2016


Doing Business vs. Global Competitiveness Index, 2016 United States
(Score of 7 "meets the highest standards in the world")
7
Singapore United Arab
(Ranking among 188 countries)
6 Emirates Singapore
Bahrain United Arab Bahrain United States
Ease of Doing Business

Emirates
Qatar 5 Oman Qatar
Oman

Score
Saudi Arabia 4
Kuwait Saudi Arabia Kuwait

140 120 100 80 60 40 20 0 1


Global Competitiveness Index $500 $5,000 $50,000
(Ranking among 138 countries) GDP per capita

Monopoly Related Indicators Burden of customs procedures


(Rank 1 - 138, the lower rank, the better)
120 120 120 120
Intensity of local competition Prevalence of trade barriers 110 110
100 100
100 100
90 90
80 80
80 80
70 70
60 60
60 60 50 50
40 40
40 40 30 30
20 20
20 20 10 10
0 0
0 0

Source: World Economic Forum and World Bank’s Doing Business Indicators.

Figure 7. Goods Export Sophistication


(Adjusted for Commodity Exports)
15000

Saudi Arabia UAE


Malaysia Mexico
Indonesia
Constant 2011 PPP dollars
5000 0 10000

1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015
Year
Source: Cherif, Hasanov, and Wang (2018); based on Hausmann; Hwang and Rodrik (2007); and World Trade Flows (Feenstra and
Romalis 2014).
30

Even in advanced oil-exporting countries such as Norway and Canada, market failures have
slowed down the growth of the non-oil tradable sector. These countries have fallen prey to
Dutch disease—broadly defined as the crowding out of the tradable sector due to oil income
flows—although to a lesser extent compared to less technologically advanced oil-exporting
countries (Cherif 2013). Dutch disease would lead to a market failure if firms do not fully
internalize the fact that the non-oil tradable sector offers higher potential for productivity
gains. And with the shrinking or slow-growing non-oil tradable sector, the prospect for
continuous productivity gains is shrinking as well. Norway and Canada do not suffer from
government failures and yet, they have not been immune to Dutch disease and resulting
market failures (Cherif and Hasanov 2016). For instance, in 2012, manufacturing hourly
wages in Norway were the highest in the world and about double that of the U.S. or Japan,
according to the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics. Unit labor costs increased by 50 percent in
the 2000s, whereas they declined in Sweden and have not changed substantially in Germany.
It is not surprising that the measure of export sophistication adjusted for commodity exports in
Norway has not increased much since the late 1970s in contrast to that of its neighbor
Denmark.

In developing an oil and gas suppliers’ cluster in the 1970s, Norway has understood that the
existence of market failures and the lack of government failures would not necessarily result
in a rush of domestic firms to the fledgling oil and gas industry. The state policies were quite
interventionist to create and grow the local cluster of firms. First, the government intervened
directly in the procurements of oil operators. The Norwegian Petroleum Code imposed that
operators communicate their lists of bidders to the government, which in turn had the
authority to impose Norwegian firms and even to change which firm was awarded the bid
(Leskinen et. al. 2012). Second, the licensing process required foreign operators to come up
with plans to develop the competencies of local suppliers (Heum 2008). Third, starting in the
late 1970s, the government imposed a minimum of 50 percent of R&D needed to develop a
field to take place in Norwegian entities (Leskinen et. al. 2012). Although the restrictions
were lifted in 1994 when Norway signed trade agreements with the EU, the government
continued to support the suppliers though the INTSOK foundation to encourage them to
internationalize their activity. Eventually the suppliers’ cluster became highly successful,
including globally, spanning a large array of sophisticated industries such as subsea, geology,
and seismic, developed the required skills, and employed directly about 114,000 workers in
2009, or more than five times the employment of the operators in the oil and gas sector
(Sasson and Blomgren 2011).

The success of several EU countries, based on FDI-led growth, could suggest that tackling
government failures is sufficient. IMF (2016) shows that high TFP growth was sustained
through FDI-technology transfers, mostly from more advanced EU countries, supported by
improvement in business environment. However, it is unlikely that such circumstances would
arise outside the EU. These policies and convergence outcomes, especially for larger
economies, are akin to the leapfrogging of Malaysia and Thailand.
31

The existence of market failures requires state intervention to correct them although many
might argue that the state intervention would only make matters worse. Intervening to correct
market failures would allow the economy to reach a socially superior outcome. At the same
time, even if market failures exist, the benefits of state intervention could be outweighed by
the costs of intervention, exacerbating government failures such as rent-seeking and
corruption. In fact, the post-WWII doctrine of “ordoliberalism” calls for the minimum role of
the government to enforce contracts and ensure competition while avoiding interfering with
the workings of the economy (Eichengreen 2016). Even though the state intervention in
certain cases could prove to be counterproductive, it does not imply the state should only fix
government failures and should not interfere to correct market failures. Being paralyzed into
inaction or by the fear of potential mismanagement cannot be the correct policy option. This
trade-off suggests that the way the state intervenes in the economy is crucial as the examples
above illustrate. And this intervention needs to be cognizant of exacerbating government
failures, or “doing no harm.”

Building Sophisticated Products

The key question in the industrial policy debate is what should be produced. In fact, the three
approaches to fixing market failures shed light on what could be produced. The snail crawl
approach suggests producing goods and services around the existing industries (e.g., tourism
and agriculture) and moving up the quality ladder. The leapfrogging approach suggests
venturing into other sectors that may be a bit beyond the existing capabilities of the economy,
perhaps with the support of FDI. The moonshot approach calls for building “sophisticated
products” by domestic firms.

We argue that to create sustained growth to catch up and keep up with the frontier, the
economy has to produce “sophisticated products.” We need to define what we mean by
“sophisticated” and “products.” Now “products” are not necessarily only goods but also could
be services although we argue below that most services probably would not qualify since they
are not sophisticated and nontradable. “Sophisticated” would essentially mean that the product
or service is conducive to high productivity gains and spillovers to the tradable sector (not
only the nontradable sector). In addition to forward linkages, the sector could have a high
content of intermediate goods to create backward linkages in the production process. The
spillovers and high linkages could result in agglomeration effects and clusters feeding back
into productivity gains. Linkages and spillovers, productivity gains, and agglomeration and
clusters should support high sustained employment, which is a key goal in the development
process.

From innovation-led growth theory, sustained productivity gains can be generated by the
introduction of new goods/sectors, development of new technologies, and quality upgrading
(Aghion and Howitt 1992, Lucas 1993). The new goods and technologies would also increase
the scope of the goods produced and further support productivity growth. Sophisticated
sectors with linkages and spillovers are more likely to be conducive to new technologies and
sustained productivity gains than other sectors. And these sectors tend to be the tradable
32

sectors. Herrendorf and Valentinyi (2012) show that a large part of aggregate TFP differences
across countries are driven by productivity differences in the tradable sector, especially in
tradable investment goods such as machinery and equipment.

Less sophisticated sectors, in contrast, may not be as conducive to sustained productivity


gains as sophisticated industries. For instance, developing a tourism industry by building the
necessary infrastructure such as hotels, roads, restaurants, sightseeing places, etc. could
produce some productivity gains and growth. It has spillovers mostly to the nontradable
sector. Yet whether it could be sustained for a long time is less likely since tourism activities
are not conducive to the introduction of new goods and development of new technologies.
Eating in restaurants and walking down the city streets are not going to be any different
tomorrow than it is today, and these activities entail mostly cooking, serving, and street
performances. And even if there is any innovation in providing tourist services such as
wearing augmented reality goggles in museums or on city streets, the activity of watching
artifacts or adoring medieval or modern architecture is still much the same. Efficiency can be
improved in cooking and serving, and as Baumol said, performers can play music faster, but it
is unlikely tourists would demand these more “efficient” services.

Spillovers to the tradable sector are an important characteristic of sophisticated products.


Many activities could have spillovers to the nontradable sector. In fact, tourism qualifies.
However, it would not result in a lot of spillovers to the tradable sector. In contrast, for
instance, the semiconductor sector would produce spillovers to downstream sectors such as
computers, phones, and other electronics products. The backward linkages that exist in the
automobile and aircraft industries with many input components, which are part of the tradable
sector, are other examples of linkages in the tradable sector.

The literature on industry linkages and spillovers emphasizes their importance. Hirschman
(1958) advocated forward and backward linkages as a strategy for development. Liu (2017),
in a model of production networks and market imperfections, shows that it is optimal for the
government to intervene in “upstream” sectors, which supply to many other sectors. In this
production network economy, downstream sectors buy less-than-optimal amounts of inputs
from their suppliers, and these distortions propagate in the network upstream through
backward demand linkages. Liu (2017) provides examples of heavy chemical and industry
(HCI) drive (steel, metals, machinery, petrochemicals, electronics, and shipbuilding) in South
Korea in the 1970s and metal, chemical, and machinery-producing industries in China in the
2000s. These industries are upstream suppliers of intermediate goods to producers in other
sectors. Lane (2017), in a comprehensive empirical analysis of the HCI drive in South Korea,
shows that the targeted industries grew much more than non-targeted ones. The author finds
strong positive spillovers from the supported industries to downstream industries, which
increased the purchase of intermediate goods and invested more. Interestingly, the effects of
industrial policy persisted even after the support to the targeted sectors was reduced or
terminated.
33

Bartelme and Gorodnichenko (2015) also document a robust and strong relationship between
industry linkages and aggregate productivity. Interestingly, even in the U.S., the tradable
sector, in particular, electronics and auto industries and professional services, contributed
about one-half to the real value-added recovery after the 2008 crisis although it accounted for
only a third of the total value added (Hlatshwayo and Spence 2014). In sum, spillovers and
linkages in the tradable sector provide opportunities for agglomeration and clustering of firms,
fostering knowledge accumulation, knowledge sharing, and innovation. These activities fuel
productivity gains and sustained growth.

Sophisticated products do not necessarily mean high value-added goods and services.
Krugman (1994a) argues that high value-added industries are not necessarily high-tech ones.
In particular, he cites cigarettes and petroleum refining as high value added per worker
industries in the U.S. Electronics and aircraft industries have about the average value added
per worker. Essentially, Krugman argues that high value-added industries are mostly capital-
intensive industries such as petroleum refining, steel, and autos, which have to charge higher
markups over labor costs to earn a normal return on large investments. In addition, some
service industries fall into the high value-added category. Some are capital intensive like
transportation and others may generate some rents like finance and real estate. Using the latest
Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA) data, industries such as parts of finance (funds, trusts,
and other financial vehicles), real estate, petroleum and coal products have the largest value
added per worker in 2016 (Figure 8). High-tech industries such as computers and electronics
have smaller value added per worker than that of mining or utilities and are similar to those
for broadcasting and telecoms, water transportation, and movie production. With its strong
bend toward heavy manufacturing such as oil and gas production and chemicals, and service
industries such as finance, real estate, and broadcasting and telecom, high value-added
industries are not necessarily the industries that countries might want to promote. The
question arises as to which industries would be considered high-tech, high-productivity-gain,
and high-spillover industries.

To measure sophisticated products, we propose a measure of “sophisticated” goods and


services based on R&D intensity and patents issued. Using the data from the National Science
Foundation (NSF) and OECD on R&D intensity (a share of R&D spending in net sales or
value added), we identify industries that have high R&D intensity (Figure 9). These are
computer/electronic/optical products, pharmaceuticals, transport equipment except for motor
vehicles, information technology services, motor vehicles, electrical equipment, machinery
and equipment, chemicals, and scientific/professional/technical services. Metals, furniture,
and textiles in manufacturing and telecom, publishing, and finance/real estate in service
industries have much lower R&D intensity. A similar picture emerges when examining the
U.S. data (Figure 10). Scientific R&D services, pharmaceuticals, computer and electronic
products, aerospace products, and IT services have relatively high R&D intensity and a share
of R&D personnel in total industry employment. Interestingly, some industries that have high-
value added per worker end up on a lower end of R&D intensity spectrum, e.g., metal
production, telecoms, and finance/real estate.
34

Figure 8. Value-Added per Worker in U.S. Industries (2016)

1600
Value added per worker = 5546
for "Funds, trusts, etc."
1400

1200
Thousand dollars

1000

800

600

400

200

Source: BEA.

Figure 9. R&D Intensity (Percent of GDP), OECD (2015)

18

16

14
Median Average
12

10
Percent

Source: OECD.
35

The patents data corroborate the above measure of “sophisticated” goods and services. Of
course, R&D and patents are correlated, and we find that in 2012, out of about 84,000 patents
issued in the U.S., about 57,500 were issued in manufacturing and 26,500 were issued in
nonmanufacturing industries. In manufacturing industries, most patents were issued in
computer and electronic products, chemicals (pharma), machinery, transportation equipment,
and medical equipment (Figure 11). In nonmanufacturing industries, patents are basically
produced by software and scientific/professional services (see Appendix Figure 5).

These measures suggest that “sophisticated” products are not only manufacturing goods but
also certain services. Electronics, machinery, pharma, aerospace, motor vehicles are key
manufacturing products with high R&D intensity and patent production. In services, these are
software/IT and various scientific and technical services. Essentially, these industries
comprise the high-tech sector.

Figure 10. R&D Intensity and Personnel, USA (2015)

35

30

25

20
Percent

15

10

R&D intensity (% of domestic net sales) R&D personnel (% of total employment)

Source: NSF, Science and Engineering Indicators.


36

Figure 11. Patents Issued by Different Industries, USA (2012)

25,000

22,500

20,000

17,500

15,000

12,500

10,000

7,500

5,000

2,500

Source: NSF, Science and Engineering Indicators.

Beyond Comparative Advantage: Vegetables, Sewing Machines, or Microcircuits?

