You are on page 1of 24

Journal of Financial Economics 105 (2012) 412–435

Contents lists available at SciVerse ScienceDirect

Journal of Financial Economics


journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/jfec

Do controlling shareholders’ expropriation incentives imply


a link between corporate governance and firm value?
Theory and evidence$
Kee-Hong Bae a, Jae-Seung Baek b, Jun-Koo Kang c,n, Wei-Lin Liu c
a
Schulich School of Business, York University, Canada
b
Department of International Business, Hankuk University of Foreign Studies, South Korea
c
Nanyang Business School, Nanyang Technological University, Singapore

a r t i c l e in f o abstract

Article history: We develop and test a model that investigates how controlling shareholders’ expro-
Received 17 August 2010 priation incentives affect firm values during crisis and subsequent recovery periods.
Received in revised form Consistent with the prediction of our model, we find that, during the 1997 Asian
28 April 2011
financial crisis, Asian firms with weaker corporate governance experience a larger drop
Accepted 15 July 2011
in their share values but, during the post-crisis recovery period, such firms experience
Available online 16 February 2012
a larger rebound in their share values. We also find consistent evidence for Latin
JEL classification: American firms during the 2001 Argentine economic crisis. Our results support the view
G15 that controlling shareholders’ expropriation incentives imply a link between corporate
G21
governance and firm value.
G32
& 2012 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
G33
G34

Keywords:
Expropriation
Corporate governance
Firm value
Asian financial crisis
Controlling shareholder
Cash flow rights
Control rights

1. Introduction
$
We thank an anonymous referee for many detailed and helpful
suggestions. We are grateful for comments from Jay Choi, Jordan Siegel, Researchers have extensively examined the link
and seminar participants at the first International Conference on between corporate governance and firm value during an
Corporate Governance and Emerging Markets, the 2010 China Interna-
economic crisis. Previous studies show that firms with
tional Conference in Finance, the 2010 International Conference on
Asia-Pacific Financial Markets, and the 2011 Asian Finance Association weaker corporate governance suffer more during such a
International Conference. Jae-Seung Baek acknowledges financial sup- period. One potential explanation for this finding is that,
port from the Hankuk University of Foreign Studies Research Fund, and during a crisis period, controlling shareholders’ incentives
Jun-Koo Kang acknowledges financial support from the Nanyang Tech- to expropriate minority shareholders tend to go up as
nological University Academic Research Fund Tier 1. All errors are our
own.
the expected return on investment falls (Johnson, Boone,
n
Corresponding author. Breach, and Friedman, 2000; Mitton, 2002; Baek,
E-mail address: jkkang@ntu.edu.sg (J.-K. Kang). Kang, and Park, 2004). This view implies that controlling

0304-405X/$ - see front matter & 2012 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
doi:10.1016/j.jfineco.2012.02.007
K.-H. Bae et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 105 (2012) 412–435 413

shareholders’ incentives to expropriate minority share- exactly opposite to that during the crisis period. If control-
holders are the key channel through which corporate ling shareholders’ increased incentive to expropriate min-
governance affects firm value during a crisis period. We ority shareholders during the crisis period is the main
term this conjecture the expropriation hypothesis. reason for the poor performance of firms with weak
However, the positive relation between the quality of corporate governance, we would expect these firms to
corporate governance and the change in firm value during experience a larger percentage increase in value during
a crisis period is also consistent with several alternative the recovery period than do firms with good corporate
explanations. One such explanation is an information- governance. This prediction does not imply that poor
based argument. For example, prior to the 1997 Asian corporate governance enhances firm value during the
financial crisis, the relation-based financial system in East recovery period. Instead, our model suggests that the
Asia worked well and, thus, investors might have ignored greater rebound in the stock prices of firms with weaker
the weaknesses of East Asian firms. Alternatively, perhaps corporate governance during the recovery period is a
investors did not have full information on whether or not reflection of the firms’ more rampant asset diversion
their funds were being deployed appropriately, but the problem during the crisis period, which severely limits
crisis exposed the inherent weakness in the corporate their ability to take full advantage of the substantially
governance systems of East Asian countries, triggering improved investment opportunities when recovery begins.
greater investor awareness of the problems in the region. The rationale for this prediction is as follows. During
This increased awareness led to investors’ pulling out the crisis period, because of the significant decline in
(Rajan and Zingales, 1998). This argument suggests that firms’ profit prospects and poorer investment opportu-
greater investor awareness of the weakness in corporate nities, controlling shareholders have stronger incentives
governance is the main driving force that links corporate to divert firm resources for their own benefits. Conse-
governance to the change in firm value during the crisis quently, firms with weaker corporate governance experi-
period. According to this view, the poor performance of ence more asset diversion and larger decline in firm value
firms with weak corporate governance during a crisis than those with better corporate governance. However, as
period is not necessarily due to increased expropriation, the economy recovers, firms’ profit outlook and invest-
but rather to investors’ paying more attention to corpo- ment opportunities improve substantially. Because con-
rate governance problems that have been hidden. trolling shareholders can benefit more from profitable
Another potential explanation is that the governance firm investments than from expropriation during this
measures used in previous studies are somehow closely recovery period, the improved economic conditions alle-
correlated with firms’ sensitivity to business conditions. viate controlling shareholders’ incentives to expropriate
For example, in our sample firms, we find a strong minority shareholders. Because firms with weaker corpo-
negative correlation between firm-level governance mea- rate governance had more extant asset diversion before
sures and systematic risk as estimated by the market the recovery period, during the recovery period they have
model beta. This finding suggests that the performance of limited resources for undertaking all the profitable invest-
poorly governed firms is more sensitive to change in ments available and are thus forced to undertake only the
market conditions, implying that firms with weaker most profitable ones. As a result, during the recovery
corporate governance suffer more when the market per- period, on a per dollar basis, firms with weaker corporate
forms poorly. governance realize higher returns on investments than
Finally, it could simply be that investors overreact to a those with better corporate governance and, thus, experi-
shock, and the degree of investors’ overreaction is more ence greater percentage increases in firm value.
pronounced for poorly governed firms. Like other expla- The case of Samsung Fine Chemical (SFC) illustrates
nations, overreaction also implies a positive relation how firms with weak corporate governance experience
between the change in a firm’s value and the quality of large declines in firm value during the crisis period but
its corporate governance during a crisis. have strong rebounds as the economy recovers. In 1996, a
While both the expropriation hypothesis and the year before the onset of the Asian financial crisis, the
alternative explanations have important implications for controlling shareholders of Samsung Group directly and
the link between corporate governance and firm value indirectly (through firms affiliated with the business
during a crisis, previous research has largely overlooked group) own 0.07% and 8.49%, respectively, of the out-
these alternative explanations in examining that link. In standing shares of SFC, and the affiliated firms addition-
this paper, we reevaluate the validity of the expropriation ally hold 32.47% of its outstanding shares. This ownership
hypothesis by developing and testing a model that con- structure (i.e., divergence between ownership and con-
siders the expropriation incentives of controlling share- trol) allows controlling shareholders to exercise full con-
holders not only during the crisis period, but also during trol over SFC despite holding a relatively small portion of
the subsequent recovery period. In our tests, we explicitly its cash flow rights. During the crisis period, the stock
consider the possibility that firms with weaker corporate price of SFC plummeted from 29,500 won in July 1997
governance suffer more during economic crisis periods by almost 74% to just above 7,700 won by the end of
because of the alternative reasons. September 1998. However, as the economy recovered, the
The novelty of using the post-crisis recovery period is stock price of SFC bounced back strongly, reaching 26,600
that the prediction of the expropriation hypothesis regard- won (an increase of 245%) by the end of December 1999.
ing the relation between the quality of corporate govern- In comparison, the increase in the Korean stock market
ance and the change in firm value during this period is index during the same period was 152%.
414 K.-H. Bae et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 105 (2012) 412–435

To test the model predictions, we first analyze a economic environment in Korea (e.g., a downgrade of
sample of 608 Korean firms listed on the Korea Stock the sovereign rating of Korea by Moody’s or other rating
Exchange (KSE) during the 1997–1998 financial crisis agencies, nationalization of the commercial bank by the
and the 1998–1999 post-crisis recovery periods. As a Korean government, chaebol bankruptcy, etc.) affect firms
further test, we then examine 598 firms listed on seven with weak corporate governance more negatively than
other East Asian stock markets during the same periods they do those firms with good corporate governance. In
and 302 firms listed on four Latin American stock contrast, the good news announcements that are asso-
markets during the 2001–2002 Argentine crisis and the ciated with brighter prospects for future investment
2002–2003 post-crisis recovery periods. We require opportunities (e.g., an upgrade of the sovereign rating of
sample firms to have data available for both the crisis Korea by Moody’s or other rating agencies, settlement of
and recovery periods, because otherwise our results the negotiation on foreign debt payments, abolition of
could be driven by different firms being in the two restrictions on foreign direct equity investment, etc.)
periods. We find strong support for the expropriation affect firms with weak corporate governance more posi-
hypothesis: Compared with well-governed firms, poorly tively than they do those firms with good corporate
governed firms drop more in stock price during the crisis governance. To the extent that these news events are
period but experience significantly more increase in largely unexpected and thus represent relatively exogen-
stock prices during the recovery period. ous shocks that significantly affect the expected return on
Our finding that poorly governed firms experience a investment, our results further confirm the expropriation
greater rebound in stock prices during the recovery period hypothesis in explaining the link between corporate
is inconsistent with the information-based explanation. The governance and firm value.
information-based explanation suggests that greater inves- We perform several robustness checks on the data. We
tor awareness of corporate governance problems revealed use various measures of the quality of corporate govern-
during a crisis period is the main reason for the poor ance and find evidence that is consistent with the expro-
performance of firms with weak corporate governance. priation hypothesis. We also experiment with alternative
Because the economic recovery does not change investor time periods for the shock and recovery periods and find
awareness of these firms’ corporate governance, this expla- robust results.
nation also suggests that, during the recovery period, the Our findings have an important implication for the
rebound in the stock prices of poorly governed firms should growing literature on law and finance. The existing
be modest or at least no greater than that of well-governed literature has demonstrated the importance of investor
firms. Our evidence shows the opposite results. During the protection in the various aspects of financial markets. For
recovery period, the stock return performance of firms with example, La Porta, Lopez-de-Silanes, Shleifer, and Vishny
weaker corporate governance is better than that of firms (LLSV, 1997, 1998), show that countries with better
with better corporate governance. investor protection have larger and deeper capital mar-
We also find that, for Korean sample firms, those with kets. Markets with better investor protection also have
weaker corporate governance suffer larger loss of higher valuation of listed firms relative to their assets
accounting profits during the crisis period but experience (LLSV, 2002; Claessens, Djankov, and Lang, 2000), a larger
a greater rebound in accounting profits during the recov- number of listed firms (LLSV, 1997), and higher quality of
ery period. This result provides further evidence that is accounting information (Hung, 2001; Ball, Robin, and Wu,
consistent with our model. 2002; Fan and Wong, 2002; Leuz, Nanda, and Wysocki,
To control for the alternative explanations (i.e., risk 2003). Furthermore, better investor protection enables
and overreaction) in addressing the link between corpo- firms to make greater use of external finance (LLSV,
rate governance and firm value, we include beta and past 1998) and larger investments from external funds (Rajan
holding period returns as explanatory variables in the and Zingales, 1998; Demirgüc- -Kunt and Maksimovic,
regressions of stock returns during both the crisis and 1998). In contrast, poor investor protection increases
recovery periods. If poorly governed firms have a higher liquidity costs (Brockman and Chung, 2003) and impedes
sensitivity to changes in market conditions, they are likely informed arbitrage that capitalizes on firm-specific infor-
to suffer more when the market performs poorly but mation, thereby resulting in less efficient stock prices
perform better when the market recovers. Similarly, firms (Morck, Yeung, and Yu, 2000). Finally, Djankov, La Porta,
whose stock prices drop more during the crisis period Lopez-de-Silanes, and Shleifer (2008) develop the anti-
could perform better during the recovery period because self-dealing index and show that it predicts a variety of
of the contrarian effects in stock returns that have been stock market outcomes. As LLSV (2000) argue, the funda-
emphasized in the asset pricing literature. Consistent with mental premise of this literature is the importance of
these arguments, we find that the coefficients on beta and investor protection in preventing the expropriation of
past holding period returns have the predicted signs minority investors. Our evidence shows that investor
in both crisis and recovery period regressions. However, expropriation is the main channel through which corpo-
controlling for beta and overreaction effects does not rate governance affects firm value.
attenuate the impact of governance variables on the stock Although our results for the recovery period generally
return. support the expropriation hypothesis, they are also con-
To provide further support to the expropriation sistent with controlling shareholders’ propping behavior
hypothesis, we present ancillary evidence showing that [negative tunneling in which controlling shareholders use
the bad news announcements about the deteriorating their private cash to temporarily prop up troubled group
K.-H. Bae et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 105 (2012) 412–435 415

