You are on page 1of 24

American Economic Association

The Economic Returns to Schooling in the West Bank and Gaza Strip
Author(s): Joshua D. Angrist
Source: The American Economic Review, Vol. 85, No. 5 (Dec., 1995), pp. 1065-1087
Published by: American Economic Association
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/2950975 .
Accessed: 05/07/2013 16:22

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at .
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp

.
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of
content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms
of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

American Economic Association is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The
American Economic Review.

http://www.jstor.org

This content downloaded from 146.155.94.33 on Fri, 5 Jul 2013 16:22:38 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
The Economic Returnsto Schooling
in the West Bank and Gaza Strip

By JOSHUA D. ANGRIST*

I use micro data from the Labor Force Surveys conducted in the West Bank and
the Gaza Strip during 1981-1991 to show that during 1981-1987 wage differ-
ences between schooling groups fell by well over one-half. This sharp reduction
is associated with large increases in the size of the educated Palestinian labor
force. Since the returns to schooling for Israeli Jews were stable, the decline in
returns to schooling for Palestinians is consistent with the notion that the returns
to schooling in the territories were determined largely by the forces of supply
and demand in a segmented marketfor skilled labor. (JEL J31, 015, 053)

The West Bank of the Jordan river and the the territories (Avi Simon, 1988). As a con-
Gaza Strip on the southeastern edge of the sequence, in the early and mid 1980's, the
Mediterranean Sea were captured by Israel labor market was flooded with new college
from Jordan and Egypt in June 1967. The graduates.This paper studies the impact of this
economies of both the West Bank and Gaza dramatic influx of skilled workers on the dis-
Strip grew rapidly after 1967, in large part as tributionof wages in the occupied territories.
a consequence of significant labor-marketand The influx of Palestiniangraduatesprovidesa
product-marketintegration with Israel (Jacob remarkablenatural experiment with which to
Metzer, 1992). Until 1972, there were no in- studythe impactof a dramaticincreasein skilled
stitutions of higher education in these territo- labor on the returnsto schooling in the context
ries. Beginning in 1972, new local institutions of a developing country.Moreover,the sudden
of higher education began to open in the West increase in the numberof Palestiniangraduates
Bank. Previously, Palestinian residents of the can be used to investigatewhetherthe measured
territorieshad to obtain their advanced school- returnsto schooling are a statisticalartifactat-
ing abroad. But by 1986, there were 20 insti- tributableto individualheterogeneitythatis cor-
tutions granting post-high-school degrees in relatedwith school enrollment.
The existence of a relatively sophisticated
and ongoing labor-force survey in the territo-
ries makes this research possible. First, the
* TerritoriesLabor Force Survey (TLFS) uses a
Departmentof Economics, Hebrew University of Je-
rusalem, Mt. Scopus, Jerusalem 91905, Israel. This re- simple questionnairecorrespondingroughly to
search has been made possible by grants from the Falk the CurrentPopulation Survey (CPS) defini-
Institute for Economic Research in Israel and the Ford
Foundation. Special thanks to Zvi Eisenbach, Zeev tions of labor-marketstatus, with a rotation-
Krischer, and other staff members at the Israel Central group design that can be used to construct
Bureauof Statistics for arrangingfor my use of micro data short panels. The latter feature of the TLFS is
from the territories.Thanks also go to Ron Arbeli, Natalie important because panel data for developing
Aflalo, Asher Doron, and Samer Haj Yehia for outstanding
research assistance, and to Maggie Eisenstadt, Victor
countries are relatively rare and often of low
Lavy, and seminar participantsat Hebrew University, the quality (Orley Ashenfelter et al., 1985). Sec-
Bank of Israel, and Princeton University for helpful dis- ond, because product marketsin Israel and the
cussion and comments. Two anonymous referees also territoriesare integrated,changes in schooling
made helpful comments. The author bears sole responsi- differentials for Israeli citizens can be used
bility for the content of this paper, which is a substantially
revised version of Falk Institute Discussion Paper 92.02 to check whether changes in the returns to
(Angrist, 1992). The paper was revised while the author schooling for Palestinians are related to de-
was visiting the MIT Departmentof Economics. mand shocks common to the two economies.
1065

This content downloaded from 146.155.94.33 on Fri, 5 Jul 2013 16:22:38 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
1066 THE AMERICANECONOMICREVIEW DECEMBER 1995

Changes in wage differentials and employ- sign, each surveyed household is interviewed
ment opportunities in the territories are of four times. Households chosen for the survey
especial interest because of recent political de- are randomly divided into four rotation
velopments. If the declining price of skilled groups, each of which is interviewed for two
labor was really caused by a shift in skilled- consecutive quarters, excluded for two con-
labor supply, then it is naturalto ask what pre- secutive quarters, and interviewed again for
vented new investments in physical capital two consecutive quarters. Interviews for the
from arising to complement newly cheap and TLFS are conducted by local Palestinian enu-
abundant human capital. Palestinians have merators employed by the Israeli Civil Ad-
long complained that employment opportuni- ministrationin the territories.
ties for graduatesand investment opportunities The sample used here contains observations
for entrepreneurshave been deliberately lim- on men aged 18-64 interviewed in the years
ited by the Israeli bureaucracy(Jerusalem Me- 1981-1991. Men constitute the bulk of the
dia and Communications Center, 1992; Zeev Palestinian labor force because labor-force
Schiff and Ehud Yaari, 1989). At the same participation rates for women are very low,
time, Israeli security forces have acknowl- ranging between 6 percent and 9 percent in the
edged that poor employment prospects for sample period (Israel CBS, 1991a). Basic de-
graduatesare likely to have contributedto the scriptive statistics and sample sizes for the
atmosphere of frustrationand discontent cul- extract used here are reported in Table 1.
minating in the 1987 Palestinian Uprising Roughly 30,000-37,000 interviews were con-
(Simon, 1988). Evidence of a decline in the ducted each year in about 7,500 households
relative wages of well-educated workers pro- interviewed four times each. The fraction of
vides evidence for the veracity of the Palestin- the sample residing in the Gaza Stripfluctuates
ian claims. from a high of 27 percent during 1981-1986
The next section of the paper describes to a low of 20 percent in 1988. The mean age
TLFS data. Section II describes the distribu- of men in the sample is 33.
tion of schooling groups in the Palestinian la- Approximately half of the men in the sam-
bor force. Section III outlines a theoretical ple are wage laborers, the remainder being
frameworkand describes wage differentialsby mostly self-employed (including work on a
schooling group. Section IV discusses evi- family farm or business), unemployed, or in
dence on schooling differentials from panel school. Wage laborersconstitute two-thirds of
data, and Section V interprets the main find- the labor force, with participationrates rang-
ings as movements along a stable demand ing from 72 percent to 82 percent. The fraction
curve for skilled workers. Section VI presents of men in the labor force who were employed
some comparisons to schooling coefficients in Israel and Jerusalem is shown in the last
for Israeli citizens. The last section contains a column of Table 1. This fraction ranges be-
summary and concluding remarks. tween 37 percent and 39 percent, including the
8-9 percent of the labor force employed in
I. Labor-Market Data and Labor-Force Jerusalem. The lower part of Table 1 shows
Characteristics' that workers from the territorieswho are em-
ployed in Israel and Jerusalem are concen-
In 1967, the Israel CentralBureau of Statis- tratedin semiskilled and unskilled jobs. Major
tics (CBS) conducted a population census in industries for these workers are construction
the West Bank and Gaza Strip. Since August and agriculture (see also Moshe Semyonov
1968, the 1967 Census has been used as a sam- and Noah Lewin-Epstein, 1987; Ephraim
pling frame (which is periodically updated) Kleiman, 1992).
for quarterly labor-force surveys in the terri- Table 1 shows that the average schooling
tories. Because of the TLFS rotation-groupde- level in the sample rose from 7.7 years in 1981
to 8.65 years in 1991. Otherfigures, not shown
in the table, indicate that the fraction of the
' Backgroundmaterialin this section is drawnfrom the labor force with 13 or more years of schooling
Israel CBS serial for 1989-1990 (Israel CBS, 1991a). rose from 7 percent to 12 percent between

This content downloaded from 146.155.94.33 on Fri, 5 Jul 2013 16:22:38 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
VOL. 85 NO. 5 ANGRIST:ECONOMICRETURNS TO SCHOOLING 1067

TABLE 1-DESCRIPTIVE STATISTICS

Days
worked Work in
Sample Years of Labor-force Wage per Israel (and
Year size Age Gazans schooling participation worker month Jerusalem)
1981 29,622 33.2 0.27 7.65 0.72 0.48 22.0 0.37
1982 30,215 33.1 0.27 7.84 0.73 0.48 22.2 0.38
1983 30,962 33.1 0.27 7.98 0.75 0.48 22.0 0.39
1984 33,737 33.2 0.27 8.07 0.76 0.48 22.0 0.39
1985 34,309 33.0 0.27 8.19 0.76 0.48 21.8 0.37
1986 36,137 32.8 0.27 8.37 0.78 0.49 22.3 0.37
1987 39,222 32.8 0.25 8.36 0.81 0.52 22.4 0.39
1988 34,525 32.7 0.20 8.39 0.82 0.51 17.9 0.39
1989 35,292 32.8 0.22 8.49 0.82 0.51 18.3 0.38
1990 36,665 32.9 0.24 8.53 0.82 0.51 18.8 0.38
1991 34,139 32.9 0.23 8.65 0.82 0.50 17.4 0.38

Distribution of Labor Force by CBS Occupation Code

Employed locally Employed in Israel (including Jerusalem)


0-2 3-5 6 7-8 9 0-2 3-5 6 7-8 9
1981 11.3 27.0 19.9 31.0 10.9 1.3 13.0 9.9 31.6 44.3
1982 12.3 27.5 20.0 30.0 10.2 1.3 12.2 9.8 32.2 44.5
1983 12.9 28.0 19.4 29.4 10.2 1.5 13.1 9.9 30.4 45.1
1984 12.3 27.8 18.6 29.8 11.5 1.1 13.9 12.1 28.4 44.5
1985 12.0 27.5 19.7 29.0 11.8 1.2 14.1 13.1 28.7 42.9
1986 12.1 27.2 19.7 29.1 11.9 1.4 14.1 13.0 29.1 42.4
1987 11.9 27.0 18.8 31.2 11.1 1.4 16.1 12.4 29.1 41.0
1988 10.9 26.4 20.9 30.4 11.3 1.4 15.5 11.9 27.1 44.1
1989 10.9 27.1 19.9 30.4 11.7 1.2 16.1 11.1 27.5 44.1
1990 10.2 27.2 21.0 30.2 11.4 1.2 14.6 10.5 25.4 48.4
1991 10.4 26.1 21.0 31.1 11.4 1.2 9.8 9.9 28.3 50.8

Notes: The sample includes men aged 18-64. Because of the sample design, only one-quarterof the sample observations
are statistically independent. Statistics in the table are unweighted counts. The Israel CBS one-digit occupation codes are
scientific, academic, professional, technical, administrative,managerial (0-2); clerical, sales, service (3-5); agricultural
(6); skilled worker in industry, mining, construction, transport,or other sector (7-8); unskilled worker, other industrial
worker, transportation(9).

