You are on page 1of 9

Electronic Commerce Research and Applications 12 (2013) 69–77

Contents lists available at SciVerse ScienceDirect

Electronic Commerce Research and Applications


journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/ecra

Under what conditions will social commerce business models survive?


Dohoon Kim
School of Business, Kyung Hee University, Hoegi-dong 1, Dongdaemoon-gu, Seoul 130-701, South Korea

a r t i c l e i n f o a b s t r a c t

Article history: This study provides a model that captures the essential features of the social commerce business. The
Available online 28 December 2012 model focuses on the relationship between key decision issues, such as marketing expenditures and
the revenue streams that are created. As more social commerce businesses enter the marketplace, they
Keywords: are faced with fierce competition, which may lead to sharp increases in marketing and advertising expen-
Competition ditures. This type of competition may lead the industry away from its optimal development path, and at
Economic analysis worst, toward a disruption of the entire industry. Another goal of this study is to examine the possibility
Game theory
that the tragedy of commons may occur in the industry. The basic analysis presents Nash equilibrium
Marketing
Regulation
results with homogeneous and heterogeneous players. The analysis further specifies the conditions that
Social commerce the tragedy of commons can occur. I discuss the strategic implications and policy directions that may be
Social networks able to overcome the shortcomings of current business model, and help the industry to achieve more sus-
Tragedy of the commons tainable development.
Ó 2013 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.

1. Introduction gest that the industry has grown ten times in terms of sales revenue
and twenty times in terms of transactions over a year. By the end of
Social commerce is an emerging category of e-commerce, based 2011, more than a third of the population in South Korea subscribed
on social media platforms like social network services. It allows its to and experienced the service (Kim 2011). Similar figures reflect
users to participate in buying and selling products and services industry growth in East Asia, where the social commerce business
through the platforms (Marsden 2010, Curty and Zhang 2011). has gotten very popular (Chung and Chen 2012, Kim 2011, Lee
Many social commerce providers started their business by combin- 2011). Over the past few years, sales revenues have increased from
ing group-buying with selling discount coupons offered from their US$1.2 billion dollars to US$3.55 billion dollars in China, and from
partners over the Internet. These social commerce providers split US$8.4 billion to US$11 billion in Japan (Financial News 2011). In
the revenues with their business partners at a predefined rate. Gro- addition, they have gone from US$780 billion to more than US$1 tril-
upon initiated this business model in 2009. It required more than a lion in the US.
certain number of customers to buy the coupons for future delivery The emergence of social commerce reflects the collective bar-
of goods or services. This has been referred to as a form of group- gaining power of end-users as the Internet has shifted the bargain-
buying. Social commerce services also involve daily deals and flash ing power from sellers to consumers (Gu et al. 2012, Wei et al.
deals; these service offerings are usually valid for a short period 2011). An exemplar of this change is what social networking ser-
of time. vices brought to the distribution channels and marketing efforts.
Social commerce has grown rapidly in the past 3 years, and Thanks to this new opportunity, consumers and the younger gen-
more customers, business partners and investors have joined the eration who are now initiating and shaping market trends have
industry. More than 500 providers are running social commerce been exposed to more deals, discounts and new information
businesses worldwide now (Reibstein 2011).1 In South Korea, the around their local areas (Stephen and Toubia 2009, 2010). Accord-
associated transactions amount to more than US$200 million (Digital ingly, they have been easily attracted to the service proposals from
Daily 2011, Lee 2011). According to Kim (2011), the sales revenue for social commerce firms and boosted the industry in its early stage.
these kinds of businesses in the country has increased from US$45 Some criticisms about social commerce firms are emerging now
million in 2010 to almost US$500 million in 2011. These figures sug- though. For example, MacMillan (2011a, 2011c) reports on the
diminishing popularity of Groupon in the US and China. Reibstein
E-mail address: dyohaan@khu.ac.kr (2011) asserts that the fundamental weaknesses of the group-buy-
1
The statistics vary to some extent since the ways to define the social commerce ing business model is that its success will eventually limit growth
industry are different across countries. Other statistics argue that the number of social due to a huge increase in competition that is likely to arise, as well
commerce firms in the middle of 2011 amounted to 320 in the US, more than 5000 in
as a sharp decrease in its capability to deliver the original value
China, more than 300 in Japan, and 230 in Korea (Chung and Chen 2012, Kim 2011,
Lee 2011, ROA Holdings 2011). business proposition that was promised to consumers. Webster

1567-4223/$ - see front matter Ó 2013 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.elerap.2012.12.002
70 D. Kim / Electronic Commerce Research and Applications 12 (2013) 69–77