One of the key ingredients of the Asian miracles’ policies was their push into technologically
sophisticated sectors, which were sectors beyond their comparative advantage at the time.
Many argue that this goes against one of the tenants of economic theory explaining why it is
doomed to fail in general. 26 A central assumption of the modern version of the theory
(Heckscher-Ohlin-Samuelson) ignores the fact that to develop new industries, a country needs
to accumulate industry specific capital and knowledge. In other words, it assumes that
technology is freely available to every country. The only barrier for the poorest developing
economies to produce, say aircrafts, robots, or satellites, is the capital-labor ratio. Moreover,
relying on comparative advantage, and implicitly on Ricardian or Heckscher-Ohlin-
Samuelson type of models, ignores the importance of experience in the technology acquisition
process, or learning by doing, and the fact that capital accumulation in general does not
necessarily imply developing new industries. In other words, it is based on theories ignoring
externalities such as learning-by-doing or Marshallian externalities (increasing returns to
scale) stemming from clustering.

26
See Chang and Lin (2009) for an excellent debate summing up the key issues around comparative advantage
and the role of the state in development.
37

Even in a standard Ricardian comparative advantage framework, Krugman (1987) shows that
in the presence of learning externalities (learning-by-doing), there is a justification for infant
industry support policies. Young (1991) further shows that in a growth model with learning by
doing, a country starting with a lower initial level of knowledge would grow less in free trade
equilibrium than in equilibrium without trade. Essentially, producing goods in the sector in
which learning by doing has been exhausted without attempting to produce goods with
learning externalities, would lead to lower growth outcome.

Another potent critique of development strategies solely based on comparative advantage is


that in most cases, developing countries that succeeded at technological leapfrogging held no
initial obvious advantage and their later success came mostly as the result of a conscious
decision to succeed in specific sectors (see Chang and Lin 2009). To paraphrase Ha-Joon
Chang, Japan’s relatively limited experience in the automotive industry, lack of natural
resources like rubber to make tires or oil to run these cars, and even the limited surface to
drive cars should have precluded the emergence of the car industry in the 1950s and 1960s.
Korea’s example is even starker as its main export in the 1960s consisted of rice, silk, wigs
(made of human hair) and tungsten, and yet it embarked in developing shipbuilding,
electronics and car industries. Korea’s path would have been quite different if it followed the
advice it was given at the time to focus on these sectors instead of following its “reckless”
industrial policy in shipbuilding, for example (Woo 1991, p. 132).

To illustrate our argument, we study the dynamics of the Revealed Comparative Advantage
(RCA), which is a standard measure of comparative advantage in the export sectors (see for
example Balassa and Noland 1989), 27 of Korea and Taiwan Province of China between 1970
and 1990. This period corresponds to a thoroughly documented and extensive state
intervention to push strategic sectors such as electronics, along the lines of TIP (see Wade
1990, Chang 2002, Woo 1991, Amsden 1989, and Cherif and Hasanov 2015). In terms of
exports, in 1970, these two economies were dominated by relatively unsophisticated
industries. For example, food exports represented 27 percent and 22 percent of total exports in
Taiwan Province of China and Korea respectively. 28 The industries with the highest revealed
comparative advantage index included vegetables (Taiwan Province of China), cork and wood
products (Taiwan Province of China and Korea) and raw silk (Korea). It is difficult to imagine
how far these economies would have gone by focusing on silk and vegetables instead of their
moonshot to highly sophisticated sectors.

We illustrate further with a subtler approach of relying on RCAs. We assume that one would
focus on the more sophisticated manufacturing industries that were nascent in these
economies at the time and verify whether it could have helped us predict their evolution.

27
The RCA is an index defined for a good j in a country i as 𝑅𝑅𝑅𝑅𝑅𝑅𝑖𝑖,𝑗𝑗 = 𝜎𝜎𝑖𝑖,𝑗𝑗 /𝜎𝜎𝑤𝑤,𝑗𝑗 where 𝜎𝜎𝑖𝑖,𝑗𝑗 is the share of export j
in country i’s total export and 𝜎𝜎𝑤𝑤,𝑗𝑗 is the share of world export of good j in total world export. If RCA is greater
(smaller) than one, the country is considered to hold a comparative advantage (disadvantage) in that good.
28
Adding up categories “0”, “1” and “2” in SITC Revision 2 classification.
38

In 1970, there were 13 industries that had an RCA greater than one in Taiwan Province of
China in the industry category “machinery and transport equipment”, representing 13 percent
of total exports (see Appendix Tables). These industries were mostly in the subcategories of
“machinery specialized for particular industries” (SITC “7”), in particular in “textile and
leather machinery”, typically sewing machines, and none in the subcategories that include
electronics and other sophisticated machinery. This is not a surprise as the electronic industry
did not even exist at the time in Taiwan Province of China and the direct intervention to create
the industry was in its early stages (see Wade 1990 and Cherif and Hasanov 2015). In other
words, this indicator “revealed” that relatively less sophisticated machinery and transport
equipment were where this economy should have focused its energy, and electronics was not
one of these sectors. Fast forward to 1990, there were 63 industries with RCAs greater than
one, representing about 34 percent of total exports, mostly in the electronics and electric
machinery industries based on the export shares (see Appendix Tables). More striking, the
13 initial comparative advantage industries in 1970, not only did not achieve RCAs greater
than one by 1990, but they all simply vanished as export industries.

The same exercise yields even more dramatic results for Korea. In 1970, only three export
industries (SITC 4-digits) within the “machinery and transport equipment” category had an
RCA greater than one (see Appendix). These industries resemble those found in Taiwan
Province of China at the time, that is, textile and leather machinery and mechanical parts. In
1990, the top 10 exports of Korea were in much more sophisticated industries such as
electronics and shipbuilding. As in the case of Taiwan Province of China, the industries that
became the top exports did not even exist in 1970 as the state was just starting its effort to
develop shipbuilding, automotive and electronics. Moreover, the industries that had an RCA
greater than one in 1970, which were supposed to be the most promising, according to this
measure, disappeared as export industries by 1990.

The same pattern could be observed in Malaysia. Few relatively unsophisticated industries
could be considered as within their comparative advantage (three in 1970 according to the
same method applied for Korea and Taiwan Province of China). In 1990, microcircuits alone
represented 10 percent of Malaysia’s total exports which did not exist as export industries
twenty years earlier. Although the microcircuit industry in Malaysia was dominated by
multinational corporations, MNCs (as in 2017), their move to Malaysia was influenced by a
strategic decision and consistent effort by the government to attract FDI in this specific sector
way beyond their initial comparative advantage (see Cherif and Hasanov 2015). In contrast,
Chile, which also had no sophisticated industry with a revealed comparative advantage in
1970, had still no industry within this category with an RCA greater than one by 1990, while
its structure of exports remained relatively stable relying on products such as copper, natural
sodium nitrate and pulpwood. More important, exports of machinery and transport equipment
remained marginal hovering around 1 percent of total exports over these two decades.

In the description of Chang and Lin (2009), the question is not whether comparative
advantage should be defied or not, but how far from comparative advantage the state should
push. Given the chosen sectors, some would argue that the state should only play the role of a
39

facilitator while others see the state as playing an active role in initiating the development of
certain industries.

Based on the experience of the Asian miracles, we argue that a comprehensive strategy should
take simultaneously different approaches in different sectors, fully benefitting from current
comparative advantage while at the same time building the expertise for tomorrow’s
industries. Let us assume that a certain developing economy has n sectors where its factors’
endowment or its experience represents a clear comparative advantage (e.g., fertile land for
agriculture, cheap labor for low-skilled manufacturing such as textiles, beautiful beaches for
tourism, or natural resources). For a typical developing economy, these are sectors of low
sophistication and limited spillovers. If these comparative advantages are real and not
imaginary, 29 these industries should not require any significant sectoral state intervention and
would flourish provided major government failures are tackled and public goods are provided,
which would be summarized as horizontal policies 30 (e.g., transportation for agricultural
products, electricity for textile factories, and safety for tourists). In this case the state should
act as a facilitator and results should materialize relatively quickly in the form of export
revenue and employment. In such sectors the state should avoid an active risk-taking role such
as subsidies, state owned enterprises or directed/guaranteed credit. There are two rationales
for this approach. If these sectors are truly comparative advantage sectors, then an active role
of the state would only discourage competition and create opportunities for cronyism and
inefficiencies. Moreover, the opportunity cost of state intervention in low-skill, low-spillover
and low productivity gain sectors (such as tourism), as opposed to intervention in high-skill,
high-spillover and high productivity gain sectors (such as electronics), is large.

In parallel, we assume there are n’ sectors for which the standard analysis would not reveal a
comparative advantage. Notable examples of such sectors in the 1960s and 1970s would be
the automotive industry in Korea, the semiconductor industry in Taiwan Province of China,
and the aircraft industry in Brazil (EMBRAER), all of which turned out to be major
commercial successes, large employers and represent a significant share of the exports of
these economies. These sectors could also include backward linkages with existing sectors
such as those in oil rich countries. As discussed earlier, Norway used very aggressive policies
to spur the growth of its oil service industry in the 1970s and until the mid-1990s, the result of
which was the emergence of a high-tech and successful oil service cluster that had not existed
before (see Cherif and Hasanov 2015). These policies included the interference in tenders by
oil companies to the benefit of local firms and laws requiring oil companies to perform one-
half of their R&D in Norway. The common features among the policies pursued to develop
these sectors in these countries included an appetite for risk-taking, emphasizing technological
development, and encouraging competition in domestic and international markets. More
important, these policies were pursued over decades.

29
Another issue is the regional crowding-out, where neighbors invest heavily in the same sectors, typically
tourism, logistics and finance.
30
See Aghion (2016).
40

Not Manufacturing vs. Services, Rather Sophisticated Manufacturing and Services

Rodrik (2016) shows that many developing countries have been undergoing premature
deindustrialization. In most developing countries, with an exception of some Asian countries,
manufacturing shares in employment and output have been falling since the 1980s. More
important, manufacturing started shrinking at much lower levels of income than what
advanced countries and early industrializers experienced in the past. Rodrik argues that many
developing countries have been turning into service economies without going through a full
industrialization process.

Premature deindustrialization could be a daunting challenge if manufacturing is key to


sustained growth. Rodrik (2016) argues that since high sustained growth in early
industrializers has been driven by manufacturing—a technologically dynamic sector—
developing countries today could miss out on this opportunity to industrialize and sustain
growth. Manufacturing industries have experienced high productivity growth for decades and
exhibit unconditional convergence (Rodrik 2013). In addition, other features of manufacturing
such as spillovers and learning by doing, tradability, and innovation suggest that
manufacturing is important for sustained growth. Indeed, Korea’s manufacturing economy-
wide productivity (manufacturing real value added per capita) has increased 45-fold for the
past 45 years while that of Chile or Mexico barely doubled. Indonesia and Malaysia have
done better than Chile or Mexico, but not as well as Korea (Figure 12).

Figure 12. Manufacturing Economy-wide Productivity Growth in Select Countries


(1970–2014)
Manufacturing Economywide Productivity (2010 $, 1970=1)
50

Korea Malaysia
Indonesia Chile
Mexico
0 10 20 30 40

1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015
Year

Source: WDI.
41

With the decline of manufacturing in developing countries, the debate ensued whether
countries should still pursue manufacturing or leapfrog toward services. Ghani and Kharas
(2010), Ghani, Goswami, and Kharas (2011), Ghani and O’Connell (2014) argue that
“modern” services could be a catalyst for growth in developing countries as these services
exhibit increasing sophistication and tradability. Hallward-Driemeier and Nayyar (2017) also
suggest that key characteristics of manufacturing such as tradability, scale, innovation, and
learning-by-doing are becoming features of services too. IMF (2018) proposes that perhaps
services could replace manufacturing as an engine of growth going forward as the shift from
manufacturing to services does not have to lead to lower productivity growth.

Although a focus on services may stem from the idea that a large part of the output structure is
usually services, in many instances, the export structure would paint a different picture.
Singapore and Bahrain illustrate this point (Figures 13–14). Bahrain has a higher share of
mining and a little lower share of services than Singapore does, but overall the output
structure of the two countries is relatively comparable. Services make up a big part of both
countries’ output. In contrast, goods exports in Bahrain are mostly concentrated in oil and
metals (about 90 percent of goods exports, excluding re-exports), which is vastly different
from the diversified export base of Singapore, which has about 40 percent of goods exports
(excluding re-exports) in machinery and other industrial products (Figure 14). Interestingly,
services account for about one-half of each country’s total exports. Bahrain mostly exports
services in insurance and travel industries, and although travel exports in Singapore are not
small, the bulk of Singapore’s service exports are in transport, business services, and finance.
Exports are a good proxy of tradable production, and even for small open economies like
Bahrain and Singapore, tradable services do not capture a large share of total exports. Since
Singapore has maintained high growth rate for decades (with services accounting for a much
smaller export share in the past), the types of tradable goods and service sectors existing in the
economy are important.

The discussion about the rise of services is mostly centered on “modern” services. IMF (2018)
indicates that two types of services—transport and communications and financial
intermediation and business services—tend to exhibit labor productivity growth similar to or
higher than manufacturing. The IMF study also finds that these types of services show
patterns of unconditional convergence to the frontier. These industries include land, water,
and air transport, post and telecommunications, financial intermediation, insurance and
pensions, real estate, and business services such as rentals of machinery and equipment,
software and data processing, R&D, and professional services.

However, it is not a clear-cut case that these “modern” services would be sufficient for
sustained growth and employment generation. Most of the services included in transport and
communications and financial intermediation and business services are not going to be
considered “sophisticated” according to our measure of sophistication. Only scientific, R&D
and professional services would fall into this category. Other service categories such as
financial intermediation may require high skills and pay high wages but may not support
employment on a large scale. Bahrain’s finance sector, about 17 percent of GDP, directly
42

employed less than 10 percent of Bahraini nationals in 2012, similar to London’s share of the
finance and insurance sector (Cherif and Hasanov 2016). Moreover, it is not clear what higher
value added implies in many of these industries such as post and telecommunications,
financial intermediation, and transport—whether these are higher rents and profits or “true”
contribution to production.