1981 and 1990. The fraction with less than 12 The usual types of sampling and nonsam-
years of schooling fell from 81 percent to 67 pling errors in labor-force surveys are also
percent.2 Finally, other statistics not reported present in the TLFS. In addition, data collec-
in the table show that, among men in the labor tion after 1988 became more difficult because
force with 13 or more years of schooling, the of civil disturbancesin the territories.Because
fraction employed as wage and salary workers TLFS data on the territories were collected
fell about 10 percentage points during 1981- by an agency of the occupying power (the Is-
1984. The fraction employed as wage and sal- raeli Civil Administration), TLFS data may be
ary workers was stable at around 70 percent less accurate than data from comparable
from 1984 until the 1991 Gulf War. labor-force surveys carried out elsewhere.3

3 According to Israel CBS (199la), during the period


2 The schooling question in the TLFS records the of unrest the fact that some men responded to questions
"number of years of schooling (including the present year about days worked by reportingthe number of paid work
for those still enrolled) in all schools ever attended" (Is- days as opposed to the numberof days actually on the job
rael CBS, 1991a p. 176). is potentially misleading.

This content downloaded from 146.155.94.33 on Fri, 5 Jul 2013 16:22:38 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
1068 THE AMERICANECONOMIC REVIEW DECEMBER 1995

Moreover, although there are many sensible- 1981, the unemployment rate for the less-
patternsin the TLFS data on labor-force status educated was around 1 percent, while more-
(e.g., seasonality, see Angrist, 1994), data on educated workers were unemployed at a rate
wages are often poor even in the best circum- of 2-5 percent. But in 1985 the unemploy-
stances. The Data Appendix thereforepresents ment rate of male labor-force participants
a brief comparison of Israel CBS wage data to with 16 or more years of schooling reached
wage data from Palestinian surveys and Israeli almost 16 percent, and the unemployment
administrativesources. rate for men with 13-15 years of schooling
reached 13 percent. In contrast, unemploy-
II. SchoolingGroupsin the LaborForce ment rates for men with 12 years of school-
ing did not exceed 5 percent until late 1989.
The educated Palestinian labor force grew All groups experienced high unemployment
substantially throughout the sample period. rates during the Gulf War. The next section
This is documented in Figure 1, which plots shows that the large differences in employ-
the log of weighted counts of labor-force ment rates by schooling group are paralleled
participants by schooling group, minus the by changes in wage differentials.
log of the count in the first quarter of 1981.
Thus, small differences along the y-axis are III. The Distributionof Wages
approximately equal to percentage changes.
For example, the figure shows that between A. Theoretical Framework
1982 and 1984 the number in the labor force
with 13-15 years of schooling grew by My interpretationof the empirical results in
roughly 40 percent (0.5-0.1), while the this paper is motivated by a simple equilibrium
number in the labor force with 11 or fewer model of workers in two skill groups who can
years of schooling grew by only a few per- work in one of two locations.6 Suppose the
centage points. labor force consists of N workers, including N.
The first university founded in the territories unskilled workers and NSskilled workers, and
was Bir Zeit in 1972, located north of Jerusa- let ir = N,/(N. + N.). Workers supply daily
lem in the West Bank. Subsequent growth in labor either locally or as migrants in Israel.
university enrollment was rapid.4Enrollment Demand for migrants is assumed to be per-
in West Bank and Gaza Strip universities dou- fectly elastic at a migrant daily wage, wi,
bled between 1981 and 1985 (from 6,450 which is the same for both skill groups. One
to 13,083 students), and 6,600 university can therefore write the probability that a
students graduated between 1981 and 1986 skilled worker works locally as pfs (Wm, We)
(Simon, 1988). Substantial increases in the and the probability that an unskilled worker
number of graduates are also recorded in data works locally as pe (wm, weu), where weS and
from postsecondary vocational and technical weu are local daily wage rates for skilled and
schools in the territories (Hasan Al-Qiq, unskilled workers.
1988). I also assume that the demand for workers
Many of the newly educated labor-force in each skill group depends only on the skill
entrants did not find jobs. Figure 2 plots un- group's wage rate and aggregate earnings
employment rates by schooling group.5 In (through product demand). Local demand
functions for skilled and unskilled workerscan
therefore be written dsy(wes ye) and deu(w,,
4 Universities in the territoriesare institutionsthat offer ye), where ye -wsN pes + we,Nupeu +
wm(N - Nps - Nupu) is total earnings (as-
four-year programsleading to a bachelor's degree. Before
offering a four-yearprogram,Bir Zeit was a two-year jun- suming that everyone works somewhere). Lo-
ior college.
' Workers are defined as employed if they worked one
cal equilibrium wages and employment are
or more hours in the last full week before the interview,
or were absent from work; they are unemployed if they
did not work and actively sought work. The labor force is 6 Similar models are discussed by George Johnson
the sum of employed and unemployed workers. (1980) and Joseph Altonji and David Card (1991).

This content downloaded from 146.155.94.33 on Fri, 5 Jul 2013 16:22:38 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
VOL. 85 NO. 5 ANGRIST:ECONOMICRETURNS TO SCHOOLING 1069

1.3

13-15 years --- -

0.9

14

0 87
LI/
14
o X ' Y years ~~~~~~~16
years or moes

~0.5-

12 years
0 0.17 f /-

0.3 11 years or less

0.1S

81 82 83 84 85 86 87 88 89 90 91 92

Year

FIGURE1. LABOR-FORCESIZEBYSCHOOLING
GROUP
Notes: The figure plots quarterlyobservationson the log size of the laborforce by schooling
group for Palestinian men aged 18-64 in four schooling groups. The log labor-force size
in the first quarterof 1981 was subtractedfrom the log counts for each schooling group.
Statistics are weighted by CBS sampling weights.

determined by a system of two equations, in local demand are negligible (as suggested by
which wm is a parameter: results in Angrist [1994]). Then one has

ds y(wf) y = r[NNpIfs(wi, Wfs)] (1) d(ln w,s)/d-r = ll[7r(77ss- ss)] < 0

de (weu ye ) = (1 - 7r)[Npif'u(w., weu) ]. d(lnweu)/dir = - 1/[( 1- - euu)] >


1r)(717uu 0

This simple framework can be used to pre- where i7ssand q.. are local labor demand elas-
dict the impact of a change in ir on skill ticities with respect to local wage rates and ess
differentials. Suppose that income effects on and sLW are local supply elasticities with

This content downloaded from 146.155.94.33 on Fri, 5 Jul 2013 16:22:38 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
1070 THE AMERICANECONOMICREVIEW DECEMBER 1995

0.16

16 years or more

0.12-

13 I 'I

13-15 years

o 0.04-
0.08

~ 'lyears or les

81 82 83 84 85 86 87 88 89 90 91 92

Year

FIGURE 2. UNEMPLOYMENT RAT ES BY SCHO()LING GROUP

Notes: The figure plots quarterlyobservations on the unemployment rate for Palestinian
men aged 18-64 in four schooling groups. Statistics are weighted by CBS sampling
weights.

respect to local wage rates. These relationships through income effects in local labor demand
imply that increasing the fraction of skilled and a labor-supplyresponse, both of which are
workers in the labor force will decrease skill likely to be similar across skill groups. Allow-
differentials. ing for a migrant-wage response to changes in
If income effects are nonnegligible, this quantities is therefore unlikely to change the
conclusion must be modified to take account basic conclusion regarding skill differentials
of the fact that changing wage rates will shift generated by this model.
labor demand. But income effects are unlikely The assumed absence of an Israeli demand
to be large enough to dominate the own-wage for Palestinian skills accentuates the negative
demand and supply effects. Note also that mi- impact of increases in 7ron skill differentials
grant wages affect skill differentials solely because an Israeli wage premium for Palestin-

This content downloaded from 146.155.94.33 on Fri, 5 Jul 2013 16:22:38 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
VOL. 85 NO. 5 ANGRIST:ECONOMICRETURNS TO SCHOOLING 1071

1,200

O0.3 - \\ /
I 16 years or more
Monthly wages
1,000

0.2- \

13 15 years
,,800-. ,

> )
12 years
n 60 0i
0

d' 600
70? 0.0

60 - / ,~~~~~Dil
mwages
11 years or lees /l

50 Az,

40 -0.1....

