You are on page 1of 11

State Support for Industrial R and D

in Developing Economies
Telecom Equipment Industry in India and China
The importance of state support for industrial R and D in literature fails to take cognisance of
the contextual specificity of late industrialising economies. The problem of inadequate
investment in technology by domestic firms, engaged primarily in ‘technology catch-up’, is
rooted in their dependence on technologically advanced foreign firms and their inability to
break down non-technological barriers to entry in the product market. Through a comparative
narrative of technology development under state support in India and China, this paper seeks
to provide some evidence on the need to be sensitive to the stage of technological development,
and the nature of industry in designing policies of state support for industrial R and D for
effective intervention.
BISWATOSH SAHA

I to entry’ in the product market which are created due to the extant
Introduction market structure and the strategies of entrenched firms in the
industry. Developing economy firms then might continue in

T
here has been a renewed debate on the role of government ‘relations of dependence’ with technologically advanced foreign
support for industrial R and D, much of it in the context firms, preferring not to take up the risk of investing in R and D.
of advanced industrial economies. The US in particular Domestic firms in developing economies, therefore, might under-
has been arguing about the necessity of state intervention invest in R and D, even if they do not face traditional problems
[CEA 1995; Hill 1995;1 Mani 1999]. As Stiglitz (1998) argues, relating to appropriation, which has occupied much of the new
“technology has numerous positive externalities. Indeed in some debate.
respect, knowledge is like a classical public good” (p 27). Hence, This paper analyses the experience of Centre for Development
without government intervention, there will be under-investment of Telematics (henceforth to be referred to as C-DoT), a public
in industrial R and D because of the inability of the investor to sector research institution in India set up in 1984 to develop
fully appropriate the returns to investment. The public policy indigenous telecommunication switching technology. Though
implication following from such an argument is that state state intervention in supporting industrial R and D in India
subsidisation of R and D, through tax breaks or direct research is not regarded as highly successful, especially compared to
grants, which makes up for the gap between private and social east Asian economies, [GoI 1986; Mani 2001] C-DoT has
return (deductively derived within the neo-liberal equilibrium been successful in developing cost-effective indigenous
model) to R and D investment, suffices to ameliorate the problem telecom switching technology, making India one of the few
of market failure. This argument, rooted in neo-liberal tra- developing economies to have indigenous design capability in
ditions (with the additional assumption of externalities) is the industry.
ahistorical, in a sense, for it fails to take account of contextual The Indian experience, however, appears modest when com-
differences between economies in different stages of industrial pared to the remarkable success of Chinese telecommunication
and technological development. This is crucial, I argue in this equipment manufacturers over the last decade, particularly their
paper, particularly for the implications for the design of instru- rapid pace of technology learning and development, and expan-
ments of state support and consequently, the success of state sion into global markets in the short span of about a decade. The
intervention. industrial policy environment and instruments of state interven-
Developing economies are “late industrialisers”, as Amsden tion in China, as will be shown, have been quite different from
(1989), Wade (1990) and others have argued. Domestic enter- that in India and this paper analyses the significance of such
prises in these economies are engaged in a process of ‘techno- differences. Through a comparative account of technology
logical catch up’ with rival firms from more advanced industrial evolutions and development in industry in the two countries, the
economies. The nature of industrial R and D in domestic enter- paper seeks to provide evidence on the need to link the design
prises indigenous to developing economies is, therefore, of instruments of state support to the stage of technological
qualitatively different from R and D in ‘cutting edge’ technolo- development of domestic industry so that state intervention is
gies that are primarily the target of state subsidisation in indus- effective.
trially advanced economies. For firms in developing economies, The paper is organised as follows. Section II deals briefly with
engaged in the technology catch-up process, low investment in the global telecommunication equipment industry, analysing the
R and D might be rooted in their inability to surmount ‘barriers nature of the industry, its market structure, nature of competition

Economic and Political Weekly August 28, 2004 3915


as well as the nature and extent of barriers to entry. Section III Nature of Industry and Sources of Entry Barriers
analyses the experience of C-DoT and evaluates its performance.
Section IV provides a brief narrative on Chinese telecom equip- The telecom equipment industry, particularly the switching
ment firms over the last decade, contrasting it with the Indian segment, is technology intensive: expenses on research and
experience. Section V analyses the significance of the somewhat development in designing new products are about 15 to 20 per
differential experience of indigenous technology development cent of sales of leading MNCs [various Annual Reports of Lucent,
in the two economies. Alcatel 2000-2001]. The manufacturing process, post design, is
a simple assembly operation. Technology barriers lie, therefore,
II at the design stage. There has been an important change in the
Global Telecom Equipment Industry: product development process from the 1980s, after digital
An Overview switching technology came in. The focus of product development
has shifted from hardware to software components (around 80
Before moving on to the particular narratives of the two cases, per cent of R and D expenses, currently, are on software devel-
a brief digression on the global telecom equipment industry will opment) over the 1990s – giving firms from developing econo-
set the context for the discussion that follows. The telecom mies a cost advantage in the R and D process itself, due to
equipment industry broadly refers to a range of products that are availability of low-wage skilled labour. Cost advantage in prod-
usually segmented into switching, transmission and access (cus- uct development can lead to cost advantages in the final product
tomer premise) products, depending on the part of the network market, due to the substantial contribution of R and D costs to
it is used in. Among these different segments, switching and some total cost. However, technology and product development is by
transmission products are generally more ‘technology intensive’ no means the only entry barrier, particularly after the recent
and are characterised by concentrated industry structures domi- regulatory and technological changes that profoundly affect the
nated by a few multinational firms. Being an intermediate in- structure and contours of evolution of the industry.
dustrial product, demand in the industry is driven by the growth The telecommunication industry, over the 1990s, experienced
in telecom service markets (it is primarily network expansion major restructuring after the introduction of competition in almost
and upgradation that creates demand for telecommunication all segments of the industry. The restructuring was led by the
equipment). Over the last decade, the rapid expansion of telecom US, where competition in fixed-line telephony was introduced
networks (and telecom service markets) in large industrialising in phases from 1984, by breaking up the monopoly operator
economies (China, India, Brazil, in particular) has made these (AT&T) into a long-distance carrier (competition was allowed
markets the new growth poles of the equipment industry – in the long-distance market) and the Regional Bell Operating
particularly for traditional fixed line networks.2 In developed Companies, which retained monopoly status in operating the
markets, growth in the telecom service industry has been more local loop. Finally in 1996, with the passage of the Telecom-
concentrated in the new technology segments that include mobile munication Act, competition was introduced in all segments of
telephony and data networks. However, developing economies fixed-line networks in the US. Technological changes over this
constitute a significant part of global markets in these new period – the rapid development of mobile telephony, other radio
segments as well. China, for instance, already had the largest based communication and the growth of data networks – created
installed base of mobile telephones in the world by the turn of competing modes of telecommunication. This played a role in
the century [Nolan 2001]. the restructuring of fixed-line networks as well – more so because
Globally, the industry is highly concentrated. The top ten the newer segments developed under competitive market struc-
manufacturers, all with their roots in advanced industrial tures in USA.
economies, accounted for 75 per cent of the global switching What essentially began as a US phenomenon gradually spread
equipment market in early 1990s [Carpentier et al 1992]. to other countries – aided in no small measure by US diplomacy
Moreover, markets in major industrialised economies that and protracted negotiations at the WTO over the World Tele-
had a major telecom equipment manufacturer – US, Japan, communications Agreement (under GATS; signed in 1997),
France, UK, West Germany – were dominated by the local firm.3 which shaped and influenced the policy dialogue in the industry
In fact, the largest telecom service markets in the world, till across the globe.5 The European Union, for instance, enacted
very recent times, were all closed markets (the sector was the EU Telecommunications Act in 1998, introducing compe-
considered strategic in terms of national interest) with private tition in the industry. Simultaneous to the introduction of com-
or public sector monopolies operating the network. The operator petition during this period, was another profound change – the
often had close relations with the local equipment supplier, opening of hitherto closed national telecom service markets to
including preferential purchase policies, which played an impor- foreign operators, which set the stage for the multinationalisation
tant role in technology development as well as evolution of the of the telecom service industry.
industry structure.4 Cross border mergers and acquisitions as well as massive
Telecom network operators in developing economies (mostly investment flows have characterised this industry over the last
under state ownership), where indigenous technological capa- few years, as the leading telecom operators (primarily from
bility for equipment manufacturing did not exist, depended on developed economies) consolidated their market positions across
foreign equipment suppliers – such dependent relations ranging major markets in North America, Europe and Japan. The merger
from imports to local assembly based on foreign technology between Vodafone, Mannesman (both EU based) and Airtouch
licensing. It is only in the 1990s that firms from developing (US based) to create VAM – the largest mobile phone operator
economies – South Korea, Brazil, India and China, entered the (12 per cent of global mobile phone subscribers in 2000) with
industry with indigenously developed technology, often pro- a trans-Atlantic market position is probably reflective of this
duced at a fraction of the cost. trend. The leading global telecom operators are also consolidating