affiliates (Friedman, Johnson, and Mitton (2003)]. During Finally, because we intend to apply our model to
the recovery period, controlling shareholders in business both the crisis and the recovery periods, ideally we need
groups could use their private funds to prop up affiliated a two-period dynamic model, which begins with the crisis
firms so as to bring in more capital quickly or to build a period and ends with the recovery period. However,
reputation that can be used to raise outside capital. Such mainly for ease of exposition, we focus on a one-period
propping activities improve firm value and lead to large model and assume that winit for the crisis period is
rebounds in the stock prices, thereby benefiting a firm’s exogenously given. However, we link the crisis period to
outside shareholders. Even though propping reduces con- the recovery period by assuming the firm’s initial invest-
trolling shareholders’ current wealth, in the long run it can able capital for the recovery period is equal to the capital
produce a net benefit to controlling shareholders by produced from its investment during the crisis period.
enhancing the values of their options to expropriate firms’ That is, winit for the recovery period is equal to the cash
future profits (Friedman, Johnson, and Mitton, 2003). flow generated from the firm’s investment in the crisis
While we do not explicitly model this propping-based period.3
explanation as an alternative to our expropriation hypoth- Following LLSV (2002), we assume that the firm has
esis, our results during the recovery period are consistent one controlling shareholder who is also the firm’s man-
with both the expropriation and propping arguments.1 ager. The manager owns a fraction of the firm and can
The rest of the paper proceeds as follows. In Section 2, we divert the firm’s capital to benefit himself at the expense
develop a simple model of managerial expropriation. In of minority shareholders.4
Section 3, we discuss the data, variables, and sample char- Diversion of firm resources generally requires costly
acteristics. Section 4 follows with a discussion of the main transactions (Burkart, Gromb, and Panunzi, 1998; Johnson,
results for the cross-sectional determinants of firm perfor- Boone, Breach, and Friedman, 2000; LLSV, 2002). However,
mance in Korea during the crisis and post-crisis periods. as the manager commands greater expropriation power,
Section 5 presents the results of robustness tests and shows he incurs less cost and derives more benefits from divert-
further evidence supporting the expropriation hypothesis. In ing capital. We assume that the manager receives a benefit
Section 6, we report the results from the out-of-sample tests of mðwinit wÞ^ from expropriating winit w ^ amount of capi-
using other Asian and Latin American firms. Finally, we tal, where m is the manager’s expropriation power.
present summary and concluding remarks in Section 7. The manager first decides how much of the firm’s
initial capital winit to expropriate and then how much of
2. A simple model of managerial expropriation the remaining capital to invest in the project. When the
manager expropriates winit w ^ amount of capital, the
In this section, we develop a simple model of manage- remaining capital available for investment is w. ^ Because
rial expropriation during crisis and recovery periods. To winit is unaffected by the manager’s decisions in the
simplify the analysis, we consider a one-period model in current period, choosing winit w ^ is equivalent to choosing
which a firm has an investment project and initial capital ^ Thus, the manager’s optimal choices are determined by
w.
pffiffi
endowment of winit . The payoff from the project is p I, the following problem:
which depends on both the investment amount, I, and pffiffi
MaxI, w^ fa½w
^ þðp IIÞ þ mðwinit wÞg,
^ ð1Þ
investment p profitability,
ffiffi p. The net present value of the
project is p II.
Subject to I r w
^ ð2Þ
We assume that the profitability of the firm’s project is
independent of the level of managerial expropriation but and
depends only on whether the firm is in the crisis period or
^ Z 0:
winit w ð3Þ
the recovery period. In practice, a firm’s profitability is likely
pffiffi
to be affected by both macroeconomic conditions and its In Eq. (1), a½w
^ þ ðp IIÞ is the manager’s share of the
managerial decisions. However, given that the economic firm’s end-of-period value, and mðwinit wÞ
^ is his gain from
conditions significantly affect a firm’s investment opportu- expropriation. Condition (2) states that investment I
nities and its profit prospects, a reasonable assumption is
that macro-factors play a key role in determining its profit-
ability. Thus, in our model, the firm’s manager cannot affect (footnote continued)
Korean firm managed to issue a small amount of equity during the
the profitability of its investment, but he can alter only the recovery period of 1998–1999 (the number of shares issued as a
extent of expropriation and thus the level of investment. percentage of total shares outstanding was only a little over 10% of
Furthermore, although the firm can obtain winit from the figure in the pre-crisis period of 1995–1996), it could not issue any
internal operations as well as external financing, given the equity during the crisis period of 1997–1998.
3
To the extent that firms are unlikely to be able to forecast how
difficulties in obtaining external financing during a crisis,
long the unanticipated economic crisis will last at its onset, planning
we assume that the firm obtains the entire winit from its ahead for recovery could be very challenging for firms. Furthermore,
previous operations.2 intuitions following our analysis suggest that a full-fledged dynamic
model is not likely to change the key features of our predictions based
on the one-period model.
1 4
See Bae, Cheon, and Kang (2008) for evidence on propping in Managerial expropriation can take many forms. For example, it can
Korean markets. take subtle legal forms, such as dilutive share issues that discriminate
2
We find that, during our sample period of 1997–1999, our sample against minority shareholders and mergers between affiliated firms to
median Korean firm could not issue any bonds and had difficulty siphon resources out of the bidder or the target. It can also take the form
extending its long-term bank debt. Moreover, although the median of outright theft or fraud.
416 K.-H. Bae et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 105 (2012) 412–435

should be smaller than the amount of capital available for the profit prospect of the firm’s investment, causing pc to
investment after managerial expropriation, w. ^ Condition be very small. Thus, wcinit , which corresponds to the capital
^ be smaller
(3) is the capital constraint that requires that w generated from the firm’s operations during the pre-crisis
than the firm’s initial investable capital. period, is likely to exceed the capital needed for invest-
To solve for the manager’s optimal decisions, consider ment during the crisis period.
first his choice of w.^ From the manager’s objective func- It follows from Eq. (6) and Assumption 1 that the
tion in Eq. (1), a dollar increase in w ^ reduces his gains manager’s optimal choice of investment during the crisis
from expropriation by m but increases his gains from period is w^ cn ¼ ðapc =2mÞ2 . The resulting managerial expro-
managerial equity holding by a. If m r a, the manager has priation is
no incentive to expropriate minority shareholders. In the c
^ n ¼ wcinit ðapc =2mÞ2 :
wcinit w ð7Þ
rest of the analysis, we follow Johnson, Boone, Breach, and
Friedman (2000) by assuming that a is small enough so The amount of capital produced from the investment is
that m 4 a. Under this assumption, the amount of expro- qffiffiffiffiffiffi
c
p w ^ cn ¼ aðpc Þ2 =2m: ð8Þ
priation is always non-negative (i.e., wr^ winit ).
qffiffiffiffiffiffi
When m 4 a, the manager chooses to minimize w ^ so pc w c
^ n is also the value of the firm at the end of the crisis
that constraint (2) is binding: period.
^ ¼ I:
w ð4Þ When the recovery period begins, the firm’s initial
capital wrinit is equal to the capital produced during the
Condition (4) says that the manager expropriates all of qffiffiffiffiffiffi
the firm’s capital except for the minimum amount needed crisis period, pc w ^ cn in Eq. (8), that is,
for investment.
pffiffi Given Eq.
pffiffiffiffi (4), the firm’s end-of-period wrinit ¼ aðpc Þ2 =2m ð9Þ
value, wþ^ ðp IIÞ, is p w ^ , so the manager’s objective
function in Eq. (1) becomes To solve for the manager’s optimal decisions during
pffiffiffiffi the recovery period, we assume that, at the beginning of
ap w ^ þ mðwinit wÞ:
^ ð5Þ
the recovery period, the firm has limited capital available
Maximizing the payoff in Eq. (5) subject to constraint for investment.
^ denoted as w
(3) shows that the optimal level of w, ^ n , is
Assumption 2. For the recovery period, wrinit o ðapr =2mÞ2 .
given by
^ n ¼ Minfðap=2mÞ2 ,winit g:
w ð6Þ This assumption is motivated by the fact that the
economic recovery substantially improves the firm’s
Eq. (6) identifies the key factors that affect the manager’s investment prospect, so the profitability of the firm’s
incentive to divert the firm’s capital. First, when the firm’s project during the recovery period, pr , is expected to be
initial capital winit is large relative to ðap=2mÞ2 , then significantly larger than that during the crisis period, pc . It
w^ n ¼ ðap=2mÞ2 . Thus, as managerial equity ownership a follows from Eq. (6) and Assumption 2 that during the
increases, the profitability of the firm’s project p improves, recovery period the manager has few incentives to expro-
or as managerial expropriation power m declines, the firm’s priate and the optimal investment is
investment w ^ n increases while managerial expropriation
^ rn ¼ wrinit
w ð10Þ
winit w ^ n decreases. The intuition for this result is straight-
forward. As a or p increases, or as m declines, the manager’s Therefore, firm value at the end of the recovery period
pffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi
benefits from the firm’s investment, the first term in is pr wrinit .
Eq. (5), increase relative to his gain from expropriation, We can summarize the above discussions of manage-
the second term in Eq. (5), resulting in greater managerial rial expropriation during the crisis and recovery periods
incentive to invest in the project and weaker incentive to as follows.
expropriate capital. Second, when the firm has limited
initial capital such that winit o ðap=2mÞ2 , then w ^ n ¼ winit . In Proposition 1. During the crisis period, the managerial
this case, there is no managerial expropriation. incentive to expropriate minority shareholders increases with
To separately examine the implications of the model the manager’s expropriation power and decreases with his
for the crisis and recovery periods, denote the profitability equity ownership in the firm. However, during the recovery
for the crisis and recovery periods as pc and pr , respec- period, the manager has few incentives to expropriate min-
tively; the investable capital at the beginning of the crisis ority shareholders.
and recovery periods as wcinit and wrinit , respectively; and Proposition 1 is similar to the Jensen (1986) free cash
the optimal investment in the crisis and recovery periods flow argument in that excess cash and low growth
as w ^ cn and w ^ rn , respectively. opportunities result in agency problems. During the crisis
To solve for the manager’s optimal decisions during period, the firm tends to have a relatively large amount of
the crisis period, we assume that at the beginning of the initial investable capital, but few profitable investment
crisis period the firm is endowed with a large amount of opportunities. This opens the door for agency conflicts,
initial investable capital. such as managerial expropriation and investment in
negative net present value projects. Expropriation is
Assumption 1. For the crisis period, wcinit 4 ðapc =2mÞ2 :
possible due to the manager’s significant controlling
Assumption 1 is motivated by the fact that the external power, but his equity ownership alleviates the extent
shock at the beginning of the crisis substantially reduces of expropriation by aligning his interests with those of
K.-H. Bae et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 105 (2012) 412–435 417

minority shareholders. However, coming off the crisis and NPV of Investment
entering the recovery period, the firm is likely to have
better investment prospects but with limited investable
capital due to the extant managerial expropriation during
the crisis period. Thus, during the recovery period, the
manager has few incentives to engage in expropriation.
The above analysis provides two testable predictions
on the relations between change in firm value and the
manager’s expropriation power and equity ownership. For
the crisis period, the firm is initially worth wcinit and is
qffiffiffiffiffiffi
worth pc w ^ cn at the end of the period. Thus, the percen-
tage change in firm value over this period is Investment (I )
 qffiffiffiffiffiffi 
pc w^ cn wcinit =wcinit ð11Þ
Fig. 1. Concavity in the firm’s production technology. wrinit is the initial
qffiffiffiffiffiffi capital endowment and amount of investmentpin
^ cn is decreasing in the ffiffi the recovery period.
We know from Eq. (8) that pc w The net present value (NPV) of the project is p II, which depends on
manager’s expropriation power but increasing in his both investment amount (I) and investment profitability (p).
equity ownership, so the change in firm value should also
be decreasing in his expropriation power but increasing
in his equity ownership. The following prediction sum- concavity in the firm’s production technology, there is
marizes the dependence of the change in firm value decreasing return to investment. Thus, for firms with high
during the crisis period on the manager’s expropriation managerial expropriation power or low managerial equity
power and equity ownership. ownership, or both, the limited amounts of initial invest-
able capital produce, on a per dollar investment basis, a
Prediction 1. The change in firm value during the crisis is
large increase in firm value.
negatively related to the manager’s expropriation power
but is positively related to his equity ownership in
3. Data, key variables, and sample characteristics
the firm.

At the beginning of the recovery period, the firm value In this section we describe the data, variables, and
is wrinit , and at the end of the recovery period, it is sample characteristics.
pffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi
pr wrinit . Thus, during the recovery period, the change
in firm value is 3.1. Data
 qffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi   qffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi 
pr wrinit wrinit =wrinit ¼ pr = wrinit 1: ð12Þ Our initial sample consists of 608 nonfinancial firms
listed on the KSE during 1997–1999, which covers both
Recall from Eq. (9) that wrinit is decreasing in the the crisis and recovery periods. To check the robustness of
manager’s expropriation power but increasing in his our results, we perform an out-of-sample test using 598
equity ownership. Thus, Eq. (12) leads to the following other East Asian firms from Hong Kong, Indonesia, Malay-
testable prediction. sia, Philippines, Singapore, Taiwan, and Thailand during
the same periods and 302 Latin American firms from
Prediction 2. The change in firm value during the recovery
Argentina, Brazil, Chile, and Mexico during the 2001
period is positively related to the manager’s expropriation
Argentine economic crisis and recovery periods. We dis-
power but is negatively related to his equity ownership in
cuss the results of using these alternative samples in
the firm.
Section 5. Because focusing on a single nation allows
Prediction 2 does not mean either that during the examination of corporate governance and firm-specific
recovery period managerial expropriation contributes to measures at a level of detail that would be hard to
firm value or that managerial equity ownership reduces aggregate across countries, our main analysis is based
firm value. During the recovery period the manager has on the single country of Korea.
few incentives to expropriate. The role of managerial Fig. 2 shows the changes in the Korea Composite Stock
expropriation power and managerial equity ownership in Price Index (KOSPI) from January 1996 to December 1999.
explaining the change in firm value during the recovery The KOSPI is a market capitalization-weighted price index
period comes indirectly from their influence on the level of of all firms listed on the KSE and is the index that is most
initial investable capital, which is determined by the widely used to evaluate market performance.
capital produced from investment during the crisis period. At the end of January 1996, the KOSPI was 879. It went
During the crisis period, as the manager’s expropriation through periods of ups and downs, reaching its highest
power increases or equity ownership declines, or both, his point at the end of June 1997, when it stood at 944.
incentives to expropriate minority shareholders increase The first event that appears to trigger the Asian financial
and thus he allocates less capital to investments, resulting crisis is the announcement on July 2, 1997 regarding the
in a smaller amount of investable capital available when Thai Baht’s devaluation (Chowdhry and Goyal, 2000). After
the recovery arrives. As illustrated in Fig. 1, because of the that, the KOSPI started to fall until September 1998, at
418 K.-H. Bae et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 105 (2012) 412–435

Korea Composite Stock Price Index


1,200

1,000

800

600

400

200

0
January June December June December June December June December
1996 1996 1996 1997 1997 1998 1998 1999 1999

Fig. 2. Changes in the Korea Composite Stock Price Index (KOSPI) from January 1996 to December 1999. The KOSPI is a market capitalization-weighted
price index of all firms listed on the Korea Stock Exchange and is the index that is most widely used to evaluate the market performance. The KOSPI data
are from the daily return files of the Korea Investors Service—Stock Market Analysis Tool and Stock Database of the Korea Securities Research Institute.