30
81 82 83 84 85 86 87 88 89 90 91 92 81 82 83 84 85 86 87 88 89 90 91 92
Year Year

FIGURE 3. AVERAGE DAILY AND MONTHLY WAGES FIGURE 4. AVERAGE DAILY WAGES
IN SEPTEMBER 1992, NEW ISRAELI SHEKELS BY SCHOOLING GROUP

Notes: The figure plots quarterlyobservations on real av- Notes: The figure plots quarterlyobservationson the aver-
erage daily and monthly wages for Palestinian men aged age daily wages of Palestinianmen aged 18-64 with wage
18-64 with wage and salary earnings. Statistics are and salary earnings. Averages were computed using CBS
weighted by CBS sampling weights. sampling weights, after removing period and age effects.

ian skills would tend to make the local supply daily and monthly wages are graphedin Figure
of skilled labor more elastic. In practice, the 3. Average real wages declined between 1983
empirical results show that Israelis do pay and 1985, and again at the end of the sample
a premium for some Palestinian schooling period. In contrast, the period 1985-1988 was
groups, but it is much less than the local pre- one of exceptionally strong growth in real
mium. Finally, note that wage compression in daily wages.
this model is aggravated by the assumed ab- The analysis of schooling differentials be-
sence of complementarity between skilled la- gins with Figure 4, which plots average log
bor- and other factors of production. The daily wages by schooling group after remov-
impact of changes in 7ris made larger by the ing period effects for each quarter and age
assumption that the demand for skilled labor effects for each year.7 The figure shows
does not eventually shift out in response to
investment opportunities arising from a de-
crease in the cost of human capital. These 7 Figure 4 plots residuals from the following regres-
characteristics of the model, if true, increase sion:
the likelihood of sharply declining schooling
log(wi,) = S di,6q, + aai.f3, + Vi,
differentials in the face of increases in the sup- q
ply of educated workers.
where diqis a dummy variable that indicates whether ob-
B. Wage Differentials by Schooling Group servation i is observed in quarterq, and 64q is a quarter-q
effect in year t; aj, is a dummy variable that indicates
whether observation i is in age group c, and f3t,is an age
The quarterlytime series of real (September effect in year t. vi, is an errorterm. The regression and the
1992, New Israeli Shekels [NIS]) average averages were computed using CBS sampling weights.

This content downloaded from 146.155.94.33 on Fri, 5 Jul 2013 16:22:38 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
1072 THE AMERICANECONOMICREVIEW DECEMBER 1995

substantial schooling premia for two groups Additional covariates in the regression in-
only: men with 13-15 years of schooling and clude sets of annualeffects for residence in the
men with 16 or more years of schooling. An Gaza Strip, residence in a refugee camp, and
importantfeature of this figure is the decline residence in an urban area, and a single work-
in schooling differentials since 1985. Between in-Jerusalem effect. The dependent variables
1981 and 1985, men with 13-15 years of are the log of daily wages and the log of
schooling received an average daily wage pre- monthly wages. The sample excludes obser-
mium of 10- 15 percent, while those with 16 vations with reportedreal wages above 15,000
or more years of schooling received an aver- September 1992 shekels/month (about 6,000
age 25-percent daily wage premium. By 1987, dollars).
however, the wage premiumfor men with 13- The first column of Table 2 shows that the
15 years of schooling was eliminated, and the daily wage premium for working in Israel fell
premium for men with 16 or more years of from roughly 18 percent in 1981 to zero in
schooling was less than half the earlier level. 1984.9 Beginning in 1986, the Israel wage pre-
Table 2 captures features of the wage dis- mium rose steeply. By 1989, daily wages paid
tribution in a regression model. Coefficients to Palestinians working in Israel were 37-
reported in the table are parameter estimates percent higher than local wages, nearly dou-
from the following equation: bling the 1987 wage differential. The monthly
wage premium for working in Israel increased
(2) log(wi,) = ; di,6 + Y. aicfct similarly. These changes parallel the patternof
q c Palestinian absences from work and are con-
sistent with movements along an inelastic
+ E big)gt+ f,9, + v,t Israeli demand curve for Palestinian labor
g (Angrist, 1994).
Columns (ii) and (iii) show that schooling
where diqis a dummy variable that indicates differentials in daily wages declined steadily
whether observation i is observed in quarterq, until 1989 and became negative for men with
and 8qtis a quarter-qeffect in year t; aic is a 13-15 years of schooling in 1988-1989. This
dummy variable that indicates age-group c, pattern is similar to that shown in Figure 4.
and ,6c,is an age effect in year t; bigis a dummy Although schooling differentials fell furtherin
variable that indicates schooling group g, and 1988, it is importantto note that the decline in
yec,is a schooling effect in year t;f, is a dummy schooling coefficients began well before the
variable that indicates work in Israel or Jeru- beginning of the Palestinian uprising. For ex-
salem, and O,is a work-location effect in year ample, a 41-percent daily wage premium for
t. Age groups indexed by c are age 25-34, men with 16 or more years of schooling in
age 35-44, age 45-54, and age 55-64. 1981 fell to 20 percent by 1986.1'
Schooling groups indexed by g are 13-15 This paper argues that the declines in skill
years and 16 or more years. v,i is an errorterm. differentials observed in Table 2 are largely
This dummy-variable parametrization cap- due to economic forces set off by an exoge-
tures the most importantwage differences by
schooling group.8
'This decline is probably because of the 1983-1984
recession and an inflation-stabilizationprogram in 1985,
which involved wage guidelines and price controls that
led to a substantial erosion of real wages. Wages and
8 The Palestinian school system has six years of ele- prices in the territories were less effectively controlled
mentary school, three years of middle school, three years (Dan Zakai, 1988; Yael Artstein and Zvi Sussman, 1990).
of high school, and two-year and four-year college pro- '?This finding is inconsistent with Radwan A. Sha-
grams. Schooling is compulsory through the ninth grade. ban's (1993 p. 667) claim that access to the Israeli labor
High-school graduates have 12 years of schooling. The market led to a compression of skill differentials in the
high-school wage premium (relative to those with less territories.The Israeli market was opened to Palestinians
than 12 years of schooling) averaged around5 percent for in October 1970. Although no evidence has been pre-
the years 1981-1985. It too declined sharply between sented for the 1970's, Table 2 shows that skill differentials
1984 and 1988. remained substantialin the early 1980's.

This content downloaded from 146.155.94.33 on Fri, 5 Jul 2013 16:22:38 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
VOL. 85 NO. 5 ANGRIST. ECONOMICRETURNS TO SCHOOLING 1073

TABLE 2-WAGE DETERMINANTS

Daily wage Monthly wage


13-15 16 or more 13-15 16 or more
Work in years years Work in years years
Israel schooling schooling Israel schooling schooling
Year (i) (ii) (iii) (iv) (v) (vi)
1981 0.184 0.251 0.408 0.073 0.296 0.462
(0.007) (0.015) (0.017) (0.009) (0.018) (0.021)
1982 0.182 0.218 0.368 0.064 0.269 0.433
(0.007) (0.014) (0.016) (0.008) (0.017) (0.020)
1983 0.171 0.160 0.334 0.043 0.221 0.408
(0.007) (0.013) (0.015) (0.008) (0.016) (0.019)
1984 -0.011 0.164 0.358 -0.133 0.212 0.427
(0.007) (0.012) (0.014) (0.008) (0.015) (0.017)
1985 0.004 0.145 0.278 -0.116 0.190 0.334
(0.006) (0.012) (0.014) (0.008) (0.015) (0.017)
1986 0.122 0.088 0.204 0.001 0.116 0.258
(0.006) (0.011) (0.013) (0.008) (0.013) (0.016)
1987 0.194 0.050 0.178 0.066 0.062 0.205
(0.006) (0.010) (0.012) (0.007) (0.013) (0.015)
1988 0.279 -0.012 0.089 0.075 0.091 0.247
(0.006) (0.010) (0.013) (0.008) (0.013) (0.015)
1989 0.368 -0.033 0.048 0.204 0.085 0.223
(0.006) (0.010) (0.012) (0.007) (0.011) (0.015)
1990 0.354 0.004 0.076 0.174 0.128 0.239
(0.006) (0.009) (0.012) (0.007) (0.011) (0.014)
1991 0.431 0.011 0.107 0.251 0.119 0.258
(0.007) (0.011) (0.013) (0.008) (0.013) (0.016)

Sample: 171,691 171,783

Notes: The sample includes men aged 18-64 who indicated that they work in the West Bank, Gaza Strip, Jerusalem,or
Israel, with valid schooling variables, excluding men interviewed in the Gulf War quarterfor 1991. The table reports
selected estimates from a regression of log wages on a full set of quarterly period effects, annual work-in-Israel (or
Jerusalem)effects, annual schooling-group effects, annual age effects, annual effects for residence in a refugee camp, an
urban area, and the Gaza Strip, and a single dummy for employment in Jerusalem. The sample was weighted by CBS
sampling weights in the estimation. Standarderrors are shown in parentheses.

nous increase in the supply of educated other Arab states appears to have been re-
workers. Alternative explanations are pos- duced after the PLO was expelled from Leb-
sible, however. One alternative explanation anon in 1982.
is related to political developments in the Another importantfactor in the Palestinian
Middle East. Many educated Palestinians are local economy is the repatriationof funds by
employed locally in the public sector as Palestinians living abroad, mostly in the Gulf
teachers. Jordan, which funded some public- States. Rough estimates based on official Jor-
sector employment in the territories, expe- danian figures (Abed el Fatah Abu-Shukar,
rienced economic growth at a rate of 10-1 1 1990) suggest that the amount of income re-
percent per year between 1976 and 1982 patriateddeclined by 15 percent between 1984
(Zakai, 1988). But economic growth in Jor- and 1985. A related development is the reduc-
dan slowed dramatically in 1983, and the tion in opportunities for foreign employment
flow of financial resources from Jordan and faced by Palestinians around 1982 (Stuart

This content downloaded from 146.155.94.33 on Fri, 5 Jul 2013 16:22:38 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
1074 THE AMERICANECONOMICREVIEW DECEMBER 1995