Figure 13. The Output Structure: Bahrain vs. Singapore

Bahrain - GDP by Sector, 1990–2016 Singapore - GDP by Sector, 1990–2016


(Share of total) (Share of total)
120 120 120 120
Agriculture Construction Transport Trade Agriculture Construction Transport Trade

Manufacturing Mining Other Manufacturing Mining Other

100 100 100 100

80 80 80 80

60 60 60 60

40 40 40 40

20 20 20 20

0 0 0 0
1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016

Source: United Nations (UN).

Figure 14. The Export Structure: Bahrain vs. Singapore

Bahrain Exports by Sector, 2016 Singapore Exports of Goods and Services, 2016
(Percent of total exports of goods and services) Oil products (Percent of total exports of goods and services) Machinery and Transport
Equipment
10.3% Oil products
Metals
10.5% Chemicals
17.5% Chemicals 5.9% 16.4%
Manufactured products
28.4%
Agricultural and Food products
Agricultural and Food
6.8% products
Machinery, Transportation and 14.3% Metals and other crude
other industrial products materials
Textiles All other merchandise
12.5% exports
Transport
15.1% All other merchandise exports
10.2% Other business services
Insurance and pension services
22.3%
13.5% Financial services
Travel 5.8%
2.1% Travel

1.6% All other services exports All other services exports


0.7% 0.8% 1.9% 0.5% 1.5%
1.3%
Source: UN COMTRADE, World Trade Organization, and Singapore Statistics.
43

These service categories may not be that easy to scale up and trade on a large level, and for
large countries that manage this, it is not going to be a long-term growth strategy. India and
Philippines are some examples of countries that managed to achieve scalability and tradability
in telecommunications and information technology services. In fact, Philippines overtook
India in call centers, which employ more than a million people, account for about 8 percent of
GDP, and bring in huge export earnings (The Economist 2016). These types of industries
could constitute “quick wins” or a snail crawl approach although it is not sufficient as a long-
term growth strategy. And for large countries such as India that focus on services-led exports,
the counterexample is China with its focus on manufacturing that has had higher sustained
growth and employment generation than India.

Other services such as tourism are also “quick wins” but do not qualify as key to long-term
growth. These industries may generate some export earnings, growth and employment. But as
shown in Arezki, Cherif, and Piotrowski (2009), specialization in tourism yields limited
growth benefits. An increase in the tourism sector share of exports by 8 percent (one standard
deviation in a sample of more than 80 countries over 1980-1990) increases growth by only
one-half percentage points a year. To generate growth, a country has to attract more tourists
every year (as real spending per tourist is mostly constant), putting an exponentially higher
strain on public services such as security, utilities, and waste management. In addition,
tourism comprises low productivity activities such as trade and hotel/restaurants. Even in
small open economies with a focus on service exports, the generated export earnings are not
sufficient to cover enough of goods imports. The case of Bahrain with its large financial
sector and tourism illustrates that the country’s positive net service balance only covered
about a third of goods imports in 2011 (Cherif and Hasanov 2016).

Business services—which are sophisticated services—could support productivity growth and


employment, and in fact, may be related to manufacturing industries. This spurred the debate
on “servicification” of manufacturing. IMF (2018) shows that value-added of services in
manufacturing gross output increased by about 6 percentage points between 1995 and 2011,
accounting for about one-third of gross manufacturing output in a median country in 2011.
Although services account for a larger share of manufacturing output now than before, it is
not a significant share yet (although for some countries it is larger than 50 percent).
Alternatively, knowledge-intensive business services seem to have sprung up in disappearing
manufacturing clusters (Cermeño 2018a, 2018b). The share of knowledge-intensive business
services in gross value added of GDP in constant dollars since the 1950s in the U.S. increased
from under 20 percent to over 35 percent, while the share of manufacturing and other services
stayed roughly the same. Cermeño (2018a, 2018b) shows that knowledge-intensive business
services tend to be concentrated in densely populated areas although they could be done
remotely. She argues that large local markets largely explain the localization of these services.
Essentially, there are increasing returns to scale in this sector with spillover effects, economies
of scale and proximity to skills, competitors and providers. And these knowledge hubs were
originally related to the proximity to manufacturing clusters (Marshall 1880, Hall 1902).
44

Hong Kong’s experience illustrates the fine line in the measurement of manufacturing and
services. Manufacturing played an important role in Hong Kong’s development. Employment
in manufacturing peaked in the early 1980s with about 1 million workers out of 5 million total
population (Trade and Industry Department 2018). Subsequently, manufacturing production
relocated outside of Hong Kong as labor costs were much lower in mainland China. For
example, in 2008, Hong Kong enterprises employed about 10 million workers in the Pearl
river delta region while Hong Kong’s total population stood at about 7 million (Trade and
Industry Department 2018). Although most of the manufacturing activities of these enterprises
are not carried out in Hong Kong, the value they generate are classified under the services
sector instead, blurring the true contribution of manufacturing to Hong Kong’s economy.

Our discussion on manufacturing as an important driver of sustained growth has come a full
circle. Berger (2011), a co-chair of MIT’s Production in Innovation Research Commission
argues that the next wave of technological innovations is tied to production processes and in
which R&D is harder to separate than in IT and electronics industries of the past. In fact,
Berger contends that innovation in manufacturing in some of these emerging industries like
solar is key. Andrew Liveris, the executive chairman of DowDuPont, echoes the same point
that manufacturing, in particular advanced manufacturing, is essential to the knowledge
economy (Knowledge@Wharton 2017). According to Liveris, manufacturing is crucial for
innovation: “If you have the shop floor, if you make things, you have the prototype for the
next thing, so you can innovate.” (Knowledge@Wharton 2017). Based on Cohen and DeLong
(2016) that studied Alexander Hamilton’s (one of the early architects of industrial policy)
approach to catapult the U.S. to the technological frontier, DeLong has emphasized that
manufacturing creates engineering communities of technological competence that help spread
knowledge, generate spillovers, and sustain productivity growth. And sophisticated products
are more likely to be in manufacturing than service industries.

A recent work by Diao, McMillan, and Rodrik (2017) examining growth episodes in
developing countries in the past couple of decades suggests that none of these episodes has
been driven by rapid industrialization observed in East Asian countries. In particular, in
Africa, structural change from low to high productivity activities have been mostly driven by
increased demand for goods and services in modern sectors rather than productivity
improvements in those sectors. Manufacturing in Africa has also performed quite poorly. In
contrast, in Latin America, which has experienced some within-sector productivity growth,
structural change has made negative contribution to overall growth as labor moved from high-
productivity sectors to low-productivity activities. McMillan and Rodrik (2011) argue that the
pattern observed in Latin America is mostly due to commodity dependence, overvalued
exchange rates, and deindustrialization. East Asia, which has experienced sustained growth,
has seen both within-sector productivity growth and structural change as new industries were
born, and resources moved from traditional to new industries. These papers cast doubt
whether recent growth experiences in Latin America and Africa could be sustained.
45

Creating Domestic Innovators: From Convergence to Growth at the Frontier

We argue that the key to long-run sustained growth to reach the advanced country status and
then keep up with the frontier growth is to promote technology and innovation at each stage of
development. And the way to create technology and generate innovation is to produce
sophisticated products. In fact, doing so and competing with other firms requires R&D and
innovation in the first place. The first key element of the growth strategy is thus
straightforward—produce sophisticated products to catch up with the frontier and keep
producing sophisticated products, although not necessarily the same products, to keep up with
the frontier. And it is not only producing sophisticated products, but also producing it by
domestic firms. This is the second key element. Only then creating own technology would be
possible. Creating and growing domestic innovators should be the focus of TIP.

The middle-income trap exemplifies the importance of creating own technology. Cherif and
Hasanov (2015) show that Malaysia did follow the standard growth recipe but was not able to
generate enough innovation to support productivity growth needed to escape the middle-
income trap. The standard growth determinants such as infrastructure, macroeconomic
stability, strength of institutions and governance, trade openness, and FDI did not seem to be
the binding constraints, especially in comparison to Korea in the 1980s, which was at a similar
level of development. The inflow of FDI and the arrival of large MNCs did result in a large
boon to exports, increasing export sophistication considerably (Figure 15). However,
manufacturing economy-wide productivity and TFP productivity growth lagged those of
Korea of the 1980s (Figures 5 and 12).

The missing link in Malaysia compared to Korea and Taiwan Province of China is own
technology creation. When Korea overtook Malaysia in 1985-86, its patents granted in the
U.S. per 1000 people was about one per year while Malaysia stood at a quarter of that number
(Figure 16). Both countries had relatively low number of patents in the early 1980s. However,
since then, Korea’s patents have skyrocketed. The number of Malaysia’s patents per 1000
people granted in 2014 (about 9) was still much below Korea’s when it had a comparable
level of income around 2000 (about 75). In this regard, Korea’s remarkable growth is driven
by its remarkable innovation. When Korea’s chaebols started investing heavily in cutting-edge
DRAM chips, with government support, in the mid-1980s, its GDP per capita relative to the
U.S. only stood at around 25 percent (Kang 2001). By the early 1990s, Korean firms were
already dominating the market. And when they started other sophisticated industries in the
early 1970s like electronics and shipbuilding (HCI drive), the country’s relative income was
only about 12 percent, just above the low-income threshold of 10 percent.

Lower R&D spending in Malaysia contributed to a smaller number of patents granted (Figure
17). R&D expense was much lower in Malaysia in 2012, a little over 1 percent of GDP, than it
was in Korea of the 1990s, more than 2 percent of GDP, and even of the mid-1980s,
1.3 percent in 1984 (Tran 2013). This could partially be explained by a higher share of
graduates in engineering, manufacturing, and construction in Korea (about 35 percent of
46

tertiary graduates) in the 1990s than that in Malaysia in the late 2000s (about 25 percent). The
figures were reverse for social science graduates, 21 vs. 33 percent (Tran 2013).

Figure 15. Export Sophistication in Malaysia, Korea, and Taiwan Province of China

20000
Korea Taiwan Province of China
Malaysia
15000
Constant 2011 PPP dollars
5000 100000

1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015
Year

Source: Cherif, Hasanov and Wang (2018).

Figure 16. Missing TIP: Patents Granted in the U.S.


500

Korea Malaysia
Taiwan Province of China
400
Patents per Million People
200 300
100
0

1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015
Year

Source: U.S. Patent and Trademark Office (USPTO).


47

A focus on MNCs and technology transfer rather than growing domestic innovators
contributed to the lack of innovation in Malaysia as compared to Korea and Taiwan Province
of China. Cherif and Hasanov (2015) argue that although Malaysia recognized the importance
of technology creation and provided various incentives for MNCs to diffuse technology and
support local firms, it was not very successful at doing so. The country had some success with
Vendor Development Program that had local content requirements (Felker 2001), but it was
not sufficient. The Malaysian electronics cluster lacked the “packaging and integrating”
capabilities of Singapore and product development and technology management capabilities
of Taiwan Province of China (Best 2007). Rasiah (2007), using a sample of auto parts firms,
showed that foreign ownership helped increase exports in East Asian countries, but R&D
intensities were mostly driven by local firms. In Taiwan Province of China, which had much
higher patent production than Malaysia, local electronics firms had higher technological
intensity than foreign firms, opposite of the pattern observed in Malaysia (Rasiah 2004).

Figure 17. R&D Spending in Malaysia and Korea, 1996 vs. 2012
4
R&D Spending (% of GDP)
1 2 0 3

Malaysia Republic of Korea


1996 2012

Source: WDI.

Singapore was more forceful in creating local firms and technology despite the large inflow of
FDI and the presence of MNCs. Initially, Singaporean SOEs engaged with MNCs as
subcontractors, but the Ministry of Finance was keen on creating local non-state-owned
MNCs (Low 2001). The cluster-based industrialization in the 1990s led by Singapore’s
Economic Development Board involved many stakeholders, including MNCs. For instance,
the electronics cluster was spearheaded by the Singapore Technologies Group, an SOE,
working in tandem with government research institutes, universities, and MNCs (Low 2001).
Unlike the Malaysian electronics cluster that continued to engage in relatively low skill
48

production, the Singaporean electronics cluster moved up the quality ladder as low-cost
manufacturing was becoming no longer viable (Best 2007).

Korea and Taiwan Province of China did not rely on MNCs in technology creation and
instead, were determined to create their own technologies led by local firms. Taiwan Province
of China’s electronics sector has been its pillar of stellar growth in the past decades, while
Korea’s venture into automotive, shipbuilding and electronics is equally impressive. In both
cases, the state played a key role in promoting these sectors (Cherif and Hasanov 2015).

Building domestic capabilities and creating own technology in sophisticated sectors are key
elements to achieving innovation and sustained growth. In many instances, it would imply to
enter sectors with little or no comparative advantage, lack of skills, experience, and resources,
and high risk of losing money. The bigger the technological leap is (or the farther away from
its comparative advantage the country is), the bigger the risk is and the longer it could take to
discover the true outcome of initial investment (Rodrik 2005 and Chang and Lin 2009).
However, in the long run, these sectors offer high returns and are the ones that could catapult
the country into the high-income status. This high risk-high return tradeoff is exemplified by
Nokia’s mobile unit (part of a Finnish logging company at the time) that had incurred losses
for about 20 years and had to be cross-subsidized (Chang and Lin 2009).