(2011) suggests that operational cost is one of the weakest links of one intended contribution of this study is to examine the possibil-
the group-buying business model. ‘‘. . . Groupon’s cost line will in- ity that the tragedy of commons (Greco and Floridi 2004, Hardin
crease as more staff are needed to find new merchants, expand to 1968) may occur in the industry.
new geographies or both. And according to the FT article, that is In Section 2, I present a model to demonstrate the essential fea-
just what is happening. In Q1 of 2011, administrative and market- tures of the social commerce business process and the competitive
ing expenses rose from US$11 million to US$387 million against landscape. I will analyze the model in the next section and inves-
revenues of US$270 million, creating a cumulative deficit of tigate the possibility that the tragedy of commons occurs in the
US$522 million’’ (Webster 2011). Last, Wheeler (2011) also ad- industry due to an excessive competition in market share. The
dresses problems beginning to surface in Groupon’s current busi- implications of my findings and analysis follow in Section 3. Sec-
ness practice that requires massive upfront investments for tion 4 discusses the future development of the social commerce
customer acquisition. business model to overcome its limitations, and concludes.
Social commerce startups have also drawn skepticism due to
their unusual accounting practices, rising marketing costs and
quality assurance issues. This has made it more difficult for social 2. Model
commerce firms to lure investors now. Groupon, for example,
experienced fluctuation of stock price after its initial public offer- Marsden (2010, p. 4) has offered a broad definition of social
ing, and LivingSocial decided not to do it. However, the most crit- commerce as follows: ‘‘Simply defined, social commerce is the fu-
ical views on the social commerce industry point out that the sion of social media with e-commerce, or in the words of IBM, so-
industry’s growth rate is unsustainable (Reibstein 2011). Some cial commerce is basically the concept of word-of-mouth applied
observers have argued that the business model has flaws and val- to e-commerce. More fully, social commerce is a subset of elec-
uations cannot be justified in the market (Webster 2011, Wheeler tronic commerce that uses social media, online media that sup-
2011). The resulting instability has left customers, business part- ports social interaction and user contributions, to enhance the
ners and investors disenchanted. online purchase experience.’’ Social commerce is an emerging busi-
According to the Korea Consumer Protection Board, the number ness that incorporates Internet-based online media, such as social
of cases involving problems and customer complaints reached 500 connections, mobility, openness, and participation. Social com-
in 2011 (Kim 2011). Many social commerce firms seem to have merce takes on various business formats in practice: for example,
been suffering under a large load of marketing expenses and low buyer communities, group-buying, purchase sharing, social cura-
average revenue per user (ARPU). This result has been predicted tion, social advice, co-shopping, and so on (Cavazza 2012, Marsden
since the firms’ business practices have to invest a big portion of and Chaney 2012). In this study, I will focus on group-buying, the
revenue on advertising and promotion. They also have maintained most popular format of social commerce (Chung and Chen 2012,
a wide range of service offerings, but the assortment is too broad, Lee 2011, Kim 2011).
and the operational costs are too high, while user revenues remain Social commerce offers a value proposition to potential custom-
low (Kim 2011, Lee 2011). ers by allowing them to buy in groups and receive quantity discounts
The prosperity and adversity of the social commerce industry (Anand and Aron 2003, Jing and Xie 2011). Merchants or suppliers,
has implications for other e-commerce industries. The business who act as business partners with social commerce firms, also gain
model of social commerce may seem to be IT-intensive, but it benefits from selling a high volume of goods or services to a group
heavily relies upon other things too. Human resources and man- through a single social commerce channel, instead rather than sell-
power are critical and costly in the competition that occurs in this ing on a one by one item or service basis. Further, suppliers can use
industry. The business model needs to operate effectively across social commerce firms as a marketing channel to access new cus-
different regions, requires negotiation and contracting with part- tomers and increase sales. The key to the social commerce business
ners, and needs advertising and promotion of its service offerings model lies in deep discounts and the pooling of consumers willing-
to attract consumers. All of these activities require human inter- ness-to-pay, and then turning that potential to an effective real de-
vention. This explains why average sales per employee is lower mand. Although business practices vary by region (Chung and Chen
than in other e-commerce sectors, such as social networking ser- 2012, ROA Holdings 2011), my study focuses on the pooling of po-
vices, search engines, and business portals (Financial News 2011, tential demand and the generation of revenue.
Lee 2011). Potential investors have expressed uncertainty about whether
These features allow social commerce providers to lower the the business model is sustainable, and seem less interested than
initial fixed cost. On the other hand, low capital investment also before (MacMillan 2011a, Wheeler 2011). The weakest link of the
diminishes the entry barriers making it easier for late-comers to business model comes from its simplicity. It is simple enough to
copy the business model. The low barriers to entry make it difficult be copied without large initial investment, and it is difficult to pre-
for a marketing campaign to be effective. One possible outcome is vent potential competitors from entering. Competition has been
that the business model could end up with a bubble and the entire intensifying as a result.
industry may collapse. Social commerce firms in this new phase of Social commerce firms also appear to forced to spend more
the industry should revise their value propositions and develop a money to acquire customers due to the intensifying competition.
differentiated niches in comparison to online shopping malls and In 2010, Groupon spent US$4.95 per new customer, but in 2011
open markets. it had to spend US$5.30, an increase of about 7% (MacMillan
This study presents model to capture the essential features of 2011a). This increase is worrisome to potential investors since it
the social commerce business model. I will analyze the model to may signal that that it is getting more costly to acquire and retain
see whether social commerce is sustainable, and discuss conditions customers.
for stable evolution of the industry. First, I will focus on the rela- This problem arises in the presence of lower available inventory
tionship between a firm’s marketing effort and the revenue stream or service capacity. When thus is the case, the willingness of sup-
that it produces. As more social commerce firms have joined the pliers to offer deep discounts will decline, and price-sensitive
industry, fierce competition has ensued, resulting in additional shoppers may switch to other social commerce firms that offer a
sharp increases in the firm-level marketing and advertising expen- better deal. In the long run, competition among social commerce
ditures. This type of competition may lead the industry away from firms will drive down the discount rate to the minimum required
its optimal development path, and at worst, result in disruption. So customer service configuration threshold.
D. Kim / Electronic Commerce Research and Applications 12 (2013) 69–77 71

Note: Although the real business practice in the social commerce industry varies from country to country, the basic
features and the key elements remain the same: in particular, social commerce as the group buying model based on
social media. Figure 1 depicts the conceptual frame of the social commerce business model in this study. Three key
elements are social commerce providers, users and partner suppliers. Arrows in solid thick line represent business
transactions. Arrows in broken thick line show the money flow. The social commerce providers connect users with
suppliers and collect service fees (commission) from suppliers.

Fig. 1. Social commerce business model: stakeholders, structure and process.