TABLE 3-SCHOOLING COEFFICIENTS BY WORK LOCATION, ESTIMATES FOR DAILY WAGES

Schooling coefficients
13-15 years schooling 16 or more years schooling
Work in Employed Work in Employed Work in
Israel locally Israel Contrast locally Israel Contrast
Year (i) (ii) (iii) (iv) (v) (vi) (vii)
1981 0.199 0.308 0.100 0.208 0.469 0.142 0.327
(0.007) (0.017) (0.029) (0.033) (0.019) (0.041) (0.045)
1982 0.194 0.269 0.100 0.169 0.406 0.142 0.264
(0.007) (0.016) (0.026) (0.031) (0.017) (0.044) (0.047)
1983 0.188 0.213 0.073 0.139 0.395 0.081 0.314
(0.007) (0.016) (0.022) (0.027) (0.017) (0.036) (0.039)
1984 0.016 0.248 0.026 0.222 0.440 0.095 0.345
(0.007) (0.015) (0.020) (0.025) (0.016) (0.030) (0.034)
1985 0.031 0.212 0.033 0.178 0.382 0.003 0.379
(0.007) (0.015) (0.020) (0.025) (0.016) (0.027) (0.031)
1986 0.142 0.131 0.032 0.099 0.295 -0.031 0.326
(0.007) (0.014) (0.017) (0.022) (0.015) (0.025) (0.029)
1987 0.208 0.078 0.018 0.060 0.237 0.031 0.207
(0.006) (0.014) (0.016) (0.021) (0.014) (0.023) (0.027)
1988 0.291 0.009 -0.032 0.041 0.143 -0.021 0.163
(0.007) (0.014) (0.015) (0.020) (0.015) (0.022) (0.027)
1989 0.366 -0.060 -0.002 -0.059 0.073 -0.017 0.090
(0.006) (0.013) (0.013) (0.018) (0.014) (0.021) (0.026)
1990 0.363 0.010 -0.000 0.010 0.127 -0.052 0.178
(0.006) (0.013) (0.014) (0.018) (0.014) (0.022) (0.025)
1991 0.441 0.014 0.012 0.002 0.163 -0.027 0.190
(0.007) (0.014) (0.017) (0.021) (0.015) (0.027) (0.027)
F statistics (d. ): 24.3 (11) 66.9 (11)

Notes: This table reports estimates from the same model and sample as those underlying Table 2 with the modification
that the schooling coefficients are allowed to differ by work location. Column (i) shows work-in-Israel (or Jerusalem)
main effects. Columns (iv) and (vi) show the difference in schooling coefficients by work location. The F statistic tests
the joint hypotheses of whether schooling coefficients differ by work location. The sample was weighted by CBS sampling
weights in the estimation. Standarderrors are shown in parentheses.

Gabriel and Eitan Sabatello, 1986; Shaban, ployed locally suggests that these factors are
1993). Out-migrationfell sharply in 1982 and of secondary importance. The decline in
1983 but remained positive throughout the schooling differentials for Palestinians em-
1980's (Israel CBS, 1993a table 27.1) . Fi- ployed in Israel is documented in Table 3,
nally, changes in the wage distribution since which reports annual schooling differentials
1988 are at least partly explained by the civil separatelyby work location." The coefficients
disorder,curfews, and strikes duringthe Pales-
tinian uprising, which disrupted economic
activity in the territoriesmore than in Israel.
Although local political and social factors " My working paper (Angrist, 1992) shows that, al-
might explain the decline in schooling differ- though educated Palestinians were always more likely to
work locally than in Israel, the tendency for educated Pa-
entials in the local labor market, the fact that lestinians to work in Israel grew throughout the 1980's.
schooling differentials declined for workers Overall, roughly 4 percent of Palestinians who worked in
employed in Israel as well as for those em- Israel had 13-15 years of schooling, and roughly 1.5 per-

This content downloaded from 146.155.94.33 on Fri, 5 Jul 2013 16:22:38 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
VOL. 85 NO. 5 ANGRIST:ECONOMICRETURNS TO SCHOOLING 1075

TABLE 4-SCHOOLING COEFFICIENTS AND OCCUPATION EFFECTS

Schooling coefficients Occupation effects


13-15 years 16 or more years Administration Clerical Agriculture Skilled
Year (i) (ii) (iii) (iv) (v) (vi)
1981 0.180 0.335 0.150 -0.007 -0.182 0.105
(0.017) (0.020) (0.016) (0.010) (0.011) (0.008)
1982 0.106 0.239 0.232 -0.028 -0.163 0.122
(0.016) (0.019) (0.016) (0.010) (0.011) (0.007)
1983 0.115 0.279 0.115 -0.056 -0.129 0.089
(0.015) (0.018) (0.015) (0.010) (0.011) (0.007)
1984 0.038 0.196 0.315 0.015 -0.202 0.115
(0.014) (0.016) (0.015) (0.009) (0.010) (0.007)
1985 0.030 0.149 0.278 0.036 -0.161 0.100
(0.013) (0.016) (0.015) (0.009) (0.010) (0.007)
1986 0.031 0.129 0.180 -0.022 -0.154 0.102
(0.012) (0.015) (0.014) (0.008) (0.010) (0.007)
1987 0.016 0.125 0.121 -0.078 -0.130 0.070
(0.011) (0.014) (0.013) (0.008) (0.010) (0.007)
1988 -0.010 0.087 0.026 -0.106 -0.133 0.055
(0.011) (0.014) (0.014) (0.008) (0.009) (0.007)
1989 0.003 0.102 -0.074 -0.128 -0.112 0.067
(0.010) (0.013) (0.012) (0.008) (0.010) (0.007)
1990 0.009 0.085 0.009 -0.129 -0.104 0.067
(0.010) (0.013) (0.013) (0.008) (0.009) (0.006)
1991 0.018 0.118 0.004 -0.157 -0.128 0.083
(0.012) (0.015) (0.015) (0.010) (0.011) (0.007)

Notes: The sample includes 171,518 men aged 18-64 who indicated they work in the West Bank, Gaza Strip, Jerusalem,
or Israel with valid schooling variables. Estimates are coefficients from the same model reported in Table 2, with the
addition of four occupation dummies: administrative(Israel CBS one-digit occupation codes 0-2), clerical (codes 3-5),
agricultural(code 6), and skilled worker (7-8). The sample was weighted by CBS sampling weights in the estimation.
Standard errors are shown in parentheses. The occupation reference group is CBS code 9 (unskilled industrial and
transportationworkers).

reported in Table 3 include main effects for 1987, the premium paid to workers with 13-
working in Israel (including Jerusalem), 15 years of schooling who were employed lo-
schooling-group dummy variables, and the in- cally declined from 31 percent to 8 percent. At
teraction of schooling-group dummies with a the same time, the premium paid to similarly
dummy that indicates working in Israel or Je- educated workers employed in Israel fell from
rusalem. For example, between 1981 and 10 percent to 2 percent.'2 These results are

cent had 16 or more years. Among workers employed in 12 The results in Table 3 are inconsistent with those of

Jerusalem,5.5 percent had 13-15 years of schooling, and Aziz S. Al-Dweik (1988), who claimed that there is no
3 percent had 16 or more years of schooling. In the sample premium for the schooling of Palestinians employed in
used here, a total of over 6,200 workers with higher edu- Israel. Moreover, the pattern of estimated returns to 13-
cation were not employed locally. Over 75 percent of local 15 years of schooling is similar when men who work in
workers with 13 or more years of schooling were in ad- Jerusalem are excluded from the sample. On the other
ministrative, managerial, or clerical positions. In contrast, hand, men with 16 or more years of schooling who were
fewer than 42 percent of educated workers working in employed in Israel outside of Jerusalem received essen-
Jerusalem or Israel were employed in similar positions. tially no returnto schooling throughoutthe sample period.

This content downloaded from 146.155.94.33 on Fri, 5 Jul 2013 16:22:38 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
1076 THE AMERICANECONOMICREVIEW DECEMBER 1995

consistent with the supply-shift story in the The most popular fields are literatureand hu-
model outlined above, provided the model is manities, although the proportion of all grad-
augmented to allow for an inelastic Israeli de- uates in these fields remains roughly constant
mand for Palestinian schooling. This demand at around 35-40 percent. Students with de-
will moderate but not eliminate the impact of grees in science, engineering, and economics
dir on schooling differentials. and management also constitute 35-40 per-
A final piece of circumstantialevidence for cent of the total numberof graduatesthrough-
the supply-shift explanation of changes in out the period of rapid growth in Palestinian
schooling differentials between 1981-1987 higher education.
appears in Table 4. This table reports school- The fact that the percentage distributionof
ing coefficients and the coefficients on coarse graduatesby field appearsto be fairly constant,
occupation dummies when these dummies are suggests that changes in the returnsto school-
added to the basic specifications reported in ing are not attributableto a changing field mix.
Table 2. The occupation mix by work location It should be noted, however, that the large
is reportedin Table 1. Studies using data from numbers of humanities graduates in recent
developed countries usually find that an im- years may have depressed the average returns
portantpartof the returnsto schooling appears to schooling if employment opportunities for
in occupation effects. Table 4 shows that this this group are especially limited. More impor-
is also true for Palestinian wage-workers be- tantly, an issue not addressed by Figure 5 is
cause the estimated schooling coefficients are the question of unobserved heterogeneity in
smaller when occupation dummies are added the graduate mix. Repeated observations on
to the regressions. Moreover, beginning in individuals can help control for selection and
1984 the patternof occupation coefficients ap- composition effects.
pears to reflect the increase in the size of ed- Households selected for enumeration in
ucated cohorts in a manner similar to the the TLFS are interviewed for a second time
schooling coefficients. For example, the pre- one quarter after the first interview, for a
mium (relative to the reference group of man- third time one year after the first interview,
ual laborers) for being in an administrativeor and for a fourth time one quarter after the
managerialjob fell from 0.32 to 0.12 during third interview. For example, men inter-
1984-1987, while the premium for clerical viewed for the first time in the first quarter
workers fell from 0.02 to -0.08. of 1981 are also interviewed in the second
quarter of 1981, and in the first and second
IV. Controllingfor IndividualHeterogeneity quarters of 1982. The TLFS can therefore be
used to construct a series of short overlap-
Circumstantial evidence for a supply shift ping panels. I was able to match 80-85 per-
notwithstanding, the results in Tables 2-4 cent of first-interview records to information
could also be explained by a change in the from the second, third, and fourth inter-
unobserved quality of graduatesor by changes views. For details, see the appendix to my
in graduates' field of study. Similarly, the im- working paper (Angrist, 1992).
pact of selection bias arising from decisions Columns(i) - (iii) of Table 5 reportestimates
about work location, labor-force status, and of thefollowingequationfit to the sampleof third-
emigration are unaccounted for. To provide interviewresponsesseparatelyfor each year:
additionalinformationon the characteristicsof
graduates, Figure 5 plots the number of grad- (3) log(wi,) = ; diq6qt+ X itf2t + Xf2,
uates from four-year bachelor's degree pro- q
grams in the West Bank and Gaza Strip by
broadfield of study for the years 1975 - 1990.1 + eityt + f,H,t+ vit t = 82, . .., 91

where 63t and f2t are the parametersin a quad-


'" Data in the figure are derived from reportspublished
by the Palestinian Institute for Higher Education (1991 ratic function of potential experience (xi,), ei,
[and selected other years]), and from unpublished tables is years of schooling, andf, is a dummy that
provided by the Institute. indicates work in Israel; y, and 9, are the