The case of Korea offers strong support to the principle of innovation at early stages of
development to generate sustained growth. Figure 18 shows patents granted in the U.S. for
Korea and other countries at comparable levels of development. For instance, in the early
1970s, when Korea’s GDP per capita was similar to that of Tunisia and Philippines, the
countries had a similar number of patents granted. Starting in 1980, as Korea had comparable
levels of GDP per capita with Brazil, Chile, Malaysia, and Mexico, it was already receiving a
higher number of patents. And the gap has been increasing with time. Looking at 2014, we
observe that some countries increased their patents but not as dramatically as Korea had done.
Even advanced countries at about same level of development in 2014 were patenting much
less than Korea. Figure 19 shows actual patents, and the gap is enormous even with many
advanced countries, which in fact have been experiencing relatively lower growth rates.

In fact, sustaining innovation at the frontier requires producing sophisticated products.


Examining business R&D in OECD countries, one finds a striking pattern (Figure 20). The
patents per capita in top innovator nations such as Korea, Japan, Finland, Switzerland, and the
U.S. indicate that most of business R&D is done in high-tech manufacturing by large
domestic firms. As discussed earlier, most of R&D is done in manufacturing and
software/scientific services. Producing sophisticated products should lead to higher R&D and
innovation. In venturing into these sectors, countries and firms would have no other option but
to invest in R&D and innovate to compete.
49

Figure 18. Patents Granted in the U.S.: When Korea Overtook Other Countries
(1970–2014)

JPN ISR

6
ISR

Log Patents per Million People


NZL

4
ITA
NZL
EST SVN
ESP HUN
ESP MYS
HUN
2

SVN GRC
ZAF PRT CHL
ZAF
GRC BRA
MEX
0

MEX
PHL TUN

TUN BRA MYS PRT


-2

PHL
CHL

1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015
Year
Source: USPTO.

Figure 19. Patents Granted in the U.S.: Korea vs. Other Countries
(1990–2014)

ISR
JPN
400

KOR
Patents per Million People
200 300

ISR
100

NZL
ITA
NZL EST SVN
ESP ESP HUN
HUN GRC SVN MYS
GRC
PRT
ZAF
BRA CHL
MEX
0

EST PRT PHL


N GATUN

1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015


Year

Source: USPTO.
50

In summary, technology and innovation are key to growth not only at the frontier but also at
much lower levels of development. Taiwan Province of China and Korea’s experience shows
that venturing into the frontier sectors and producing own technology at early stages of
development pay off in sustaining high growth. It is a high return-high risk strategy and that is
why it is important to support sectors rather than firms as it is not known ex ante which firm
would succeed (Aghion 2016). Korea’s strategy followed this approach. 31

We have come a full circle on income convergence toward the frontier and growth at the
frontier. Producing sophisticated products provides productivity gains, spillovers, and other
positive externalities needed to catch up. At the same time, producing sophisticated products
requires high R&D spending and innovation to keep up with the frontier. High spending on
R&D by large domestic firms in high tech areas early on suggests a path to achieving high and
sustained growth.

Figure 20. Who Creates Technology?

Source: http://innovationpolicyplatform.org/STICharting/BERD.htm?iso=KR

31
As argued by Hausmann and Rodrik (2003), it is optimal to encourage investments in the modern sector ex
ante in the presence of uncertainty in terms of the sectors the country is good at.
51

VI. TIP THROUGH HISTORY

TIP Has Always Failed in the Past…Because It Was Not Tried

A standard argument against any sort of state intervention to spur the growth of new industries
lies in the fact that there have been many failures in the past. On a superficial level it is true
that most developing countries somehow attempted to develop new industries and acquire
new technologies using some sort of state intervention. The policy tools used were diverse and
ranged from subsidies and protection through tariffs all the way to price controls and the use
of state enterprise monopolies.

Many public enterprises created in the great wave of industrial policies of the 1960s and
1970s ended up in financial disarray eating up huge amounts of resources. The widespread
view is that industrial policy leads to inefficient enterprises which would perpetually live on
state handouts mainly benefitting cronies. It is also usually believed that the bad financial
situation of many developing economies in the 1980s and 1990s was the direct result of the
resource misallocation and inefficiency resulting from “industrial policies”. If this is the case,
how can it be that TIP was behind the spectacular success of the Asian miracles and how can
one draw from it any useful lessons?

We argue that there are very few examples of TIPs in the past according to our definition. One
of the pillars of the Asian miracles’ policies was export orientation in technologically
sophisticated industries. In other words, transport companies such as airline companies, power
companies, telecommunication networks or tourism do not qualify as part of TIP. That still
leaves a great number of attempts in manufacturing industries such as heavy industries,
automobile and electronics. There are a few examples where state intervention had an explicit
objective to export immediately. Indeed, the pattern of the industrial policies of the 1960s and
1970s was to create productive capacities, mostly in heavy industries, which were mainly
inward looking, i.e., import substitution industrialization.

The first observation is that the golden age of import substitution did yield a sizable increase
in manufacturing production although it did not match those of the Asian miracles. We use the
Groningen Growth and Development Centre (GGDC) 10-Sector database, which provides
comparable data on sectoral productivity performance for 10 broad sectors from 1950 onward
for many countries. 32 Figure 21 shows the average annual growth rate of value added (VA) in
manufacturing (in real terms per capita) over two different periods, i.e., 1965–1980 and 1980–
2010. Over the first period, during the height of industrial policies, many developing
economies achieved relatively high growth rates in manufacturing spurred by the import
substitution policies. Among the best performers, manufacturing value added per capita grew
at an average annual rate of about 10 percent in Indonesia, 7 percent in Nigeria and 6 percent
in Brazil over 1965–1980. Yet, these performances were still dwarfed by that of the Asian
miracles. Korea which started at a level of income per capita comparable to that of Indonesia

32
See Timmer et. al. (2015).
52

saw its manufacturing VA per capita grow at an annual rate of 15 percent, while those of
Taiwan Province of China and Singapore grew by around 12 percent.

Figure 21. The Rise and Fall of Import Substitution Led Growth

.15 Growth of Manufacturing VA per capita


KOR

TPC
SGP
CHN CHN
.1

IDN
in percent

NGA
THA KOR
BRA JPN
ITA
THA
ESP
.05

IND KEN IDN CRI MYS


EGY MUSMEX FRA
BOL COL TPC SGP
ETH ZAF NLD
TZA VEN
ETH EGY PER CHL SWE
DNK
IND ZMB ARG CRI JPN
USA
TZA PER NGACOL USA
MWI BOL
SENKEN
ZMB GHA ARGCHL MEX
GBR
GHA PHL
0

BRA ZAF HKG


VEN

6 7 8 9 10 11
Initial GDP per capita (ppp in log)

Avg. annual 1965-1980 Fitted values (1965-1980)


Avg. annual 1980-2010 Fitted values (1980-2010)

Source: GGDC 10-Sector Database (Timmer, de Vries, and de Vries 2015) and Penn World Tables 9.0.

During the later period, 1980–2010, when import substitution policies were rolled back in
most developing economies, the average growth rates of manufacturing production dropped
significantly, and manufacturing stagnated in many economies. 33 Meanwhile, manufacturing
VA in the Asian miracles kept growing at relatively high rates, especially when controlling for
initial income per capita.

We offer evidence that among developing economies, very few pursued an export-oriented
industrialization policy on a large scale as it was the case in the Asian miracles. 34 Inward
looking or outward looking could be proxied by the strength of the short-term relationship
between the growth of manufacturing value-added and the growth of manufacturing exports.
By strength, we mean whether these growth rates are correlated in a significant way and how

33
As shown by the decline in the slope and intercept of the fitted line.
34
In practice, countries may have mixed export orientation with little state intervention in some sectors with
import substitution policies in others. This was the case in Malaysia for example which pursued import
substitution in the automotive industry while being export oriented in electronics, heavily relying on MNCs (see
Cherif and Hasanov 2015).
53

large this elasticity is. For example, if the relationship is significant and the elasticity is close
to or greater than one, then one could say that such a country is export-oriented.

We use a structural break test to determine whether a break in the relationship happened and if
so, the year of the break. 35 The kernel distribution of the break years (when the null hypothesis
that there was no structural break was rejected at a 5 percent level) shows that the distribution
has a mode in mid- to late-1970s (Figure 22). Most countries that changed their short-term
export/import orientation had already done so by 1990.

Studying the strength of the short-term relationship (elasticity and R-squared), the Asian
miracles are clearly outliers over the 1970-1990 period. Singapore and Korea are among the
very few countries with a high R-squared and an elasticity that is both significant and positive
(Figure 23). Over 1990–2010, many countries would see the strength of the short-term
relationship between exports and manufacturing output change (see Appendix Figure 1).

Figure 22. Kernel Distribution of Structural Break Years


.03
.025
Density
.02
.015

1970 1980 1990 2000 2010


Break year

Source: GGDC and WDI.

35
The regression model is (where all the variables are in real terms): ∆log(manufacturing
exports)=c+α∆log(manufacturing value added)+ε
54

The difference between the Asian miracles and other developing economies is even starker in
terms of export performance. Figure 24 shows the ratios of manufacturing exports per capita
relative to Korea in a large set of countries. While most advanced economies were exporting
between 25 and 150 times as much as Korea in 1965, the ratios shrank by an order of
magnitude to between twice to 8 times Korea’s exports per capita by 1980 (Figure 24a).
Figure 24b covers the same period zooming on countries that started at less than twice
Korea’s level of exports in manufacturing encompassing most of the available developing
economies in the sample. Korea stands out as no country even remotely kept pace with it in
terms of manufacturing exports. At best, countries like Malaysia and Tunisia, which exported
more manufactured goods per capita than Korea in 1965, represented about 40 percent and
20 percent of Korea’s exports by 1980. Figure 24c and 24d show that Korea kept catching up
with advanced economies, especially those with a comparable population size, while most
developing economies kept falling behind (or at best their ratios stagnated at a fraction of
Korea’s).

Figure 23. Short-term Relationship Between Manufacturing Exports and Output,


1970–1990
4

CRI
COL

PHL MUS

IDN
2

ZAF KOR
BOL
INDMWI
GHA
ESP
MEX ETH
Elasticity

CHN
ZMB
MYS
ARG
THA
CHL
NGA
TZA
0

EGY
PER
BRA
KEN
VEN
-2

SEN

0 .1 .2 .3 .4 .5
R-squared

Source: GGDC and WDI.


55

Figure 24. Export Performance (Korea vs. the World)

(a) (b)
Relative to Korea in 1980 HKG KOR

Relative to Korea in 1980


8

0 .2 .4 .6 .8 1
BEL
6 SGP CHE

SWE NLD
FIN
4

GRC
MLT AUTDNK
DEUNOR
CAN MYS
ISR GBR
IRL FRA
JPN
ITA TUN CRI
2

USA JOR
KOR BRA ARG GTM
NZL
GRCAUS
ESP
ISLPRT THA
PER PHLCHL HND
COLNIC SLV
MEX
MYS
CRI
TUN
JOR TUR
LKA MAR
PAN
ECU
TGO SEN PAK PRY VEN
GTM
BRA
ARG
SLV
COG
MEX
THA
HND
PER
CHL
COL
PHL
MAR
VEN
PAN
PRY
PAK
SEN
TUR
NIC
LKA
ECU
EGY
TGO
CAF
IND
BOL
CMR
MDG
BFA
BEN
GHA
MLI BFA
BEN
GHA
MLI CMR MDGEGY
IND BOL CAF
0

0 50 100 150 0 .5 1 1.5 2


Relative to Korea in 1965 Relative to Korea in 1965

(c) (d)
KOR
Relative to Korea in 2010

Relative to Korea in 2010


HUN
6

0 .2 .4 .6 .8 1
SGP
HKG ISR
4

BHS ITA FRA


MYS CAN
JPN GBRNOR
BEL
ESP
PRT
IRL CHE TTO
2

NLD USA
AUT
DEU SWE THA ISL
DNK FIN MEX
BHS
MYS
KOR
HUN ISRCAN
FRA
ITA MLT TUR CRI GRCAUS
OMN
SAU
TUN NZL
CYP
ESP
PRT
TTO JPN GBR
NOR SLV
COG
ARG
CHL ZAF
URYJAM BHR
JOR BRB
THA
MEX
OMN
SAU
TUR
CRI
TUN
SLV
COG
ARG
CHL ISL
AUS
NZL
GRC
ZAF
JOR
URY USA
CYPBRB
BHR MAC BRA
PAN
MAR
PHL
IDN
PER
SYR
EGY
ECU
BGD
VEN
IND
HND
PAKDMA
DOM
VCT
GTM
COL
BRA
PAN
MAR
DMA
DOM
PHL
FJI
VCT
IDN
LKA
GTM
COL
PER
SYR
EGY
ECU
BGD
IND
VEN
HND
PAK
SEN
PRY
TGO
BOL JAM
BLZ
DZA
GHA
KEN
NIC
MDG
MLI
NPL
TZA
CMR
CPV
BEN
BFA
MWI
CAF
GMB
SDN PRY
TGO
BOL
KEN
NIC
DZA
MDG
NPL
CPV
CMR
BFA
MWI
BEN
CAF
GMB
SDN BLZ
0

0 2 4 6 8 0 1 2 3
Relative to Korea in 1980 Relative to Korea 1980

Source: WDI.

We show further evidence that although most developing economies had tried some sort of
industrial policy in the 1960s–1980s, there are very few countries that had achieved sustained
growth in their production of manufacturing, especially beyond the 1980s and had a clear
export orientation view that was even remotely comparable to Korea’s (and other Asian
miracles’). In fact, our conjecture is that is it precisely thanks to its export orientation that
Korea managed to sustain its growth in manufacturing output. In addition, Cherif, Hasanov,
and Wang (2018), using cross-country growth regressions and neighbor-country instruments,
find that export sophistication measures such as EXPY (Hausmann, Hwang, and Rodrik
2007), a manufacturing exports share, and manufacturing exports per capita, are all robust
determinants of long-run growth.