which point the index level had dropped to 406. Thus, as sum of direct equity ownership and the minimum value of
in the previous study by Baek, Kang, and Park (2004), we ownership in the chain of voting rights. We use both total
set the period from July 1997 to September 1998 as the and block ownership to estimate voting rights. By obtain-
crisis period. ing data on total holdings, we can accurately measure the
In October 1998, the Korean stock market recovered its controlling shareholders’ voting rights. We compute the
previous losses. In particular, during 1999, investor opti- divergence between cash flow rights and control rights as
mism gained momentum and the stock market perfor- the logarithm of the ratio of voting rights to cash flow
mance was spectacular. At the end of 1999, the KOSPI rights (disparity variable).
reached a new high of 1214. This movement in the KOSPI We use equity ownership by controlling shareholders
suggests that investors would have realized a holding as the measure for managerial equity ownership (variable
period return of about 300% if they had invested in the a in our model). Following Mitton (2002) and Baek, Kang,
market portfolio from October 1998 to December 1999. and Park (2004), we use two additional variables related
Thus, we set the period from October 1998 to December to block holdings as alternative measures of equity own-
1999 as the recovery period. ership. The first measure is the sum of block holdings by
all shareholders who own 5% or more of issued shares.
3.2. Key variables The second measure is the block holdings by the largest
shareholder owning 5% or more of issued shares. We
We measure the change in firm value during the crisis further separate the block holdings by the largest share-
(recovery) period by the holding period stock return from holder into two components, the largest managerial
the beginning of the crisis (recovery) to the end of crisis block ownership and the largest nonmanagerial block
(recovery) and use it as the dependent variable. The ownership.
explanatory variables include the following. As an alternative measure for controlling shareholders’
expropriation power m, we use the extent of a firm’s
3.2.1. Expropriation variables diversification. The degree of expropriation could be more
As a direct empirical measure of the manager’s expro- severe for highly diversified firms, as these firms tend to
priation power (variable m in our model), we use the suffer more from information asymmetry and agency costs
disparity between cash flow rights and voting rights of the (Mitton, 2002; Lins and Servaes, 1999). To measure diver-
controlling shareholders. The controlling shareholders sification, we use a dummy variable that takes a value
with high ownership disparity could have strong incen- of zero if 90% or more of a firm’s sales come from one three-
tives to siphon resources out of the firm to benefit digit Standard Industrial Classification (SIC) and a value of
themselves. We measure the cash flow rights of the one otherwise. We then interact this diversification dummy
controlling shareholders (defined as owner-managers with the diversity of investment opportunities. To measure
and their family members) as the sum of the direct equity the diversity of investment opportunities, we follow Rajan,
ownership and the product of the ownership stakes Servaes, and Zingales (2000). We first identify competing
obtained indirectly. We obtain the information on these undiversified firms for each segment of diversified firms at a
stakes by tracing up to two layers along the control chain four-digit SIC level and then measure the standard deviation
in a pyramid structure. We measure voting rights as the of the Tobin’s q (book value of debt plus market value of
K.-H. Bae et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 105 (2012) 412–435 419

equity divided by total assets) of matched undiversified of cross-debt guarantees among member firms.6 If the
firms for all segments of a diversified firm. We define chaebol affiliation allows risk sharing among chaebol firms,
diversified firms with standard deviations above (below) we expect chaebol firms to suffer less during a crisis. We use
the median for all diversified firms as having a high (low) a dummy variable that equals one if a firm belongs to one of
variation of investment opportunities. the 30 largest business groups and zero otherwise.
We expect firms with high foreign ownership and
3.2.2. Risk and overreaction variables those having a listed American Depositary Receipt (ADR)
We use beta as the key measure of firm risk. We to suffer less during a crisis. To control for these effects,
estimate beta by the slope of the market model regres- we use equity ownership by foreign investors and a
sion. To estimate beta before the crisis (recovery) dummy variable that takes the value of one if the firm
period, we use two-year daily stock returns preceding has an ADR listed in the United States.
the crisis (recovery) period. We also include as a risk We control for inefficiency in resource allocation
variable firm-specific risk measured as the standard among member firms within the same chaebol by includ-
deviation of residual errors from the market model ing the ratio of financial securities invested in affiliated
regression. (nonaffiliated) firms to the firm’s total assets.
A contrarian (overreaction) effect in stock returns Finally, we control for other determinants of firms’
predicts that better-performing firms before the crisis stock returns, including future investment opportunity
period drop more during the crisis period and worse- (Tobin’s q), liquidity [ratio of cash flow (operating income
performing firms during the crisis period perform better plus depreciation) to total assets], and industry effects
during the recovery period. To control for such a contra- (industry dummies).
rian effect, we use past holding period returns (HPR) as
our key measure. We compute the HPR of firm i between 3.3. Sample characteristics
t1 and t2 as
Table 1 provides summary statistics of our sample
HPRi ðt 1 ,t 2 Þ ¼ ð1þ Ri,t1 Þð1 þ Ri,t1 þ 1 Þð1þ Ri,t1 þ 2 Þ firms as of the end of fiscal years 1996 and 1997. We
ð1þ Ri,t1 þ 3 Þ    ð1þ Ri,t2 Þ21 obtain the daily stock return data from the Stock Database
of the Korea Securities Research Institute, which includes
where Ri,t is the daily return of firm i at time t. As past
all firms listed on the KSE, and financial data from the
holding period returns for the shock and recovery periods,
Listed Company Database of the Korean Listed Companies
we use the HPR during year 1996 and the HPR during the
Association.
shock period, respectively.
The average ratio of voting rights to cash flow rights is
3.22 in 1996 and 1.91 in 1997. Closely examining the ratio
3.2.3. Control variables of voting rights to cash flow rights shows that outlier
As in Baek, Kang, and Park (2004), we control for several problems are much more severe in 1996 than in 1997.
other variables that could affect firm performance during When we delete observations in which the ratio of voting
the crisis and recovery periods. First, we control for firm rights to cash flow rights is larger than the 99th percentile
size (logarithm of total assets). Larger firms tend to have of the sample, the average ratio in 1996 becomes 2.31, but
easy access to external finance and suffer less from infor- the average ratio in 1997 is 1.85.
mation asymmetry. Thus, we expect larger firms to be less In 1996, the average equity ownership by controlling
vulnerable to external shock. To control for the nonlinear shareholders and the average equity ownership by
effect of firm size on HPR, we include the square of the affiliated firms are 20.51% and 8.79%, respectively. The
logarithm of total assets as an additional control variable. corresponding values in 1997 are 19.69% and 10.91%. Tests
In addition, we control for leverage (total debt/total of differences in mean and median equity ownership by
assets). Because highly leveraged firms have difficulty controlling shareholders between 1996 and 1997 do not
obtaining external financing during a crisis, we expect reject the null hypothesis that they are equal, but those in
such firms to experience a larger drop in equity value. mean and median equity ownership by affiliated firms
In Korea, a large business group is often referred to as a between 1996 and 1997 reject the null hypothesis that
chaebol. The Korea Fair Trade Commission (KFTC) ranks they are equal. These results suggest that during the crisis
business groups according to the size of their total assets period, instead of using their own wealth, controlling
and identifies the 30 largest business groups. Chaebol shareholders use the resources of member firms to
firms that belong to the 30 largest business groups increase their control power in the chaebol.
operate in many different industries, are bound together The sum of block ownership by all shareholders
by a nexus of explicit and implicit contracts, maintain averages 30.96% in 1996 and 31.15% in 1997. The average
substantial business ties with other firms in their group, of largest blockholder concentration, as measured by the
and are mostly family controlled.5 They are also charac- block holdings of the largest shareholder owning 5% or
terized by an extensive arrangement of pyramidal or
multilayered shareholding agreements and the existence
6
Chang (2003) examines the simultaneous relation between own-
ership and firm performance for chaebol affiliates. He shows that using
5
Fogel (2006) shows that greater oligarchic family control over insider information, chaebol families and their affiliates take higher
large corporations, which is the case for chaebol firms, is associated with ownership stakes in more profitable and more promising firms and
worse social economic outcomes. transfer profits to affiliates through intragroup trade.
420 K.-H. Bae et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 105 (2012) 412–435

Table 1
Summary statistics.
The sample contains nonfinancial firms listed on the Korea Stock Exchange during 1997–1998. The summary statistics are the values at the end of fiscal
years 1996 and 1997, except for beta and firm-specific risk, which we estimate by using two-year daily returns preceding the crisis and recovery periods.
Previous HPR are the holding period returns during the year of 1996 and HPR during the shock period (July 1997–September 1998). Cash flow rights of
controlling shareholders are the sum of direct equity ownership and the product of the ownership stakes obtained indirectly along the chain of a pyramid
structure for controlling shareholders. Voting rights of controlling shareholders are the sum of direct equity ownership and the minimum of the level of
ownership in the pyramid structure. Equity ownership by controlling shareholders is the sum of equity ownership by controlling families and affiliated
firms. The sum of block ownership is the sum of block holdings by all shareholders owning 5% or more of issued shares. Block ownership by the largest
shareholder denotes block holdings by the largest shareholder who owns 5% or more of issued shares. The largest managerial blockholder concentration
refers to block holdings by owners involved with management, and largest nonmanagerial blockholder concentration refers to block holdings by other
largest shareholders. Beta is estimated by the slope of the market model regression. Firm-specific risk is estimated by the standard deviation of residual
errors from the market model regression. We measure Tobin’s q as the book value of debt plus market value of equity divided by total assets. Financial
investment in affiliated (nonaffiliated) firms means financial securities invested in affiliated (nonaffiliated) firms. The firm is considered to be diversified
if 10% or less of that firm’s sales come from one three-digit Standard Industrial Classification.

Variable A: 1996 (N ¼ 608) B: 1997 (N ¼ 608) Test of difference


(A-B): p-value

Mean Median Mean Median t-test Wilcoxon


Z-test

Expropriation variables
Voting rights/cash flow rights of controlling shareholders (owner-managers and their family 3.219 1.000 1.906 1.000 0.003 0.001
members)
Cash flow rights of controlling shareholders (percentage) 22.101 22.330 24.668 24.460 0.001 0.001
Voting rights of controlling shareholders (percentage) 25.064 24.990 29.203 28.015 0.001 0.001
Equity ownership by controlling shareholders (percentage) 29.295 28.090 30.698 28.580 0.019 0.001
By ownermanagers and their family members 20.510 20.020 19.691 18.770 0.585 0.331
By affiliated firms 8.785 0.000 10.911 3.955 0.004 0.001
Sum of block ownership by all shareholders (percentage) 30.956 29.620 31.151 29.150 0.817 0.721
Block ownership by the largest shareholder (percentage) 19.289 16.915 20.970 19.380 0.008 0.004
By managers 11.303 9.440 12.427 11.000 0.083 0.028
By non-managers 7.987 8.700 8.544 6.643 0.288 0.052
Equity ownership by foreign investors (percentage) 5.006 1.620 4.694 1.070 0.478 0.010

Control variables
Market model beta 0.849 0.915 0.904 0.945 0.001 0.015
Firm-specific risk 0.071 0.068 0.069 0.056 0.535 0.001
Previous HPR 0.174 0.035  0.696  0.754 0.001 0.001
Total assets (billion won) 621.001 156.781 713.327 174.626 0.001 0.001
Total debt/total assets 0.701 0.699 0.733 0.715 0.057 0.005
Cash flow ((operating income þ depreciation)/total assets) 0.055 0.054 0.047 0.052 0.038 0.045
Tobin’s q 1.087 0.997 0.946 0.883 0.001 0.001
Financial investment in affiliated firms/total assets 0.079 0.047 0.069 0.040 0.014 0.084
Financial investment in unaffiliated firms/total assets 0.020 0.000 0.019 0.000 0.851 0.129
Percentage of firms with an American depositary receipt 2.65 2.82 0.860 –
Percentage of diversified firms 32.28 29.91 0.005 –

more of shares, is 19.29% in 1996 and 20.97% in 1997. The The average size of firms measured by total assets is 621
average largest managerial blockholder concentration, i.e., billion won in 1996 and 713 billion won in 1997, and the
block holdings by owners involved with management, is average leverage ratio is 70.1% in 1996 and 73.3% in 1997. In
11.3% in 1996 and 12.43% in 1997. The corresponding 1996 and 1997, the ratios of cash flow (operating income
values for the largest nonmanagerial blockholder concen- plus depreciation) to total assets average 5.5% and 4.7%,
tration, i.e., block holdings by largest shareholders respectively, and the means of Tobin’s q are 1.1 and 0.95.
who are not associated with management, are 7.99% and The average ratio of financial investment in affiliated (non-
8.54%, respectively. The median equity ownership by affiliated) firms to total assets is 7.9% (4.7%) in 1996 and 6.9%
foreign investors is 1.62% in 1996 and 1.07% in 1997, (4.0%) in 1997. We note a slight increase in the proportion of
suggesting that, during the crisis, the median foreign sample firms whose ADR is listed in the United States, from
investor reduces her previous holdings by almost 34%. 2.65% in 1996 to 2.82% in 1997. The proportion of diversified
All of these differences in block ownership and foreign firms decreased from 32.28% in 1996 to 29.91% in 1997.
ownership between 1996 and 1997 are statistically sig-
nificant at the 0.01 level. 4. Determinants of firm performance during the crisis
Not surprisingly, betas show an increase during the and recovery periods
crisis period. The mean betas are 0.85 in 1996 and 0.9 in
1997. However, firm-specific risk shows little changes. This section presents the main results of the paper. First,
The past HPR shows that firm value is significantly lower using univariate tests, we examine the relation between
in 1997 than in 1996. The average of past HPR in 1996 is expropriation variables and firm performance. Then, using
0.17, while the corresponding number in 1997 is  0.7. multivariate regression analyses, we show that the most
K.-H. Bae et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 105 (2012) 412–435 421

Table 2
Mean and median holding period return (HPR) during the crisis (7/97–9/98) and recovery (10/98–12/99) periods.
The sample contains nonfinancial firms listed on the Korea Stock Exchange during 1997–1998. Ownership variables are the values at the end of fiscal
years 1996 (for the shock period) and 1997 (for the recovery period). Cash flow rights of controlling shareholders are the sum of direct equity ownership
and the product of the ownership stakes obtained indirectly along the chain of a pyramid structure for controlling shareholders. Voting rights of
controlling shareholders are the sum of direct equity ownership and the minimum of the level of ownership in the pyramid structure. Equity ownership
by controlling shareholders is the sum of equity ownerships by owner-managers and their family members. ***, **, and * denote significance of the
parameter estimates at the 0.01, 0.05, and 0.10 level, respectively.