This content downloaded from 146.155.94.33 on Fri, 5 Jul 2013 16:22:38 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
VOL. 85 NO. 5 ANGRIST:ECONOMICRETURNS TO SCHOOLING 1077

2,500- Field: L Literature/humanities


Economics/Business
Science
Nursing/Education
Islamic Studies
Engineering 2,144 2,155

2,000

01,5001 ls1,566
4)
1,500-

'0
0~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~,4

1 19904
1,000 ~~~~~~868
878 872

689
580 582
\
500

249
17
140
74

1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990

Year

FIGURE5. WEST BANK AND GAZA STRIPUNIVERSITYGRADUATESBy FIELD


Notes: The figure shows the distributionof graduatesfrom four-year bachelor's degree programsby year and broad field
of study.
Source: Published and unpublished statistics from the Palestinian Institute for Higher Education.

schooling and work-in-Israel coefficients. residence in the Gaza Strip, in a refugee


For purposes of panel estimation, the rela- camp, or in urban areas, for each year. These
tionship between schooling and earnings variables are added to control for regional
was parameterized as being linear in school- differences in worker characteristics other
" than work location.
ing. Equation (3 ) was estimated with three
additional dummy variables that indicate Work-in-Israel and linear schooling coef-
ficients for the third-interview regression,
reported in columns (i) and (ii) of Table 5,
show the same patterns observed in Tables 2
to
4 Becauselinearityis likely to be a poor approximation
the schooling-earningsrelationshipat the extremes,observa-
and 3. The Israel wage premium was nega-
tions with less than six years of schooling or more than 20 tive in 1984-1985, but rose to a new high in
yearsof schoolingare droppedfrom the estimationsample. 1989. The schooling coefficient declined

This content downloaded from 146.155.94.33 on Fri, 5 Jul 2013 16:22:38 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
1078 THE AMERICANECONOMICREVIEW DECEMBER 1995

TABLE5-FIRST-DIFFERENCE ESTIMATESOFTHE DAILY WAGE EQUATION

Levels (3rd interview) Differences (3rd interview - 1st interview)


Work in Years of Potential Work in Work in Work in Years of
Israel, schooling, experience, Israel, Israel, Israel, schooling,
6, 6. A, 61 - 06-1 6t,t - 7t_1
Year (i) (ii) (iii) (iv) (v) (vi) (vii)
1981 0.281
(0.031)
1982 0.214 0.040 0.276 0.268 -0.013 0.193 -0.001
(0.019) (0.003) (0.024) (0.031) (0.023) (0.031) (0.003)
1983 0.154 0.032 0.185 0.171 -0.022 0.250 0.0004
(0.019) (0.003) (0.024) (0.031) (0.023) (0.031) (0.003)
1984 -0.008 0.039 0.281 0.054 -0.196 0.150 0.008
(0.018) (0.003) (0.023) (0.030) (0.022) (0.029) (0.003)
1985 -0.048 0.031 0.210 0.073 -0.078 0.032 -0.011
(0.017) (0.003) (0.022) (0.029) (0.021) (0.027) (0.003)
1986 0.119 0.021 0.172 0.105 0.072 0.219 -0.013
(0.016) (0.002) (0.022) (0.027) (0.020) (0.025) (0.003)
1987 0.199 0.026 0.192 0.264 0.045 0.141 -0.008
(0.016) (0.002) (0.020) (0.025) (0.019) (0.024) (0.003)
1988 0.282 0.011 0.136 0.227 0.087 0.114 -0.008
(0.016) (0.002) (0.020) (0.025) (0.019) (0.028) (0.003)
1989 0.399 0.003 0.126 0.198 0.083 0.300 -0.013
(0.016) (0.003) (0.021) (0.028) (0.020) (0.028) (0.003)
1990 0.347 0.014 0.171 0.232 -0.067 0.323 0.005
(0.015) (0.002) (0.019) (0.027) (0.018) (0.028) (0.003)
1991 0.429 0.017 0.118 0.354 0.031 0.002
(0.017) (0.003) (0.023) (0.029) (0.021) (0.003)

Sample size: 20,333 19,762

Notes: The table shows estimates of equations (3) and (5) in the text. The sample includes men aged 18-62 with earnings
at the time of the first interview, who were interviewed for the third time in 1982 or later, and who reported 6-20 years
of schooling at the third interview. The sample was not weighted by the CBS sampling weight for the estimation. The
potential experience quadraticis evaluated at the mean of experience and experience-squared.Columns (iv) and (vi) are
alternative estimates of the same work-in-Israel coefficients. Four out of nine of the alternative estimates of 6, were
significantly different (p < 0.002). The joint F[9, 19.6431statistic is 7.98. Columns (v) and (vii) report the change in work-
in-Israel and schooling coefficients, respectively.

from roughly 4 percent in 1984 to 2.1 per- same quarterone year earlier than third-time
cent in 1986, and it dropped to zero during interviews:
the Palestinian uprising. Column (iii) of Ta-
ble 5 shows a similar decline in the effect of (4) log(wi,, - I) = ai + E di,q6q,t_
potential experience (defined as age minus q
years of schooling minus 5, and evaluated at
the mean of experience and experience- + (Xj,, _)p
- ,t_ + (Xi,t - 1) 22,t-1
squared).
Lagging equation (3) one year and adding + ei,ty, I ?f1t- lt- I + vi,t- I
individual effects gives the following equation
for first-time interviews, which occur in the t= 82, ...,91.

This content downloaded from 146.155.94.33 on Fri, 5 Jul 2013 16:22:38 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
VOL. 85 NO. 5 ANGRIST:ECONOMICRETURNS TO SCHOOLING 1079

Here I assume that schooling is time-invariant, this average. Estimates from equation (3)
so that e,,t = e,, l and xi, = xi,_, + 1. Sub- therefore answer the question of whether
tracting (4) from (3) and using these (on average) specific individuals experi-
assumptions, one obtains enced a year-to-year decline in the returns to
schooling.
(5) log (wi,) - log (wi,t- ) Columns (iv) - (vi) of Table 5 report esti-
mates of 9, and (9, - 0, - I). Column (iv) re-
= S di,q(6q,t -6qt- I) ports the coefficient on fi, - f, - I in equation
q (5), which provides one estimate of 0,. Col-
umn (v) reports the coefficient on fi,,, which
+ (,-,t-I- 2,t--) provides an estimate of 9, - 9, -. Columns
(iv) and (v) are combined to provide a second
+ xj,,(2f2, -I + 3,, -
AI,t- 1) estimate of 0, in column (vi). All three col-
umns show evidence of the same decline in
+ x i't(2,t -
)2,t-I)
the Israel wage premium as observed in col-
umn (i), although the alternative estimates
+ ei,(jy, - - I) + fJot(9-,t- I)
suggest somewhat different timing. The alter-
native estimates are not significantly different
in five out of nine comparisons (p < 0.02),
+ (fit-.t -I) t I + (Vi,t- ,t- I
but the joint test of coefficient equality for the
alternativeestimates of 0, leads to rejection of
The derivation of equation (5) makes use the null hypothesis of equality.
of the fact that x?, - x?t - = 2xi, - 1. In the Column (vii) reports the year-to-year
estimation, equation (5) includes the time- change in schooling coefficients, estimated
invariant region - of- residence dummies in- as the coefficient on ei,, in equation (5). Here
cluded in equations (3) and (4) because too, the coefficients indicate a change qual-
time-invariantregressors are assumed to have itatively similar to the changes in the levels
time-varying effects. regression of column (ii). The schooling co-
It is importantto note that equation (5) can efficient is estimated to have declined by
be modified to allow for heterogeneous returns roughly 1.1 percentage points between 1984
to schooling as well as additive heterogeneity and 1985, and by 1.3 percentage points be-
originating in the decision to go to school (the tween 1985 and 1986, with further substan-
latter is represented by ai). Define (yi,, - tial declines during the Palestinian uprising.
yi,t- I) = ej't to be the individual-specific The results in Table 5 therefore support the
change in returns to schooling. For example, claim that the decline in the average returns
the year-to-yearchange in returnsto schooling to schooling was experienced by individual
would differ across individuals if the returns Palestinian graduates.
to schooling differ by school quality or by field A potential problem with the interpretation
of study. Replacing ( yi, - -yi,t - I) by -i, in of the panel results is that while the derivation
(5), it is straightforwardto show that ordinary of equation (5) assumes that schooling is time-
least-squares (OLS) estimates of the differ- invariant,reportedschooling changes between
enced equation have an expectation or proba- the first and third interviews for roughly 30
bility limit equal to a weighted average of percent of the sample. The fact that the fre-
Y.'15 Thus, the reported estimates of (y, - quency distribution of schooling changes is
yt-l) can be interpreted as estimates of nearly symmetricaroundzero suggests thatthe
changes in reported schooling from interview
to interview are at least partly attributableto
misreporting or other types of measurement
'5 The weights are j2 where ei is the residual from
e2/y
error. The observed decline in schooling co-
a regression of schooling on all other covariates in the
differenced equation. This simple interpretationrequires efficients, especially after 1987, could there-
that yj, and yi,,, be the only randomcoefficients in equa- fore be at least partly attributableto changes
tion (5). in data quality.