I will formulate a social commerce business model that incorpo- commerce firm faces. Usually, the revenue function of firm k can be
rates the strengths and inherent weaknesses, and examine the pos- represented by rk (tk, ek, E), where
sibility of transaction and market failures. I also will focus on key
@rk @r k @ 2 rk
decision issues such as marketing effort and service configurations > 0; < 0; and < 0: ð1Þ
that are offered to customers. (See Fig. 1.) @ek @Ek @t 2k
Due to the competition, however, the revenue sharing rate be- For example, I may employ r k ðtk ; ek ; EÞ ¼ eEk  t k  ðdk  tk Þ, where dk is
tween the supplier and the group-buying intermediary is likely the maximum threshold that firm k uses; firm k will loses money if
to be standard across most social commerce firms. For example, it sets tk beyond dk.
the rate in South Korea was about 20% several years ago, according Now, some additional explanation about the conditions in Eq.
to Kim (2011). With a fixed rate, my model allows a social com- (1) is in order. First, the sales revenue based on the number of deals
merce firm to leverage its minimum required number of items to concluded by firm k will be proportional to its relative marketing
be sold as a competitive tool. I further assume that the discount expenses. This feature reflects the current situation with low entry
rates associated with different service configurations are already barriers and brand recognition directly related to market share.
reflected in this customer service configuration threshold level. This yields the first inequality in Eq. (1). The marketing efforts of
Suppose there is a set of N social commerce firms, where k is an other players negatively affect the corresponding revenue rk, as
individual social commerce firm. N may also denote the set of so- the second inequality suggests.
cial commerce firms if it is clearly distinguishable in the context, The threshold positively and negatively affects the sales reve-
N = {1, . . . , n}. I define the following modeling notation: nues of firm k. The bigger tk is, the larger the profit margin firm k
will expect. On the other hand, the probability of transaction fail-
ek = marketing efforts of social commerce firm k; ure increases as tk rises. A transaction failure occurs when demand
tk = customer service configuration threshold (hereafter thresh- falls short of the threshold needed to permit sales to be completed.
old) set by social commerce firms (a reference point represent- Social commerce firms should compensate for transaction failures
ing a service configuration including a discount package and a according to some predefined service-level agreement that is
minimum number of customers in order for the service offering reached with the partner suppliers, recognizing losses in their rev-
to be effective)2; enue streams, and losses from the customers’ viewpoint too.
dk = social commerce firm k’s tolerance capability to maintain According to a survey conducted by the Korea Chamber of Com-
positive cash flows in choosing the threshold level (the maxi- merce and Industry (2011) in 2011, more than 50% of the com-
mum level of threshold that social commerce firms k endures); plaints from social commerce firm customers come from
and, transaction failures, where there are quantity shortages and qual-
E = total marketing efforts currently under way in the industry ity degradation due to excessive sales of coupons. Firms are
P
ðE ¼ k2N ek Þ. responsible for their transaction failures, and they should compen-
sate customers for breaches of service agreements, which reduces
My model of social commerce firm business activities follows. their revenues. Thus, an increase of the threshold tk will enhance
First, a firm issues coupons that can be used to purchase products the revenue at first, but it will also increase the possibility of trans-
or services from a partner supplier at a constant discount rate. action failures, thereby reducing revenues in the end. I model the
However, those coupons are effective only when the amount of effect of tk on revenues as a concave function, which requires the
coupons sold exceeds a minimum required number of users, or a third inequality in Eq. (1).
threshold tk set by the corresponding firm k. The revenue of the Finally, I need to net the costs of effort of social commerce firm
firm k will be proportional to the effective demand that the social k, which is assumed to be proportional to the amount of effort ek:
that is, ck  ek. Note that ck involves both pecuniary and non-pecu-
niary unit costs incurred in the course of operations pertaining to
2
marketing. Thus, it can be thought of as all the ex ante burden
As I explained earlier, social commerce business models in some countries do not
include tk and dk as their key decision elements. I will provide a business model in
when firm k implements one unit of marketing action. Also, ck
Section 2 which excludes these from the decision elements. should not be confused with marketing expenses ek, which
72 D. Kim / Electronic Commerce Research and Applications 12 (2013) 69–77

Note: The relative marketing efforts εk’s are uniquely determined if the pair of constants (ζ12, ζ13) belong to the feas-
ible region specified above. For example, for a given tuple (ζ12, ζ13) = (1, 0.5), which belongs to the feasible region
above, the relative marketing efforts in a Nash equilibrium, ε1*, ε2*, ε3* are determined as , , .
 2
di c
Fig. 2. fij  dj
 cj parameter region where
i
ej ’s are feasible (i.e., 0 6 ej 6 1).

