You are on page 1of 11

Cambridge Journal of Regions, Economy and Society 2019, 12, 401–422

doi:10.1093/cjres/rsz012
Advance Access publication 5 October 2019

Industrial Policy in China: The Planned Growth of


Specialised Towns in Guangdong Province

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/cjres/article-abstract/12/3/401/5581697 by Universidad EAN user on 17 May 2020


Elisa Barbieria, Marco R. Di Tommasob, Chiara Polliob and
Lauretta Rubinib
a
Department of Economics, University of Venice Ca’ Foscari, Fondamenta S. Giobbe, 873,
30100 Cannaregio, Venezia, Italy. elisa.barbieri@unive.it
b
Department of Economics and Management, University of Ferrara, Via Voltapaletto, 11,
44121 Ferrara, Italy. marco.di.tommaso@unife.it, chiara.pollio@unife.it, lauretta.rubini@
unife.it
Received on September 20, 2018; accepted on July 4, 2019

We analyse one of the most important policy experiences for industrial clustering in
Southern China—the Specialised Towns programme—that has transformed some Chinese
clusters into the backbone of global production chains. We offer a long-term, detailed over-
view of the policy programme and of Guangdong’s specialised towns, classifying them as
endogenous or exogenous according to their features, and investigate their contribution to
local growth and rebalancing. This analysis of the Specialised Towns programme contrib-
utes to the international debate on revisiting industrial policy and suggests that the discus-
sion should conceive them as articulated processes to reach long-term societal objectives.

Keywords: China, Guangdong, industrial policy, specialised towns, clusters


JEL Classifications: O18, O25, R12, R58

Introduction areas in a sort of “controlled” industrialisation.


The underlying idea was that such develop-
China is today at the centre of several global net-
ment would then trigger the rest of the country
works of production. Starting from the launch
(Groenewald et al., 2008; Knight, 2013).
of the open-door policy in 1978, the country’s
Simultaneously, since the early 1980s, policy
growth and structural change have been re-
actors have interacted with overseas capitals,
markable and fast. While for some scholars
allowing them to build large and globally rele-
this has happened despite state intervention
vant production bases in the country. The
(Nee and Opper, 2007; Parish and Michelson,
Guangdong Province, Southeast China, offers
1996), recent contributions emphasise the role
a special viewpoint on this interplay. Half as
of planning and policy activities of national
large as Germany but with 20 million more
and provincial governments (Veek et al., 2016;
people, Guangdong is the leading province for
Yueh, 2013). This process has assumed a pre-
its contribution to national GDP—10.8%, cor-
cise spatial shape. The open-door policy inten-
responding to 1.3 billion US$ in 2017. A feature
tionally favoured the initial growth of selected

© The Author(s) 2019. Published by Oxford University Press on behalf of the Cambridge Political Economy Society.
All rights reserved. For permissions, please email: journals.permissions@oup.com
Barbieri et al.

of the province’s growth is its outward orienta- come from the ST of Chenghai (Jankowiak,
tion. In 2017, Guangdong accounted for nearly 2017) and 20% of smartphones manufactured
30% of China’s national exports1 and 15% of its globally every year comes from Dongguan City
total foreign direct investment (FDI).2 It had a (where 93% of the total townships participate

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/cjres/article-abstract/12/3/401/5581697 by Universidad EAN user on 17 May 2020