This content downloaded from 146.155.94.33 on Fri, 5 Jul 2013 16:22:38 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
1080 THE AMERICANECONOMICREVIEW DECEMBER 1995

To correct for possible measurement error line drawn is for the group with 16 or more
in schooling variables, I tried an instrumental years of school. For the sample of 28 quarterly
variables (IV) strategy using schooling levels observations for 1981-1987, 4g is equal
reported at the second interview as an instru- to -0.16 (standard error = 0.06, partialR2 =
ment for schooling variables in equations for 0.21) for men with 13- 15 years of schooling;
third-interview responses or first - third 4pg is equal to -0.25 (standard error = 0.11,
interview differences. A statistical model jus- partial R2 = 0.16) for men with 16 or more
tifying this approachis outlined in my working years of schooling; and 4g is equal to -0.28
paper (Angrist, 1992). It turns out that IV es- (standarderror = 0.07, partialR2 = 0.37) for
timates from this procedureare virtually iden- men with 12 or fewer years of schooling.
tical to the OLS estimates.'6 The regression line in Figure 6 appears to
account for an importantfraction of the vari-
V. The Demand for Skilled Labor ance in wage differentials between 1981 and
1987. Overall, the figure for 1981-1987 is
Figures 6 and 7 show the relationship be- consistent with a moderately elastic demand
tween the log of average daily wages and the for educated workers. On the other hand,
log of cohort size (including men in the labor points plotted in Figure 7 show that in the sam-
force plus men temporarily out of the labor ple of quarterly observations for 1988-1991
force) by quarterand by schooling group for there is little relationship between schooling-
men who reportedtheir usual work location as group size and wage differentials. This sug-
being in the territories, Israel, or Jerusalem. gests that declines in relative wages for
These graphs are motivated by the theoretical educated workers after 1988 are more likely
frameworklaid out in the beginning of Section to be attributableto the disruptionof local ec-
III, which relates changes in schooling differ- onomic activity duringthe Palestinianuprising
entials to changes in the size of schooling than to supply shifts.
groups. Averages and counts used to construct
the figures were computed using CBS sam- VI. Changesin the IsraeliWageDistribution
pling weights. The data in Figure 6 are for
1981-1987 only; the data in Figure 7 are for The findings presented so far naturallyraise
1988-1991. the question of what was happening to the
The figures plot the residuals from regres- wages of Israeli citizens during the sample pe-
sions of average log daily wages and log labor- riod. If the Palestinian experience was not
force counts on a full set of quarterly period unique among groups under Israeli influence,
effects and annual schooling-group effects. then some of the decline in returnsto school-
The slope of the line drawn throughthe points ing among Palestinians could reflect demand
in the figure is therefore an estimate of the pa- shocks common to the Palestinian and Israeli
rameter 4g in the equation economies.
Table 6 presents estimates of wage equa-
(6) ln(wgt) = , d,6t + I bgygt tions for Jewish and non-Jewish Israeli citi-
I g zens.'7 The data used to construct these
estimates are drawn from the Israeli Income
+ 4gln(Lgt) + vgt Survey (IS) and are described in the Data Ap-
pendix. Briefly, the IS interviews residents of
where g indexes schooling groups and Lg, is urban areas in outgoing rotation groups from
the size of the schooling-group cohort. The the Israeli Labor Force Survey (LFS). This
sampling frame includes about 94 percent of
the Jewish population but only 40 percent of
16 IV estimation is based on a modified specification in

which the potential-experiencequadraticis replaced by an


age quadratic.Only for one year are IV estimates different
from OLS estimates, and for equations in levels as well as "7Most non-Jewish Israelis are Moslem Arabs, al-
differences, the statistically significant contrast by esti- though some are Christian Arabs, Druze, or members of
mation technique is very small. other ethnic minorities.

This content downloaded from 146.155.94.33 on Fri, 5 Jul 2013 16:22:38 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
VOL. 85 NO. 5 ANGRIST:ECONOMICRETURNS TO SCHOOLING 1081