3916 Economic and Political Weekly August 28, 2004


market positions in large parts of the developing world – par- similar lines, through strategic alliances and consortium. Incum-
ticularly in Latin America, where extensive privatisation and bent multinational equipment manufacturers have already re-
liberalisation of foreign investment rules have led to the com- sponded to these expected shifts by taking recourse to strategic
prehensive takeover of national operators. By the late 1990s, 18 alliances and acquisitions to gain access to complementary
out of 20 largest operators in Latin America, for instance, were technologies and products and develop capabilities for imple-
controlled by strategic foreign investors [Nolan 2001:778-79]. menting turnkey installations of complete networks.6
This fundamental reordering in the organisation of the telecom Thirdly, the multinationalisation of the service industry (the
service industry had a profound impact on the relation of the client for equipment manufacturers) will imply that the national
network operator with equipment suppliers. Firstly, the erstwhile operation of an equipment manufacturer will become increas-
monopoly telecom operators (many of whom are today corporatised ingly unviable. To the extent that developing economies have
or privatised) faced with competition in their service markets, to open up the telecom service industry to foreign competition,
are becoming more demanding in looking for attractive commer- the ability of the state to provide an assured domestic market
cial terms for equipment procurement. Provision of vendor credit, to indigenous equipment manufacturers will get eroded. Even
supplier finance and strategic equity investments in operators at the turn of the century, most telecom markets in east Asia,
have become important competitive tools in opening up and India and China remain protected and segmented from global
developing telecommunication equipment markets. The financial markets to a large extent due to various restrictions. But, how
strength of entrenched MNCs and their institutional links with long such restrictions will remain is an open question.7 For
international banks/financiers (developed historically) is enabling indigenous firms from developing economies in the equipment
them to provide cheap and extended credit to finance equipment industry, the path to salvation might well lie in establishing a
sales to clients. toehold in global markets. And surmounting the technology
As the Annual Report of Lucent Technologies (1999) notes – barrier alone is unlikely to be a sufficient condition for successful
The purchasing behavior of Lucent’s largest customers has increas- entry into global markets.
ingly been characterised by the use of fewer and larger contracts.
These contracts typically involve longer negotiation cycles, require III
the dedication of substantial amounts of working capital and other C-DoT and Telecom Equipment Industry
resources; and in general require costs that may substantially in India
precede the recognition of associated revenues. Lucent has increas-
ingly provided or arranged long-term financing for customers as C-DoT was set up in August 1984, as an autonomous registered
a condition to obtain or bid on infrastructure projects” scientific society under Department of Telecommunications
(‘Management’s Discussion and Analysis of Results of Operations (DoT), government of India, with a specific mission to indig-
and Financial Condition’, 1999). enously design high capacity digital telecom switches. Creation
At year-end September 2000, Lucent had around US$ 8.1 of C-DoT transferred the technology-intensive R and D function
billion of customer financing assets (loans or guarantees) on to an autonomous institution, separating it from the manufac-
annual revenues of about US$ 28.9 billion. Some of these assets turing activity, which was then being carried out at public sector
turned bad as the telecom industry entered a downturn at the end Indian Telephone Industries (ITI) through technology licensing
of the century, forcing Lucent to incur US$ 765 million and arrangements with Alcatel. The switching equipment envisaged
US$ 1.8 billion as financing charges in 2001 and 2002 respec- for development in C-DoT was to cater to capacities from 128
tively, [Annual Report, Lucent Technologies 2002]. This clearly to 40,000 ports,8 for a variety of applications like PBX, local,
brings out the significance of such competitive tools in opening trunk and tandem9 in rural, urban and metropolitan areas in India.
up markets for equipment vendors. Similar perceptions about To appreciate the context under which C-DoT was formed,
industry dynamics were referred to in annual reports of other large a short digression about the existing switching technology in the
MNCs as well. Indian network is essential. ITI, the sole licensed manufacturer
The other major change affecting the industry involves a shift of switching equipment in India, was dependent on various
in the role of the ‘system integrator’, from network operators foreign technology suppliers since its inception in 1949. Mani
to equipment suppliers. To understand this shift, we need to (1989), after a review of ITI’s technology imports, concluded
remember that switching equipment constitutes only one com- that the direct cost of technology import by ITI was quite high.
ponent of a telecom system and that the integration of different More importantly, absorption and assimilation of imported
components constitutes an important aspect of network design
and installation. Under the old industry structure, the network Table I: Major Milestones in C-DoT’s Technology Development
operator played the system integration role, often in close relation in Digital Switching
with the equipment supplier – particularly in developed markets Date Technological Breakthrough
where domestic equipment suppliers existed. This role is slowly
July 1986 128 port RAX installed at Kittur, Karnataka.
shifting to equipment suppliers, as network operators concentrate May 1987 Installation of 512 port MAX at Delhi Cantonment.
on their core function of marketing telecom services. On the other August 1987 Installation of 16,000 port MAX-L at Ulsoor in Bangalore.
hand, for new entrants into the telecom service industry, who March 1988 Mass production of RAX at ITI, Bangalore started.
lack in-house technical expertise, this shift is obvious. To be December 1995 Installed the first MAX-XL switch (maximum capacity 40,000
ports)
competitive in this new environment, equipment manufacturers 1996-97 CCS No 7 introduced successfully in an existing RAX.
need to have a complete product portfolio to cover all segments April 1998 ISDN compatibility achieved, IN features launched
of the network (switching, transmission and access) or bid in 1999-2000 C-DoT switches can be used as fixed line exchange and
mobile switching unit.
consortium. Because of the system nature of the downstream
network, the upstream industry also needs to organise along Source: C-DoT Annual Reports.