We further illustrate our point by measuring the level of “manufacturing export intensity”
(MEI) of a country by its market share in world manufacturing export (that is a country’s
exports of manufacturing divided by the world’s total exports of manufacturing) normalized
by its share in world population. For example, in 2010, Switzerland’s weight in world
population was about 0.11 percent and its manufacturing export market share was 1.7 percent,
producing the level of manufacturing export intensity of about 150 percent, which was 250
times greater than India’s (India represented close to 18 percent of world population at the
time). In contrast to the growth rate of exports of manufacturing, which can be misleading if
56

for example a big country in terms of population starts exporting with almost no initial
manufacturing base, a sizable change in this measure captures adequately whether a country is
making a serious foray in world markets in relation to its population size over longer periods.
The differences between low and middle-income countries and high-income countries
according to this variable are stark. In 1970, the median manufacturing export intensity in low
and middle-income economies was 5 percent compared to 270 percent in high-income
economies. In 2014, it was 8 percent in low and middle-income economies and 370 percent in
high-income economies. The gap between poor and rich countries in terms of manufacturing
intensity was immense, and it has widened further.

Figure 25 shows the average growth of manufacturing value added per capita (in real terms) in
relation to the change in manufacturing export intensity over 1970–1990 in a sample of
developing economies (as of the 1970s). 36 As noted above, these countries started at a very
low level of manufacturing export intensity (with a median close to 0.05), and most have not
increased it much over the period. Countries such as Korea, and to less extent Malaysia and
Thailand, managed to simultaneously grow fast both in terms of manufacturing output and
manufacturing export intensity. In fact, by 1990, Korea jumped close to the initial level of
export intensity of the median high-income country. Meanwhile, countries such as China and
Indonesia achieved particularly high growth rates in manufacturing output (7–10 percent on
average in per capita terms) without changing much their manufacturing export intensity. This
provides compelling evidence of an import substitution policy that was still largely in place
until the late 1980s. Other countries known for their import substitution policies in the 1970s
and 1980s, such as Egypt, Nigeria and India, follow the same pattern of relatively high growth
of manufacturing output and a negative change in their manufacturing export intensity. The
rest of the countries had both small growth rates in manufacturing output and small or
negative change in manufacturing export intensity. Chile is a clear outlier as its laissez-faire
policy led to an anemic growth in manufacturing output and a collapse in its manufacturing
export intensity. In other words, besides Korea and a few other countries, developing
economies did not pursue simultaneously a rapid industrialization and an export-oriented
policy.

36
The data are taken from de Vries et al. (2015). Appendix Figure 2 uses U.N. statistics data and covers more
countries, but the overall picture is similar.
57

Figure 25. Manufacturing Export Market Share Change


1970–1990

Change in relative manufacturing export market share


3
KOR
2

MUS
ESP
MYS
1

THA
MEX
VENBRA IDN
ARG CHN
COL INDNGA
0

TZA ETH
MWI
GHA SENZAF CRI KEN EGY
BOL
PER
-1

CHL

-5 0 5 10 15
Manufacturing (avg. growth per capita)

Source: GGDC and WDI.

ISI in India: The State as a Micromanager

Although important, economies of scale are not necessarily the only reason behind the failure
of ISI policies. The lack of export orientation leads to a lack of productivity improvements,
innovation, and dynamism while ISI policies are also usually accompanied by distortions and
perverse incentives. India, with its large market, represents a good case that controls for the
lack of economies of scale in the failure of ISI policies.

India led a particularly ambitious import substitution policy in the wake of its independence in
1947 and until the late 1970s. Its objective was to produce domestically a high proportion of
its consumption of most manufactured goods. By 1970, this goal was achieved to a
considerable extent (Krueger 1975). Meanwhile, despite its huge domestic market and relative
fast growth in manufacturing output, India has suffered regularly from hard currency
shortages and its growth rate in per capita terms was nonetheless anemic. It is worth studying
the policy tools and incentives and disincentives put in place at the time and how they
distorted economic decisions.

The import substitution goal was achieved through an intricate web of rules and regulations at
the center of which was the licensing system. Domestic producers were completely shielded
from international competition through restrictions on imports and sometimes import bans.
Moreover, domestic firms enjoyed extensive monopoly rents as domestic competition was
58

heavily curtailed. In parallel, cumbersome regulations were a constant burden on firms. To be


able to produce a certain good (finished or intermediate), an industrialist needed to apply for
several licenses including a capacity license allowing to produce a specific good and setting
total capacity and yearly production 37 as well as the number of shifts (and sometimes at the
level of specific models in the case of the car industry). To import inputs and machinery, a
separate license was needed to secure the foreign exchange needed. Even the technical support
associated with some machinery purchase had to be licensed separately as “foreign
collaboration” license (see Krueger 1975). Price controls were also applied in many industries
and the delays to get licenses approved could be in the order of several years.

These policies resulted in a situation where profits depended more on the ability to secure the
adequate licenses than on competition through improved productivity or innovation. 38 The
inability to produce continuously (as a result of power shortage, unavailable spare parts or raw
materials, and other administrative hurdles to import intermediate goods) also influenced the
type of technology adopted, which did not entail economies of scale and was less conducive
to learning-by-doing or R&D. For example, the automotive industry in 1970 was producing
models that were produced in other countries in the early 1950s (Krueger 1975). The policies
pursued were also detrimental to many firms that were prevented from integrating vertically
and had to rely on inefficient and often expensive suppliers. Some indigenous materials and
local machinery makes were banned from imports leading to prices up to tenfold international
prices.

Despite rules that forced firms to export some of their production in some industries or to
generate enough exports to cover their initial investment in machinery (e.g., firms producing
for more than 5 years had to export 5 percent of their output in the automotive industry),
exports generated rarely exceeded the minimum requirements, which were small to begin
with. Among the reasons cited, the heavy paperwork burden, the costly expansion of capacity,
the difficulty to meet continuously the stringent delivery deadlines and volumes in a context
of recurrent disruptions 39, and above all profit margins that were way too low compared to the
domestic market.

India’s import substitution policy, which is representative of the policies pursued by


developing economies in the 1960s and 1970s, contradicts key principles of TIP except for the
intervention to create domestic capabilities, which it did with relative success. Krueger (1975)
argues that many of the firms supported by ISI policies could compete globally if they had

37
The anecdote of a firm in the automotive industry reaching its production limit before end-year and asking its
entire staff to work on building a garden, illustrates the limits of the type of state micromanagement associated
with import substitution policies (Krueger 1975).
38
For example, some firms would strategically aim at over-capacity and the associated oversized rights to
intermediate goods imports, to drive out competitors.
39
A great source of uncertainty for potential exporters is that an input can be added to the list of banned imports,
provided a domestic firm justifies that it can ex ante meet local demand. However, firms may still fail to meet the
demand quantity and quality standards, costing the exporter several months of disruption while it tries to lift the
import ban.
59

access to raw materials and intermediate inputs, which were heavily restricted (e.g., licensing
requirements). She concludes that “By that criterion, import-substitution policies have been
highly successful” (Krueger 1975, p. 111). However, pushing domestic firms to compete on
international or domestic markets was far from a priority. On the contrary, monopoly rents on
the huge domestic market insured that firms had no serious interest in the difficult and risky
export markets. More important, achieving self-sufficiency in most tradable final goods did
not prevent India from suffering from hard currency shortages as it still relied on key imported
inputs such as raw materials and machinery. In other words, import substitution gives an
illusion of self-sufficiency while remaining vulnerable to external shocks.

Export Orientation, not Tariffs, is the Secret Ingredient

As mentioned earlier, export orientation has been a critical ingredient of the Asian miracles’
industrial policies. It represented a major departure from the import-substitution policies
adopted in most developing economies in the 1960s–1980s. On the surface, these two types of
policies, Asian miracles vs. the typical ISI that failed in the past, were similar. Both relied on
tariffs to protect their domestic markets and used subsidies to support domestic champions in
selected strategic sectors (see Wade 1990, Chang 2002 and Woo 1991). However, these
similarities, which are usually downplayed or simply ignored as they do not fit the standard
recipe, hide fundamental differences in the approaches taken.

In the typical developing economy, tariffs and other barriers to entry were meant to limit
competition on the domestic market, in some cases a public monopoly, and there was no
specific incentive to export and compete on international markets. This model can lead to
some successes in the sense that production would increase, and capabilities would improve.
This is consistent with the evidence shown in the 1970s–80s. However, over time, the lack of
competition would mean little investment in R&D and innovation and quasi-total dependence
on imported intermediate goods, especially critical high technologies. In relatively small
economies, the protected firms would have to put in place relatively small-scale production
units and would not take advantage of economies of scale. In large economies such India, ISI
policies would lead to sizable misallocation of factors, where inefficient firms would
perpetually survive, and efficient ones prevented from growing as a result of different
constraints such as access to imported inputs (see Krueger 1975 and Hsieh and Klenow 2009
for a more recent study). Even if these firms were well managed and were not captured by
well-connected individuals, they would perpetually depend on different types of protection
from international and domestic competition and on subsidies. In this context, domestic firms
would be extremely vulnerable to a combination of devaluation and lifting of tariffs as they
would see the cost of their inputs increase without an improvement in their competitiveness in
the absence of exports. Although textbook economics would predict a pick-up in exports
following a depreciation, in practice, firms cannot start exporting overnight. When eventually
these protections and support are lifted, typically in a phase of fiscal consolidation or currency
60

crisis, the ISI model becomes suddenly unsustainable and industrial policy ultimately doomed
to be a failed experiment. 40

In contrast, in the Asian miracles, tariffs were only a tool among many to promote exports by
ensuring a minimum rent for domestic producers while competition was fierce both at home
and abroad. The Asian miracles used all the tools available to ensure as much revenue as
possible to the whole sector but not necessarily to specific firms and they managed to get
away with it in the context of the cold war. More important, firms receiving support were
expected to export and were subject to strict accountability, including export quotas in Korea
(see Woo 1991) or preferred credit and tariff conditions in Taiwan Province of China (see
Wade 1990). Firms had to invest heavily in R&D and innovate to compete on international
markets. They would also have to set large production capacities, much larger than if they
were limited by the domestic market and reap the benefits of economies of scale. An ever-
increasing level of integration was sought to increase profitability and take advantage of lower
wages domestically, which was often the result of state intervention. 41 Exporting firms would
either integrate vertically or they would help create a network of suppliers by sending teams
of engineers to train their workers (see Wade 1990 and Chang 2002). Given enough time, and
under a strict accountability framework and exposed to intense competition in foreign
markets, exporting firms would become immune to lifting barriers and would even benefit
from a devaluation as their primary market was outside the country.

Export orientation prevents from falling in an illusion of economic “independence” and tariffs
are neither necessary nor sufficient to succeed. The contrast between ISI and export
orientation can be illustrated by the different paths followed by Korea’s Hyundai and
Malaysia’s Proton. 42 While Hyundai became a global brand and a highly successful and
innovative car maker, providing demand for a dense network of suppliers, Proton is a less
integrated automaker relying on critical imported inputs (e.g., Mitsubishi’s engine to this day)
with insignificant exports and a domestic market, which is challenged by foreign automakers
despite tariffs and subsidies.

In both countries, strong state intervention led to the creation of new capabilities in the 1970s
in the automotive industry. A mix of subsidies, tariffs to protect the domestic market as well
as joint-ventures and licensing agreements with Japanese and U.S. automakers helped
establish the first car makers in both countries. However, there were key differences in terms
of policies followed.

Proton never experienced the kind of strong push for exports and competition Hyundai faced
in Korea. The Korean conglomerate targeted aggressively foreign markets since the beginning
following a strategy described as “move first, then learn and adjust”. One of the first factories

40
These firms could even be profitable without subsidies as long as they can import inputs at a favorable
exchange rate and sell them on a domestic market with a high markup.
41
See Wade (1990) for the case of Taiwan Province of China.
42
See Cherif and Hasanov (2015) for more details and references.
61

built in the mid-80s had an annual capacity of 300,000 surpassing the total annual domestic
demand of Korea of 250,000 and solely dedicated to the U.S. market. It also built early on its
own network of car dealerships and advertisement in the U.S. In contrast, Proton remained
inward oriented with a modest production capacity compared to global players. When Proton
was trying to export to the U.S. market, it relied on local dealerships and could not build a
strong brand. It is reported that dealers would use the cheap Proton cars as bait and try to sell
more aggressively other more expensive brands. 43 In terms of local content, to this day Proton
still relies on a license from Mitsubishi to produce its engine while Hyundai leapfrogged
technologically in the 1980s and managed to design its own engine. Finally, Hyundai is one of
the few survivors of many attempts to set up global automotive players by other chaebols.

Can Laissez-Faire Be Worse than Import Substitution?

In contrast to Norway and most developing economies at the time, Chile followed a literal
version of “laissez-faire” policy until the early 1980s with disastrous effects. Among others, it
ruled out import substitution policies (e.g., it lifted tariffs unilaterally) and avoided sectoral
policies altogether founding its strategy on the expectation that comparative advantage sectors
would naturally emerge in the absence of state intervention, provided the business
environment and major government failures were tackled. As shown in Figure 25, this
strategy made Chile an outlier in a negative way. Over 1970–90, it witnessed a sizable loss in
terms of market share in manufacturing exports although it started from a relatively high
position compared to other developing economies. For example, in 1970, Chile’s
manufacturing export intensity was about 200 percent compared to a median of 5 percent in
developing economies and much greater than Malaysia’s, which was about 80 percent. In
1990, the situation was reversed where Chile’s MEI was about 70 percent and Malaysia’s
210 percent. More striking, while most developing economies managed to achieve relatively
high growth rates in their manufacturing output, Chiles manufacturing per capita grew at a
meagre annual rate of 0.35 percent compared to more than 8 percent in Malaysia, for example.