0.14
Schooling group: X X X 13 - 15 years
16 or more years
0.12 00 0 12 or fewer years
0
0
0.10

000
0.08 0

0.06
o
~~~~~x*
0.02-
0.04 x*

0.02 *

-0.02 x x x* ~ ~~~
x ~ ~ ~~~~~ O

-0.04 * 0~~~~~~~~~~~~~
*

-0.08 0 *

-0.10

-0. 12

-0.22 -0.18 -0.14 -0.10 -0.06 -0.02 0.02 0.06 0.10 0.14 0.18 0.22

Log labor-force size

FIGURE 6. WAGES AND THE SIZE OF SCHOOLING GROUPS,


BY SCHOOLING GROUP, FOR 1981-1987

Notes: The figure plots quarterly observations on average log daily wages by school-
ing group against the average log labor-force size, after removing quarterly period and
schooling-group main effects. The regression line in the figure is fit to averages for men
with 16 or more years of schooling. The slope of this line can be interpretedas an estimate
of 4' in equation (6) in the text. Averages were computed using CBS sampling weights.

the non-Jewish population. For both ethnic schooling (Israel CBS, 199 lb table 22.1 ). Fi-
groups, the sample used here is restricted to nally, Census data show that, like Arabs from
men aged 18-59. the territories, Israeli Arabs have a high
Citizen Arabs in the Israeli labor market proportion (28 percent) of employment in
have labor-force characteristicscloser to those construction.
of noncitizen Arabs than to those of Israeli The wage variable used to construct the es-
Jews. For example, estimates from the 1983 timates reportedin Table 6 is the log of weekly
Israeli Census, reported in Noah Lewin- wage and salary earnings. Columns (v) and
Epstein and Moshe Semyonov (1993 tables (x) in the table show average log weekly earn-
3.2-3.3), show that 30 percent of Arab men ings along with standarddeviations for Jewish
in the Israeli labor force were self-employed and non-Jewish workers. Columns (iv) and
and 12 percent were employed as agricultural (ix) show sample sizes for the subsamples
workers. Both of these proportions are much with valid wage data. The estimates in the
lower among Israeli Jews. The distributionof table are based on samples of 2,489-3,189 ob-
educational attainmentamong Israeli Arabs is servations for Jews but only 119-262 obser-
also closer to the distribution among nonciti- vations for non-Jews. Wages of non-Jews are
zen Arabs than to the distribution among substantiallylower and have less variance than
Israeli Jews. In 1985, for example, 25 percent the wages of Jews.
of Israeli Jews aged 15 and over had 13 or Columns (i), (ii), (vi), and (vii) report
more years of schooling, while only 8.5 per- schooling coefficients on dummies for 13-15
cent of Israeli Arabs had 13 or more years of years of schooling and for 16 or more years of

This content downloaded from 146.155.94.33 on Fri, 5 Jul 2013 16:22:38 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
1082 THE AMERICANECONOMICREVIEW DECEMBER 1995

0.14
Schooling group: X X X 13 - 15 years
16 or more years
0.12 000 ?12 or fewer years

0.10

0.08

0.06
0 *
5 0.04a

a 0 0.02-
eX
*
*
*
* 00~~~~~~~~~~~~~~
e x
X X* 'X X

0.02 * *O
** *X

-0.00 * Ex *
-0.024'*

-0.06

-0.08

-0.10

-0.12 E,

-0.22 -0.18 -0.14 -0.10 -0.06 -0.02 0.02 0.06 0.10 0.14 0.18 0.22

Log labor-force size

FIGURE 7. WAGES AND THE SIZE OF SCHOOLING GROUP,


BY SCHOOLING GROUP, FOR 1988-1991

Notes: The figure plots quarterly observations on average log daily wages by school-
ing group against the average log labor-force size, after removing quarterly period and
schooling-group main effects. The regression line in the figure is fit to averages for men
with 16 or more years of schooling. The slope of this line can be interpretedas an estimate
of (g in equation (6) in the text. Averages were computed using CBS sampling weights.

schooling in regressions that include quarter premiumfor Palestinianswas 0.41 in 1981 and
dummies, dummies for continent of birth (for 0.37 in 1982.
Jews), dummies for 5-year age groups, and The returns to higher education for Jewish
dummies for work location and region of res- Israelis show a noticeable decline between
idence. The work locations and regions of res- 1989 and 1991. The weekly wage premiumfor
idence are Jerusalem, Haifa, northern Israel, workers with 16 or more years of schooling
central Israel excluding Tel Aviv, and south- fell from 0.45 to 0.37, and the wage premium
ern Israel. Tel Aviv is the reference location for 13-15 years of schooling fell from 0.23 to
for both sets of dummies. 0.18. These declines probably reflect the ar-
The estimates for Jewish Israelis show a pat- rival of a wave of relatively skilled immigrants
tern of schooling coefficients that is remarka- from the former Soviet Union. This wave of
bly stable in the 1980's, and similar to the immigrationbegan in earnest in late 1989. The
1981 and 1982 coefficients for Palestinians. results of replacing the schooling dummies
The weekly wage premium for those with 13- with years of schooling as a linear regressor,
15 years of schooling ranges from 0.24 in reported in column (iii), show a similar pat-
1981 to 0.29 in 1985, falling to 0.23 in 1989. tern. Per-year returns are stable at around 6
The daily wage premium for Palestinians was percent between 1981 and 1988 (with a slight
0.25 in 1981 and 0.22 in 1982 (these estimates dip in 1988) but show a continued decline only
are from Table 2). The premiumfor Jews with between 1989 and 1991.
16 or more years of schooling ranges from Estimated schooling dummies for non-
0.40 in 1982 to 0.45 in 1989. The comparable Jewish Israeli citizens are reportedin columns

This content downloaded from 146.155.94.33 on Fri, 5 Jul 2013 16:22:38 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
VOL. 85 NO. 5 ANGRIST:ECONOMICRETURNS TO SCHOOLING 1083

TABLE6-SCHOOLINGCOEFFICIENTS
FORISRAELI
CITIZENS

Jews Non-Jews
Schooling coefficients Schooling coefficients
16 or 16 or
13-15 more Mean 13-15 more Mean
years years Sample log years years Sample log
schooling schooling Linear size wage schooling schooling Linear size wage
Year (i) (ii) (iii) (iv) (v) (vi) (vii) (viii) (ix) (x)
1981 0.240 0.413 0.062 3,189 7.04 0.044 0.855 0.042 119 6.44
(0.028) (0.029) (0.003) (0.610) (0.196) (0.237) (0.013) (0.545)
1982 0.282 0.403 0.059 3,141 7.86 0.152 0.561 0.046 158 7.38
(0.028) (0.028) (0.003) (0.597) (0.160) (0.233) (0.013) (0.519)
1985 0.286 0.448 0.060 2,733 5.18a 0.231 0.364 0.044 172 4.61 a
(0.031) (0.032) (0.003) (0.648) (0.171) (0.178) (0.013) (0.612)
1988 0.231 0.396 0.056 2,489 6.01 0.274 0.427 0.040 255 5.57
(0.029) (0.030) (0.003) (0.605) (0.089) (0.129) (0.008) (0.393)
1989 0.229 0.448 0.063 2,696 6.19 0.266 0.564 0.038 243 5.84
(0.029) (0.030) (0.003) (0.640) (0.083) (0.098) (0.007) (0.581)
1990 0.191 0.391 0.057 2,801 6.33 0.296 0.257 0.033 237 5.98
(0.028) (0.029) (0.003) (0.632) (0.093) (0.078) (0.007) (0.368)
1991 0.180 0.368 0.053 3,062 6.43 -0.015 0.074 0.020 262 6.17
(0.027) (0.028) (0.003) (0.638) (0.095) (0.097) (0.007) (0.390)

Notes: The table shows coefficients on dummies for 13-15 years of schooling and for 16 or more years of schooling
from regressions of log weekly wages on quarterdummies, dummies for continent of birth, 5-year age groups, work
location, and region of residence. The sample includes male salaried employees aged 18-59 in the Israeli Income Survey.
Standarderrorsare shown in parenthesesexcept for columns (v) and (x), which show the standarddeviation of log wages
in parentheses.
a The currency was switched to new Israeli shekels (1 NIS = 1,000
Shekels) in 1985.

(vi) and (vii). These estimates are based A final point for this section is that, while
on small samples and reflect considerable unemployment rates appear to be increasing
sampling variance, with some very low and with schooling among Palestinians, among
some very high estimates. The results show Israeli citizens unemployment rates are lower
a pattern of a steadily increasing payoff to for the more educated. The former pattern is
13-15 years of schooling from 1981 to typical of less - developed countries (e.g.,
1990. The payoff to 16 or more years fell Kenya [see Michael P. Todaro, 1981]), while
during the period 1981-1985, as it did for the latter is more commonly observed in
Palestinians, but rose from 1985 to 1989, in wealthier countries like the United States
contrast with continued declines for Pales- (Jacob Mincer, 1991). Moreover, in the early
tinians over this period. The conclusion that 1980's when unemployment among educated
declining returns were not experienced by Palestinians was growing worse, the situation
non-Jewish Israeli citizens is further rein- for educated Israeli Jews improved. For ex-
forced by the much more precisely estimated ample, Israeli Jews with 13-15 years of
linear schooling coefficients reported in col- schooling experienced a 1.6-percentage-point
umn (viii). The linear schooling coefficients lower unemployment rate in 1981 than did
for non-Jews are virtually unchanged during Israeli Jews with 12 or fewer years of school-
1981-1985. Schooling coefficients for non- ing. By 1985, the unemployment gap in favor
Jews decline thereafter, but these declines of the more educated had grown to 3.9 per-
are not sharp until 1990. centage points.

This content downloaded from 146.155.94.33 on Fri, 5 Jul 2013 16:22:38 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
1084 THE AMERICANECONOMICREVIEW DECEMBER 1995

VII. Summary and Conclusions bility that culminated in large-scale civil


unrest in 1988. The consequences of this mis-
This paper provides a case study of wages match are all the more impressive when one
in a developing region when the higher- notes that the period of most sharplydeclining
education system expanded rapidly. Palestin- skill differentials, 1985-1988, was one of ex-
ian students who observed wage premiums as ceptionally strong growth in real wages for
high as 40 percent when they made enrollment both Palestinians and Israelis.
decisions ended up earning less than 20-
DATA APPENDIX
percent more than high-school graduateswhen
they entered the labor market. This suggests Alternative Sources of Wage Data
that contemporaneous schooling coefficients
can be a poor indicator of the ultimate eco- Palestinian Sources.-The frequency distribution of
nomic value of additional schooling when daily wages for a sample of roughly 700 workers em-
ployed in Israel in the summer of 1984, reportedin Abu-
large numbersof new graduatesenter the labor Shukar ( 1987a), generates an average daily wage of
market. NIS 34.5 (in fourth-quarter1990 prices) for Gazans and
The findings also have implications for NIS 30.8 for residents of the West Bank.'8 Comparably
models of education in economic develop- deflated, CBS data on the wages of workers employed in
Israel in third-quarter1984 yield an average of NIS 33.1
ment. In a survey of returns to schooling for male Gazans and NIS 31.2 for men living in the West
worldwide, George Psacharopoulos (1985 p. Bank. The wage distributionfor a sample of roughly 400
592) wrote, "Judging from past trends and the workersemployed locally in the summerof 1985, reported
degree of underinvestmentin education in de- in Abu-Shukar( 1987b), generates an average daily wage
veloping countries, the fears that further edu- of NIS 31 for Gazans and NIS 28 for residents of the West
Bank. CBS data on the wages of workersemployed locally
cational expansion would lead to unemployed in the third quarterof 1985 give an average of NIS 33.3
graduatesor would lower social rates of return for Gazans and NIS 32 for men living in the West Bank.
are unfounded." Although the evidence pre- Standarderrors for the CBS average are on the order of
sented here does not speak directly to the issue NIS 3-4, so these alternativeestimates are not statistically
of social returns,it would appearthat this view different from the CBS estimates.
was overly optimistic for the developing econ- Israeli EmploymentService Data. -Workers from the
omies of the West Bank and Gaza Strip. On territoriesemployed in Israel must register with the Em-
the other hand, recent declines in Palestinian ployment Service (ES). Moreover, Israeli law requiresthat
enrollment probably reflect the beginning of a payments to workers from the territoriesbe made through
the ES.'9 As a consequence, the ES collects data on wages
belated supply response to low returns to and days worked from employer payroll worksheets. A
schooling. A similar response was observed by copy of the employer worksheet appears in Israel Em-
RichardB. Freeman (1975) in his study of the ployment Service (1992). For each month, the ES data
weak U.S. labor market for college graduates show the total payments made to workers from the terri-
in the early 1970's. This supply response and tories and the total number of days worked by registered
workers.
the recent prospect of increasing capital in- An estimate of the average daily wage for this period
vestment should eventually restore the eco- is the ratio of total payments to total days worked. ES