Economic and Political Weekly August 28, 2004 3917


technology was extremely tardy. Switching technology used in failed to design a reliable EPABX system of its own in spite
the Indian network kept pace, broadly, with shifting technological of significant investment in R and D.
frontiers in the international industry. But, in every case of
transition to a higher generation technology, ITI had to depend RAX: Entry into Digital Public Switching Market
on technology transfer from foreign sources. In many cases, the
choice of technology was not appropriate and was governed by The first digital public switching system designed by C-DoT
factors other than commercial considerations.10 ITI spent close was the 126 port Rural Automatic Exchange (RAX), installed
to 8 per cent of its revenues on R and D throughout the 1980s, in 1986 to replace the existing Strowger type electro-mechanical
but most of it was spent on costly exercises to adapt inappropriate exchanges in the DoT (monopoly telecom operator till the mid-
foreign technologies to local conditions.11 Meanwhile, the Rajiv 1990s) network in rural areas. By 1999, over 90 per cent of the
Gandhi government, which came to power in 1984, began rural switching capacity in India was made up of RAX products.
implementing fresh projects for technological modernisation and After the success of RAX, DoT reserved its requirement of rural
indigenous capability development. C-DoT was formed, at this exchanges for preferential purchase of RAX products. RAX has
stage, as part of the Technology Mission on Telecommunication been particularly successful because it was tailored to local Indian
(identified as one of the five thrust areas), ‘cherry-picking’ some conditions, with ability to withstand extreme temperature con-
of the best engineers in the country to form the core team. ditions (–20 to 500C), dust and humidity. It consumes very little
power and does not even require air conditioning, and has upto
Technology Development at C-DoT 512 port applications. It may also be noted that MNCs did not
have a competing product suited to rural applications in India and
The first product designed by C-DoT was the EPABX (Private C-DoT products found ready acceptance in a ‘niche’ not served
Automatic Branch Exchange) system. The basic design was by incumbents. The product development trajectories of estab-
formulated within a year after C-DoT’s formation. By 1989, lished MNCs in the industry, influenced as they are by demand
nearly 70 per cent of local EPABX manufacturers entered into patterns in industrially advanced developed markets (characterised
technology collaboration arrangements with C-DoT, instead of by high quality, advanced features and premium pricing), pre-
looking towards foreign sources of technology [C-DoT 1989]. cluded product development suited to specific local conditions
The achievement was all the more laudable because ITI, which in India.12 This gave C-DoT opportunities for ‘technological
was manufacturing EPABX systems of smaller capacity since learning’, as RAX was used as a basic building block to scale
1976-77 under foreign technical collaboration, had till then, up to higher capacity switches in C-DoT’s product portfolio.13

3918 Economic and Political Weekly August 28, 2004


C-DoT’s design philosophy, since it evolved out of unique local cost), but it could not influence DoT procurement policy. It was
demand conditions, was different from established industry norms. also argued that the demand for value added services would be
Instead of standardising one switch to suit all needs, usually a low and concentrated in only a few metropolitan cities – so DoT
cost-effective solution for MNCs, C-DoT had a four-pronged could, for a large part of its purchases, utilise MAX-XL switch
product strategy (PABX, RAX, MAX-L, MAX-XL) to suit even without those features. It is pertinent, perhaps, to point out
different applications. Its product strategy emphasised ‘common- that the lobbying and promotional effort of MNCs, who have
ality of hardware and software’ between different product lines better capability to deliver on advanced features, also plays a
to reduce manufacturing complexity and costs. It also used role in shaping the network operator’s procurement decision as
capital-sensitive, labour-intensive equipment process technolo- it reinforces or even shapes the dominant discourse on technology
gies, for instance, PC-based testing was used instead of costly choices. While the DoT can be blamed for being susceptible to
electronic (advanced) testing jigs. It also did not have a fully- such lobbying efforts (and the dominant discourse), analytically,
automated plant (manual assembly of cards was used) so that it is also useful to look into these dynamics as an outcome of
the investment requirement was minimised [Ray 2001]. firm rivalry – which influences the parameters on which com-
C-DoT gradually migrated to the development of higher ca- petition operates in the industry. Over the years, C-DoT itself has
pacity switches, and they were inducted into the DoT network. begun investing in developing advanced features, styling, and
By 1999, the MAX, MAX-L series (capacity upto 10,000 ports) aesthetics – moving away from its ‘no frills’ design philosophy.
of C-DoT switches made up 40 per cent of the DoT urban network The late 1990s also witnessed another major change in the
as well. All DoT purchases of digital switches, with capacity less product development strategies of leading MNCs in the industry.
than 10,000 terminations, were reserved for C-DoT manufactur- As developing economy markets started growing, as mentioned
ers, since the successful design and installation of the MAX- earlier, MNCs realised the importance of tailoring their products
L switch in the early 1990s. Multiple manufacturers with tech- to unique operating conditions in these markets and started
nology licences from C-DoT, actually compete for DoT14 pur- developing country specific competencies. They have started
chases in this segment through a tendering process. offering products suited to rural applications in the Indian market,
which they claim can compete with RAX.
Entry into Large Capacity Wwitch Market By the end of the decade, however, C-DoT had succeeded in
developing state-of-the-art large capacity digital switches, with
As C-DoT upgraded its product portfolio – entering the large technical features that almost matched those of leading multi-
capacity switch segment – it faced direct competition from national firms in the industry (products offered in Indian market),
foreign firms in the Indian market and, as is argued below, the while the cost of equipment was generally lower (Appendix 1).
protection it received also began to be contested. The balance Price comparisons should, however, be made very carefully
of payment problem in India in 1991 and the economic restruc- because pricing of complex technology capital equipment is
turing initiatives that followed the adoption of the IMF bailout extremely complicated and sensitive to specifications as well as
package, led to fundamental re-ordering in several sectors. The terms of service support. Analytically, this shows that price, on
New Industrial Policy (announced July 1991) allowed foreign its own, is a weak signalling device in these industries and
equity participation (up to 51 per cent) in the telecom equipment competitive rivalry will occur on many non-price fronts as well.
industry. During that period of foreign exchange crisis in the As C-DoT licensees competed in the tenders, new strategies came
country, several MNCs arranged for foreign exchange loans, to the fore – it has been claimed that MNCs have under-quoted
including soft credit. Siemens, for instance, offered DM 500 in the bids (lower than landed costs) in order to gain market shares
million to finance the import requirement (equipment) of DoT. [VANS Information Limited, various dates, Ray 2001:545]. C-DoT
Alcatel similarly offered a 0.1 million lines exchange to DoT claims that the prices of its products (over the life of the equip-
on a ‘lease basis’ – to reduce the immediate outgo of foreign ment) are lower because it offers after-sales service, software
exchange [Ray 2001].
All these facilitated the entry of MNCs, who established joint Table 2: C-DoT Switching Equipment in DoT Network
ventures (eventually the Indian partner’s stake was bought over Product No of Exchanges No of Lines (Million),
by all the MNCs) to carry out assembly operations in India. DoT, including Expansion
December 1996 March 2003 December 1996 March 2003
which till then, depended solely on Alcatel (through its licensee)
for its large capacity switch requirement, started apportioning RAX 16998 32990 1.83 4.56
its orders to MNCs (through their licensees or joint ventures SBM-RAX 2025 9971 1.80 9.4
MAX-L 250 874 0.82 3.53
(JVs)) – the largest share of the order going to the lowest bidder. MAX-XL 1 1237 0.03 7.33
To add to the problems of C-DoT, it became the subject of Total 19274 45072 4.49 25.01
prolonged political inquests, beginning with the appointment of
Source: C-DoT internet site at http://www.cdot.com
the Nambiar Committee in 1989; political interference and attempts
to break up the organisation debilitated it considerably, as it lost Table 3: Sources of Revenue of C-DoT
many people during that period of turmoil (refer to note 13). (in Rs million)
Although the large capacity C-DoT switch (MAX-XL) was Year 1991- 1992- 1993- 1994- 1995- 1996- 1997- 1998- 1999-
installed in the DoT network in 1995, C-DoT licensees were not 92 93 94 95 96 97 98 9 9 2000
allowed to bid for DoT tenders of large switches till 2000 – as Grant 192 290 600 280 400 585 550 747.5 709.7
MAX-XL did not incorporate value added features (like IN, Tech transfer,
ISDN, etc) till then. C-DoT argued that development work on royalty, etc 52.4 77.5 111 117.9 118.1 49.7 74.1 328.6 190.4
Total 244.3 367.5 711 398 518 637.7 700 1086 900.1
the advanced features were nearing completion and that they
would be retrofitted to all MAX-XL switches (without any extra Source: Annual Reports, C-DoT, various issues.