The 1982 crisis triggered a roll back of Chile’s laissez-faire experiment when it raised its tariff
on imports and re-introduced some sort of state intervention to spur export growth albeit
through indirect tools and favoring what it considered comparative advantage sectors such as
agroindustry. For example, over 1985-2003, the “reintegro simplificado” (simplified
reintegration) program provided an export subsidy to help firms export in non-traditional
sectors (Varas 2012). Later, in the 1990s and early 2000s, the Chilean Economic
Development Agency (CORFO), which focused on SMEs, helped facilitate funding and
technical assistance while Fundación Chile, which was based on a private-public partnership,
helped create start-up companies in projects promoting technology transfers. After Fundación
Chile helped adopt Norwegian technology in its nascent salmon industry, the industry took off
and remained its most successful case. Yet overall Chile still pursued the free market
approach, which indirectly translated to less interventionist policies for Fundación Chile

43
This asymmetry in incentives for car dealerships could explain why Tesla, which relies on its own network,
has been more successful than other firms in selling fully electric cars (see de Rubens et. al. 2018).
62

(Varas 2012). Interestingly, the main successes of Chile in non-mineral exports such as
salmon and blueberries can be attributed to its state interventions through these agencies.

Despite these successes and Chile’s relatively steady real GDP growth and macro-stability, its
productivity growth has lagged its peers. Chile’s GDP per capita relative to that of the U.S.
fluctuated in the range of about 20–30 percent since early 1960s until mid-2000s. This could
be explained by its focus on natural resources and low sophistication sectors such as
agroindustry in contrast to other natural resource producers such as Malaysia, Mexico and
Indonesia. They have outpaced Chile by a large margin in terms of export sophistication for
the past two decades. More striking, Chile’s total factor productivity has stagnated since 1970
(see Cherif and Hasanov 2015).

Earlier Miracles in Advanced Economies and the Forgotten Hand of the State

“Late late comers”, as the Asian miracles are usually described in the development literature
(see Amsden 2003), are not the only ones that used state intervention to steer the economy
into specific industries. As argued by Chang (2002), there is strong evidence that the catching
up of the original “late comers,” i.e. Japan, Germany and before them the United States, show
similar patterns.

Alexander Hamilton, the first secretary of the Treasury of the United States, outlined a
strategy to promote manufacturing to catch up with Britain (Hamilton 1791). Chang (2002)
and Cohen and De Long (2016) argue that the economic dominance of the U.S. was the result
of a stream of visionary market-distorting state interventions which started with Alexander
Hamilton. Among the policies they cite, protectionism and intervention to develop research
appear to have played a prominent role to develop infant industries.

High tariffs to protect nascent manufacturing industries had been a landmark of U.S.
economic policy since Alexander Hamilton until after Second World War. For example, at the
turn of the 20th century, when Argentina and the U.S. had similar levels of income per capita,
tariff on manufactured goods were about 45 percent in the former and about 5 percent in
Argentina, the highest and the lowest among the advanced countries, respectively. Moreover,
state directed research and development to acquire new technologies has also been an integral
part of Hamilton’s strategy and, although it has changed in its form, the tradition has
continued to the present. One would see the same pattern in the development of Germany and
Japan (see Chang 2002).

To this day, there are still strong elements of industrial policy in advanced economies albeit in
a quite indirect form. Mazzucato (2013) studies the direct contribution of government
programs to what is commonly thought of as private innovations. For example, she shows that
many components of the Apple iPhone, the product that made Apple one of the biggest
companies in the world by market valuation, including its path-breaking touch screen
technology, were originally developed thanks to government subsidies and in particular from
defense programs. The same applies to what is considered as a key innovation in the last two
decades, the internet and computers. O’Mara (2004) shows that the origins of Silicon Valley’s
63

rise are strongly related to the prodigious defense and space programs during the cold war, in
particular through procurement policies.

Other industrial policy tools were used in advanced economies. The German development
bank KfW, played a major role in the reconstruction of the country after the Second World
War (see Naqvi, Henow, and Chang 2018). The public bank targeted among others
sophisticated tools and machinery industries which later became the engine of the German
economy. To this day, the bank plays an important role with assets representing 14 percent of
GDP in 2016 and about 6 percent of the banking sector (more than 500 billion euros). As an
example of its leading role in technological leapfrogging, the public bank financed close to
100 percent of all the projects in renewable energy between 2007 and 2009 in the early stages
of the “Energiewende” drive. The private sector has since gradually increased its share of
financing but only after the government undertook most of the risky initial investment.

VII. CONCLUDING REMARKS

We argue that the success of the Asian Miracles was not a matter of luck but the result of TIP.
Although they were not hit with severe negative shocks or possessed some intrinsic
characteristics for success, their high sustained growth was the outcome of the implementation
of an ambitious technology and innovation policy over decades that kept adapting to changing
conditions and moving to the next level of sophistication. The state set ambitious goals,
managed to adapt fast, and imposed accountability for its support to industries and firms. We
argue that first, TIP was based on the state intervention to facilitate the move of domestic
firms into sophisticated sectors beyond the existing comparative advantage. Second, export
orientation since the onset played a key role in sustaining competitive pressure and pushing
firms to innovate. This strategy contrasts with import substitution industrialization strategies,
prevalent until the late 1980s among developing economies, that led to inefficiencies, lack of
innovation, and persistent dependence on key imported inputs. Finally, the discipline of the
market and accountability were enforced in a strict manner.

We interpret the various degrees of success of developing economies in achieving a higher


income status as corresponding to different levels of ambition and policies pursued in
conducting TIP. The more a country was willing to leap technologically beyond comparative
advantage and the more this technology was produced by domestic firms, the higher the
chances were to sustain high growth.

Most countries in the middle-income trap have followed some elements of TIP, notably by
attracting MNCs and joining GVCs of sophisticated products, but they have mostly failed in
developing their own technology at the frontier or moving away from low R&D intensity
sectors such as natural resource extraction. Relatively successful countries such as Chile and
Malaysia have managed to solve a great deal of government failures while developing new
exports such as salmon and blueberries in Chile and rubber and palm oil in Malaysia, but
mostly relying on foreign technologies. Meanwhile, the Asian miracles were moving to the
64

frontier, undertaking long-term and risky projects in automotive and electronics while
developing own technologies in these fields.

For the other countries stagnating or falling behind, we argue that either the policies they
followed do not qualify as TIP, given the criteria we have established, or it is difficult to
disentangle bad luck from bad policies. Most developing countries have attempted some type
of industrial policy in the past and there are many examples of failures. For example,
industrial policy in the automotive industry in Malaysia and India failed in the past but they
were conducted within an ISI framework, which was the rule rather than the exception in the
1960s-1980s. Other examples such as the aircraft industry in Indonesia in the past do not
provide sufficient evidence against TIP. Perhaps Indonesia was hit with bad luck with the
Asian crisis of 1998 and could have emulated the success of EMBRAER in Brazil if given
more time.

We gave a broad definition of TIP, but it would be useful to clarify what it is not. Our
argument is not that TIP succeeds in every sector every time or that it does not entail risks.
Rather, we argue that TIP offers broad concepts of a growth strategy, the modalities (e.g.,
tools) of which are yet to be defined. We also do not argue that the tools traditionally
associated with industrial policy, such as subsidies, tariffs and the use of SOEs 44, are
necessarily effective ways to pursue TIP. Some of these policies could in fact explain the
failures of industrial policy in the past. In terms of the role of state, TIP is the exact opposite
of centralized planning, as it favors more competition and autonomy of the private sector, not
less. The role of the state to intervene is to correct market failures where they exist and
enforce a strict market discipline. As such, it is the exact opposite of indefinite support for
under-performing, under-innovating and rent-seeking firms. We are not arguing that TIP is
easy to pursue or that there is a cookbook recipe. For example, how to select sectors or
enforce a strict market discipline is still an uncharted territory, but it is an important area to
explore.

More important, TIP is not in opposition to the standard recipe of macro-stability, improving
institutions and business environment, or investing in infrastructure and human capital. All
these ingredients are necessary, but not necessarily sufficient for high sustained growth.
Through the lens of TIP, policymakers can set clearer priorities for their growth strategies,
and we argue that higher and more sustained growth is more probable. The Asian Miracles
correspond to the most ambitious version of TIP, which led them from low-income to high-
income status in a couple of generations. But there is a spectrum of possibilities depending on
domestic and external conditions and how ambitious the authorities are and how willing they
are to implement TIP.

44
The public sector is not necessarily unfit for the task as the example of Singapore shows, where the
government-linked companies played a significant role in the economy since independence and are run
efficiently on a competitive and commercial basis (Ramirez and Tan 2004).
65

To apply the principles of TIP, one would need to specify the strategies that countries can use
depending on their own circumstances. This entails addressing questions such as what specific
sectors to focus on, what type of institutions to build, and what types of skills and
infrastructure to acquire, and how to do so. Cherif and Hasanov (forthcoming) attempt to
address these issues in a follow-up paper.
66

REFERENCES

Abramovitz, Moses. 1986. “Catching Up, Forging Ahead, and Falling Behind.” Journal of
Economic History 46(2): 385–406.

Acemoglu, Daron, Philippe Aghion, and Fabrizio Zilibotti, 2006. “Distance to Frontier,
Selection, and Economic Growth,” Journal of the European Economic Association,
4(1): 37–74.

Acemoglu, Daron, and James A. Robinson. 2012. Why Nations Fail: The Origins of Power,
Prosperity and Poverty. 1st ed. New York: Crown.

Aghion, Philippe and Peter Howitt. 1992. “A Model of Growth Through Creative
Destruction” Econometrica 60: 323–51.

Aghion, Philippe. 2016. “Growth Policy Design for Middle-Income Countries.” In Cherif,
Reda, Fuad Hasanov, and Min Zhu (editors), Breaking the Oil Spell: The Gulf
Falcons’ Path to Diversification. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund
Press.

Amsden, Alice. 1989. Asia’s Next Giant: South Korea and Late Industrialization. Oxford:
Oxford University Press.

Amsden, Alice. 2003. The Rise of “The Rest”: Challenges to the West from Late-
Industrializing Economies. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Arezki, Rabah, Reda Cherif, and John Piotrowski. 2009. “Tourism Specialization and
Economic Development: Evidence from the UNESCO World Heritage List,” IMF
Working Paper 09/176. (Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund)

Arrow, Kenneth. 1962. “The Economic Implications of Learning by Doing.” The Review of
Economic Studies 29(3): 155–73.

Balassa, Bela and Marcus Noland, 1989. “Revealed Comparative Advantage in Japan and the
United States,” Journal of International Economic Integration 2 (2): 8–22.

Bartelme, Dominick and Yuriy Gorodnichenko. 2015. “Linkages and Economic


Development.” BEHL Working Paper WP2015–07.

Bazzi, Samuel and Michael A. Clemens. 2013. “Blunt Instruments: Avoiding Common
Pitfalls in Identifying the Causes of Economic Growth,” American Economic Journal:
Macroeconomics 5(2): 152–86.

Benhassine, Najy and Gael Raballand. 2009. “Beyond Ideological Cleavages: A Unifying
Framework for Industrial Policies and Other Public Interventions.” Economic Systems
33(4): 293–309.
67

Berg, Andrew, Jonathan D. Ostry, and Jeromin Zettelmeyer. 2012. “What Makes Growth
Sustained?” Journal of Development Economics 98(2): 149–66.

Berger, Suzanne. 2011. “Why Manufacturing Matters.” MIT Technology Review July 1.
Available: https://www.technologyreview.com/s/424554/why-manufacturing-matters/.

Best, Michael. 2007. “Cluster Dynamics in Malaysian Electronics,” in Jomo K. S. (ed.),


Malaysian Industrial Policy, Singapore: National University of Singapore Press, 249–
76.

Boulton, William. 1997. “Hong Kong-South China Electronics Industry.” In Electronics


Manufacturing in the Pacific Rim, Michael Kelly and William Boulton (eds). WTEC
Panel Report, Loyola College in Maryland.

Bulman, David, Maya Eden, and Ha Nguyen, 2012. “Transitioning from Low-Income Growth
to High-Income Growth: Is there a Middle-Income Trap?” World Bank, background
paper for G-20 Meeting, June.

Callen, Tim, Reda Cherif, and Fuad Hasanov. 2016. “Introduction.” In Cherif, Reda, Fuad
Hasanov, and Min Zhu (editors), Breaking the Oil Spell: The Gulf Falcons’ Path to
Diversification. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund Press.

Cermeño, Alexandra L. 2018a. “The driving forces of service localization during the twentieth
century: evidence from the United States.” European Review of Economic History,
Online.

Cermeño, Alexandra L. 2018b. “The transformation of the Manufacturing Belt: How market
size drove the localisation of knowledge hubs.” VoxEU. 23 May. Available:
https://voxeu.org/article/how-market-size-drove-localisation-knowledge-hubs-us.

Chang, Ha-Joon. 2002. Kicking Away the Ladder: Development Strategy in Historical
Perspective. London: Anthem Press.

Chang, Ha-Joon. 2009. “Industrial Policy: Can We Go Beyond an Unproductive


Confrontation?” Annual World Bank Conference on Development Economics, Seoul,
South Korea, June 22–24.

Chang, Ha-Joon. 2013. “Industrial Policy: From Ideology to Pragmatism,” presentation at the
World Bank conference on Making Growth Happen: Implementing Policies for
Competitive Industries, October.

Chang, Ha-Joon and Antonio Andreoni. 2016. “Industrial Policy in a Changing World: Basic
Principles, Neglected Issues and New Challenges,” 40 Years of the Cambridge Journal
of Economics Conference, Cambridge, July 13.