nomic value of schooling in the territories. wage data calculated in this manner are plotted in Figure
Finally, it is worth noting that, because the Al along with a comparable survey-based series (both in
September 1992 prices). The gross ES series in the figure
area is under occupation, the labor market in was computed from ES records of the monthly Palestinian
the territories has many unique features. For payroll (aggregated to a quarterlyseries), including over-
example, economic aspects of life in the ter-
ritories during the sample period include the
lack of an effective private capital marketor a
banking system with the power to make loans 18 I calculated these averages from reported frequency
(Shaban, 1993). These limitations undoubt- distributions using interval midpoints. The Abu-Shukar
edly contributedto the decline in economic re- (1987b) sample is 97-percent male.
"9 During most of the sample period, the number of
turns to schooling in the territories.The social
workers registered was less than half the number who in-
implications of this human-capital/physical- dicated in CBS surveys that they work in Israel. ES cov-
capital mismatch would appear to include the erage of workers from the territoriesrose to roughly 70
climate of disappointment and political insta- percent after the 1991 Gulf War.

This content downloaded from 146.155.94.33 on Fri, 5 Jul 2013 16:22:38 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
VOL 85 NO. 5 ANGRIST:ECONOMICRETURNS TO SCHOOLING 1085

110 The net ES and CBS series in Figure Al show that in


1982 and between 1986 and 1988 there was little differ-
ence between net ES wages and TLFS wages. In other
100 years, net ES wages are no more than 20-percent higher
than TLFS wages. The gap between ES and TLFS wages,
90 h t\ \ Gross ES wages ,
however, appears to have been growing since 1988. The
post-1988 decline in TLFS wages relative to ES net
wages might reflect a decline in demand for unregistered
workers when enforcement of worker-registration pro-
5 ~~~~IH visions became stricter as a consequence of the Palestin-
ian uprising.

Net ES wages Israeli Income Surveys


70Y
60-
The IS is a supplement to the quarterly Israeli Labor
Force Survey (LFS), which is a stratifiedrandom sample
Survey wage f
drawn from a sampling frame of almost all residential
s0
dwelling units in Israel, supplemented with data from the
1983 or earlier Censuses of Population. Data for the LFS
are collected using the same 2-2-2 quarterlyrotationgroup
40-
design used in the TLFS. Thus, in every quarter, one-
fourth of the households who have been interviewed in the
30
LFS are retiredfrom the survey. Only households in these
.. . . . . . . .. .
81 82 83 84 85 86 87 88 89 90 91 92 outgoing rotation groups are given the IS supplementary
Year questionnaire.A detailed discussion of the LFS appearsin
Israel CBS ( 1992). A detailed discussion of the IS appears
FIGURE Al. DAILY WAGE DATA FROM in Israel CBS (1993b).
ALTERNATIVE SOURCES The IS sample is limited to outgoing LFS households
in Jewish or mixed-ethnicity localities with 2,000 inhabi-
Notes: The figure piots quarterlyobservationson real daily
tants or more at the time of the 1983 Census and house-
wages in September 1992 new Israeli shekels (NIS). The
holds in non-Jewish localities with 10,000 or more
line labeled "survey wages" is the average daily wage for
inhabitantsat the time of the 1983 Census. This sampling
workers in the TLFS who were employed in Israel or Je-
frame includes about 94 percent of the Jewish population
rusalem. The line labelled "gross ES wages" is the av-
but only 40 percent of the non-Jewish population. The
erage daily payroll payment per worker, derived from Is-
sample size is also reduced by a high refusal rate among
rael Employment Service (ES) data on registered workers
selected households (about 28 percent in the 1989-1991
from the territorieswho were working in Israel. The line
surveys; see Israel CBS, 1993b). Many of those who do
labelled "net ES wages" subtractsnational insurancecon-
respond to questions about income are willing to supply
tributions, income tax payments, pension contributions,
only partialinformation.Some of the missing information
social and health program contributions, and union dues
for partialrespondentsis imputed.The survey weights are
from the gross ES series.
also adjusted for demographic correlates of nonresponse.
Sources: Author's tabulation from TLFS micro data and
As with the TLFS, the IS and LFS micro data files are
unpublished employment service reports.
not systematically released for public use with official user
documentation, although some files with Israeli data are
maintainedand distributedby the Social Science Data Ar-
chive (SSDA) at Hebrew University. Results from the
time, employers' and workers' National Insurancecontri- 1991 IS (reported in Israel CBS [1993b p. 21]) show that
butions, and cash benefits (e.g., sick pay, vacation pay). 3,933 households were surveyed in 1991. My tabulation
The ES and TLFS wage series show a similar pattern, of the 1991 SSDA micro-datatape generated a sample of
although the ES daily wage is roughly double the TLFS 3,373 men aged 18-59. The IS questionnaireformat and
survey wage. variable definitions change from year to year. For this
One reason why ES and TLFS levels differ is that the project, I prepareduniform extracts from the 1981, 1982,
ES payments data record payments before deductions of 1985, and 1988-1991 survey tapes, imposing consistent
any kind. The TLFS data, however, probably correspond variable definitions wherever possible. There was no IS
to a measure of net wage rates after taxes and other de- in 1986, and micro data from the 1983, 1984, and 1987
ductions. I therefore used ES monthly data on taxes and surveys contained many inconsistencies and appeared
deductions to convert ES gross wages into net wages by unreliable.
subtractingemployer and employee contributions to Na- The IS micro sample contains relatively few demo-
tional Insurance (11-15 percent of net wages), income graphic variables, while the LFS micro sample is released
taxes (2-3 percent of net wages), pension-fund contri- with a rich and detailed set of covariates but no informa-
butions (roughly 13 percent of net wages), and training- tion on wages or income. For this project, LFS variables
fund contributions, health insurance, and union dues (4- were matched to the IS data using a statistical matching
6 percent of net wages). algorithm so that some LFS covariates (such as survey

This content downloaded from 146.155.94.33 on Fri, 5 Jul 2013 16:22:38 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
1086 THE AMERICANECONOMICREVIEW DECEMBER 1995

quarter) could be included in the analysis. The statistical 94.02, Hebrew University, Jerusalem, Jan-
match was virtually 100-percent successful. uary 1994.
Wage and salary earnings collected in the IS are meant
to be a measure of gross earnings. During 1981-1982,
Artstein,Yael and Sussman,Zvi. "Wage Policy
wage data in the IS were collected by recording monthly During Disinflation: The Israeli Policy Sta-
earnings in each of the 12 months preceding the interview bilization Programof 1985." Bank of Israel
and summing to annual earnings. Annual earnings were Economic Review, January 1990, 64(1),
converted to weekly earningsby dividing by annualweeks pp. 1-35.
worked. From 1985 onward, data on monthly wage and
salary earnings were collected by recordingmonthly earn- Ashenfelter,Orley; Deaton, Angus and Solon,
ings for the three months preceding the IS interview and Gary. "Does It Make Sense to Collect Panel
then averaging. This measure was converted to weekly Data for Developing Countries?" Woodrow
earnings by dividing average monthly earnings by the av- Wilson School Research Programin Devel-
erage number of weeks worked per month in the three
preceding months.
opment Studies Discussion Paper No. 119,
Princeton University, May 1985.
Freeman,RichardB. "Overinvestment in Col-
REFERENCES lege Training?" Journal of Human Re-
sources, Summer 1975, 10(3), pp. 287-
Abu-Shukar,Abedel Fatah.The labor marketin 311.
the West Bank and Gaza Strip [in Arabic] . Gabriel,Stuart and Sabatello,Eitan. "Palestin-
Nablus, West Jordan:Al-Najah University, ian Migrationfrom the West Bank and Gaza
1987a. Strip: Economic and Demographic Analy-
. The social and economic conditions ses." Economic Development and Cultural
of workers from the West Bank and Gaza Change, January1986, 34(2), pp. 245-62.
Strip employed in Israel [in Arabic]. Nab- Israel CBS. Judea, Samaria, and Gaza area
lus, West Jordan: Al-Najah University, statistics quarterly, 1989-90, Vol. 19. Je-
1987b. rusalem: Central Bureau of Statistics, Feb-
. The economic implications of emigra- ruary 1991a.
tionfrom the WestBank and Gaza Strip [in . The statistical abstract of Israel
Arabic]. Jerusalem: Arab Thought Forum, 1991, Vol. 42. Jerusalem:CentralBureauof
July 1990. Statistics, 1991b.
Al-Dweik,Aziz S. "Self-Selection and Spatial . Laborforce surveys 1990, CBS Spe-
Mobility of PalestinianMale Workersin the cial Series No. 912. Jerusalem:Central Bu-
West Bank and Gaza Strip." Ph.D. disser- reau of Statistics, January 1992.
tation, University of Pennsylvania, 1988. . The statistical abstract of Israel
Al-Qiq, Hasan. Vocational training and edu- 1993, Vol. 44. Jerusalem:CentralBureauof
cation in the occupied territories [in Ara- Statistics, 1993a.
bic]. Jerusalem:Arab Thought Forum,June . Income of households 1989, 1990,
1988. 1991, CBS Special Series No. 933. Jerusa-
Altonji,Joseph and Card, David. "The Effects lem: Central Bureau of Statistics, May
of Immigration on the Labor Market Out- 1993b.
comes of Less-Skilled Natives," in John IsraelEmploymentService.Wagepayments and
Abowd and Richard Freeman, eds., Immi- social benefitsfor workersfrom Judea, Sa-
gration, trade, and the labor market. Chi- maria, and the Gaza Strip, Israel Employ-
cago: University of Chicago Press, 1991, ment Service Payments Division, Pamphlet
pp. 201 -34. for Employers (in Hebrew). Jerusalem:
Angrist,JoshuaD. "Wages and Employment in Ministry of Labor, January 1991.
the West Bank and Gaza Strip: 1981-90." Jerusalem Media and CommunicationsCenter.
Falk Institute for Economic Research in Is- Israeli obstacles to economic development
rael Discussion Paper No. 92.02, Hebrew in the occupied Palestinian territories. Je-
University, Jerusalem, July 1992. rusalem: Jerusalem Media and Communi-
__. "The Demand for Palestinian La- cations Center, November 1992.
bor." Falk Institute for Economic Re- Johnson,George."The LaborMarketEffects of
search in Israel Discussion Paper No. Immigration." Industrial and Labor Rela-

This content downloaded from 146.155.94.33 on Fri, 5 Jul 2013 16:22:38 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
VOL. 85 NO. 5 ANGRIST:ECONOMICRETURNS TO SCHOOLING 1087

tions Review, April 1980, 33 (3), pp. 331 - Psacharopoulos,George. "Returns to Educa-
41. tion: A Further International Update and
Kleiman,Ephraim."The Flow of Labour Ser- Implications." Journal of Human Re-
vices from the West Bank and Gaza to sources, Fall 1985, 20(40), pp. 583-97.
Israel." Hebrew University (Jerusalem) Schiff, Zeev and Yaari, Ehud. Intifada. New
Department of Economics Working Paper York: Simon and Schuster, 1989.
No. 260, July 1992. Semyonov, Moshe and Lewin-Epstein, Noah.
Lewin-Epstein,Noahand Semyonov,Moshe.The Hewers of wood and drawers of water. Ith-
Arab minorityin Israel's economy: Patterns aca, NY: Industrial and Labor Relations
of ethnic inequality. San Francisco: West- Press, 1987.
view, 1993. Shaban,RadwanA. "Palestinian Labor Mobil-
Metzer, Jacob. "What Kind of Growth? A ity." International Labour Review, 1993,
Comparative Look at the Arab Economies 132(5-6), pp. 655-72.
in Mandatory Palestine and in the Admin- Simon, Avi. "Education and Employment in
istered Territories." Economic Develop- the Territories." Israel Economist, May
ment and Cultural Change, July 1992, 1988, (44), pp. 8-10.
40(4), pp. 843-65. Todaro, Michael P. "Education and Na-
Mincer, Jacob. "Education and Unemploy- tional Development in Kenya," in Tony
ment." National Bureau of Economic Re- Killick, ed., Papers on the Kenyan econ-
search (Cambridge, MA) Working Paper omy: Performance, problems, and poli-
No. 3838, September 1991. cies. London: Heinemann, 1981, pp.
PalestinianInstitutefor HigherEducation.Statis- 269-78.
tical guide to Palestinian universities and Zakai, Dan. Economic developments in Ju-
colleges: 1990. Ramallah (West Bank, Is- dea, Samaria, and the Gaza district,
rael): Palestinian Institute for Higher Edu- 1985-86. Jerusalem: Bank of Israel,
cation, 1991. December 1988.

This content downloaded from 146.155.94.33 on Fri, 5 Jul 2013 16:22:38 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

You might also like