Panel A: HPR by disparity variable

Crisis/recovery periods Disparity between cash flow rights and control rights (voting right/cash flow right) Test of difference: p-value

Low High t-test Wilcoxon Z-test

HPR (7/97–9/98)  0.682  0.735 0.03nn 0.01nn


(  0.739) ( 0.797)
HPR (10/98–12/99) 1.236 1.587 0.00nnn 0.00nnn
(0.507) (0.964)

Panel B: HPR by equity ownership by controlling shareholders

Crisis/recovery periods Equity ownership by controlling shareholders Test of difference: p-value

Low High t-test Wilcoxon Z-test

nnn
HPR (7/97–9/98)  0.729  0.664 0.00 0.00nnn
(  0.786) ( 0.730)
HPR (10/98–12/99) 1.764 0.898 0.00nnn 0.00nnn
(0.834) (0.396)

Panel C: HPR by sum of block ownership by all shareholders

Crisis/recovery periods Sum of block ownership by all shareholders Test of difference: p-value

Low High t-test Wilcoxon Z-test

HPR (7/97–9/98)  0.745  0.646 0.00nnn 0.00nnn


(  0.786) ( 0.731)
HPR (10/98–12/99) 1.701 0.948 0.00nnn 0.02nn
(0.678) (0.529)

Panel D: HPR by largest managerial block ownership

Crisis/recovery periods Largest managerial block ownership Test of difference: p-value

Low High t-test Wilcoxon Z-test

nnn
HPR (7/97–9/98)  0.732  0.661 0.00 0.00nnn
(  0.779) ( 0.725)
HPR (10/98–12/99) 1.857 0.782 0.00nnn 0.00nnn
(0.867) (0.396)

important determinants of firm performance during the 0.05 level. These results are consistent with Prediction 1
crisis and recovery periods are expropriation variables. of our model.
During the recovery period, firms with high disparity
4.1. Univariate test realize an average (median) HPR of 158.7% (96.4%),
while firms with low disparity realize an average (med-
We partition our sample firms by the sample medians ian) HPR of 123.6% (50.7%). The differences in mean
of key expropriation variables at the end of fiscal years and median HPR between these two subsamples are
1996 and 1997, respectively, and then compare the HPR significant at the 0.01 level. These results, together with
during the crisis (July 1997 to September 1998) and those during the shock period, suggest that poorly gov-
recovery (October 1998 to December 1999) periods. erned firms suffer more during the shock period but
In Panel A of Table 2, we use the ratio of voting rights perform better during the recovery period. This evidence
to cash flow rights as a key expropriation variable. During of reversal in stock returns supports Prediction 2 of
the shock period, firms with high disparity realize an our model.
average (median) HPR of  73.5% (  79.7%), while firms In Panel B of Table 2, we use equity ownership by
with low disparity realize an average (median) HPR of controlling shareholders as our key expropriation vari-
68.2% ( 73.9%). The differences in mean and median able. We find that firms with lower equity ownership by
HPR between these two subsamples are significant at the controlling shareholders suffer more during the shock
422 K.-H. Bae et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 105 (2012) 412–435

period but bounce back more during the recovery period, and significant, showing the importance of including risk
again supporting Predictions 1 and 2 of our model. and contrarian variables in the regression.
However, the greater reversal of stock prices for firms In Regression 3, we control for all other variables. We
with weak governance could be due to factors that are not add the logarithm of total assets, squared logarithm of
related to ownership structure. It could be that ownership total assets, total debt over total assets, top 30 chaebol
variables are correlated with other aspects of firm char- dummy, equity ownership by foreign investors, ADR
acteristics, such as firm risk. For example, firms with high dummy, the ratio of financial investments in affiliated
betas perform worse during the shock period and better firms to total assets, the ratio of financial investments in
during the recovery period. While not reported in the unaffiliated firms to total assets, Tobin’s q, and the ratio of
paper, we split the sample firms according to the sample cash flow to total assets. We also include four industry
median beta and examine whether stock return perfor- dummy variables (construction, manufacturing, whole-
mance differs according to the beta. During the shock sale and retail, and transportation and services) to control
period, high-beta firms experience a mean (median) loss for a possible industry effect. To conserve space, we do
of about 71.4% (76.9%), while the corresponding loss is not report coefficients on these industry dummies. Con-
67.5% (74.5%) for low-beta firms. However, during the trolling for these variables increases the adjusted R2 of the
recovery period, this pattern is reversed. High-beta firms regression to 11%, suggesting that ownership disparity,
experience a mean (median) gain of about 151.1% (63.9%), beta, firm-specific risk, and previous HPR, together with
while the corresponding gain is 110.3% (58.9%) for low other control variables, are able to capture successfully
beta firms. These findings underscore the importance of the variation of the HPR during the crisis. Adding control
controlling for firm risk in detecting the relation between variables does not affect the significance of the disparity
firm performance and governance variables. variable. This result is consistent with Prediction 1 of
In Panel C of Table 2, we use sum of block ownership our model.
by all shareholders as our key expropriation variable. We Among the control variables, previous HPR, logarithm
find that firms with lower block ownership by all share- of total assets, and leverage variables are negatively and
holders realize more loss during the shock period but gain significantly related to HPR during the shock period. In
more during the recovery period, supporting the expro- contrast, squared logarithm of total assets, chaebol
priation hypothesis. dummy, and ADR dummy are positively and significantly
We further break down block ownership into manage- related to HPR.
rial block ownership and nonmanagerial block ownership Our regression analyses for the recovery period begin
and examine their relation to firm performance. Panel D with Regression 4, in which we regress HPR during the
of Table 2 shows that firms with lower managerial block recovery period on the disparity variable. Supporting
ownership have lower returns during the crisis period and Prediction 2 of our model, the result shows that the
higher returns during the recovery period. Nonmanagerial coefficient estimate on the disparity variable is positive
block ownership, however, shows no relation to firm and significant at the 0.01 level.
performance (not reported). In Regression 5, we add beta, firm-specific risk, and
previous HPR as explanatory variables. We find that
4.2. Cross-sectional variation in HPR the coefficient estimate on beta is significantly positive,
whereas the coefficient estimate on previous HPR is
In this subsection we estimate cross-sectional regres- significantly negative.
sion of HPR on firm-specific variables that capture expro- In Regression 6, we control for other variables. Adding
priation while controlling for other variables that could the control variables does not change the magnitude and
affect firm value such as risk and overreaction. significance levels of our key variables.
Table 3 shows the results from the cross-sectional In Table 4, we use equity ownership by controlling
regression. As the dependent variable, Regressions 1 shareholders as the key expropriation measure. In Regres-
through 3 use the HPR during the shock period, and sion 1, we replace the disparity variable in Regression 1
Regressions 4 through 6 use the HPR during the recovery of Table 3 with equity ownership by controlling share-
period. Regression 1 includes the logarithm of the ratio of holders. Consistent with Prediction 1 of our model, we
voting rights to cash flow rights as a key explanatory find that the coefficient estimate on equity ownership by
variable.7 The coefficient estimate on this variable is controlling shareholders is positive and significant.
negative and significant, showing that firms with high In the next model, we add beta, firm-specific risk, and
disparity between voting rights and cash flow rights previous HPR. Beta and previous HPR are negatively
perform worse during the crisis period. related to HPR during the shock period. In contrast, equity
In Regression 2, we include beta, firm-specific risk, and ownership by controlling shareholders is positively
past HPR as explanatory variables, in addition to owner- related to HPR.
ship disparity. We find that the coefficient estimates on In Regression 3, we use the control variables used in
beta, previous HPR, and ownership disparity are negative Table 3. Adding the control variables does not change the
significance of these three variables, except that the
7
coefficient estimate on beta loses its significance.
In untabulated tests, we also experiment with the difference
between control rights and cash flow rights instead of their ratio as an
In Regressions 4 and 5, following Joh (2003), we
alternative measure of the expropriation variable. We obtain similar examine a nonlinear effect of equity ownership by con-
results as those reported in the paper. trolling shareholders on firm value. Morck, Shleifer, and
K.-H. Bae et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 105 (2012) 412–435 423

Table 3
Cross-sectional regression of holding period return (HPR) on expropriation, risk, overreaction, and firm characteristic variables.
The sample contains nonfinancial firms listed on the Korea Stock Exchange during 1997–1998. Cash flow rights of controlling shareholders are the sum
of direct equity ownership and the product of the ownership stakes obtained indirectly along the chain of a pyramid structure for controlling
shareholders. Voting rights of controlling shareholders are the sum of direct equity ownership and the minimum of the level of ownership in the pyramid
structure. Using two-year daily returns preceding the crisis and recovery periods, we estimate beta by the slope of the market model regression and firm-
specific risk as the standard deviation of residual errors from the market model regression. Previous HPR are the holding period returns during the year of
1996 (for the shock period) and HPR during July 1997 to September 1998 (for the recovery period). Top 30 chaebol dummy is a dummy variable that
equals one if the firm belongs to one of the 30 largest business groups in Korea. ADR dummy equals one if the firm is cross-listed in the US stock
exchanges. We measure Tobin’s q as the book value of debt plus market value of equity divided by total assets. Financial investment in affiliated
(nonaffiliated) firms means financial securities invested in affiliated (nonaffiliated) firms. We measure cash flow as the sum of net income and
depreciation. nnn, nn, and n denote significance of the parameter estimates at the 0.01, 0.05, and 0.10 level, respectively.

Variable HPR (crisis period: 7/97–9/98) HPR (recovery period: 10/98–12/99)

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

Intercept  0.673nnn  0.559nnn  0.421 0.956nnn  1.381nn 5.021


(  52.05) (  12.80) (  0.17) (6.79) ( 2.00) (0.20)
Log (voting right/cash flow right)  0.037nn  0.028n  0.037nn 1.173nnn 1.049nnn 1.159nnn
( 2.48) (  1.82) (  2.09) (5.36) (4.79) (4.19)
Beta  0.103nnn  0.069 1.055n 1.772nn
(  2.78) (  1.51) (1.91) (2.52)
Firm-specific risk  0.317  0.040  1.549 1.162
( 0.80) (  0.07) (  0.38) (0.19)
Previous HPR  0.033  0.046n  2.235nnn  2.136nnn
(  1.58) (  1.87) ( 4.97) ( 3.68)
Log (total assets)  0.444n  0.649
(  1.79) (  0.25)
[Log (total assets)]2 0.011n 0.017
(1.68) (0.26)
Total debt/total assets  0.198nnn 0.034
(  2.66) (0.04)
Top 30 chaebol dummy 0.119nnn  0.235
(3.20) (  0.52)
Equity ownership by foreign investors 0.285 0.039n
(1.41) (1.69)
ADR dummy 0.164n 0.732
(1.70) (0.70)
Financial investment in affiliated firms/total assets  0.168  3.292n
(  1.12) ( 1.74)
Financial investment in nonaffiliated firms/total assets  0.085 4.986nn
(  0.51) (2.07)
Tobin’s q 0.004  0.358
(0.11) (  0.44)
Cash flow/total assets 0.385  2.414
(1.26) ( 1.10)
Industry dummies Yes Yes
F-value 6.14 3.74 4.03 28.73 14.55 3.91
Adjusted R2 0.010 0.020 0.107 0.049 0.093 0.097
Sample size 534 526 432 534 526 432

Vishny (1988) present evidence of a nonlinear relation 1 through 3 is particularly evident when ownership con-
between management ownership and firm value. They centration is high. We also find that, in Regression 5, the
show that firm value increases in management ownership coefficient estimate on equity ownership by controlling
at low levels of management ownership and decreases in shareholders is positive and significant, but the coefficient
management ownership at high levels of management estimates on (controlling shareholders’ ownership)2 and
ownership. Thus, to examine whether ownership effects (controlling shareholders’ ownership)3 are not significant.
on firm value during the crisis vary depending on the size Therefore, unlike Joh (2003) who shows a nonlinear effect of
of controlling shareholders’ ownership, in Regression 4, equity ownership by controlling shareholders on firm value,
we use piecewise linear splines from 0–5%, 5–25%, and during the crisis period, ownership concentration seems to
above 25%, and in Regression 5, we include (controlling yield a linear effect on firm value.
shareholders’ ownership)2 and (controlling shareholders’ Regressions 6 through 10 show the results for the
ownership)3 as additional explanatory variables. In Regres- recovery period. The results for Regressions 6, 7, and 8
sion 4, we find that the coefficient estimate on the above are remarkably similar to those for Regressions 4, 5, and 6
25% variable is positive and significant while the coefficient of Table 3. In particular, the coefficient estimates on equity
estimates on the 0–5% and 5–10% variables are positive but ownership by controlling shareholders are negative and
insignificant. Thus, the positive effect of equity ownership by significant, affirming the expropriation incentives of con-
controlling shareholders on firm value shown in Regressions trolling shareholders during the recovery period discussed
424
Table 4
Cross-sectional regression of holding period return (HPR) on expropriation, risk, overreaction, and firm characteristic variables.
The sample contains nonfinancial firms listed on the Korea Stock Exchange during 1997–1998. Equity ownership by controlling shareholders is the sum of equity ownerships by owner-managers and their family
members. Using two-year daily returns preceding each of the crisis and recovery period, we estimate beta by the slope of the market model regression and firm-specific risk as the standard deviation of residual
errors from the market model regression. Previous HPR are the holding period returns during the year of 1996 (for the shock period) and HPR during July 1997 to September 1998 (for the recovery period). Top
30 chaebol dummy is a dummy variable that equals one if the firm belongs to one of the 30 largest business groups in Korea. ADR dummy equals one if the firm is cross-listed in the US stock exchanges. We
measure Tobin’s q as the book value of debt plus market value of equity divided by total assets. Financial investment in affiliated (nonaffiliated) firms means financial securities invested in affiliated (non-
affiliated) firms. We measure cash flow as the sum of net income and depreciation. nnn, nn, and n denote significance of the parameter estimates at the 0.01, 0.05, and 0.10 level, respectively.