Economic and Political Weekly August 28, 2004 3919


upgrades, etc, without any extra cost. Its repair and equipment support, especially on software development, to the licensees for
maintenance strategy, which depends on replacement of parts tailoring applications to local conditions in foreign markets. The
rather than sub-assemblies (the general industry norm), ensures domestic switching equipment industry in India has, therefore,
a far lower maintenance cost, unlike MNCs – whose pricing of developed on the basis of vertical separation of the technology
repairs and after-sales service is high, although the initial equip- development function from other value chain activities and the
ment sale price might be lower. Such pricing strategies with back- success of C-DoT products in the market depends on the com-
loading of the revenue stream due to high maintenance charges petitiveness of manufacturers as well.
on a locked-in consumer, however, is quite common in the sales C-DoT technology has been transferred to more than 50
of technologically complicated capital equipment in other indus- manufacturers, thus creating a fragmented manufacturing base.
tries and it is no surprise that such strategies will be employed This was done by design, as it was felt that a fragmented industry
by MNCs in the telecom equipment industry as well. structure would keep prices of C-DoT products low for DoT,
Apart from its success in the domestic market, C-DoT products, the main purchaser. The MAX-XL technology, for instance, has
particularly RAX solutions, have also been exported to several been transferred to about 11 manufacturers. The average annual
countries including Russia, Vietnam, Nepal, Bangladesh, Indo- demand for large capacity exchanges for DoT between 1997-
nesia, Thailand, Nigeria, Ethiopia, Uganda, Gambia, Zambia and 2000 has been around 3.5 million lines, which implies that even
Ghana [Annual Report, C-DoT, various issues]. The total value if half of DoT purchases of large capacity switches of C-DoT
of exports of C-DoT products, however, could not be obtained. technology, the average annual demand for each of the 11
Estimates suggest that the value of exports is small compared manufacturers of MAX-XL would only be about 0.15 million
to domestic sales (just around 3 per cent), in spite of the con- lines, which is very low compared to internationally competitive
siderable excess manufacturing capacity in the domestic industry. scales of operation (see Section IV). It is estimated that the total
Exports of C-DoT products, however, have mostly been in the installed annual capacity for C-DoT switches in India is around
low-end (low value added) segments – primarily for rural net- seven million, which leads to very low capacity utilisation rates
works. – sometimes as low as 20 per cent [www.cdot.com, Ray 2001].
Before moving to the next section, it is perhaps important to The fragmented industry structure has kept prices of C-DoT
look into the technology development cost of C-DoT. Table 3 equipment low, but it has also created problems of excess capacity
shows the sources of income for C-DoT between 1991-92 and leading to low capacity utilisation in the industry.15
1999-2000. Grant-in-aid from the government of India, around Earlier, it was argued that deregulation in the telecommuni-
Rs 5,500 million till March 2000, has been the major source of cation industry worldwide has led to many changes, some of
financing for C-DoT. which are taking roots in the Indian market as well, particularly
Estimated sales of switching equipment, till 2000, would be after the introduction of competition by the entry of private sector
more than Rs 50,000 million (C-DoT website), which implies telecom operators from the mid-1990s. Private telecom operators
that C-DoT’s technology development budget has been just over in India, who lacked technical expertise in designing networks
10 per cent of sales generated, which is far lower compared to in-house, had entrusted their equipment suppliers with the
the R and D expense (15-20 per cent of sales) incurred by leading responsibility of network planning and full installation on a
MNCs in the industry. Moreover, the price of C-DoT switches turnkey basis.16 Provision of vendor credit has been an important
being lower, the R and D expense in absolute terms is far lower element in all the equipment supply deals to private telecom
compared to global benchmarks. operators in India, which can be understood as the private
operators were often financially constrained [Appendix 2,
Manufacturing and Marketing of C-DoT Products Saha 2001 provides more details]. C-Dot licensees have been
unable to break into the equipment market of private operators
C-DoT, being a technology development centre, has not been in India.
undertaking any manufacturing activity. Once a technology reached Analytically, it is important to realise the importance of non-
the commercialisation stage, it was licensed to domestic manu- price competitive tools in gaining market shares in industries with
facturers. The technology transfer process, therefore, has been oligopolistic market structures like telecom equipment. Such
an important aspect of C-DoT strategy. At every stage, when any dynamics can be expected to drive competition as C-DoT pro-
product was designed, likely manufacturers were involved in trial ducts compete directly with offerings from MNCs in Indian as
productions. Detailed documentation was developed as part of well as foreign markets. The C-DoT technology based indigenous
the designing process itself and elaborate training and support equipment industry – given the vertical separation of technology
was provided to manufacturers to set up their production lines. development from other functions and the fragmented structure
C-DoT also played a pro-active role in developing the vendor of the manufacturing segment – appears ill-suited to respond
base (around 680 registered C-DoT vendors) for manufacturing adequately to the new competitive dynamics. The C-DoT product
components through technology transfer to component produc- portfolio is also narrow, as it has not been as successful in
ers, which went a long way in indigenising production and developing transmission products – although the mission of the
increasing the local content. organisation was expanded in 1989 to include transmission
C-DoT has not been undertaking marketing of its product as equipment development as well. This obviously limits the ability
well, except promoting the generic technology solutions that it of C-DoT licensees to bid for turnkey installations unless a
has developed in international telecom technology fairs. The consortium arrangement is made with manufacturers (essentially
marketing, pricing and bidding for equipment supplies depend foreign firms or technology licensees of foreign firms) who can
on the multiple licensees of C-DoT technology, in the domestic offer complementary products. Given the convergence in the
as well as export markets. Given the technological complexity strategies, and the structure of organisation of different value
of the product, however, C-DoT has to provide technology chain activities by multinational equipment manufacturers, it is