represents ex post values paid for marketing-related activities. To check out the second-order sufficient conditions, I construct
There will be no costs associated with the decision for tk since the Hessian matrix H as follows3:
the decision is a matter of deliberation and does not incur pecuni- " #
 2EEk tEk4ðdk tk Þ Ek ðdk 2t k Þ
ary costs. Thus, the profit of firm k is: H¼ E2
;
e 
k
dk 2t k
E
 2eEk
pk ¼ r k  ck  ek ¼ tk   ðdk  t k Þ  ck  ek ðtk 6 dk Þ ð2Þ P
E where Ek ¼ i–k ei . The matrix is negative definite at the points sat-
P
and total industry profit is defined as k2N pk . isfying the first-order necessary conditions if both t k and ek are po-
sitive as I have assumed in the proposition. h
3. Analysis For example, when N = 3 and (f12, f13) lies in the shaded area in
the figure below, the ek ’s are: e1 ¼ 1þf 12 þf13
1þf12 þf13
; e2 ¼ 1f12 þf13
1þf12 þf13
, and
My analysis first presents the Nash equilibria of the model. e3 ¼ 1þf12 f13
1þf12 þf13
.
Assuming that heterogeneous social commerce firms may employ According to the Best Response Threshold and Marketing Effort
different strategies, the following proposition shows that there are Proposition (P1), the optimal threshold is proportional to the capa-
infinitely many solutions, as in the Nash bargaining game (Fuden- bility that the corresponding firm can exert in the market. The rel-
berg and Tirole 1991), for a best response individual marketing ef- ative marketing effort of firm k; ek (and ek too) increases as fkj
 e
fort ek. However, the relative marketing effort ek  Ej can be (j – k) increases, but decreases as fjk (j – k) increases. Thus, more
uniquely determined. Let k denote an arbitrary firm among N social marketing effort by firm k is expected if its relative capability
d2 c
commerce firms, k 2 {1, . . . , N}. Also define the constants fij  di2  cji (ddkj ; j–k) increases or its relative marketing cost (cckj ; j–k) de-
e j
for all i < j and ej  Ej for all j in N. The latter represents the relative creases. However, the former will have a stronger effect on ek than
strength of marketing effort from social commerce firm j. This the latter since fij is proportional to square of the relative capabil-
leads to Proposition 1: ity. Subsequently, the critical competitive edge can be gained from
enhancing the capability that a social commerce firm has to main-
Proposition 1 (The Best Response Threshold and Marketing Effort tain a positive cash flow against low margins.
Proposition). Given that N  1 firms except firm k have decided their If all firms have the same capability and cost structure, a sym-
optimal best response threshold tj and marketing effort ej metric Nash equilibrium can be found based on the following prop-
(j = 1, . . . , k  1, k + 1, . . . , N), firm k’s optimal t k and ek (both positive) osition.4 As for homogenous social commerce firms, it is not
are: t k ¼ d2k and ek as a solution to the following linear equation necessary to distinguish the player strategies ek’s since they will be
system, 1  fij ¼ fij  ei þ ej ; 8i < j in N. Then, ek is determined by the same. Thus, I employ e, instead of ek, as the representative
P  ek with a suitable proportional constant P. player’s strategy without specifying a player’s index.
Proof of Proposition 1. First, one can show that t k satisfies the The symmetric case with homogeneous firms may fit two stages
first-order necessary condition. The linear equation system for the of the industry lifecycle. The first is the very early stage of the
ek’s (k = 1, . . . , N) comes from a set of first-order necessary condi- industry, when a small number of similar-size companies consti-
tions. It is possible to derive a closed form solution for ek by utiliz- tute the industry. Another one is the mature stage of the lifecycle,
ing the matrix structure of the linear system and employing
Cramer’s rule (Chiang 2006, Fudenberg and Tirole 1991). The de- 3
The Hessian matrix is the square matrix of 2nd order partial derivatives of a
tailed procedure is omitted here, but an example is demonstrated function with multiple variables. It is frequently used by examining the sign of the
below. (See Fig. 2.) matrix to prove that the current solution under investigation is really a local
Once the ek ’s are identified, next is to construct the values of ek extremum (Chiang 2006). Here, I need to employ the Hessian matrix since the model
deals with two types of decision variables: tk and ek.
by multiplying the corresponding ek by the constant P. Although 4
Nash equilibrium in a symmetric game permits changing the identities of the
the system of simultaneous equations for the ek’s has infinitely players without changing the payoff to the strategies (Fudenberg and Tirole 1991).
many solutions, thanks to the linearity of the equation system Here, the game becomes symmetric since all the social commerce firms are now
for ek’s, ek is unique up to scalar multiplication. assumed to be identical in terms of the capability and the cost structure.
D. Kim / Electronic Commerce Research and Applications 12 (2013) 69–77 73

X
PBðE; tÞ  pk ¼ t  ðd  tÞ  c  E:
k2N

CB is supposed to have a linear and additive relationship with E and t:


that is, CBðE; tÞ ¼ a  E  b  t, where a and b are positive coefficients.
This notion of CB is natural since the scale of demand for social com-
merce services is more likely to increase with greater total marketing
effort. In addition, the degree of customer benefits will grow as the
average customer service configuration threshold level falls.
However, CB and PB are not measured by the same standard,
and they cannot be combined in a simple weighted sum. The liter-
ature on cost-benefit analysis and multi-criteria decision-making
suggests to employ a multiplicative form in this case (Alroy
2001, Sirakoulis and Karafyllidis 2012). It is also possible to incor-
porate additional weights to adjust the balance between CB and PB.
We did not apply such weights in Eq. (3) though, since mypurpose
Fig. 3. A sample graph of E (c = 1 and d = 10; thus, b
E ¼ 25). is not to quantify or estimate the exact amount of the industry per-
formance, but to examine qualitative behaviors of the system. As a
result, my industry performance measure is the product of CB and
PB, and the expression for W(–) in Eq. (3) is:
where many small and medium-sized firms with low value of dk
are forced out of the market, and a small number of big with sim- WðE; tÞ ¼ ft  ðd  tÞ  c  Eg  ða  E  b  tÞ: ð4Þ
ilar properties survive. This discussion leads to Proposition 2: With the industry performance measure defined in Eq. (4), I next of-
fer a third proposition to explain how socially-optimal values of E0
Proposition 2 (The Symmetric Player Strategies Proposition). In the and t0 can be determined.
symmetric strategies case, where ck = c and dk = d for all k = 1, . . . , N, a
symmetric Nash equilibrium is determined via tk ¼ t ¼ 2d and Proposition 3 (The Industry Performance Proposition). Assume that
d2
ek ¼ e ¼ N1
N2
 4c for all k = 1, . . . , N. the firms employ symmetric strategies p asffiffiffiin Proposition 2, and that the
Proof of Proposition 2. For tk here, the same reasoning as in following condition holds dc > ab  ð1 þ 3Þ. Then, the total marketing
Proposition 1 is applicable. By assuming symmetric strategies, I effort E0 and the average threshold t0 maximize industry performance
can construct a system of linear equations for the ek’s directly from as defined in Eq. (4) will be t0 ¼ dc and E0 ¼ dðadþ2cbÞ .
2 8ca
the set of first-order necessary conditions, c  ðE Þ2 ¼ d4  Ek , for all Proof. First, the first-order conditions are satisfied with t0 and
2 d2 ðN1Þ
k. The last equation reduces to c  N  e ¼ 4 
since E⁄ = N  e⁄ E0, if a  d > c  b (in particular, for t0), which is also satisfied by
   
and Ek ¼ ðN  1Þ  e . Thus, I get tk and ek as above, from which the condition above. To check out the second-order conditions,
the second-order sufficient conditions are satisfied too. h we constructed the Hessian matrix,
In the case of symmetric strategies, the optimal level of the  
2c  a c  b þ a  ðd  2tÞ
threshold t will not depend on the number of social commerce H¼
c  b þ a  ðd  2tÞ b  ð4t  dÞ  2a  E
. This is negative defi-
firms in the industry. On the other hand, it is interesting to look
nite at t0 and E0, when (a  d  c  b) > 3(c  b)2. This is equivalent to
2
into the combined effort or total expenditure from all social com- d b2  2  2  2
merce firms, E ¼ N  e ¼ N1
2
 d4c, which depends on how many c
 a > 3  ab , or dc  2  ab  dc  2  ab > 0. Since dc is positive,
N 
there are. The combined effort increases with N dE