Variable HPR (crisis period: 7/97–9/98) HPR (recovery period: 10/98–12/99)

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10)

nnn nnn nnn


Intercept  0.736  0.616  0.447  0.504  0.503 2.222  0.537 5.404 0.498 4.041
(  34.80) (  12.51) ( 0.18) ( 0.20) ( 0.20) (10.18) (  0.84) (0.21) (0.02) (0.18)

K.-H. Bae et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 105 (2012) 412–435


Equity ownership bycontrolling shareholders 0.231nnn 0.196nn 0.221nn 0.103n  0.045nnn  0.039nnn  0.046nnn  0.014nn
(2.86) (2.31) (1.99) (1.94) ( 5.20) ( 4.51) ( 3.75) (  2.20)
Equity ownership by controlling shareholders: 0 to 5% 0.020 0.038
(0.16) (0.76)
Equity ownership by controlling shareholders: 5 to 25% 0.074  0.094nn
(1.12) (  2.00)
Equity ownership by controlling shareholders: Above 25% 0.126nn  0.121nn
(2.01) (  2.53)
(Equity ownership by controlling shareholders)2  0.240 0.382
( 1.13) (1.26)
3
(Equity ownership by controlling shareholders) 0.164  0.039
(0.68) (  0.95)
Beta  0.093nn  0.050  0.042  0.046 1.298nn 1.704nn 1.266nn 1.294nn
(  2.45) (  1.03) ( 0.87) ( 0.94) (2.37) (2.40) (2.04) (2.08)
Firm-specific risk  0.354  0.142  0.126  0.091 0.633 2.089 1.152 0.963
( 0.88) ( 0.24) ( 0.21) ( 0.15) (0.66) (0.35) (0.22) (0.18)
Previous HPR  0.035n  0.046n  0.051nn  0.052nn  2.068nnn  2.176nnn  1.795nnn  1.844nnn
(  1.65) (  1.86) (  2.06) ( 2.10) ( 4.61) (  3.75) (  3.52) (  3.61)
Log (total assets)  0.478n  0.554nn  0.553nn  0.576 0.006 0.014
(  1.92) (  2.20) ( 2.19) ( 0.22) (0.11) (0.24)
Log (total assets)2 0.012n 0.013nn 0.013n 0.105  0.083  0.235
(1.81) (2.08) (2.07) (0.23) (  0.07) (  0.21)
Total debt/total assets  0.184nn  0.183nn  0.190nnn  0.400  0.157  0.231
(  2.46) (  2.46) ( 2.55) ( 0.47) (  0.21) (  0.31)
Top 30 chaebol dummy 0.106nnn 0.108nnn 0.112nnn 0.148 0.161 0.212
(2.82) (2.88) (2.95) (0.34) (0.42) (0.55)
Equity ownership by foreign investors 0.335n 0.305 0.278 0.035 0.031 0.031
(1.67) (1.49) (1.36) (1.52) (1.56) (1.58)
Equity ownership by affiliated firms 0.117 0.191 0.209  0.003  0.091  0.113
(0.93) (1.47) (1.57) ( 0.26) (  0.85) (  1.04)
ADR dummy 0.171n 0.166n 0.166n 0.351 0.328 0.237
(1.77) (1.72) (1.72) (0.34) (0.36) (0.26)
Financial investment in affiliated firms/total assets  0.161  0.166  0.170  3.973nn  3.144n  3.480nn
(  1.06) (  1.10) ( 1.12) ( 2.08) (  1.90) (  2.09)
Financial investment in nonaffiliated firms/total assets  0.088  0.067  0.052 6.274nnn 4.563nn 4.861nn
( 0.52) ( 0.40) ( 0.31) (2.60) (2.16) (2.30)
Tobin’s q  0.009  0.008  0.008  0.149 0.001 0.065
K.-H. Bae et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 105 (2012) 412–435 425

in Section 2. We also find that the coefficient estimates on


 0.149

both the above 25% variable and equity ownership by


(  0.78)
(0.09)

0.093
3.69

432
Yes

controlling shareholders are negative and significant at the


0.05 level in Regressions 9 and 10, further supporting the
expropriation hypothesis. As in the crisis period, we find
no evidence of nonlinear relations between equity own-
0.098
 0.153
(0.01)

(  0.80)

3.56

432
Yes

ership by controlling shareholders and firm value during


the recovery period. Thus, our results suggest that own-
ership effects on firm value differ across the normal and
crisis/recovery periods.8
 0.468
( 0.18)

( 0.98)

0.093
3.61

432
Yes

One concern with our empirical results is that a few


large firms in the Korean equity market dominate other
firms in terms of market capitalization. For instance,
Samsung Electronics has often constituted as much as
14.12
0.090

20% of total equity market capitalization in Korea.


526

Although we control for any nonlinear effect of firm size


on HPR by including squared logarithm of total assets in
the regressions, to further mitigate the concern that our
results are mainly driven by a few extremely large firms,
27.07
0.048
534

we reestimate all regressions in the tables excluding the


ten largest firms from the sample. We also use weighted
least squares to estimate the regressions where the
weight is given by the relative market capitalization.
0.111
0.376
( 0.21)

(1.22)

3.80

432
Yes

Our key results are robust to these alternative tests.


Thus far, our findings indicate that the effects of
governance variables on firm value during the crisis and
recovery periods are opposite to each other. A natural
question that arises is, then, whether over the entire cycle,
0.114
0.342
(1.11)
( 0.20)

3.88

432
Yes

down and up, governance matters for firm value on net.


To address this issue, in untabulated tests, we compute
the holding period return over the entire cycle encom-
passing both the crisis and recovery periods, and we
0.104
0.358
( 0.22)

(1.17)

3.77

432
Yes

regress the computed return on governance variables


and other control variables as in Tables 3 and 4. We find
that neither the disparity variable nor the equity owner-
ship by controlling shareholders is significantly related to
0.023
4.31

the holding period return. This lack of an overall effect of


526

governance on firm value suggests that before the crisis


the stock prices are determined to give a similar expected
risk-adjusted return, irrespective of the strength of firms’
governance. Although firms with poorer governance suf-
0.014
8.20

534

fer more during the crisis period, they also perform better
during the subsequent recovery period. Thus, when one
considers both the crisis and recovery periods, stock
returns are not different across firms with different
governance. These findings help explain why firms with
weak governance are able to survive, together with those
with strong governance, and even predominate in emer-
ging markets.

8
Instead of using a top 30 chaebol dummy, Joh (2003) uses a top 70
chaebol dummy (a dummy that equals one if the firm belongs to one of
Cash flow/total assets

the 70 largest business groups and zero otherwise) in her regression


Industry dummies

analyses. To examine whether our results are robust to using a different


definition of business groups, we replace the top 30 chaebol dummy
Adjusted R2
Sample size

with the top 70 chaebol dummy and reestimate the regressions in


Table 4. In untabulated tests, we find that the coefficient estimates on
F-value

the top 70 chaebol dummy are positive and significant at the 0.10 level
in Regressions 3 through 5, but insignificant in Regressions 8 through 10.
These results are similar to those using a top 30 chaebol dummy.
426 K.-H. Bae et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 105 (2012) 412–435

5. Sensitivity tests Korean economy. We assume that the crisis ended in June
1998, because the stock market index reached its bottom of
In this section, we perform various sensitivity checks 404 in that month.
on our main results. In untabulated tests, we find that when we use these
alternative periods of shock and recovery, the results are
5.1. Alternative measures of corporate governance remarkably similar to those in Table 3. In particular, the
coefficient estimates on the key expropriation variable and
To further investigate the existence of an expropriation their significance levels are almost the same in two tables.
effect, we use various alternative measures of corporate For instance, the coefficient estimate on the logarithm of the
governance as explanatory variables. In Regressions 1 and 2 ratio of voting rights to cash flow rights and its t-statistic in
of Table 5, as a measure of good governance we use the sum Regression 1 of Table 3 are  0.037 and  2.48, respectively.
of block holdings by all shareholders who own 5% or more The corresponding numbers for the same variable in unta-
of issued shares. Unlike small shareholders who like to free bulated tests are 0.035 and  2.36, respectively. Other
ride the corporate governance activities of other share- regressions show similar results.
holders (Grossman and Hart, 1980), large shareholders have We also examine how long the upswing effects last by
strong incentives to monitor managerial performance and extending the recovery period up to December 2000 (2001).
take actions that enhance firm value (Shleifer and Vishny, The results are reported in Table 6. When we redefine the
1986). To the extent that blockholders play an important recovery period to be from October 1998 to December 2000
role in disciplining corporate managers, they reduce owner- and reestimate the regressions in Table 3, we find that the
managers’ incentives to expropriate minority shareholders. coefficient estimates on the logarithm of the ratio of voting
The results are consistent with the prediction of the rights to cash flow rights remain positive and significant,
expropriation hypothesis. In Regression 1, which uses the albeit smaller in magnitude as compared with those reported
HPR during the shock period as the dependent variable, in Table 3 (Regressions 1 through 3). When we further
the coefficient on block ownership is positive and sig- extend the recovery period to the end of 2001, we again find
nificant at the 0.01 level. In contrast, in Regression 2, similar results as those in Table 3, although the statistical
which uses the HPR during the recovery period as the significance of the coefficient estimate on the logarithm of
dependent variable, the coefficient on block ownership is the ratio of voting rights to cash flow rights becomes much
negative and significant at the 0.01 level. weaker than that of the regressions in Table 3.
In the next two regressions, we replace the sum of block
ownership by all shareholders with the largest managerial 5.3. Effects of managerial expropriation on accounting
block ownership and the largest nonmanagerial block own- profitability
ership. We find that the results for largest managerial block
ownership are similar to those for the sum of block own- Increased (reduced) expropriation risk can affect firm
ership by all shareholders. However, the coefficients on the value through two channels: An increase (decrease) in risk
largest nonmanagerial block ownership are not significant. premium used in discounting future cash flows and a
In Regressions 5 and 8, we use the extent of a firm’s decrease (increase) in future cash flows that are expected
diversification as our measure of corporate governance. to be distributed to investors. Here, we examine whether
The results in Regressions 5 and 7 show that, during the poorly governed firms experience a decrease in cash flows
shock period, the interaction term between the diversifi- during the shock period and an increase in cash flows during
cation dummy variable and the dummy variable indicat- the recovery period. We use the changes in net income as our
ing high variation in investment opportunity adversely proxy for the changes in cash flows. For the shock period, as
affects firm value. However, in Regressions 6 and 8, the the dependent variable we use the ratio of the change in net
coefficient on this interaction term becomes positive and income from 1997 to 1998 to total assets in 1997. For the
significant during the recovery period. These results again recovery period, as the dependent variable we use the ratio of
support the expropriation hypothesis. the change in net income from 1998 to 1999 to total assets in
1998.9 Our independent variables are similar to those used in
5.2. Alternative choice of crisis and recovery periods Table 3.

So far, our analysis has set the crisis period from July 9
As expected, the Pearson correlation analysis shows that our measures
1997 to September 1998 and the recovery period from for the changes in firm value during the crisis and recovery periods are
October 1998 to December 1999. Here, we examine if our highly and significantly correlated with the changes in accounting perfor-
results are sensitive to the choice of alternative dates for mance (untabulated). For example, HPR during the crisis period is positively
the crisis and recovery periods. and significantly associated with the ratio of the change in net income from
1996 to 1997 to total assets in 1996 and the ratio of the change in net
As an alternative crisis period, we assume that the crisis
income from 1997 to 1998 to total assets in 1997 (0.24 and 0.25,
started as early as January 1997 and ended in June 1998, and respectively). The results using earnings before interest and taxes (EBIT)
as an alternative recovery period, we assume that the and cash flow as alternative measures of accounting performance are similar
reversal started in July 1998. Anecdotal evidence suggests to those using net income (0.24 to 0.31). We also find that, albeit the relation
that some symptoms of crisis arose starting in early 1997. For is somewhat weak, HPR during the recovery period is positively and
significantly related to the ratio of the change in net income from 1998 to
example, in January 1997, the Hanbo business group, one of 1999 to total assets in 1998 and the ratio of the change in net income from
the fastest growing business groups in Korea, announced its 1999 to 2000 to total assets in 1999 (0.09 and 0.08, respectively). Spearman
default, potentially triggering the financial crisis in the correlation analysis shows similar results.
K.-H. Bae et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 105 (2012) 412–435 427

Table 5
Cross-sectional regression of holding period returns (HPR) on expropriation, risk, overreaction, and firm characteristic variables: using alternative
measures of ownership variables.
The sample contains nonfinancial firms listed on the Korea Stock Exchange during 1997–1998. The crisis period is from July 1997 to September 1998 and the
recovery period is from October 1998 to December 1999. Sum of block ownership is the sum of block holdings by all shareholders owning 5% or more of issued
shares. Largest managerial blockholder concentration refers to block holdings by owners involved with management, and largest nonmanagerial blockholder
concentration refers to block holdings by other largest shareholders. Cash flow rights of controlling shareholders are the sum of direct equity ownership and the
product of the ownership stakes obtained indirectly along the chain of a pyramid structure for controlling shareholders. Voting rights of controlling shareholders
are the sum of direct equity ownership and the minimum of the level of ownership in the pyramid structure. Equity ownership by controlling shareholders is the
sum of equity ownerships by owner-managers and their family members. Diversification dummy takes the value of zero if 90% or more of a firm’s sales come
from one three-digit Standard Industrial Classification. We classify firms as having high (low) variation if the standard deviation of the Tobin’s q ratios of matched
nondiversified firms for all segments of a diversified firm is above (below) the median for all diversified firms. Using two-year daily returns preceding the crisis
and recovery periods, we estimate beta by the slope of the market model regression and firm-specific risk as the standard deviation of residual errors from the
market model regression. Previous HPR are the holding period returns during the year of 1996 (for the shock period) and HPR during July 1997 to September 1998
(for the recovery period). Top 30 chaebol dummy is a dummy variable that equals one if the firm belongs to one of the 30 largest business groups in Korea. ADR
dummy equals one if the firm is cross-listed in the US stock exchanges. We measure Tobin’s q as the book value of debt plus market value of equity divided by
total assets. Financial investment in affiliated (nonaffiliated) firms means financial securities invested in affiliated (nonaffiliated) firms. We measure cash flow as
the sum of net income and depreciation. nnn, nn, and n denote significance of the parameter estimates at the 0.01, 0.05, and 0.10 level, respectively.