3920 Economic and Political Weekly August 28, 2004


unlikely that a different ‘strategic position’ (like that of C-DoT) Huawei Technologies
would be sustainable unless the environment is radically different
in India. This is quite unlikely given the trend towards deregu- Huawei Technologies was formed in 1988, with a seed capital
lation and greater liberalisation in the telecom service industry. of US $ 1,000 in Shenzen, and has been one of the most successful
With this brief narrative about the C-DoT experience, I shift to indigenous firms to develop the design and manufacturing
a discussion of the Chinese industry. capability for a number of hi-tech telecom products in China.
Table 4 shows the annual sales revenues of the firm and Table
III 5 indicates sales volume and market share of some of its important
Telecom Equipment Industry in China products. Its product portfolio includes products for optical,
fixed, mobile and data communication networks. Huawei Tech-
China’s telecom service sector has grown rapidly over the nologies currently spends 10 per cent of its net annual revenues
1990s, becoming one of the largest markets in fixed line and on R and D and employs 40 per cent of its employees in the
mobile telephony by the turn of the century. The pro-growth R and D unit. It had 4,000 employees in R and D in 1999, and
macroeconomic environment as well as the ambitious five-year 11,000 in 2003, compared to around 1,000 employees in R and
plans to expand and modernise the telecom network played a D in C-DoT. Apart from its conventional circuit switching based
crucial role in this rapid growth. The Chinese government has digital switches, Huawei also developed other state-of-the-art
been making proactive efforts to strengthen China’s technologi- transmission products like SDH equipment, ATM switches and
cal and manufacturing capabilities in the sector, but has not GSM/CDMA based products for mobile infrastructure and rout-
invested directly in the technology development effort. The entry ers and LAN switches for data networks. By 1999, within a decade
of foreign firms has been regulated, creating a domestic market of its inception, it had graduated into a major manufacturer having
for Chinese firms as they develop products. It is reported that a wide product line to implement end-to-end turnkey solutions
the licence to enter the Chinese market (according to rules for network operators.
effective from January 1999, a licence to a foreign telecom Apart from its dominance in the domestic Chinese market,
equipment supplier was valid for only three years) was accom- Huawei’s products have also been exported and used in telecom-
panied by stringent conditions to transfer technology to Chinese munication networks in more than 40 countries, including Brazil,
partners in joint ventures (JV). Foreign firms, however, in many Bulgaria, Estonia, Iraq, Kazakhstan, Kenya, Latvia, Lithuania,
cases, succeeded in getting across the barriers through interna- Russia, Singapore, South Korea, Tazhakistan, US and Uzbekistan
tional joint ventures and promises of technology transfer. But with exports making up around 13 per cent of its revenues in 2001.
given the rapid growth in the market, even limited attempts to The company’s target is to achieve 33 per cent of its revenues
protect the domestic market did lead to the assurance of a large from overseas sales by 2006; in 2002 exports increased by 66
market for domestic producers. Foreign suppliers dominated the per cent to US $ 552 million from 2001 (www.huawei.com.cn).
fixed line switching market in China in the early 1990s, with It has also attained turnkey capability in network planning and
Alcatel being the largest supplier through its JV, Shanghai Bell. has set up the network of Hong Kong Hutchison Telecom, the
By 1998, however, domestic Chinese firms had captured a second-largest telecom operator in Hong Kong [Gasper 2000].
dominant share of the fixed line switching market, supplying 98 Huawei has also been able to challenge the dominance of the
per cent of the switches added to the network. market leader, Cisco Systems, in the router market in US. In 2003,
Due to historical reasons, the telecom equipment sector in
China developed into a fragmented industry (like several other Table 4: Net Sales Figures of Huawei Technologies Company
industries as well), but over the 1990s, government policy (US $ million)

encouraged consolidation in the industry, often by providing 1996 1997 1999 2000 2001
cheap credit to finance merger and acquisition deals. Great Net Sales 350 500 969 1933 2407
Dragon Telecom, for instance, was formed in 1995 by merging Net Income - - 128 345 574
four different telecom equipment manufacturers. To make Chinese
Source: www.huawei.com.cn
manufacturers competitive in the market, the government also
encouraged commercial banks to provide loans to both the telecom Table 5: Sales and Market Share of Huawei Technologies
operators and producers to purchase equipment from domestic in China, 2000
producers [Wang and Kullman 1999]. Sales Volume Market Share
Chinese fixed line switch manufacturers have developed (Per Cent)
their own brands and designed their switch architecture inde-
Switches 7.5 million 32
pendently. They include HJD04 by Great Dragon Telecom, SP30 Access Network 4.5 million 64
by Datang, ZXJ10 by Zhongxing, C&C08 by Huawei, ETM601 SDH Transmission 15,000 sets 24
by Jinpeng, JSN-1 by Huaguang, LEX-500 by Legend, HJD-1000 WLL 8,000 channels 72
GSM 4500,000 subscriber 18
by Sang Da and JSU2000-05 by Beijing Telecom Equipment Access Server 120,000 ports 32
Factory. Unlike in India, there have been multiple technologies Signal Transfer Points (STP) 1,2000 lines 70
developed by different local firms in China under conditions of BITS 120 sets 31
intense rivalry. Decentralised equipment procurement by the Notes: The C&C08 family of fixed line digital switching equipment of Huawei
provincial telecom authorities also created an environment Technologies can be configured to yield a maximum of 800,000 lines
which could support competition among domestic equipment or 180,000 trunk connections. The BHCA of the switch is 6000 K for a
producers. Huawei Technologies is one of the successful telecom fully configured system, which is better than the specifications of C-DoT
MAX-XL switch. By 2002, there were over 100 million ports of C&C08
equipment firms and below I briefly discuss some aspects of its switches installed globally
strategies. Source: www.huawei.com.cn

Economic and Political Weekly August 28, 2004 3921


it entered into a joint-venture with 3Com (3Com had a 49 per argued earlier, access to a large domestic market and close
cent stake for US $160 million) for its data networking products, relations with the domestic telecom operator were also important,
which includes co-branding, joint global marketing and cross historically, in the technology development process of incumbent
licensing of technologies and products between the two com- multinational telecom equipment manufacturers.
panies (www.huawei.com.cn). But as the Indian experience illustrates, a protected domestic
Huawei is seeking to increase its international business, from market does not necessarily spur technology learning and invest-
the simple provision of telecommunication equipment to the ment in domestic firms. The formation of C-DoT was crucial,
engineering and development of large turnkey projects, through in India, in breaking the organisational inertia that had developed
a strategy of alliances and partnerships worldwide. In recent in R and D activities of ITI (which also operated in a protected
years, the company has expanded its global marketing and service domestic market) through prolonged dependence on foreign
network by establishing branch offices in 32 countries, eight technology suppliers, deterring development of indigenous tech-
regional headquarters and several customer support centres around nology.17 The agency of the technology leader is clearly crucial
the world. It has developed distributorship as well as OEM in moving beyond the paradigm of dependence and breaking out
manufacturing arrangements in several countries in order to of the mould. The leadership role played by senior C-DoT
service those markets. It has also launched a joint venture in managers and the Technology Mission on Telecommunications
Russia for manufacture and marketing of its products. Over the in conceiving and charting an independent trajectory of technol-
last few years it has also globalised its R and D set up, investing ogy development was extremely crucial. C-DoT, it may be recalled,
in setting up overseas R and D facilities in US, India, Russia was set up with a clearly articulated target and a mission, which
and Sweden to supplement its R and D activities in China was important in the absence of market pressures of competition
(www.huawei.com). Till 2002, it had filed 1,762 patents, includ- in creating incentives for managers/technocrats in the organisation
ing 455 in advanced mobile (3G) technologies. In 2003 it entered to perform and reach the targets envisioned. Moreover, from the
into a co-development and marketing joint venture with Siemens very beginning, C-DoT targeted commercialisation and mass
for 3G products (TD-SCDMA). Through its own R and D efforts, production of the products that it designed – thus forging concrete
co-development and other strategic alliances, Huawei has begun links with the market and industry and averting the problems
playing a role in the global battle for setting standards in the of ‘ivory tower’ research, which many argue [GoI 1986] is a major
telecommunication industry. problem with several state financed R and D institutions in India.
Recently it hired over 70 senior managers from IBM in a major The financial investment of the state, in terms of its budgetary
global recruitment drive in order to manage its international outlay, has also been comparatively quite low.
expansion, and link its technology development with the mar- Notwithstanding C-DoT’s success, the comparison with the
keting and promotion of its products [Forbes 2002]. It has also technology development of Chinese manufacturers, particularly
been actively engaging management consultancy firms like IBM, the rapid rate of innovation and technological catch up and the
Towers Perrin and PWC to develop and enhance management expansion into global markets raises issues about the design and
capabilities within the organisation. Financial commitment to instruments of state intervention. The Chinese Ministry of In-
foreign markets through outward foreign direct investment (FDI) formation Industries encouraged multiple technology developers,
and aggressive marketing has been a feature of Huawei’s foreign unlike in the case of India, creating immense pressures for
expansion, similar to that of many other Chinese enterprises in innovation through rivalry between local firms – a factor that
industries like consumer electronics and household appliances may not be insignificant in explaining the rapid pace of tech-
[Saha 2001]. Huawei is one of the Chinese name-brand firms nology development in the Chinese telecom equipment industry.
identified by MoFTEC for leading China’s process of globalisation The decentralised procurement practices of Chinese telecom
and is supported by liberal access to cheap credit from Chinese operators (by the Provincial Telecom Authorities) also created
banks and financial institutions. Within a short span of just over institutional spaces for competing equipment manufacturers to
a decade, Chinese firms like Huawei have grown remarkably. operate.
Though Huawei still remains much smaller (in terms of revenues) However, the industry in China was not allowed to become
than the global leaders in the industry (in 2002 Lucent revenues fragmented and industrial policy of the state encouraged the
were US $ 12 billion which was a 42 per cent year-on-year decline growth of a concentrated oligopolistic industry structure. The
from 2001), it is closing the gap with them fast. It has continued successful firms, therefore, had the advantage of scale economies
its growth, including sales in international markets, even during and the financial strength to face foreign competition – particu-
a global downturn in the industry. larly in export markets. Vertical integration of R and D, manu-
facturing and marketing in the same firm also allowed for greater
IV coordination within organisational hierarchies, which became
Implications of Comparative Narratives important in responding to a rapidly changing market characterised
by technological flux in the industry over the last decade. Support
The development of indigenous technological capability in the from Chinese banks and financial institutions, by providing
telecom equipment industry in both India and China, aided by access to low cost credit lines, also played a role in enabling
support from the state, is quite remarkable given the fact that firms like Huawei Technologies to pursue aggressive expansion
the industry has been dominated, for decades, by firms from strategies and make the strategic investments required to gain
advanced industrial economies. In either case, access to a pro- and preserve market share in oligopolistic industries. Chinese
tected domestic market or creating an assured demand, through telecom equipment firms, therefore, were much better placed than
preferential purchase policies of the local network operator or the Indian telecom switching equipment industry, to breach the
restrictions on entry of foreign firms, facilitated entry as well multiple barriers to entry in foreign markets and emerge as
as the initial technology learning in domestic firms. As was significant global competitors.