> 0 , but the this inequality is satisfied if the condition in the proposition
dN
2 
rate of growth is diminishing in NðddNE2 < 0Þ. Furthermore, E con- holds. h
verges to a number as N goes to infinity: limN!1 E ¼ d4c  b
2
E. Thus, Note that t0 = t; so at least for the threshold, the socially-opti-

E is a concave function of N, which converges to E. (See Fig. 3.) b mal level and the optimal level of individual choice coincide. This
Although each social commerce firm may exert less marketing permits us to predict that social commerce firms will manage their
effort when there is a large number of firms (see e in Proposition threshold levels at the socially-optimal level.
2), the addition of new social commerce firms will swamps this ef- This desirable feature may not be sustained when we consider to-
fect, leading to increases in total marketing efforts (E) in the mar- tal marketing effort. Further, a ramification of the tragedy of the
ket. If we assume that the revenue function reflects market commons shows the possibility of a phase transition, where the rela-
demand, then there will be the possibility of overexploitation of tionship between dc and ab specifies the sharp boundary of the phase
customers. Collectively, social commerce firms will exert market- transition. We have already seen that a relationship between these
ing effort far beyond the point that boosts potential market de- two terms presents the conditions in the Industry Performance
mand to its maximum level. This resembles the typical situation Proposition (P3). These conditions hold when dc is far larger than ab.
of the tragedy of the commons: this sort of negative externality The next proposition goes further and provides another relationship
is at the heart of the problem (Alroy 2001, Hardin 1968, Greco in a somewhat different format between these two terms, and this
and Floridi 2004). When a social commerce firm advertises, it does relation is critical in triggering the tragedy of the commons:
not take into account the negative effect that its action might have
on the revenue streams of other social commerce firms. Proposition 4. (The Trigger for the Tragedy of the Commons Proposi-
To examine this possibility in more detail, I first define the tion). Assume the symmetric situation as in Proposition 2. Now, consider
industry performance measure W() as a function of the total mar- the following two cases that are mutually exclusive and complete.
keting expenses E and the average customer service configuration
threshold t:
WðE; tÞ ¼ CBðE; tÞ  PBðE; tÞ ð3Þ  Case A. When dc > 2  ab, then there is a positive critical value T
such that the tragedy of commons occurs (E > E0) if the number
where CB and PB stand for customer benefits and producer benefits. of social commerce firms exceeds this critical number (N P T). T
Under symmetric strategies, 
d ¼ d and t ¼ t, the latter is simply the 2ad
is larger than 1 and determined by T ¼ ad2cb .
sum of all the profits from the social commerce firms:
74 D. Kim / Electronic Commerce Research and Applications 12 (2013) 69–77

an upper bound on the relative size between a and b: b cannot


be larger than d2ca. As a result, T appears more sensitive to ab than
to d as shown in Fig. 5. (See Fig. 5 and compare the scales in the
axes of figures.)
Since t0 = t and they do not depend on the number of social
commerce firms that use symmetric strategies, we can view the
performance structure from a different angle by defining two para-
metric functions based on my model: H ¼ HðtÞ  b  t and
J ¼ JðtÞ  t  ð
d  tÞ. Note that at a symmetric equilibrium, both