Variable HPR HPR HPR HPR HPR HPR HPR HPR


(7/97– (10/98– (7/97– (10/98– (7/97– (10/98– (7/97– (10/98–
9/98) 12/99) 9/98) 12/99) 9/98) 12/99) 9/98) 12/99)
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)

Intercept  0.427 21.098  0.481 20.372  0.487 10.105  0.491 4.046


(  0.70) (0.80) (  0.91) (0.78) ( 0.95) (0.39) (  0.98) (0.19)
nnn nnn
Sum of block ownership by all shareholders 0.309  3.767
(2.76) (  3.18)
Largest managerial block ownership 0.501nnn  5.108nnn
(3.42) (  3.01)
Largest nonmanagerial block ownership 0.021  3.752
(0.07) (  1.29)
Log (voting right/cash flow right)  0.036n 1.019nnn
( 1.94) (3.73)
Equity ownership by controlling shareholders 0.197n  3.727nnn
(1.73) (  3.57)
Diversification  high variation  0.099nn 1.118nnn  0.099nn 0.635nn
( 2.34) (3.16) (  2.37) (2.02)
Diversification  low variation  0.025 0.325  0.022  0.017
( 0.80) (0.69) (  0.68) (  0.04)
Beta  0.027 1.481nn  0.046 1.617nn  0.054 1.716nn  0.054 1.382nn
(  0.55) (2.06) (  0.98) (2.29) ( 1.16) (2.46) (  1.10) (2.30)
Firm-specific risk  0.242 0.626  0.270 0.795  0.103 0.029  0.042 0.169
(  0.41) (0.11) (  0.46) (0.13) ( 0.18) (0.01) (  0.07) (0.03)
Previous HPR  0.044n  2.132nnn  0.045n  2.155nnn  0.046n  2.042nnn  0.047n  1.798nnn
( 1.78) (  3.68) (  1.81) (  3.73) ( 1.88) ( 3.55) (  1.89) (  3.75)
Log (total assets)  0.460n  2.092  0.512nn  2.012  0.513nn  1.121  0.529nn  0.430
( 1.80) (  0.79) (  2.01) (0.76) ( 2.01) (  0.43) (  2.10) (  0.20)
[Log (total assets)]2 0.011n 0.052 0.012n 0.049 0.012n 0.027 0.013nn 0.011
(1.70) (0.77) (1.90) (0.73) (1.90) (0.40) (2.00) (0.20)
Total debt/total assets  0.192nnn 0.444  0.185nn 0.474  0.225nnn 0.546  0.207nnn 0.236
( 2.58) (0.48) (  2.48) (0.56) ( 3.02) (0.66) (  2.76) (0.32)
Top 30 chaebol dummy 0.101nnn 0.181 0.109nnn 0.124 0.115nnn  0.290 0.096nnn 0.332
(2.70) (0.42) (2.94) (0.29) (3.05) (  0.65) (2.57) (0.89)
Equity ownership by foreign investors 0.291 0.038nnn 0.343 n
0.032 0.268 0.035 0.332 0.038nn
(1.43) (3.08) (1.69) (1.41) (1.32) (1.57) (1.62) (1.98)
Equity ownership by affiliated firms 0.079  0.867
(0.62) (  0.86)
ADR dummy 0.160 0.364 0.168n 0.484 0.154 0.614 0.168n 0.105
(1.64) (0.35) (1.74) (0.46) (1.59) (0.60) (1.73) (0.12)
Financial investment in affiliated firms/total assets  0.168  2.020  0.113  2.179  0.133  2.013  0.156  3.536nn
( 1.09) (  1.07) (  0.73) (  1.14) ( 0.86) ( 1.08) (  1.03) (  2.22)
Financial investment in nonaffiliated firms/total assets  0.063 4.515n  0.052 4.332n  0.044 2.898  0.067 5.143nnn
(  0.38) (1.88) (  0.31) (1.79) ( 0.26) (1.21) (  0.40) (2.65)
Tobin’s q  0.007  1.120  0.006  1.185 0.023  0.971 0.016 0.055
(  0.18) (  1.37) (  0.16) (  1.45) (0.54) ( 1.19) (0.38) (0.08)
Cash flow/total assets 0.281  1.132 0.323  1.514 0.395  1.722 0.374  0.108
(0.91) (0.52) (1.05) ( 0.70) (1.29) (  0.80) (1.21) (  0.80)
Industry dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
F-value 3.96 3.18 4.07 2.97 3.84 3.74 3.69 3.75
2
Adjusted R 0.113 0.081 0.122 0.078 0.114 0.105 0.112 0.106
Sample size 420 420 420 420 420 420 420 420
428 K.-H. Bae et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 105 (2012) 412–435

Table 6
Cross-sectional regression of holding period returns (HPR) on expropriation, risk, overreaction, and firm characteristic variables: using alternative
definitions of recovery period.
The sample contains nonfinancial firms listed on the Korea Stock Exchange during 1997–1998. Cash flow rights of controlling shareholders are the sum
of direct equity ownership and the product of the ownership stakes obtained indirectly along the chain of a pyramid structure for controlling
shareholders. Voting rights of controlling shareholders are the sum of direct equity ownership and the minimum of the level of ownership in the pyramid
structure. Using two-year daily returns preceding the crisis and recovery periods, we estimate beta by the slope of the market model regression and firm-
specific risk as the standard deviation of residual errors from the market model regression. Previous HPR are the holding period returns during the year of
1996 (for the shock period) and HPR during July 1997 to September 1998 (for the recovery period). Top 30 chaebol dummy is a dummy variable that
equals one if the firm belongs to one of the 30 largest business groups in Korea. ADR dummy equals one if the firm is cross-listed in the US stock
exchanges. We measure Tobin’s q as the book value of debt plus market value of equity divided by total assets. Financial investment in affiliated
(nonaffiliated) firms means financial securities invested in affiliated (nonaffiliated) firms. We measure cash flow as the sum of net income and
depreciation. nnn, nn, and n denote significance of the parameter estimates at the 0.01, 0.05, and 0.10 level, respectively.

Variable HPR (recovery period: 10/98–12/2000) HPR (recovery period: 10/98–12/2001)

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

Intercept 0.232nnn 0.333nn 0.121 0.361nnn 0.388n 0.241


(7.16) (2.11) (0.02) (8.91) (1.90) (0.52)
Log (voting right/cash flow right) 0.111nn 0.123nnn 0.196nn 0.125nn 0.136nn 0.133n
(2.30) (2.64) (2.51) (2.08) (2.27) (1.69)
Beta  0.171 0.190  0.145 0.027
(  1.35) (1.35) (  0.88) (0.11)
Firm-specific risk  1.486  1.185  1.382  1.988
(  0.25) (  1.32) (  1.16) (  1.32)
Previous HPR  0.189n  0.349nn  0.259n  0.042
(  1.80) (  1.99) (  1.92) ( 0.20)
Log (total assets) 0.045  0.023
(0.09) ( 0.52)
[Log (total assets)]2  0.002 0.019
( 0.17) (0.08)
Total debt/total assets 0.215 0.552nn
(1.28) (2.46)
Top 30 chaebol dummy 0.005  0.037
(0.05) ( 0.35)
Equity ownership by foreign investors 0.009n 0.032nn
(1.94) (2.36)
ADR dummy 0.141 0.777
(0.67) (1.57)
Financial investment in affiliated firms/total assets  0.653n  0.966
(  1.72) (  1.63)
Financial investment in nonaffiliated firms/total assets 0.284 1.092nn
(0.59) (2.38)
Tobin’s q 0.015 0.045
(0.09) (0.42)
Cash flow/total assets  0.412  0.207
( 0.93) ( 0.42)
Industry dummies Yes Yes
F-value 5.27 3.42 3.49 4.32 2.69 2.90
Adjusted R2 0.008 0.019 0.085 0.006 0.014 0.027
Sample size 534 526 432 534 526 432

We report the results in Table 7. Regressions 1 through 4 Regressions 5 through 8 use the change in net income
use the change in net income during the shock period as the during the recovery period as the dependent variable. In
dependent variable. In Regression 1, we use the disparity Regressions 5 and 6, we find that the coefficient estimates
variable as an explanatory variable. The coefficient estimate on the disparity variable are positive and significant at the
on the disparity variable is negative and significant at the 0.01 level. In Regressions 7 and 8, we find negative and
0.05 level. Regression 2 adds various control variables used in significant estimates on equity ownership by controlling
Table 3. Adding the control variables does not change the shareholders.
results. The results for the regression estimates of the These results are consistent with the predictions of the
leverage variables and the dummy for the top 30 chaebol model developed in Section 2. The results also suggest
are remarkably similar to those shown in Regression 3 of that the expropriation of minority shareholders is the key
Table 3, in which we use HPR during the shock period as the factor that determines the link between corporate gov-
dependent variable. These results are consistent with those of ernance and firm value.
Joh (2003).
In Regressions 3 and 4 we replace the disparity vari- 5.4. Endogenous issue and event study
able with equity ownership by controlling shareholders.
The coefficient estimates on equity ownership by control- The advantage of focusing on a crisis period is that it
ling shareholders are positive and significant. allows us to examine unambiguously the effect of
K.-H. Bae et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 105 (2012) 412–435 429

corporate governance on firm value. In other words, recovery period. Consequently, our findings that poorly
because the Asian financial crisis represents an exogenous governed firms experience larger increase in their share
shock to the economy, we can largely eliminate any values during the recovery period could be subject to
spurious causality due to the endogeneity problem. In interpretations other than the expropriation hypothesis.
the context of our model, the exogenous shock ensures To address the possible endogeneity issue, we consider
that the managerial equity ownership (a) and expropria- other exogenous events during the 1997–1998 period and
tion power (m) are independent of the profitability of firm examine the relation between the change in firm value due
investment. to such events and a set of governance variables at the fiscal
However, the effect of corporate governance on firm year-end that immediately precedes the announcement
value during the recovery period is not free from the date of events. For the 1997–1998 period, we select ten
endogeneity problem. For example, it could be that firms bad news events that signal deteriorating future investment
adapt their governance structures in such a way that they opportunities in the economy, events that are likely to
fit better in a recovering economy. That is, if managers are provide controlling shareholders strong incentives to expro-
able to correctly anticipate when recovery will start, they priate. These events include a downgrade of the sovereign
could try to increase their ability to raise future capital rating of Korea by Moody’s or other rating agencies, the
through increasing a and relinquish some of their expro- nationalization of troubled commercial banks by the Korean
priation power m by adopting more stringent governance government, chaebol bankruptcy, and Russian default on
rules. Should that be the case, our model predications government bonds. We also select eight good news events
would no longer apply, as variables a and m are deter- that are associated with brighter prospects for future
mined in part by the profitability of investment during the investment opportunities, events that are likely to reduce

Table 7
Cross-sectional regression of change in net income on expropriation, risk, overreaction, and firm characteristic variables.
The sample contains nonfinancial firms listed on the Korea Stock Exchange during 1997–1998. Cash flow rights of controlling shareholders are the sum
of direct equity ownership and the product of the ownership stakes obtained indirectly along the chain of a pyramid structure for controlling
shareholders. Voting rights of controlling shareholders are the sum of direct equity ownership and the minimum of the level of ownership in the pyramid
structure. Equity ownership by controlling shareholders is the sum of equity ownerships by owner-managers and their family members. Top 30 chaebol
dummy is a dummy variable that equals one if the firm belongs to one of the 30 largest business groups in Korea. ADR dummy equals one if the firm is
cross-listed in the US stock exchanges. We measure Tobin’s q as the book value of debt plus market value of equity divided by total assets. Financial
investment in affiliated (nonaffiliated) firms means financial securities invested in affiliated (nonaffiliated) firms. We measure cash flow as the sum of net
income and depreciation. nnn, nn, and n denote significance of the parameter estimates at the 0.01, 0.05, and 0.10 level, respectively.

Variable Change in net income from 1997 to 1998/total Change in net income from 1998 to 2000/total
assets in 1997 assets in 1998

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)

Intercept  0.041 4.627  0.175nnn 4.862 0.074nnn  6.053n 0.176nnn  5.700n


( 1.53) (1.26) (  4.24) (1.33) (3.67) ( 1.81) (5.52) (  1.69)
Log (voting right/cash flow right)  0.097nn  0.113nnn 0.116nnn 0.126nnn
( 2.28) (  2.85) (3.59) (3.31)
Equity ownership by controlling shareholders 0.511nn 0.539nnn  0.330nnn  0.410nn
(3.16) (3.27) (  2.64) (  2.50)
Log (total asset)  0.429  0.468 0.600n 0.574n
(  1.14) ( 1.24) (1.76) (1.67)
[Log (total assets)]2 0.011 0.012  0.015n  0.015n
(1.11) (1.21) ( 1.79) (  1.70)
nnn
Total debt/total assets  0.376  0.372nnn 0.453nnn 0.416nnn
(  2.75) ( 2.73) (3.92) (3.55)
Top 30 chaebol dummy 0.188nnn 0.134nn  0.116n  0.058
(3.02) (2.25) ( 1.93) (  0.99)
Equity ownership by foreign investors 0.361 0.428  0.159  0.196
(1.14) (1.36) (  0.53) (  0.64)
Equity ownership by affiliated firms 0.325n  0.113
(1.76) (  0.72)
ADR dummy 0.098 0.065 0.219 0.164
(0.62) (0.42) (1.52) (1.13)
Financial investment in affiliated firms/total assets 0.228 0.260  0.443  0.475n
(0.87) (0.99) ( 1.61) (  1.71)
Financial investment in nonaffiliated firms/total asset  1.878nnn  1.919nnn 2.724nnn 2.887nnn
(  3.26) ( 3.34) (4.53) (4.79)
Tobin’s q  0.058  0.088 0.020 0.044
( 0.93) ( 1.40) (0.19) (0.41)
n
Cash flow/total assets 0.846 0.838n  0.656nn  0.653nn
(1.74) (1.72) ( 2.13) (  2.11)
Industry dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes
F-value 5.20 3.54 10.02 3.50 12.87 6.12 9.43 5.29
Adjusted R2 0.008 0.081 0.028 0.085 0.023 0.142 0.016 0.130
Sample size 498 405 498 405 498 405 498 405
430 K.-H. Bae et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 105 (2012) 412–435

Table 8
Fixed effect regression of cumulative abnormal return (CAR) on expropriation, risk, overreaction, and firm characteristic variables.
The sample contains nonfinancial firms listed on the Korea Stock Exchange during 1997–1998. For the period of 1997–1998, we select ten bad news
events that signal deteriorating investment opportunities in the future economy and eight good news events that are associated with brighter prospect for
future investment opportunities as the sample events. See the appendix for the list of these events. We compute the abnormal announcement return by
estimating the market model. We use the KOSPI (Korea Composite Stock Price Index) return as the benchmark. We estimate the market model by using two
hundred trading days of return data ending 20 days before the event announcement. Then, we collect the daily abnormal returns to get the cumulative
abnormal return from day  5 before the announcement date to day þ 5 after the announcement date. We compute the CAR ( 5, 5) for each news event
and for each sample firm. We then pool all CARs across firms and events. The regression includes a dummy variable for each event. We use firm
characteristics and governance variables at the fiscal year-end of 1996 (1997) for the events taking place during 1997 (1998). Cash flow rights of controlling
shareholders are the sum of direct equity ownership and the product of the ownership stakes obtained indirectly along the chain of a pyramid structure for
controlling shareholders. Voting rights of controlling shareholders are the sum of direct equity ownership and the minimum of the level of ownership in the
pyramid structure. Equity ownership by controlling shareholders is the sum of equity ownerships by owner-managers and their family members. Sum of
block ownership is the sum of block holdings by all shareholders owning 5% or more of issued shares. Largest managerial blockholder concentration refers to
block holdings by owners involved with management, and largest nonmanagerial blockholder concentration refers to block holdings by other largest
shareholders. Top 30 chaebol dummy is a dummy variable that equals one if the firm belongs to one of the 30 largest business groups in Korea. ADR dummy
equals one if the firm is cross-listed in the US stock exchanges. We measure Tobin’s q as the book value of debt plus market value of equity divided by total
assets. Financial investment in affiliated (nonaffiliated) firms means financial securities invested in affiliated (nonaffiliated) firms. We measure cash flow as
the sum of net income and depreciation. nnn, nn, and n denote significance of the parameter estimates at the 0.01, 0.05, and 0.10 level, respectively.