3922 Economic and Political Weekly August 28, 2004


While state intervention in India in directly financing and does capture, to a large extent, the problem of investment in
promoting C-DoT as a research institution in the public sector ‘cutting-edge’ technologies in advanced industrial economies.
did succeed in lifting the industry out of technological depen- The problem of investment in R and D and development of
dence on foreign suppliers, it has been inadequate in enabling indigenous technology in developing economies is, however,
domestic firms to overcome the non-technological barriers to quite different, owing to the legacy of the technological back-
entry in the final product market, especially in global markets. wardness of domestic industry. For developing economy firms,
Vertical separation of R and D from manufacturing and marketing the problem is of breaking down barriers to entry in markets
and the fragmented manufacturing base of C-DoT products is dominated by entrenched firms, mainly from developed econo-
bound to become a serious problem in deregulated telecom mies. That is shaped as much by the ability to invest in technology
markets. The Chinese strategy, on the other hand, did not seek (industrial R and D), as by the ability to make strategic invest-
to directly finance R and D activity in the industry, but through ments in developing and defending market shares. The locus of
its industrial policy instruments succeeded in creating favourable such entry barriers and the nature of investments required to break
conditions for the growth of a globally competitive domestic them, moreover, would vary between industries and between the
industry. The argument here is not against state ownership or different stages of development of an industry.
its financial and management involvement per se in R and D Analytically, the neo-liberal framework fails to take cognisance
organisations. The essential difference between the Indian and of the contextual specificity of ‘late industrialising’ developing
Chinese experience has been that of industry structure, both with economies. It also fails to accommodate the complex dynamics
respect to horisontal levels of industry concentration in each part of oligopolistic competition and the multiple dimensions of entry
of the value chain, as well as the vertical scope of operation of barriers that incumbent firms can create in such industries. In
the firm. That, as has been argued, plays a crucial role in defining such an environment, state support for R and D in developing
the firms’ incentives as well as their capability to make invest- economies has to tackle problems of domestic industry that are
ments required to break entry barriers in the industry. quite distinct from their developed counterparts and such support
Another key element of difference between the Indian and is most likely to succeed as part of a well-rounded industrial policy
Chinese experience is the ability of the state bureaucracy to package, possibly using multiple instruments, that aid domestic
respond to markets and its evolution in the design of policy firms to breach the multiple barriers to entry.
interventions. The formation of C-DoT and the creation of the This analytical failure is not just an epistemological issue –
associated industry structure was reflective of the structure of it has connotations for the design of policies that can affect
the domestic telecom service industry (with a protected national significantly the trajectory of technological development. Regu-
monopoly operator) prevalent at the time of C-DoT’s formation. lations in the WTO, for instance, are quite permissive of sub-
As the global telecom service industry underwent a deep restruc- stantial state subsidisation and financial participation in R and
turing over the next decade and a half, the Indian industry D projects at the ‘pre-competitive stage’ [Mani 1999].18 Within
followed, at least in part, a similar trajectory. State intervention a neo-liberal framework, such forms of state support should
in the equipment industry failed to reorient itself. The Indian suffice to tackle the problem of ‘externality’. But, as was argued
industry has, as yet, failed to relocate itself into the same ‘strategic in this paper, state support for technology development in domestic
group’ (in terms of strategies adopted and organisation of value firms in developing economies is much more likely to succeed
chain activities) as the MNCs in the industry. Chinese government as a complement in a package of well-rounded industrial policy
officials, on the other hand, seem to have developed a more intervention. WTO rules, however, are far more critical of such
nuanced idea about the process of globalisation and the structure policy interventions. This analytical slip, therefore, has the potential
and dynamics of evolution of industries like telecom equipment to have a differential effect on economies in different stages of
and have been able to respond to them in designing appropriate technological development – and lock in technologically laggard
policy supports for indigenous firms in China. Chinese firms, economies in states of dependence. The new debate on state
therefore, have been better placed to attain the same differential support for industrial R and D, which is likely to play a role in
sources of competitive advantage as multinational equipment shaping the instruments of public policy intervention in the years
manufacturers of the country. The Chinese state also seems to to come, does not adequately reflect this unique concern of
have an uncanny ability to direct selective industrial policy developing economies. EPW
supports to the right set of well-performing indigenous firms.
And the failure of the bureaucracy in India to deal with the poor Appendix 1
performance of enterprises, which benefit from state support (ITI,
Comparison of C-DoT MAX-XL with Large
prior to formation of C-DoT), only provides a sharp contrast. What
Capacity MNC Switch
determines this differential ability of the state and its bureaucracy
to play an essentially ‘entrepreneurial’ role, to my mind, is an Below is a brief comparison between C-DoT MAX-XL and
important question but beyond the purview of this paper. MNC switches installed in the Indian network, which includes
State support for industrial R and D, especially in developing Alcatel’s OCB-283, AT&T’s 5ESS 2000, Siemens’s EWSD and
economies, has been under attack in economic restructuring Ericsson’s AXE-10. The comparison is done on the basis of
initiatives undertaken with neo-liberal inspiration over the last information obtained in mid-2000 from C-DoT officials.
decade. The new debate on industrial R and D, however, has Capacity: Most MNC switches have termination capacities higher
brought back the concern over inadequate investment in indus- than 1,00,000. Some have a termination capacity of 240,000 lines.
trial R and D if it were left to the market – primarily by appealing The C-DoT MAX-XL currently has a maximum capacity of 40,000
to its ‘public good’ nature. But, this debate has been inspired, terminations (32,000 local and 8,000 trunk). But, both the Base
principally, by concerns about the loss of future competitiveness Module (BM) and the Central Module (CM) of the MAX-XL
of industrially advanced economies and the analytical framework are undergoing enhancements. A Value-Engineered BM would