H() and J() are constant functions: specifically, H ¼  b2d and
d2

J ¼ 4 for both the social and individually-optimal levels (t0 and
t). Accordingly, the performance measure in Eq. (4) can be viewed
as if it were a function of E only:
c ¼ ða  E þ HÞ  ðJ  c  EÞ:
W ð5Þ
This characterization of system performance is similar to a well-
known system performance measure in ecology (Alroy 2001, Hardin
1968). One can interpret H and J as a location parameter and an eco-
logical capacity. The latter J is proportional to the average capability
Note: Here, = 1 is fixed, but this ratio does not affect the overall pattern of partitions. and the former H, together with J, determines the generic perfor-
mance without marketing effort; that is, J  H (<0) corresponds to
Fig. 4. Parameter areas where the tragedy of commons can be avoided. the performance level when E = 0. From Eq. (5), we know that both
solutions to W c ¼ 0 in terms of E are positive, and Wc is maximized
at bE ¼ aJcH
2ac
.
 Case B. When dc 6 2  ab, then for any number of firms N, the total There are two forces at work in Eq. (5). First, for a given poten-
marketing effort falls short of the socially-optimal level tial market size with fixed H and J, more marketing effort by social
(E 6 E0). commerce firms means additional revenues: this is the first term
a  E + H in Eq. (5). In fact, in the early stage of the industry, excess
Proof. E > E0 if and only if (a  d + 2c  b)  N < 2a  d  N  2a  d. marketing expenditures contributed to the rapid growth of the en-
This expression can be rearranged into (2c  b  a  d)  N < 2a  d. tire market for social commerce services (Anderson et al. 2012). In
We have two cases to explore. The condition in Case A corresponds South Korea, for example, the social commerce business has grown
to the situation where the left-hand side is negative, while the con- into a US$1 billion industry over the last several years, and many
dition in Case B guarantees that the left-hand side is non-negative. experts agree that the massive marketing activities have raised
Thus, in Case B the inequality E > E0 cannot hold unless N is nega- consumer awareness. However, due to the fierce competition,
tive, which is impossible. In Case A, E > E0 holds for N > ad2cb
2ad
 T. more marketing effort has resulted in a smaller population to tar-
Further, the denominator of T is always bigger than the numerator get in the next period: the second term (J  c  E) in Eq. (5). The
under the condition in Case A, which guarantees that T > 1. h overall effect of these two forces is reflected in the multiplicative
The results of the Trigger for the Tragedy of the Commons Prop- system performance measure.
osition (P4) imply that one cannot expect that the social commerce The corollary below provides more streamlined expressions of
industry will be sustainable unless the condition in Case B comes the conditions pertaining to the tragedy of the commons when
true. It depends on the number of social commerce firms whether the tk’s are identical and fixed at some t such as t0 = t for some pol-
the industry in Case B survives. A limited number of social com- icy reasons, and ek is the only effective strategy for firm k.
merce firms may thrive only if the size of the industry is main-
tained at less than T. Corollary (Alternative Conditions for the Tragedy of the Commons to
Fig. 4 illustrates some partitions of the c–d parameter space Occur). Let us assume that the tk’s are fixed at t and the
along the critical boundaries for a phase transition. The shaded re- performance measure is given as in Eq. (5). With symmetric
gions represent the area where the tragedy of the commons can be strategies as in Proposition 2, each social commerce firm sets its
avoided (the condition in P4) and the socially-optimal level can be optimal marketing effort at tðdtÞ
c  N1
N2
, thereby, E ¼ tðdtÞ
c  N1
N .
attained (the condition in P3). Note that the shaded regions occupy There are two cases.
a relatively small portion of the entire parameter space. Further,
even a small increase in the number of social commerce firms
(from 3 to 6 in Fig. 4) may significantly reduce the size of the
shaded region. Therefore, Case B together with the limited oppor-
 Case A. When c  b < a  (d  t), then there is a positive critical
tunity of N < T in Case A of Proposition 4 will be rarely observed in b such that the tragedy of the commons occurs ðE P b
value T EÞ
practice, and the tragedy of the commons seems inevitable in most
if the number of social commerce firms exceeds this critical
situations. b Þ. Tb is larger than one and determined as fol-
a , we can see that T is larger than 2 and
number ðN P T
By rearranging T into a22cb b  2aðdtÞ .
d lows: T aðdtÞcb
dT d2 T
converges to 2 as d becomes large. Since dd
< 0 and dd2
> 0, T is  Case B. When c  b P a  (d  t), then for any number of firms,
diminishing but will slowly converge to 2 as d goes infinity. How- the total marketing effort will fall short of the socially-optimal
ever, T shows a different behavior when q  ab changes. Again, by level ðE < b
EÞ.
rearranging terms in T, we can get another expression for
2d
T ¼ d2cq , and dT
> 0 and d2 T
> 0 when d > 2c. Subsequently, T is The proof follows procedures similar those for Propositions 3
dq dq2
  and 4, and so it is omitted.
close to 2 when a is far larger than b ab  0 , and very rapidly in- b > 1 in Case A of Corollary 5. This suggests that the
Note that T
b d
creases to infinity as a approaches to 2c
ð> 1Þ. This behavior puts tragedy of the commons is not inevitable, even in Case A when
D. Kim / Electronic Commerce Research and Applications 12 (2013) 69–77 75

Fig. 5. Changes of critical value (T) (c is fixed at 1; thus, d > 2 and q < 0.5).

N<T b . Unfortunately though, T


b is likely to always be larger than 2, ratios in my analysis, dc and ab, play an important role in determining
and not small in most normal situations. whether the outcome will be a market failure, further analysis will
be useful to understand the mechanics a little better. For example,
4. Conclusions if the unit costs of marketing are much larger than the average
capabilities of firms with similar ratios, then the opportunity to
My analysis work reveals the weak points in the group-buying avoid market failure will improve.
business model associated with the social commerce industry. I Thus, social commerce firms need to be aware of the real costs
will review the main results and suggest some practical implica- of marketing in their business and industry. The current levels of
tions. I will focus on the value proposition that social commerce marketing expenses are too high because the firms are spending
firms should deliver to the market: they should seek a niche that on activities that are beyond the point of social optimality.5 This
is different from online shopping malls and open markets. Some distortion in the marketing-related efforts of social commerce firms
social commerce firms have revised their prospectuses to clarify needs to be addressed. If these firms were forced to abide by the
how they are differentiating themselves, but they have not yet rules and practices that normally are implemented among ex-
proved to investors that their businesses can achieve sustainable change-listed companies, their costs would increase further.
growth (Webster 2011, Wheeler 2011). I also will present some My comments suggest a policy direction to overcome the short-
guidelines and policy directions to address these difficulties. comings of the current business model, and to encourage the
First, my basic analysis under the symmetric competition industry to develop sustainable business models for the future. A
assumption argues that there will be a significant possibility of set of regulations may be required to curb the unnecessary adver-
the tragedy of commons. Although there is a gap between practice tisements and promotions to reduce overall marketing expendi-
and my assumption of homogeneous firms with symmetric strate- tures. In fact, excessive competition in the social commerce
gies, leading firms in the industry nevertheless seem to actually be industry is becoming the focus of monitoring and regulation in
implementing fairly similar strategies. For example, the top three many countries. For example, the UK Office of Fair Trading investi-
social commerce firms in South Korea constitute almost 90% in gated Groupon’s British unit after receiving a complaint from the
market share in terms of sales revenue, and their marketing ex- country’s advertising watchdog (Larson 2011). The Korean Fair
penses in 2010 to 2011 ranged from US$5 million to US$5.5 million Trade Committee also has shown serious concerns about social
(Baek 2011). Further, their service configurations and consumer commerce firms’ ability to comply with proper advertising codes
participation threshold levels, controlling for category of commod- (Digital Daily 2011).
ity or service, also look remarkably similar (Kim 2011). Thus, a There are a number of different activities that tend to increase
symmetric model appears to be a good approximation of the cur- the marketing costs of social commerce firms.6 The costs of running
rent situation. a customer care center and operating a help desk tend to be sub-
I also have claimed that, under a certain conditions, the social sumed into overall marketing costs. Some major social commerce
commerce industry is likely to experience a tragedy of commons firms in South Korea are starting to operate logistics centers and
and face disruption. My findings suggest that the critical number implement refund policy for unused coupons too. Institutional and
of firms for the tragedy of the commons to occur is quite small. legal devices to establish and enhance trust between social com-
A small number of large social commerce firms in the industry merce firms and customers are another example of such measures.
may lead the market toward problems. The arguments that I have
made suggest that the explosive growth of the social commerce
5
business may become too great to allow an effective business mod- Since only one social commerce provider, Groupon, has gone public so far, it is not
easy to accurately identify the financial status of most of the others. Many experts
el to continue to exist.
look at the firms’ reports on their marketing activities and financial justification with
Prior research offers insights on how to deal with the potential suspicion (Financial News 2011, MacMillan 2011a, Webster 2011). This is also
for excessive competition and diversify social commerce business partially due to unconventional accounting practices in the industry. I argue that the
models so that the original intention of social commerce can be current marketing cost is underestimated, and the actual figure should go up
recovered. Liang et al. (2011), Stephen and Toubia (2009, 2010), significantly if all the true marketing efforts are included.
6
To avoid confusion, I stress again that it has a positive connotation in my context
and Westland (2010) have demonstrated the potential of social
to increase the marketing costs. My point here is that the current marketing efforts
business, but increasing marketing expenses need to be addressed focus on promotions and advertising and overlook necessary efforts that should be
to remedy future problems. Since the relationships between key regarded as marketing activities.
76 D. Kim / Electronic Commerce Research and Applications 12 (2013) 69–77