Variable CAR ( 5, 5) for bad news events CAR ( 5, 5) for good news events

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)

Intercept  0.036  0.065  0.054  0.055 0.157n 0.127n 0.136n 0.149n


( 0.49) ( 0.89) ( 0.74) ( 0.74) (1.93) (1.65) (1.77) (1.91)
nnn
Log (voting right/cash flow right)  0.016 0.006
( 3.88) (1.56)
Equity ownership by controlling shareholders 0.060nnn  0.062nnn
(2.67) (  2.58)
Equity ownership by affiliated firms 0.044n  0.008
(1.88) ( 0.33)
Sum of block ownership by all shareholders 0.052nnn  0.038n
(2.71) (  1.92)
Largest managerial block ownership 0.075nn  0.076nn
(2.42) (  2.28)
Largest nonmanagerial block ownership 0.027  0.012
(0.98) (  0.39)
Beta  0.065nnn  0.058nnn  0.056nnn  0.060nnn 0.058nnn 0.060nnn 0.054nnn 0.057nnn
( 6.12) (  5.33) (  5.19) (  5.60) (4.47) (4.77) (4.30) (4.57)
Firm-specific risk  0.022  0.051 0.079  0.071  0.099  0.106  0.094  0.104
(0.19) ( 0.44) ( 0.68) (0.61) ( 0.79) ( 0.88) (  0.78) (  0.86)
nnn nnn nnn
Log (total asset) 0.011 0.010 0.010 0.010nnn  0.009nn  0.008nn  0.009nn  0.009nnn
(3.45) (2.96) (2.92) (3.04) (  2.49) (  2.31) (  2.53) (  2.68)
Total debt/total assets  0.114nnn  0.104nnn  0.101nnn  0.103nnn 0.028n 0.025n 0.031nn 0.032nn
( 8.26) (  7.60) (  7.41) (  7.63) (1.85) (1.68) (2.14) (2.21)
Top 30 chaebol dummy 0.032nnn 0.023nnn 0.019nn 0.023nnn  0.005  0.008  0.001  0.006
(3.92) (2.92) (2.52) (3.02) ( 0.60) ( 0.94) (  0.11) (  0.70)
Equity ownership by foreign investors 0.121nnn 0.172nnn 0.146nnn 0.156nnn  0.032  0.048  0.036  0.050
(3.15) (4.61) (3.98) (4.22) ( 0.72) (  1.19) (  0.92) (  1.27)
ADR dummy 0.020 0.039nn 0.039nn 0.037nn 0.037n 0.037nn 0.037nn 0.038nn
(1.07) (2.19) (2.24) (2.13) (1.77) (2.01) (2.03) (2.09)
Financial investment in affiliated firms/total assets  0.018  0.012  0.032  0.024  0.007 0.012 0.014 0.005
( 0.56) ( 0.37) (  1.01) ( 0.74) ( 0.19) (0.35) (0.39) (0.14)
nnn nnn nnn
Financial investment in nonaffiliated firms/total asset  0.101  0.116  0.116  0.119nnn  0.001  0.020  0.034  0.029
( 2.74) (  3.24) (  3.23) (  3.31) ( 0.02) ( 0.49) (  0.84) (  0.71)
Tobin’s q 0.028nnn 0.028nnn 0.023nn 0.026nnn 0.002 0.010 0.003 0.002
(2.83) (2.77) (2.39) (2.65) (0.14) (0.77) (0.28) (0.14)
Cash flow/total assets 0.083n 0.068 0.068 0.073  0.071  0.074  0.062  0.066
(1.76) (1.45) (1.46) (1.57) (  1.51) (  1.65) (  1.37) (  1.46)
F-test (p-value) for the hypothesis that all event 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000
dummies estimates are zero
F-test (F-value) 191.72 188.77 189.29 189.20 33.84 33.18 32.58 32.69
Industry dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
F-value 77.93 74.76 77.96 74.31 12.41 12.13 12.19 11.76
Adjusted R2 0.276 0.270 0.271 0.270 0.064 0.061 0.059 0.059
Sample size 4,634 4,785 4,760 4,765 3,701 3,960 3,952 3,950

controlling shareholders’ incentives to expropriate. and abolition of restrictions on foreign direct equity
The good news events include an upgrade of the sovereign investment. The appendix describes all these events. To
rating of Korea by Moody’s or other rating agencies, the extent that investors are not able to forecast the
settlement of the negotiation on foreign debt payments, occurrence of these events, they represent exogenous
K.-H. Bae et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 105 (2012) 412–435 431

events. Thus, these events provide a natural experiment to Overall, our results in this section provide further
test the link between firm value and corporate governance convincing evidence that controlling shareholders’ expro-
without involving the endogeneity issue. priation incentives imply a link between corporate gov-
To measure the announcement returns related to good ernance and firm value.
and bad news events, we compute the abnormal return by
estimating the market model. We use the KOSPI return as
6. Out-of-sample tests
the benchmark. We obtain our estimates of the market
model by using two hundred trading days of return data
In this section we further check the robustness of the
ending 20 days before the event announcement. Then, we
results by conducting out-of-sample tests that use firms
sum the daily abnormal returns to get the cumulative
in other Asian and Latin American countries.
abnormal return (CAR) from day  5 before the announce-
ment date to day þ5 after the announcement date.
Table 8 shows the results for the fixed effect regression 6.1. Out-of-sample test using firms in other Asian countries
of CARs (  5, 5) on governance and control variables. To during and after the 1997 Asian financial crisis
estimate the fixed effect regression, we first compute the
CARs for each news event and for each sample firm. We We reestimate Tables 3 and 4 using 598 firms from seven
then pool all CARs across firms and events. We use as East Asian countries [Hong Kong (145 firms), Indonesia (65
independent variables the firm characteristics and gov- firms), Malaysia (103 firms), Philippines (41 firms), Singapore
ernance variables at the fiscal year-end of 1996 (1997) for (109 firms), Taiwan (105 firms), and Thailand (35 firms)] that
the events that take place during 1997 (1998). Finally, we are listed on the stock exchanges during the period from July
add a dummy variable for each event, so that any 1997 to December 1999.
common movement in a sample firm’s CARs is captured Our sample selection procedures are as follows. We
by the fixed effect. By testing the joint hypothesis that all start with the list of firms analyzed in Claessens, Djankov,
event dummies have zero coefficients, we should then and Lang (2000) and obtain data on the ownership
have a testable hypothesis that common movements structures of these firms from the Journal of Financial
across firms on the same announcement date are statis- Economics website (http://jfe.rochester.edu/data.htm).
tically significant. We then restrict our sample firms to those whose stock
Regressions 1–4 are for the bad news events and returns data are available in the Datastream International.
Regressions 5–8 are for the good news events. In Regres- Finally, we obtain financial data from Worldscope. This
sion 1, we examine the effect of a disparity variable on the selection procedure results in a final sample of 598 firms.
announcement returns. The coefficient estimate is nega- Table 9 shows the results from reestimating the regres-
tive and significant at the 0.01 level, consistent with the sions in Table 3 using sample firms from the other seven East
expropriation arguments discussed in Section 2. In Asian countries. The first three regressions show the impact
Regression 2, we replace the disparity variable with of ownership disparity on HPR during the shock period. In
controlling shareholders’ equity ownership. The coeffi- Regression 1, we include as the explanatory variable the
cient estimate is positive and significant at the 0.01 level. logarithm of the ratio of voting rights to cash flow rights. The
In Regression 3, we use the sum of block ownership by all regression controls for country and ten industry dummy
shareholders as a measure of corporate governance. This variables, but, for brevity, the estimates are not reported. The
variable is again positively and significantly related to coefficient estimate on the disparity variable is negative and
CARs (  5, 5) at the 0.01 level. In Regression 4, we replace significant at the 0.05 level. In Regression 2, we add beta,
the sum of block ownership with the largest managerial firm-specific risk, and previous HPR as explanatory variables.
block ownership and the largest nonmanagerial block The magnitude and significance level of the estimate on the
ownership. We find that only the coefficient on the largest disparity variable drop a little, but the estimate is still
managerial block ownership is positive and significant at significant at the 0.05 level. In Regression 3, we add other
the 0.05 level. firm-specific variables, including log of total assets, squared
For the good news events in Regressions 5 through 8, we logarithm of total assets, leverage, Tobin’s q, and cash flow
find that the signs of the coefficient estimates on governance over total assets. We find that the coefficient estimate on the
variables are opposite to those in Regressions 1 through 4. disparity variable is negative and significant at the 0.10 level.
With the exception of the disparity variable in Regression 5, These results are consistent with Prediction 1 of our model.
which is not significant, the coefficient estimates on all other The next three regressions show the impact of ownership
governance variables are negative and significant.10 disparity on firm value during the recovery period. In all
specifications, we find significantly positive estimates on the
10 disparity variable at the 0.01 level, supporting Prediction 2 of
Among our exogenous events, some events could be more
exogenous than others. For instance, the Russian default appears to our model. The adjusted R2s in Regressions 4, 5, and 6 are
satisfy the golden standard of exogeneity, as it would be almost higher than those in Regressions 1, 2, and 3, suggesting that
impossible for Korean firms to affect Russian government default. When
we examine the cross-sectional regression of CARs (  5, 5) associated
with this exogenous event only on governance variables, we find that (footnote continued)
the CARs ( 5, 5) are negatively and insignificantly related to the dependent variable, we find a significantly negative (positive) relation
coefficient on ownership disparity. We find that the CARs (  5, 5) are between the CARs (  1, 1) and the disparity (equity ownership by
positively and significantly related to the coefficient on equity owner- controlling shareholders) variable. We thank Jordan Siegel for suggesting
ship by controlling shareholders. When we use CARs (  1, 1) as the Russian government default as the strictly exogenous event.
432 K.-H. Bae et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 105 (2012) 412–435

Table 9
Cross-sectional regression of holding period returns (HPR) on expropriation, risk, overreaction, and firm characteristic variables: out-of-sample tests
using firms in seven East Asian countries.
The sample contains nonfinancial firms in seven East Asian countries (Hong Kong, Indonesia, Malaysia, Philippines, Singapore, Taiwan, and Thailand)
that are listed in the stock exchanges during the period from July 1997 to December 1999. Stock return and financial data are obtained from Datastream
and Worldscope, respectively. Data on voting rights and cash flow rights of the largest shareholders are obtained from Claessens, Djankov, and Lang
(2000). Using two-year daily returns preceding the crisis and recovery periods, we estimate beta by the slope of the market model regression and firm-
specific risk as the standard deviation of residual errors from the market model regression. Previous HPR are the holding period returns during the year of
1996 (for the shock period) and HPR during July 1997 to September 1998 (for the recovery period). We measure Tobin’s q as the book value of debt plus
market value of equity divided by total assets. We measure cash flow as the sum of net income and depreciation. nnn, nn, and n denote significance of the
parameter estimates at the 0.01, 0.05, and 0.10 level, respectively.

Variable HPR (crisis period: 07/97–09/98) HPR (recovery period:10/98–12/99)

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

Intercept  0.74nnn  0.58nnn  0.75nnn 0.67  1.22  0.91


(  4.26) ( 3.54) ( 3.23) (0.69) ( 1.29) (  0.49)
Log (voting right/cash flow right)  0.13nn  0.10nn  0.07n 1.07nnn 0.96nnn 1.24nnn
(  2.52) ( 2.21) ( 1.67) (3.74) (3.50) (3.91)
Beta  0.15nnn  0.11nnn 0.79nnn 0.53n
( 3.80) ( 3.02) (3.13) (1.67)
Firm-specific risk 0.00 0.00 0.22nnn 0.23nnn
(0.42) (0.09) (5.30) (3.19)
Previous HPR  0.02  0.02  0.82nnn  1.09nnn
( 1.10) ( 1.23) ( 3.43) ( 3.19)
Log (total assets) 0.03  0.55n
(0.84) ( 1.95)
[Log (total assets)]2  0.00 0.04nnn
( 0.37) (2.65)
Total debt/total assets  0.11  0.03
( 1.26) (  0.04)
Tobin’s q  0.00 0.07
( 0.06) (0.40)
Cash flow/total assets 0.71nnn 1.99nn
(3.38) (2.30)
Country dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Industry dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
F-value 9.31 9.62 8.48 12.35 15.62 9.95
Adjusted R2 0.16 0.20 0.26 0.21 0.30 0.30
Sample size 598 585 478 598 585 469

Argentina Merval Stock Price Index


1,200

1,000

800

600

400

200

0
January June December June December June December
2001 2001 2001 2002 2002 2003 2003

Fig. 3. Changes in the Argentina Merval Stock Price Index from January 2001 to December 2003. Merval index is the most important index of the Buenos
Aires Stock Exchange and is a price-weighted index of a portfolio of stocks selected based on their market share, number of transactions, and
quotation price.
K.-H. Bae et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 105 (2012) 412–435 433

Table 10
Cross-sectional regression of holding period returns (HPR) on expropriation, risk, overreaction, and firm characteristic variables: out-of-sample tests
using firms in four Latin American countries.
The sample contains nonfinancial firms in four Latin American countries (Argentina, Brazil, Chile, and Mexico) that are listed in the stock exchanges
during the period from January 2001 to July 2003. Stock return and financial data are obtained from Datastream and Worldscope, respectively. Data on
inside ownership (equity ownership held by officers, directors, and their immediate families) are obtained from Worldscope. Using two-year daily
returns preceding the crisis and recovery periods, we estimate beta by the slope of the market model regression and firm-specific risk as the standard
deviation of residual errors from the market model regression. Previous HPR are the holding period returns during the year of 2000 (for the shock period)
and HPR during August 2001 to July 2002 (for the recovery period). We measure Tobin’s q as the book value of debt plus market value of equity divided by
total assets. We measure cash flow as the sum of net income and depreciation. nnn, nn, and n denote significance of the parameter estimates at the 0.01,
0.05, and 0.10 level, respectively.