Economic and Political Weekly August 28, 2004 3923


allow a doubling of the MAX-XL capacity and a Value-Engineered Manufacturability: MAX-XL, like all other C-DoT products, was
CM (in which the core switch architecture would be modified) designed to attain high levels of indigenisation. The level of
would further double the capacity upto 1,60,000 in the near indigenisation is about 80 per cent for C-DoT switches. Integrated
future. But, even a 40,000 line exchange is believed to be circuit chips are the main imported components. Local content
sufficient under Indian conditions (except in TAX applications). is significantly higher than the MNC switches, which are im-
A very large capacity exchange necessitates the laying of cables ported in CKD/SKD form, with only 4-5 simple components (out
to subscribers spread over a large geographical area, which may of around 500) sourced locally.
not be cost-effective. A better solution is to have a separate access Cost: The costs of telecommunication switches are difficult to
network linked to the main exchange through high-speed digital compare, as they are sensitive to the features in the switch. The
links. C-DoT is presently working on this solution as well. ‘per line cost’ of a MAX-XL exchange, of typical configuration,
Traffic Handling Capacity: All MNC switches have a BHCA is around Rs 4,500, while it is higher than Rs 6,000 for all MNC
of 1.2 million. MAX-XL supports a BHCA of 0.8 million, the exchanges. In addition to that, C-DoT provides all subsequent
specification set by DoT. If required, it is possible to support software upgrades for the exchange to DoT, free of cost. In case
BHCA of 1.2 million through software fine-tuning. In terms of of retrofitable upgrades to add new features, C-DoT charges only
per line BHCA, C-DoT switches are better placed with figures for the extra hardware fittings.
of around 20 as against 5-7 for other switches. In terms of Erlang
capacity, MAX-XL supports 6400 Erlangs, while MNC switches Address for correspondence:
support 24,000 Erlang. The Erlang capacity in the enhanced biswatosh@xlri.ac.in
MAX-XL would be 12,800.
Concentration: All MNC switches have flexibility in concen- Notes
tration, from 4:1 to 10:1. MAX-XL has a concentration of 4:1
at the Base Module level. In enhanced versions, it can go up to 8:1. 1 Hill (1995) argues that empirical evidence shows a significant co-relation
between federal R and D spending and private sector investment in R
Compactness: A 40,000 line MNC switch currently occupies and D in the US.
about 60 per cent of the floor space required for the MAX-XL. 2 For instance, between 1997-2002, India had a target of adding more than
However, work is on to introduce miniaturisation in large switches. 32 million lines of switching capacity in fixed-line networks, which is
# 7 Handling: All MNC switches allow all digital trunk to be almost equal to the installed network size of the world’s fifth largest
configured as # 7 trunk. In MAX-XL, since centralised resources telecom network in France (at 34 million lines in 1998). (DoT, Annual
Reports and World Telecommunication Development Report, ITU,
are used for # 7 handling, it can handle upto 64 # 7 trunks, which Geneva, 1999].
is sufficient in the current network. 3 Siemens held a 90 per cent share of the domestic installed switching
Network Synchronisation: MAX-XL is comparable to all other capacity in Germany, while Alcatel supplied equipment for about 80
switches. per cent of the French network till the early 1990s. NEC and Fujitsu,
Access Network: MAX-XL is the only exchange in India capable together, supplied about 80 per cent of the switching equipment in the
Japanese network [Carpentier et al 1992]. Even post-deregulation, 70
of supporting both V5.1 and V5.2 protocols. per cent of Lucent’s sales come from the US market.
ISDN: MAX-XL has ISDN capability, but it does not have an 4 The complex nature of technology made close cooperation between
integrated packet handler. Data packets are routed towards data equipment supplier and network operator important for successful network
network. operation and new innovations. Moreover, telecom network operation
Appendix 2
Foreign Currency Loans and Vendor Credit for Cellular Operators, December 1998
Cellular Operator Cellular Network Foreign Loans and Vendor Finance
Equipment Vendor

Birla AT&T Ericsson, Sweden Syndicated Non-recourse loan (US$ 283 million) from consortium led by Bank of America and
Toronto Dominion (SE Asia) . Political risk of coverage of US$ 65 million by Swedish Export Credit Agency.
Spice Telecom Motorola, Siemens Motorola, Siemens provided supplier’s credit of US$ 140 million, rupee loan from Bank of America and
Standard Chartered, US$ 60 million loan from GE Capital.
BPL-US West Nokia and Motorola Equipment purchase on vendor finance of US$ 80 million. Finnish ECA financed purchase of Nokia
equipment, Motorola gave bridge loans till US ECA loan was finalised.
J T Mobile Ericsson – turnkey Vendor credit of $ 60.8 million
Koshika Alcatel turnkey Vendor credit from Alcatel, which also took a 3 per cent stake
Reliance Ericsson, Motorola US$ 40 million vendor finance from Ericsson, with the backing of Swedish ECA. US$ 80 million vendor finance
from Motorola backed by US EXIM Bank. Non-recourse loan of US$ 176 million from Bank of America and
Deutsche Bank
Aircell Digilink Siemens switch and US$ 110 million vendor credit for equipment in three circles. Plans to raise US$ 250 million from Union Bank
Motorola BTS of Switzerland

Foreign Currency Loans and Vendor Credit for Basic Service (fixed line) Operators, December 1998
Operator Vendor contract

Bharti Telenet Vendor credit of US$ 50 million each from Motorola, Siemens and Alcatel; Alcatel loan is for 6 years with moratorium on payment in first
two years.
Hughes Ispat Supplier Hughes Networks has equity position; Marubeni to be approached for long term vendor finance, switching equipment from NEC,
Japan.
Telelinks Qualcomm for WLL equipment on vendor credit for 85 per cent of the equipment cost, to be repaid over seven years, with moratorium
on payment in first three years. To use domestic corDECT technology for WLL also.

Note: Includes only the deals for which information was available.
Source: Compiled from operators details provided in ‘Telecoms and Wireless Markets and Strategies: India’, Pyramid Research, Economist intelligence unit, 1998.