Chang, Ha-Joon and Justin Lin. 2009. “Should Industrial Policy in Developing Countries
Conform to Comparative Advantage or Defy it? A Debate Between Justin Lin and Ha-
Joon Chang,” Development Policy Review, 27, September: 483–502.
68

Chen, Edward K.Y. 1987. “Foreign Trade and Economic Growth in Hong Kong: Experience
and Prospects.” In NBER’s Trade and Structural Change in Pacific Asia, Colin I.
Bradford, Jr. and William H. Branson (eds). Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press,
333–78.

Cherif, Reda. 2013. “The Dutch Disease and the Technological Gap.” Journal of
Development Economics 101(C): 248–55.

Cherif, Reda, and Fuad Hasanov. 2013. “Oil Exporters’ Dilemma: How Much to Save and
How Much to Invest.” World Development 52 (C): 120–31.

Cherif, Reda and Fuad Hasanov. 2015. “The Leap of the Tiger: How Malaysia can Escape the
Middle-Income Trap,” IMF Working Paper 15/131. (Washington, DC: International
Monetary Fund)

Cherif, Reda and Fuad Hasanov. 2016. “Soaring of the Gulf Falcons: Diversification in GCC
Oil Exporters in Seven Propositions.” In Cherif, Reda, Fuad Hasanov, and Min Zhu
(editors), Breaking the Oil Spell: The Gulf Falcons’ Path to Diversification.
Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund Press.

Cherif, Reda and Fuad Hasanov. Forthcoming. “The Return of the Policy that Shall Not Be
Named: Strategies of Industrial Policy.” Working paper.

Cherif, Reda, Fuad Hasanov, and Alfred Kammer. 2016. “Lessons for Today and the Way
Forward.” In Cherif, Reda, Fuad Hasanov, and Min Zhu (editors), Breaking the Oil
Spell: The Gulf Falcons’ Path to Diversification. Washington, DC: International
Monetary Fund Press.

Cherif, Reda, Fuad Hasanov, and Lichen Wang. 2018. “Sharp Instrument: A Stab at
Identifying the Causes of Economic Growth.” IMF Working Paper WP/18/117.
(Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund)

Clauset, A., C.R. Shalizi, and M.E.J. Newman. 2009. “Power-law Distributions in Empirical
Data” SIAM Review 51(4): 661–703.

Cohen, Stephen and Bradford DeLong. 2016. Concrete Economics: The Hamilton Approach
to Economic Growth and Policy. Harvard Business Review Press.

Criscuolo, Chiara, Ralf Martin, Henry G. Overman, and John Van Reenen. 2019. “Some
Causal Effects of an Industrial Policy,” American Economic Review 109(1): 48–85.

De Rubens, G. Z., L. Noel, and B. K. Savacool. 2018. “Dismissive and Deceptive Car
Dealerships Create Barriers to Electric Vehicle Adoption at the Point of Sale,” Nature
Energy 3: 501–07.

Devan, Janamitra. 2011. “Strengthening Industrial Competitiveness to Promote Job Creation.”


A speech delivered at the conference organized by Trade and Industrial Policies
Strategies (TIPS) and World Bank in Pretoria, South Africa, October 27.
69

Diao, Xinshen, Margaret McMillan, and Dani Rodrik. 2017. “The Recent Growth Boom in
Developing Economies: A Structural Change Perspective.” NBER Working Paper No.
23132.

Easterly, William. 1995. “Explaining Miracles: Growth Regressions Meet the Gang of Four,”
In Growth Theories in Light of the East Asian Experience, NBER-EASE Volume 4:
National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc., 267–99.

Eichengreen, Barry, Donghyun Park, and Kwanho Shin, 2013. “Growth Slowdowns Redux:
New Evidence on the Middle-Income Trap,” NBER Working Paper No. 18673.

Eichengreen, Barry. 2016. “Confronting the Fiscal Bogeyman.” Project Syndicate column,
March 11.

Fallows, James. 1995. Looking at the Sun: The Rise of the New East Asian Economic and
Political System. Vintage (first published in 1994).

Feenstra, Robert and John Romalis. 2014. “International Prices and Endogenous Quality.” The
Quarterly Journal of Economics 129(2): 477–527.

Feenstra, Robert C., Robert Inklaar and Marcel P. Timmer. 2015. “The Next Generation of the
Penn World Table.” American Economic Review 105(10): 3150-3182. Available for
download at www.ggdc.net/pwt.

Felker, Greg. 2001. “The Politics of Industrial Investment Policy Reform in Malaysia and
Thailand,” in Jomo K. S. (ed.), Southeast Asia’s Industrialization: Industrial Policy,
Capabilities and Sustainability, New York: Palgrave, 129–82.

Gabaix, Xavier. 2009. “Power Laws in Economics and Finance,” Annual Review of
Economics 1(1): 255–94.

Gerschenkron, Alexander, 1962. Economic Backwardness in Historical Perspective, Harvard


University Press.

Ghani, Ejaz, Arti Grover Goswami, and Homi Kharas. 2011. “Can services be the next growth
escalator?” VoxEU. December 12. Available: https://voxeu.org/article/can-services-
be-next-growth-escalator.

Ghani, Ejaz and Homi Kharas. 2010. The Service Revolution. Economic Premise No 14.
World Bank. (Washington, DC: World Bank Group)

Ghani, Ejaz and Stephen O’Connell. 2014. “Can Service be a Growth Escalator in Low-
Income Countries?”, World Bank Policy Research Working Paper Series 6971.

Hall, Frederic S. 1902. “The Localization of Industries.” Bulletin of the Twelfth Census of the
United States.

Hallegatte, Stéphane, Marianne Fay, and Adrien Vogt-Schilb. 2013. “Green Industrial
Policies: When and How.” World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 6677.
70

Hallward-Driemeier, Mary and Gaurav Nayyar. 2017. Trouble in the Making? The Future of
Manufacturing-Led Development. Washington, DC: World Bank.

Hamilton, Alexander. 1791. Report on the Subject of Manufactures. Presented to Congress on


December 5.

Harrison, Ann and Andrés Rodríguez-Clare. 2010. “Trade, Foreign Investment, and Industrial
Policy for Developing Countries.” In Dani Rodrik and Mark Rosenzweig, editors:
Handbook of Development Economics 5, The Netherlands: North-Holland,
pp. 4039–214.

Harrison, Ann, Leslie A. Martin, and Shanthi Nataraj. 2017. “Green Industrial Policy in
Emerging Markets.” Annual Review of Resource Economics 9:253–274.

Hausmann, Ricardo, Jason Hwang, and Dani Rodrik, 2007. “What You Export Matters,”
Journal of Economic Growth, 12(1), March: 1–25.

Hausmann, Ricardo, Lant Pritchett, and Dani Rodrik. 2005. “Growth Accelerations” Journal
of Economic Growth 10(4): 303–29.

Hausmann, Ricardo. 2015a. “The Role of Productive Development Policies.” Presentation at


the Inter-American Development Bank’s Policy Dialogue, Washington, DC, May 14.

Hausmann, Ricardo. 2015b. “What are the Challenges of Economic Growth?” Available:
http://growthlab.cid.harvard.edu/publications/what-are-challenges-economic-growth.

Hausmann, Ricardo, Luis Espinoza, and Miguel Angel Santos. 2015. “The Low Productivity
Trap: Growth Diagnostics of Chiapas.” Executive Summary. Center for International
Development Working Paper 304, Harvard University.

Henry, Peter Blair and Conrad Miller. 2009. “Institutions versus Policies: A Tale of Two
Islands.” American Economic Review 99(2): 261–67.

Herrendorf, Berthold and Akos Valentinyi. 2012. “Which Sectors Make Poor Countries So
Unproductive?” Journal of the European Economic Association 10(2): 323–41.

Heum, P. 2008. “Local Content Development – Experiences from Oil and Gas Activities in
Norway,” SNF, Bergen.

Hirschman, Albert, 1958. The Strategy of Economic Development. New Haven, Conn.: Yale
University Press.

Hlatshwayo, Sandile and Michael Spence. 2014. “Demand and Defective Growth Patterns:
The Role of the Tradable and Non-Tradable Sectors in an Open Economy.” American
Economic Review: Papers & Proceedings 104(5): 272–77.

Hsieh, Chang-Tai. 2002. “What Explains the Industrial Revolution in East Asia? Evidence
from the Factor Markets,” American Economic Review 92(3): 502–26.
71

Hsieh, Chang-Tai and P. Klenow. 2009. “Misallocation and Manufacturing TFP in China and
India.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 124(4): 1403–48.

Inter-American Development Bank. 2014. Rethinking Productive Development: Sound


Policies and Institutions for Economic Transformation. IDB: Washington, DC.

International Monetary Fund. 2016. Central, Eastern, and Southeastern Europe: How to Get
Back on the Fast Track. Regional Economic Issues, May.

International Monetary Fund. 2018. “Manufacturing Jobs: Implications for Productivity and
Inequality,” World Economic Outlook, Chapter 3, April.

Johnson, Chalmers. 1982. MITI and the Japanese Miracle: The Growth of Industrial Policy,
1925-1975. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.

Johnson, Paul and Chris Papageorgiou. Forthcoming. “What Remains of Cross-Country


Convergence?” Journal of Economic Literature.

Jomo K. S., Chen Yun Chung, Brian Folk, Irfan ul-Haque, Pasuk Phongpaichit, Batara
Simatupang, and Mayuri Tateishi. 1997. Southeast Asia’s Misunderstood Miracle:
Industrial Policy and Economic Development in Thailand, Malaysia, and Indonesia.
Westview Press, Oxford.

Juhász, Réka. 2018. “Temporary Protection and Technology Adoption: Evidence from the
Napoleonic Blockade,” American Economic Review 108(11): 3339–76.

Kalouptsidi, Myrto. 2018. “Detection and Impact of Industrial Subsidies: The Case of Chinese
Shipbuilding.” Review of Economic Studies 85(2): 1111–58.

Kang, Joonkyu. 2001. “A Study of the DRAM Industry.” Massachusetts Institute of


Technology Sloan School of Management. Master’s thesis.

Kavlaka, Goksin, James McNerneya, and Jessika E. Trancik. 2018. “Evaluating the Causes of
Cost Reduction in Photovoltaic Modules.” Energy Policy 123: 700–10.

Knowledge@Wharton. 2017. “DowDuPont’s Andrew Liveris: How America Can Bring Back
Manufacturing.” October 12. Available:
http://knowledge.wharton.upenn.edu/article/dowduponts-andrew-liveris-america-can-
bring-back-manufacturing/.

Krueger, Anne. 1975. The Benefits and Costs of Import Substitution in India. St. Paul, MN:
University of Minnesota Press.

Krugman, Paul. 1987. “The Narrow Moving Band, the Dutch Disease, and the Competitive
Consequences of Mrs. Thatcher: Notes on Trade in the Presence of Dynamic Scale
Economies,” Journal of Development Economics 27(1-2): 41–55.

Krugman, Paul. 1994. “Competitiveness: A Dangerous Obsession.” Foreign Affairs 73(2):


28–44.
72

Krugman, Paul. 1994. ‘‘The Myth of Asia’s Miracle,’’ Foreign Affairs 73: 62–78.

Lane, Nathan. 2017. “Manufacturing Revolutions: Industrial Policy and Networks in South
Korea.” Working paper, Institute for International Economic Studies, Stockholm.

Leskinen, Olivia, Paul Klouman Bekken, Haja Razafinjatovo, and Manuel García 2012.
“Norway Oil and Gas Cluster: A Story of Achieving Success through Supplier
Development,” Harvard Business School.

Lin, Justin. 2012. The Quest for Prosperity: How Developing Economies Can Take Off.
Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

List, Friedrich. 1885. The National System of Political Economy, translated from the
original German edition published in 1841 by Sampson Lloyd. London: Longmans,
Green, and Company.

Liu, Ernest. 2017. “Industrial Policy in Production Networks.” Working paper, Princeton
University.

Low, Linda. 2001. “The Role of the Government in Singapore’s Industrialization,” in Jomo K.
S. (ed.), Southeast Asia’s Industrialization: Industrial Policy, Capabilities and
Sustainability, New York: Palgrave, 113–28.

Lucas, Robert Jr., 1988. “On the Mechanics of Economic Development.” Journal of
Monetary Economics 22, 3–42.

Lucas, Robert Jr., 1993. “Making a Miracle,” Econometrica, 61(2), March: 251–72.

Marshall, Alfred. 1880. Principles of Economics. Chapter 10, London, U.K.: MacMillan.

McMillan, M., and D. Rodrik. 2011. “Globalization, Structural Change, and Productivity
Growth.” NBER Working Paper 17143.

Mazzucato, Mariana, 2013. The Entrepreneurial State: Debunking Public vs. Private Sector
Myths. New York: Public Affairs.

Monnery, Neil. 2017. Architect of Prosperity: Sir John Cowperthwaite and the Making of
Hong Kong. London: London Publishing Partnership.

Murphy, Kevin M., Andrei Shleifer, Robert W. Vishny. 1989. “Industrialization and the Big
Push,” Journal of Political Economy 97(5): 1003–26.

Naqvi, Natalya, Anne Henow, and Ha-Joon Chang. 2018. “Kicking Away the Financial
Ladder: German Development Banking under Economic Globalisation.” Review of
International Political Economy, Online.

Newman, M. E. J., A. Reggiani, and P. Nijkamp. 2005. “Power Laws, Pareto Distributions
and Zipf's Law.” Cities 30: 323–51.
73

Ocampo, Jose Antonio, Lance Taylor and Codrina Rada. 2009. Growth and Policy in
Developing Countries: A Structuralist Approach. New York: Columbia University
Press.

O’Mara, Margaret. 2004. Cities of Knowledge: Cold War Science and the Search for the Next
Silicon Valley. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

Ramalingam, Ben. 2013. Aid on the Edge of Chaos: Rethinking International Cooperation in
a Complex World. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Ramírez, Carlos and Ling Hui Tan. 2004. “Singapore Inc. versus the Private Sector: Are
Government-Linked Companies Different?” IMF Staff Papers 51(3): 510–28.