Variable HPR (crisis period: 01/01–07/02) HPR (recovery period: 08/02–07/03)

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

Intercept 0.07  0.04  0.81 3.15nnn 4.32nnn 4.92nnn


(0.23) (  0.11) ( 1.34) (4.48) (4.29) (2.66)
Inside ownership 0.43nnn 0.56nnn 0.45nn  0.66nn  0.83n  0.79n
(3.16) (3.37) (2.59) (  1.99) (  1.86) (  1.66)
Beta  0.20nn  0.13 0.00 0.03
(  2.02) ( 1.21) (0.02) (0.11)
Firm-specific risk  0.02n  0.00 0.00  0.01
(  1.67) ( 0.24) (0.12) (  0.32)
Previous HPR 0.00 0.10  0.13  0.04
(0.04) (1.29) ( 0.69) (  0.21)
Log (total assets) 0.18n  0.10
(1.72) (  0.34)
[Log (total assets)]2  0.01 0.00
( 1.49) (0.08)
Total debt/total assets  0.01 0.02
( 0.44) (0.34)
Tobin’s q  0.01  0.04
( 0.68) (  1.32)
Cash flow/total assets 0.13nn  0.07
(2.06) (  1.21)
Country dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Industry dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
F-value 3.04 3.13 3.03 6.29 5.35 3.92
Adjusted R2 0.07 0.12 0.15 0.16 0.23 0.22
Sample size 302 204 201 302 195 192

NPV of Investment.

the impact of ownership disparity on firm value is greater abandonment of peso–dollar parity in January 2002, which
during the recovery period than during the shock period. resulted in almost 40% devaluation of the peso.
While not reported, we reestimate the regressions in Fig. 3 shows the changes in the Merval index (Argen-
Table 4 using our out-of-sample firms. Consistent with tina’s main stock market index) from January 2001 to
the predictions of our model, we find that equity owner- December 2003. The Merval index is a price-weighted
ship by the largest shareholder is positively related to the index and is considered the most important index of the
HPR during the shock period and negatively related to the Buenos Aires Stock Exchange. At the beginning of January
HPR during the recovery period. 2001, the Merval index was 464. Although it went
through periods of ups and downs, it showed continuing
6.2. Out-of-sample test using firms in Latin American downward trends until reaching a low of 313 in June
countries during and after the 2002 Argentine currency crisis 2002. Since then, the Merval index continued to rise until
reaching its highest level of 1,102 in December 2003
To further test the prediction of our model, we experi- during the past three years. This fluctuation in the Merval
ment with the Argentine currency crisis of 2002 using the index from 2001 to 2003 suggests that investors would
sample of Latin American firms. In 1991, the Argentine have realized holding period returns of almost 33% and
government passed a convertibility law that linked the peso 250%, respectively, during January 2001–June 2002 and
to the US dollar at parity. The initial effects of this law on the during July 2002–December 2003, if they had invested in
Argentine economy were positive, as Argentina’s chronic the market portfolio.
inflation was curtailed and foreign investment poured in. While its impact was not as pervasive as the Asian
However, as the US dollar appreciated on the world market, financial crisis of 1997, the 2001 Argentine currency crisis
the Argentine peso became stronger as well, which hurt also affected many firms in several Latin American countries.
Argentina’s export trade and caused a protracted economic In particular, Brazil, an important trading partner of Argen-
downturn with soaring inflation and increasing unemploy- tina, was severely hit by the crisis. The level of the Brazilian
ment. The continued economic crisis led to the stock index, BOVESPA, was 17,673 at the beginning of 2001
434 K.-H. Bae et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 105 (2012) 412–435

but became almost a half of that by September 2002. The expropriation in linking corporate governance and firm
index bounced back to more than 22,000 by December 2003. value. We find that poorly governed firms, i.e., firms that
The fact that Argentina went through the cycle of economic have
crisis and recovery during 2001–2003 and its crisis affected a high disparity between voting and cash flow rights,
other Latin American countries (particularly Brazil) makes those that have low equity ownership by controlling
the Argentina’s economic crisis particularly suited to our shareholders, those that have low block ownership, and
investigation of the expropriation hypothesis. those that are highly diversified, suffer more during the
We select the sample of Latin American firms as crisis period but rebound more during the recovery
follows. We start with the list of all Latin American firms period. We also find that bad (good) news in the economy
covered in the Worldscope. We then restrict our sample affects firms with weak corporate governance more nega-
firms to those whose stock returns data are available in tively (positively) than those firms with good corporate
the Datastream International. Finally, we require the governance. These results support the expropriation
country to have at least ten firms available in both hypothesis.
Worldscope and Datastream International. This selection We also find results that are somewhat consistent with
procedure results in a final sample of 302 firms from the explanations based on risk and overreaction. Stock
Argentina (10 firms), Brazil (185 firms), Chile (92 firms), prices of high-beta firms perform worse during the crisis
and Mexico (15 firms). Because inside ownership (equity period but rebound more during the recovery period.
ownership held by officers, directors, and their immediate Similarly, firms whose stock prices drop more during
families) is the only ownership variable available in the pre-crisis (crisis) period perform better during the
Worldscope, we use it as our main expropriation variable crisis (recovery) period, indicating that the contrarian
in testing our model. We set the period from January 2001 effects in stock returns play an important role in explain-
to June 2002 as the crisis period and the period from July ing the cross-sectional variation in firm value during the
2002 to December 2003 as the recovery period. aftermath of the Asian financial crisis. However, control-
Table 10 shows the results from reestimating the ling for beta and overreaction effects does not reduce the
regressions in Table 3 using the sample of 302 Latin importance of governance variables in explaining the
American firms. The first three regressions show the change in firm value.
impact of inside ownership on HPR during the crisis Our results suggest that controlling shareholders’
period. In Regression 1, we include only inside ownership incentives to expropriate minority shareholders are a
as the explanatory variable. The regression controls for key factor that implies a link between corporate govern-
country and industry dummy variables. The coefficient ance and firm value during the crisis period.
estimate on inside ownership is positive and significant at
the 0.01 level. In Regression 2, we add beta, firm-specific
risk, and previous HPR as explanatory variables. We lose Appendix A
about one hundred sample firms due to lack of data.
Nevertheless, the magnitude and significance level of the See Table A1.
coefficient estimate on inside ownership remain
unchanged. In Regression 3, we add other firm-specific
variables. Because information on depreciation amount is
Table A1
missing in Worldscope for many of our sample firms, we Major exogenous events in the Korean economy from January 1997 to
are not able to calculate cash flow over total assets and December 1998.
use it in Regression 3. Thus, to minimize the loss of
Announcement Description of events
sample in estimating the regression, we replace cash flow
date
over total assets with return on assets. We find that the
coefficient estimate on the ownership variable is positive Bad news
and significant at the 0.05 level. These results are con- 1997/01/23 Hanbo business group announces its default
sistent with Prediction 1 of our model. 1997/07/15 Kia business group files for bankruptcy
1997/10/25 S&P downgrades the sovereign rating of Korea
The next three regressions show the impact of inside
to A þ
ownership on firm value during the recovery period. In all 1997/11/22 Korean government seeks a rescue package from
specifications, we find the significantly negative coeffi- the IMF to control the financial crisis
cient estimates on the ownership variable, which support 1997/12/09 Korean government announces the nationalization
of the Korea First Bank and the Seoul Bank
Prediction 2 of our model.
1998/03/06 Moody’s downgrades the sovereign rating of Korea
Overall, the results using out-of-sample firms provide 1998/04/04 Moody’s downgrades the sovereign rating of Japan
further evidence that expropriation risk is the main 1998/05/12 Moody’s downgrades credit ratings of 19
channel through which corporate governance affects commercial banks
firm value. 1998/08/18 Russia defaults on government bonds
1998/10/13 Moody’s warns of possible downgrades of the
sovereign rating of Korea
7. Summary and conclusions
Good news
1997/03/25 OECD updates the sovereign rating of Korea
In this paper, we use the experience of East Asian and 1997/12/25 IMF and G-7 countries make US$10 billion
Latin American firms during the post-crisis recovery available to Korea
period to examine the importance of managerial 1998/01/28 Negotiations on foreign debt payments are settled
K.-H. Bae et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 105 (2012) 412–435 435

Table A1 (continued ) Fogel, K., 2006. Oligarchic family control, social economic outcomes, and
the quality of government. Journal of International Business Studies
Announcement Description of events 37, 603–622.
date Friedman, E., Johnson, S., Mitton, T., 2003. Propping and tunneling.
Journal of Comparative Economics 31, 732–750.
1998/02/17 S&P upgrades the sovereign rating of Korea by Grossman, S.J., Hart, O.D., 1980. Takeover bids, the free-rider problem,
and the theory of the corporation. Bell Journal of Economics 11,
three levels
42–64.
1998/03/28 Moody’s upgrades the sovereign rating of Korea to
Hung, M., 2001. Accounting standards and value relevance of financial
‘‘stable’’ statements: an international analysis. Journal of Accounting and
1998/05/16 Restrictions on foreign direct equity investment Economics 30, 401–420.
are abolished Jensen, M.C., 1986. Agency costs of free cash flow, corporate finance, and
1998/10/19 S&P upgrades the sovereign rating of Korea to takeovers. American Economic Review 7, 323–329.
‘‘stable’’ Joh, S.W., 2003. Corporate governance and firm profitability: evidence
1998/12/05 Moody’s upgrades the rating of Korea government from Korea before the economic crisis. Journal of Financial Econom-
bond denominated in Korean won ics 68, 287–322.
Johnson, S., Boone, P., Breach, A., Friedman, E., 2000. Corporate govern-
ance in the Asian financial crisis, 1997–98. Journal of Financial
Economics 58, 141–186.
La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., Vishny., R.W., 1997.
References Legal determinants of external finance. Journal of Finance 52,
1131–1150.
Bae, G.S., Cheon, Y.S., Kang, J.K., 2008. Intra-group propping: evidence La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., Vishny, R.W., 1998. Law and
from the stock-price effects of earnings announcement by Korean finance. Journal of Political Economy 106, 1115–1155.
business groups. Review of Financial Studies 21, 2015–2060. La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., Vishny, R.W., 2000. Investor
Baek, J.S., Kang, J.K., Park., K.S., 2004. Corporate governance and firm protection and corporate governance. Journal of Financial Economics
value: evidence from the Korean financial crisis. Journal of Financial 58, 3–27.
Economics 71, 265–313. La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., Vishny, R.W., 2002. Investor
Ball, R., Robin, A., Wu, J.S., 2002. Properties of Accounting Earnings in protection and corporate valuation. Journal of Finance 57,
Four East Asian Countries. Unpublished Working Paper. University of 1147–1170.
Rochester, Rochester, NY. Leuz, C., Nanda, D., Wysocki, P.D., 2003. Earnings management and
Brockman, P., Chung, D., 2003. Investor protection and firm liquidity. investor protection: an International comparison. Journal of Finan-
Journal of Finance 58, 921–938. cial Economics 69, 505–527.
Burkart, M., Gromb, D., Panunzi, F., 1998. Why higher takeover premia Lins, K.V., Servaes, H., 1999. International evidence on the value of
protect minority shareholders. Journal of Political Economy 106, corporate diversification. Journal of Finance 54, 2215–2239.
172–204. Mitton, T., 2002. A cross-firm analysis of the impact of corporate
Chang, S.J., 2003. Ownership structure, expropriation, and economic governance on the East Asian financial crisis. Journal of Financial
performance of group-affiliated companies in Korea. Academy of Economics 64, 215–241.
Management Journal 46, 238–253. Morck, R., Shleifer, A., Vishny, R., 1988. Management ownership and
Chowdhry, B., Goyal, A., 2000. Understanding the financial crisis in Asia. market valuation: an empirical analysis. Journal of Financial Eco-
Pacific-Basin Finance Journal 8, 135–152. nomics 20, 293–315.
Claessens, S., Djankov, S., Lang, L.H.P., 2000. The separation of ownership Morck, R., Yeung, B.Y., Yu, W., 2000. The information content of stock
and control in East Asian Corporations. Journal of Financial Econom- markets: why do emerging markets have synchronous stock price
ics 58, 81–112. movements Journal of Financial Economics 58, 215–260.
Demirgüc--Kunt, A., Maksimovic, V., 1998. Law, finance and firm growth. Rajan, R.G., Servaes, H., Zingales, L., 2000. The cost of diversity: the
Journal of Finance 53, 2107–2137. diversification discount and inefficient investment. Journal of
Djankov, S., La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., 2008. The law and Finance 55, 35–80.
economics of self-dealing. Journal of Financial Economics 88, 430–465. Rajan, R.G., Zingales, L., 1998. Which capitalism? Lessons from the East
Fan, J.P.H., Wong, T.J., 2002. Corporate ownership structure and the Asian crisis. Journal of Applied Corporate Finance 11, 40–48.
informativeness of accounting earnings in East Asia. Journal of Shleifer, A., Vishny, R.W., 1986. Large shareholders and corporate
Accounting and Economics 33, 401–425. control. Journal of Political Economy 94, 461–488.

You might also like