These may include quality assurance through careful selection of January 20, 2012. Available at www.booz.com/media/uploads/BaC-
Turning_Like_to_Buy.pdf.
partners and service opportunities, self-inspection systems for con-
Baek, B. S. Ticket Monster and Coupang, head-to-head competition for the industry’s
firmation of service specifications and other agreements, a legal obli- number one position (in Korean). Economy Today, November 25, 2011.
gation that forces social commerce firms to subscribe to insurance Available at www.eto.co.kr/news/outview.asp?Code=20111125145743203&
for damage compensation, and so on. ts=133239.
Cavazza, F. The six pillars of social commerce. Forbes Magazine, February 1, 2012.
All of these measures should have been employed in the early Available at www.forbes.com/sites/fredcavazza/2012/02/01/the-six-pillars-of-
stages of the social commerce industry. For example, Groupon social-commerce/.
introduced a deal evaluation system to build trust with its custom- Chiang, A. C. Fundamental Methods of Mathematical Economics, 4th edition. McGraw-
Hill/Irwin, New York, NY, 2006.
ers and partners. After deploying this system, Groupon’s expenses Chung, W., and Chen, L. Group-buying e-commerce in China. IT Pro, 2012, 24–30.
decreased due to a sharp increase in other kinds of marketing costs Curty, R. G., and Zhang, P. Social commerce: looking back and forward. Proceedings
(Patel 2011). Similar trends have been observed in South Korea of the American Society for Information Science and Technology, 48, 1, 2011, 1–10.
Digital Daily. Special report on brightness and darkness of social commerce in Korea
after the Korean Fair Trade Committee strongly encouraged that (in Korean). April 6–20, 2011. Available at www.ddaily.co.kr/news/
social commerce firms should establish standardized refund poli- news_view.php?uid=76416.
cies, together with damage compensation plans. Actual marketing Financial News. Special report on social commerce (in Korean), December 18, 2011.
Available at www.fnnews.com/
expenses diminished and over-issuance of free coupons also de- view?ra=Sent0901m_View&corp=fnnews&arcid=09224
clined after institutional measures were introduced to raise the 94751&cDateYear=2011&cDateMonth=12&cDateDay=18.
real costs of marketing. Fudenberg, D., and Tirole, J. Game Theory. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA, 1991.
Gu, B., Park, J., and Konana, P. The impact of external word-of-mouth sources on
Last but not least, we seek for technological innovations to
retailer sales of high-involvement products. Information Systems Research, 23, 1,
strengthen the potential merits of the social commerce business 2012, 182–196.
model. One of my results implies that it is necessary to reduce Greco, G. M., and Floridi, L. The tragedy of the digital commons. Ethics and
the gap between a firm’s capability index and its service configura- Information Technology, 6, 2004, 73–81.
Hardin, G. The tragedy of the commons. Science, 162, 1968, 1243–1248.
tion threshold to avoid the tragedy of the commons, or at least Heidemanna, J., Kliera, M., and Probstb, F. Online social networks: a survey of a
diminish its likelihood. For example, the new launch of location- global phenomenon. Computer Networks, 56, 18, 2012, 3866–3878.
based services for smart phone users may narrow this gap since Jing, X., and Xie, J. Group buying: a new mechanism for selling through social
interactions. Management Science, 57, 8, 2011, 1354–1372.
the service will provide more information to consumers, and in- Korea Chamber of Commerce and Industry. A consumer satisfaction survey on social
crease the chance of successful service offerings. Some players such commerce services (in Korean). Research report. Seoul, South Korea, March 8,
as Groupon Mobile in the US and TicketMonster Now in South Kor- 2011. Available at www.korcham.net/EconNews/KcciReport/CRE01102R.asp?
m_chamcd=A001&m_dataid=20110308001&m_page=1& m_query=TITLE&m_
ea are already moving in this direction (Baek 2011). These firms queryText=%BC%D2%BC%C8%C4%BF%B8%D3%BD%BA.
sell real-time mobile coupons to smart phone users and provide Kim, Y. H. Social commerce: current market situations and policy issues. Korea
customized service packages targeted to specific consumer seg- Information Society Development Institute Issues Report, 23, 11, 2011, 41–63 (in
Korean).
ments. Such activities differentiate these social commerce firms Knowledge at Wharton. Dot-com bubble, part II? Why it’s so hard to value social
from online shopping malls and other e-commerce sites, as dis- networking sites? October 4, 2006. Available at knowledge.wharton.upenn.edu/
cussed by Heidemanna et al. (2012). When 4G networks and inter- article.cfm?articleid=1570.
Kumar, V., and Rajan, B. Social coupons as a marketing strategy: a multifaceted
active mobile communications proliferate, location-based services
perspective. Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science, 40, 1, 2012, 120–136.
will be one of the most promising areas for social commerce. The Kumar, V., and Rajan, B. The perils of social coupon campaigns. MIT Sloan
technology will give the firms more capacity to configure service Management Review, Summer 2012, 15–16.
offerings with a wide variety of negotiation and coordination capa- Larson, E. Groupon advertising practices being probed in U.K. on promotions,