3924 Economic and Political Weekly August 28, 2004


and equipment manufacturing were often integrated within the same firm. 17 The problem of technological dependence has been analysed in the
For instance, AT&T’s manufacturing activities were divested into a literature of ‘dependant industrialisation’ as well as ‘technology
separate firm, Lucent Technologies, only in 1996. management’. The role of the ‘technology leader’ in breaking off from
5 “[The World Telecoms Agreement] .. is a triumph for the American way… the dependant mode to chart an independent course of technology
US companies are the most competitive telecommunications providers development and innovation is often very crucial. Senior managers in
in the world; they are in the position to compete and win under this C-DoT, including Sam Pitroda – a leading force behind the initiative,
agreement”; (Charlene Barshefsky, US Trade Representative designate, played this role effectively. But, public policy also plays an important
Financial Times, February 18, 1997). role in nudging managers is taking up such roles, especially in developing
6 Alcatel, for instance, recently acquired DSC Communication Corporation economies where the problem of technology dependence is acute, due
of US, which has design expertise in transmission products (Annual to the historically derived legacy of technological backwardness in the
Report, Alcatel, 1998). Motorola and Alcatel also entered into an agreement industrial sector.
to jointly promote, develop and sell each other’s complementary product 18 The WTO list of non-actionable subsidies allows up to 75 per cent of
lines in the digital cellular phone infrastructure market – radio equipment state financing of industrial R and D with planned future commercial
and base stations of Motorola and switching equipment of Alcatel. use and 50 per cent state financing for pre-competitive development uptil
7 Telmex, the former state-owned monopoly service provider of Mexico the first prototype. State support for R and D, in the US, which is
(which also happens to be the largest listed telecom service provider principally carried out through 50-50 participation of government and
from a developing country), has been dragged into a WTO dispute by industry is, thus, left undisturbed under the new WTO norms. US
the US in 2001 for violating the terms of the World Telecoms Agreement, negotiators, in fact, lobbied hard to retain this clause. [Gibbons 1994;
1997. Telmex was provided protection through its right to charge high cited in Mani 1999].
interconnect charges – a move that effectively blocked the growth of
AT&T and WorldCom in Mexico. The dispute is yet to be resolved, with References
a panel ruling not being expected before December 2003. (www.wto.org)
Amsden, A (1989): ‘Asia’s Next Giant: South Korea and Late Industrialisation’,
8 Each port is a termination in an exchange – number of ports signifying
Oxford University Press, New York.
the termination capacity of a switch.
Brundenius, Claes and Bo Goransson (1985): The Quest for Technological
9 PBX is a private exchange limited within the subscriber premise; local
Self-Reliance: The Case of Telecommunications in India, Discussion
exchanges are used in the public network for local communication alone,
Paper No 176, Research Policy Institute, Lund.
trunk exchanges are used only for inter-exchange long-distance
Carpentier, M, S Farnoux-Toparkoff and C Garric (1992): Telecommunications
communication and tandem exchanges are a combination of local and
in Transition, John Wiley and Sons, Great Britain.
trunk functions in the same exchange. C-DoT (1989): 128 PBX, List of Manufacturers, mimeo Centre for
10 It is widely believed that the choice of Alcatel-CIT for the E-10B digital Development of Telematics, New Delhi.
switching technology transfer in the early 1980s was motivated by the Council of Economic Advisors (CEA) (1995): Supporting Research and
French government’s tacit support for the Indian nuclear programme. Development to Promote Economic Development: The Federal
Alcatel was chosen though it did not respond to the global tender floated Government’s Role, Council of Economic Advisors, www.whitehouse.gov
for the purpose [Brundenius and Goransson 1985]. Forbes (2002): ‘The Challenge from China’, www.forbes.com, May 13.
11 The most sensational among them was the case of cross-bar technology Gasper, Peter (2000): ‘Telecom’ 99 China Pavilion Exhibitor Profile: Huawei
for electro-mechanical switches, imported in 1964 from Bell Telephone Technologies Company Ltd’, PRC Information Technology Review, Vol
Manufacturing Company of Belgium. The exchange was designed keeping 1, No 40.
in mind usage (call) patterns in developed countries. It led to the formation Gibbons, John, H (1994): Statement of the Honorable John H Gibbons,
of the Indian Crossbar Project (ICP) in June 1974, to adapt the technology Director, Office of Science and Technology Policy before the Subcommitte
to Indian conditions. When the new design was ready by 1979-80, a on Technology, Environment and Aviation, Committee on Science,
new technical collaboration agreement had to be signed with the same Space and Technology, United States House of Representatives,
foreign firm for the process technology [Mani 1989]. www.whitehouse.gov.
12 “The core strategy [in the subsidiary] cannot be any different because GoI (1986): ‘Report of the CSIR Review Committee’, chairman, Abid
the core strategy is driven largely, in industries of this nature, by Hussain, Government of India, New Delhi.
technology. And since, technology emanates from the centre, automatically Hill, Christopher (1995): ‘Federal R and D Spending: Will the Private Sector
everyone has to follow. It is not that globally Alcatel is developing product Cover the Cuts?’, North-East Midwest Economic Review, March.
A and I find the market for product B. We cannot make product B because Mani, Sunil (1989): ‘Technology Acquisition and Development: Case of
the volume of product B for the local market will not justify spending Telecom Switching Equipment’ in Economic and Political Weekly,
on R and D for product B in the Indian market” [senior executive of November 25, pp 1181-91.
Alcatel in Ray 2001:540-41]. – (1999): Public Innovation Policies and Developing Countries in a Phase
13 This was possible, in part, because of the modular design of all C-DoT of Economic Liberalisation, discussion paper series no 1999-2, United
switches, where the basic unit continued to be the 128 port RAX. Nations University, Institute for New Technologies, Maastricht, October.
C-DoT could scale up and design switches of upto 10,000 ports (the – (2001): Role of Government in the Promotion of Innovation in the
MAX and MAX-L series) by the early 1990s. However, the design of Enterprise Sector: An Analysis of the Indian Experience, discussion
MAX-XL series, with capacity upto 40,000 ports was significantly paper series no 2001-3, United Nations University, Institute for New
delayed. Considering that C-DoT was set up with the mission to design Technologies, Maastricht, April.
large exchanges within three years, i e, by 1987, this was a large time Nolan, Peter (2001): China and the Global Business Revolution, Palgrave,
over-run and in 1989, a committee (Nambiar) set up to enquire into C- New York.
DoT’s activities did express scepticism about the basic design philosophy Ray, Pradeep Kanta (2001): ‘Centre for Development of Telematics: Switching
of C-DoT. See The C-DoT Story by G B Meemamsi, Kedar Publications, on the Telecom Revolution in India’ in Sumantra Ghosal, Gita Piramal,
New Delhi, 1993 for a detailed account of the political interference that Sudeep Budhiraja (eds), World Class in India, Penguin Books, New Delhi.
plagued C-DoT right through the 1990s. The telecommunications minister Saha, Biswatosh (2001): ‘Foreign Investment, Financial Markets and Industry:
K P Unnikrishnan, allegedly with the backing of MNCs, attempted India in the 1990s’, unpublished doctoral dissertation, mimeo, Indian
breaking up the organisation. Institute of Management Calcutta, May.
14 The network operations of DoT was transferred to Bharat Sanchar Nigam Stiglitz, Joseph E (1998): More Instruments and Broader Goals: Moving
Limited – a corporatised PSU, in 2000. Towards a Post Washington Consensus, WIDER Annual lecture 2, UNU/
15 C-DoT licensed manufacturers of switching equipment had a capacity WIDER, http://www.unu.wider.edu/stiglitz.htm
of 4 million lines per annum, working only on a single shift (full capacity Wang, Michael and Paul Kullman (1999): ‘Telecommunications Equipment
utilisation implies working in three shifts) in 1999-2000. In 1999-2000, Market’, Industry Sector Analysis Series, Country Analysis: China, US and
the total order for C-DoT switches was about 4.6 million lines. (Interview Foreign Commercial Service and US Department of State, Beijing, February.
with C-DoT managers in August, 1999). Wade, R (1990): Governing the Market: Economic Theory and the Role
16 In this respect, the C-DoT product portfolio itself has problems since of the Government in East Asian Industrialisation, Princeton University
it has not been as successful in the design of transmission products. Press, Princeton, New Jersey.

Economic and Political Weekly August 28, 2004 3925

You might also like