Rasiah, Rajah. 2004. “Foreign Ownership, Technological Intensities, and Network Strengths:
Electronics Firms in East Asia,” OECD conference paper on The Impact and
Coherence of OECD Country Policies on Asian Developing Economies.

Rasiah, Rajah. 2007. “R&D and Export Intensities in Automotive Parts Firms in China,
Malaysia, Philippines and Taiwan: Does Ownership Matter?” RIETI Discussion Paper
Series.

Rodrik, Dani. 2005. “Growth Strategies,” in Philippe Aghion & Steven Durlauf (ed.),
Handbook of Economic Growth, edition 1, volume 1, chapter 14, Oxford: Elsevier,
967–1014.

Rodrik, Dani. 2012. “Why We Learn Nothing from Regressing Economic Growth on
Policies,” Seoul Journal of Economics 25(2): 137–51.

Rodrik, Dani. 2013. “Unconditional Convergence in Manufacturing,” The Quarterly Journal


of Economics 128(1), February, pp. 165–204.

Rodrik, Dani. 2016. “Premature Deindustrialization,” Journal of Economic Growth 21(1),


pp.1–33.

Romer, Paul. 1990. “Endogenous Technological Change,” Journal of Political Economy


98(5), pp. S71–102.

Rumbelow, Helen. 2017. “Don’t Mess with Mariana Mazzucato, the World’s Scariest
Economist.” The Times, November 17.

Sasson, Amir and Atle Blomgren 2011. “Knowledge Based Oil and Gas Industry,”
Knowledge-based Norway, March, Report No. 4.

Senhadji, Abdelhak. 2000. “Sources of Economic Growth: An Extensive Growth Accounting


Exercise.” IMF Staff Papers 47(1): 129–57.

Stiglitz, Joseph and Bruce Greenwald. 2014. Creating a Learning Society. New York, NY:
Columbia University Press.
74

The Economist. 2016. “The End of the Line.” February 6. Available:


https://www.economist.com/international/2016/02/06/the-end-of-the-line.

Timmer, M. P., G. J. de Vries, and K. de Vries. 2015. “Patterns of Structural Change in


Developing Countries.” In J. Weiss and M. Tribe (Eds.), Routledge Handbook of
Industry and Development Routledge: 65–83.

Trade and Industry Department. 2018. “Support to Hong Kong Industries.” The Government
of the Hong Kong Special Administrative Region. Online. Accessed November 2018.
Available:
https://www.tid.gov.hk/english/smes_industry/industry/industry_content.html.

Tran, Van Tho. 2013. “The Middle-Income Trap: Issues for Members of the Association of
Southeast Asian Nations,” Asian Development Bank Institute Working Paper 421.

Wade, Robert. 2018. “The Development State: Dead or Alive? Development and Change
49(2): 518–46.

Wade, Robert. 1990. Governing the Market. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

Warwick, K. 2013. “Beyond Industrial Policy: Emerging Issues and New Trends,” OECD
Science, Technology and Industry Policy Papers, No. 2, OECD Publishing, Paris.

Weiss, John. 2005. “Export Growth and Industrial Policy: Lessons from the East Asian
Miracle Experience.” ADB Institute Discussion Paper No. 26.

Woo, Meredith. 1991. Race to the Swift: State and Finance in Korean Industrialization. New
York: Columbia University Press.

Varas, Maria Elena. 2012. “Economic Diversification: The Case of Chile,” Revenue Watch
Institute.

Young, Alwyn. 1991. “Learning by Doing and the Dynamic Effects of International Trade,"
The Quarterly Journal of Economics106(2): 369–405.

Young, Alwyn. 1995. “The Tyranny of Numbers: Confronting the Statistical Realities of the
East Asian Growth Experience,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 110 (August
1995): 641–80.
75

APPENDIX I. TABLES

Table 1. Taiwan Province of China: Machinery and Transport Equipment Top RCAs Industries
1970
sitc4 Description RCA Expport share
7241 Textile and leather machinery, and parts thereof, nes 9.0 2.7%
7242 Textile and leather machinery, and parts thereof, nes 8.3 3.2%
7231 Civil engineering, contractors plant and equipment and parts, nes 3.4 0.9%
7173 Parts, nes, of rotating electric plant 3.1 0.5%
7331 Metalworking machinery 2.9 0.3%
72XX Parts, nes of machines in headings 72348, 72721, and 72842-72848 2.8 0.0%
7293 Parts, nes of machines in headings 72348, 72721, and 72842-72848 2.7 1.4%
7292 Parts, nes of machines in headings 72348, 72721, and 72842-72848 2.3 0.3%
7299 Parts, nes of machines in headings 72348, 72721, and 72842-72848 2.2 1.1%
7249 Machinery for preparing, tanning, working leather, etc; parts nes 2.0 1.8%
7291 Parts, nes of machines in headings 72348, 72721, and 72842-72848 1.7 0.2%
7329 Metalworking machinery 1.5 0.4%
7221 Tractors (other than those falling in heading 74411 and 7832) 1.1 0.6%
Note
72348 Machines and mechanical appliance for public works, nes
72721 Machines, appliances for animal, vegetable fats and oils industry
72842 Machines for the rubber and plastics materials industries, nes
72843 Machines and mechanical appliances for the tobacco industry, nes
72844 Machines and mechanical appliances for treating wood, nes
72845 Machines and mechanical appliances for treating metals, nes
72846 Machines and mechanical appliances for treating metals, nes
72847 Machines and mechanical appliances for treating metals, nes
72848 Other machinery, mechanical appliances having individual functions

Table 2. Taiwan Province of China: Machinery and Transport Equipment Top Export Industries
1990
sitc4 Description RCA Expport share
7525 Peripheral units, including control and adapting units 3.9 3.2%
7599 Parts, nes of and accessories for machines of headings 7512 and 752 2.4 3.1%
7764 Electronic microcircuits 1.6 2.2%
7523 Complete digital central processing units; digital processors 3.0 1.8%
7649 Parts, nes of and accessories for apparatus falling in heading 76 2.2 1.6%
7852 Cycles, not motorized 20.2 1.4%
7788 Other electrical machinery and equipment, nes 2.4 1.3%
7731 Insulated electric wire, cable, bars, etc 2.8 1.1%
7721 Switches, relays, fuses, etc; switchboards and control panels, nes 1.3 1.0%
7284 Machinery for specialized industries and parts thereof, nes 1.1 1.0%
7522 Complete digital data processing machines 3.6 1.0%
7528 Off-line data processing equipment, nes 3.8 0.9%
7853 Invalid carriages; parts, nes of articles of heading 785 6.2 0.8%
Note
7512 Calculating, accounting, cash registers, ticketing, etc, machines
752 Automatic data processing machines and units thereof
76 Telecommunications, sound recording and reproducing equipment
785 Cycles, scooters, motorized or not; invalid carriages
Source: UN COMTRADE and World Trade Flows (Feenstra and Romalis 2014).
76

Table 3. Korea: Machinery and Transport Equipment Top RCAs Industries 1970
sitc4 Description RCA Expport share
7242 Textile and leather machinery, and parts thereof, nes 1.6 0.6%
7292 Parts, nes of machines in headings 72348, 72721, and 72842-72848 1.8 0.2%
7293 Parts, nes of machines in headings 72348, 72721, and 72842-72848 6.8 3.4%
Note
72348 Machines and mechanical appliance for public works, nes
72721 Machines, appliances for animal, vegetable fats and oils industry
72842 Machines for the rubber and plastics materials industries, nes
72843 Machines and mechanical appliances for the tobacco industry, nes
72844 Machines and mechanical appliances for treating wood, nes
72845 Machines and mechanical appliances for treating metals, nes
72846 Machines and mechanical appliances for treating metals, nes
72847 Machines and mechanical appliances for treating metals, nes
72848 Other machinery, mechanical appliances having individual functions

Table 4. Korea: Machinery and Transport Equipment Top Export Industries 1990
sitc4 Description RCA Expport share
7764 Electronic microcircuits 4.5 5.9%
7932 Ships, boats and other vessels 5.2 2.4%
7525 Peripheral units, including control and adapting units 2.3 1.9%
7611 Television receivers, colour 3.8 1.9%
7638 Other sound recording and reproducer, nes; video recorders 3.9 1.7%
7649 Parts, nes of and accessories for apparatus falling in heading 76 1.8 1.4%
7761 Television picture tubes, cathode ray 7.4 1.0%
7621 Radio receivers for motor-vehicles 7.7 1.0%
7758 Electro-thermic appliances, nes 3.7 0.9%
7861 Trailers and transports containers 7.8 0.9%
Note
76 Telecommunications, sound recording and reproducing equipment
Source: UN COMTRADE and World Trade Flows (Feenstra and Romalis 2014).
77

APPENDIX II. FIGURES

Figure 1: Short-term Relationship Between Manufacturing Exports and Output,


1990–2010

3
TZA

SEN
COL
2

CHL PHL ZAF


CRI
PER BRA THA
ETH IDN
MYS
Elasticity

MEX
MUS
BOL
1

EGY
GHA IND

ARG
CHN
VEN
KEN
0

ZMB
NGA
MWI
-1

0 .2 .4 .6 .8
R-squared

Source: GGDC and WDI.

Figure 2. Manufacturing Export Market Share Change, 1970–1990


Change in relative manufacturing export market share
3

KOR
2

PRT
CYP MUS
ESP
MYS
1

LBR HUN LCA


GRC VGBTUN
SYC THA
URY
JOR ATG TUR DMA
POL
PAN FJI MEX
VEN DOM
MAR VCT GRD
SYR PHL BRALKA IDN
DJI ARG ZWE
HTI ALB COL
CPV
PRY NER
NPL
MNG MDV
ECU
IRQ BTN
0

MDGTCD
KHMSLE
GNB MMR
TZA
MOZ SDNRWA
GMB
STP
MLI VNM
BFA
MWI
TGO
MRT BLZ BDI
IND
LAONGA
KEN BGR BEN
AGO GHA UGACAF ZAF
GNQ
BOL
HND
CIV
SEN CRI
CMR DZA
EGY
COG KNAIRN
PAK OMN
NIC PER SLV GTM GIN
COM
GAB
COD TTO
LBN
JAM
-1

CHL

-5 0 5 10 15
Manufacturing (avg. growth per capita)

Source: UN and WDI.


78

Figure 3. Manufacturing Export Market Share Change, 1990–2010

Change in relative manufacturing export market share


4
SGP
2 KOR

MYS
CRI

THA
MEX
CHL CHN
ZAF
ZMB PHL ARGIDN
EGY
COL BOL PER
NGA
BRA TZA IND
0

KEN MWI
SEN
GHA ETH
VEN

MUS
-2

0 5 10 15
Manufacturing (avg. growth per capita)

Source: GGDC and WDI.

Figure 4. Manufacturing Export Market Share Change, 1990–2010


Change in relative manufacturing export market share

HUN
4

VGB

SGP
KOR
2

MYS POL
CRI
TTO
MEX BGR THA
PAN CHL OMN
ZAF TUR ABW VNM
ESP
VCTALBKNA
COG SLVLBN KHM GNQ
TCA ZMB
GTMPHL
HND
ECU
CPVARG
TUN
NIC IDNIRNBTN
JOR
LKA
CIVCOL
STP
TGONGA
BRA EGY
DOM
PER
AIA
AGO
BOL
MAR
TCD
TZA BGD
MOZ
IND
UGA LAO MMR
0

COD BDI
MSR
HTI SLEBFA
IRQBEN
NER
ZWE GMB
KEN
GNB
DZA
DJIMRT
CAF
MDG ETH
SEN
GHAGIN
PRYRWA
COM
CMR SYRMWI
MNG GAB
NPL
PAK
BLZ SDN MLI
DMA
VEN SUR
URY MDV SYC
JAM GRCFJI GRD
LCA
LBR PRT
CYP
MUS

MLT
-2

-10 0 10 20 30
Manufacturing (avg. growth per capita)

Source: UN and WDI.


0
10,000
12,000

2,000
4,000
6,000
8,000
Software publishers
Semiconductor and other electronic components
Pharmaceuticals and medicines
Medical equipment and supplies
Navigational, measuring, electromedical, and control…
Communications equipment
Other computer and electronic products
Automobiles, bodies, trailers, and parts
Telecommunications
Other machinery
Engine, turbine, and power transmission equipment
Aircraft, aircraft engine, and aircraft parts
Other miscellaneous manufacturing
Data processing, hosting, and related services
Electrical equipment, appliances, and components

Source: NSF, Science and Engineering Indicators.


Mining, extraction, and support activities
Plastics and rubber products
Physical, engineering, and life sciences (except…
Other information
Biotechnology research and development
Food
Wholesale trade
Fabricated metal products
Computer systems design and related services
79

Soap, cleaning compound, and toilet preparation


Paper
Basic chemicals
Semiconductor machinery
Pesticide, fertilizer, and other agricultural chemical
Patents Issued, USA (2012)

Finance and insurance


Nonmetallic mineral products
Paint, coating, adhesive, and other chemicals
Resin, synthetic rubber, and artificial synthetic fibers and…
Electronic shopping and electronic auctions
Textile, apparel, and leather products
Architectural, engineering, and related services
Lessors of nonfinancial intangible assets (except…
Other nonmanufacturing
Agricultural implement
Other professional, scientific, and technical services
Figure 5. Patents Issued by Detailed Sectors, USA (2012)

Petroleum and coal products


Beverage and tobacco products
Primary metals
Furniture and related products
Printing and related support activities
Guided missile, space vehicle, and related parts
Health care services
Wood products
Transportation and warehousing
Social sciences and humanities research and development

You might also like