savings. Bloomberg, December 2, 2011. Available at www.bloomberg.com/
bilities to establish partnerships with local firms. One of the most news/2011-12-02/groupon-advertising-practices-are-being-probed-by-u-k-
promising directions along this line of development will be inte- antitrust-regulator.html.
grating location-based, personalized social commerce services Lee, E. M. Global market survey on social commerce. Korea Information Society
Development Institute Issues Report, 23, 3, 2011, 36–44 (in Korean).
with mobile payment systems using near field communication. Liang, T. P., Ho, Y. T., Li, Y. W., and Turban, E. What drives social commerce: the role
In conclusion, my analysis suggests that social commerce firms of social support and relationship quality. International Journal of Electronic
should return to their original value proposition, where the mar- Commerce, 16, 2, 2011, 69–90.
MacMillan, D. Groupon’s stumbles may force it to pare back size of IPO. Bloomberg
keting activities focus more on word-of-mouth diffusion through Online (October 3, 2011a). Available at www.bloomberg.com/news/2011-10-
social networks than through aggressive multi-media advertising 03/groupon-s-stumbles-seen-paring-back-size-of-ipo-as-investor-interest-
campaigns. We believe that this will be the best way to strike a bal- wanes.html.
MacMillan, D. LivingSocial aims to be different from Groupon. Business Week
ance between the ‘‘social’’ and ‘‘commerce’’ aspects of the social Online (September 22, 2011b). Available at www.businessweek.com/magazine/
commerce business model (Knowledge at Wharton 2006, Kumar livingsocial-aims-to-be-different-from-groupon-09222011.html.
and Rajan 2012a, 2012b; Urstadt 2008). Although social commerce MacMillan, D. Groupon China venture said to fire workers for poor performance.
Bloomberg Online (August 24, 2011c). Available at www.bloomberg.com/news/
firms have engaged in massive advertising campaigns to generate
2011-08-23/groupon-china-joint-venture-said-to-fire-workers-for-poor-
public awareness and interest in the early stage of the industry’s performance.html.
lifecycle, it is time to return for them to emphasize the social as- Marsden, P. Social Commerce: Monetizing Social Media. Syzygy, Hamburg, Germany,
pects of their business models now.7 2010.
Marsden, P., and Chaney, P. The Social Commerce Handbook: 20 Secrets for Turning
Social Media into Social Sales. McGraw-Hill, New York, NY, 2012.
References Patel, K. Groupon marketing spending works almost too well. Ad Age Digital
(November 12, 2011). Available at adage.com/article/digital/groupon-
Alroy, J. A multispecies overkill simulation of the end-Pleistocene mega faunal mass marketing-spending-works/230777.
extinction. Science, 292, 2001, 1893–1896. Reibstein, D. How sustainable is Groupon’s business model? Knowledge at Wharton
Anand, K. S., and Aron, R. Group buying on the web: a comparison of price-discovery (May 25, 2011). Available at knowledge.wharton.upenn.edu/article.
mechanisms. Management Science, 49, 11, 2003, 1546–1562. cfm?articleid=2784.
Anderson, M., Sims, J., Price, J., and Brusa, J. Turning ‘‘like’’ to ‘‘buy’’: social media ROA Holdings. The rapidly expanding social commerce market of South Korea and
emerges as a commerce channel. White paper, Booz & Company, New York, NY, Japan. Research report (February 21, 2011). Available at global.roaholdings.
com/report/research_view.html?type=country&num=143.
Sirakoulis, G. C., and Karafyllidis, I. G. Cooperation in a power-aware embedded-
system changing environment: public goods games with variable multiplication
7
Polyvore, Shopkick, Swipely and others in the US are trying new business models factors. IEEE Transactions on Systems, Man, and Cybernetics – Part A, 42, 3, 2012,
different from group-buying (Anderson et al. 2012, Kumar and Rajan 2012a, 2012b; 596–603.
MacMillan 2011b). Their service offerings emphasize the social aspect in their value Stephen, A. T., and Toubia, O. Explaining the power-law degree distribution in a
social commerce network. Social Networks, 31, 2009, 262–270.
proposition based on local commerce information.
D. Kim / Electronic Commerce Research and Applications 12 (2013) 69–77 77

Stephen, A. T., and Toubia, O. Deriving value from social commerce networks. Westland, J. C. Critical mass and willingness to pay for social networks. Electronic
Journal of Marketing Research, 47, 2, 2010, 215–228. Commerce Research and Applications, 9, 1, 2010, 6–19.
Urstadt, B. Social networking is not a business. MIT Technology Review (July/August Wheeler, R. Groupon gone wrong! Harvard business fellow’s warning to investors
2008). Available at www.technologyreview.com/business/20922/. and entrepreneurs. Pymnts.com, August 23, 2011. Available at pymnts.com/
Webster, K. Groupon’s business model: bubble or the real deal? Pymnts.com briefingroom/shopping-and-social-buying/social-shopping-and-social-buying/
(September 19, 2011). Available at pymnts.com/commentary/pymnts-voice/ groupon-gone-wrong-a-warning-to-investors/.
groupon-s-business-model-bubble-or-the-real-deal/.
Wei, Y., Straub, D. W., and Poddar, A. The power of many: an assessment of
managing Internet group purchasing. Journal of Electronic Commerce Research,
12, 1, 2011, 19–43.

You might also like