leading role during the open-door policy. When, in the programme).5 This means that a signifi-
in 1978, Deng Xiaoping launched it, Guangdong cant part of consumption in the West is today
and Fujian were the first provinces to experi- possible because these Chinese clusters have
ment the “special policies, flexible measures” emerged, with the support of this programme.
(Di Tommaso et  al., 2013; Li, 1997). Such ini- Gradually, Guangdong has become econom-
tiatives were at the core of Xiaoping’s plan ically polarised [Organization of Economic
of Chinese socialist economy modernisation, Cooperation and Development (OECD),
based on gradual opening up to the global cap- 2010]. To correct this, since 2008, policymakers
italistic market, via trade and FDI, and power have used the STs programme also to promote
delegation to local governments. Guangdong within-province rebalancing (Di Tommaso
was chosen as a pilot area for two reasons: (i) its et  al., 2013), encouraging specialisations more
strategic location, near Hong Kong and Macao, related to existing local economic and social
which was considered a booster to FDI and contexts (Su and Sun, 2016).
to the diffusion of entrepreneurial practices International scholars have increasingly fo-
[Barbieri et al., 2009; Enright et al., 2005; Yeung cussed on China’s clustering and spatial indus-
et al. (1998)]—indeed, between 1988 and 1999, trial agglomerations (for example, Barbieri
Hong Kong and Macao accounted for more et al., 2010; Butollo, 2015; Long and Zhang, 2012;
than 66% of total FDI directed to the region,3 Wang et al., 2010; Zhu et al., 2019). However, the
detaching themselves by far from the other literature on the specific case of Guangdong’s
Asian contributors—and (ii) its initial low eco- STs programme is surprisingly small (cf. Bellandi
nomic performance, reducing the risk to test the and Caloffi, 2010; Bellandi and Di Tommaso,
opening-up process here with respect to other 2005; Barbieri et  al., 2012). To the best of our
more powerful areas, such as Shanghai (Chung, knowledge, there is no systematic up-to-date
1998; Di Tommaso et al., 2013). In this context, overview of the phenomenon as a whole and
national and local governments devoted special no international contribution with empirical
attention to the spatial organisation of pro- evidence on the linkages between the STs pro-
duction through spatially targeted incentives gramme and local economic performances.
(Rubini et  al., 2015; Zeng, 2010, 2012, and so We attempt to fill this gap by offering a
on). As a result, Guangdong’s industrialisation long-term, detailed overview of the STs pro-
pattern is today largely based on industrial ag- gramme, which we believe is worth of investi-
glomerations (Lai et al., 2005; Zeng, 2010). gation for its distinctive features:
In this article, we focus on a crucial indus-
trial policy initiative for industrial clustering in 1. Number of towns involved. As far as we
Guangdong—the so-called Specialised Towns4 know, no other place worldwide has sup-
(STs) programme. By July 2017, there were ported such a high number of clusters over
416 STs, accounting for 40% of the provincial such a long time with a unique and coherent
GDP. In some prefectures, such as Dongguan policy programme.6
or Foshan, STs represent 90% of GDP. 2. Evolution from industrial park to cluster
Furthermore, 70% of the European and US promotion. The policy originally fostered in-
mass-market luggage is produced in the ST of dustrial parks, but, after learning from the
Shiling; 30% of the toys manufactured globally successful experiences of other countries’

402
Industrial policy in China

clusters, the Chinese government restruc- The article is organised as follows. After dis-
tured it to support, drive and accelerate clus- cussing the international literature useful to in-
ters growth (Rubini et al., 2015). terpret the STs’ experience, we describe data
3 . Central role of the Department of Science and methodology. Next, we offer a detailed

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/cjres/article-abstract/12/3/401/5581697 by Universidad EAN user on 17 May 2020


and Technology of Guangdong Government analysis of the programme and its evolution
(DSTGG). Since the launch of the pro- and analyse the features of endogenous versus
gramme, innovation has been at the centre exogenous STs; we, then present and discuss the
of the policy through publicly funded innov- empirical analysis. The article ends with some
ation platforms for the specialised sector implications for policy design and for the inter-
(also when low-tech productions). national debate on industrial policy, with ideas
4. Changing long-term aims. From promo- for future research lines.
tion of specialisation, competitiveness and
investment rationalisation to territorial
rebalancing.
Specialised towns in the context of
industrial clusters
To encouraging local growth, STs have also Since Marshall (1890), the economic advan-
been used as means for structural transform- tages related to industrial clusters7 have been
ation, economic upgrading and promotion widely discussed (for example, Boschma and
of general economic and societal objectives Fornahl, 2011; Delgado et  al., 2014; Martin
(Department of Science and Technology of and Sunley, 2003; Porter, 2000; Vicente, 2018).8
China (DSTC), 2011a, 2011b; DSTGG, 2003, Recently, the debate has interested experts
2006a, 2006b, 2008). In this sense, these tools on both the industrialised world (Eisingerich
have a broader industrial policy interpretation. et  al., 2010; Slaper et  al., 2018) and emerging
Hence, our contribution is also valuable for economies (Kesidou and Szirmai, 2008; Nadvi,
the international debate on revisiting indus- 1999; Van Dijk and Rabellotti, 2005). Although
trial policies (Bailey and Cowling, 2006; Chang, scholars do not unanimously agree on these ef-
1994; Cimoli et al., 2009; Rodrik, 2007; Vicente, fects, there seems to be growing consensus that
2018), which, we argue, needs to look to new clusters’ contribution to local economic per-
economic giants’ experience, such as that of formance is idiosyncratic to the hosting context
China, often neglected by Western scholars (Puig and González-Loureiro, 2017).
(Heilmann and Shih, 2013). Since Becattini’s seminal contributions
We focus on two empirical research ques- (Becattini, 1987, see also Becattini et al., 2014)
tions: (i) Is the ST programme associated with on industrial districts and Schmitz’s (1999) on
improved territorial economic performances? clusters, a well-established literature has as-
(ii) Can it contribute to territorial rebalancing serted the relevance of joint actions and trust
within the province? With the first question, to foster collective efficiency and produce
we investigate the capability of local industrial positive effects of clustering on performance
policy to promote local growth; with the second, (Porter, 2000). To achieve collective efficiency,
we tackle the relationship between industrial co-located economic actors need to engage in
policy and territorial rebalancing (Bellandi joint actions, either spontaneously or following
and Di Tommaso, 2005; Bianchi et al., 2000). In policy incentives.
doing so, we focus on the so-called endogenous A specific literature has focussed on clus-
clusters, as they might be interpreted to some tering as a target of industrial policies, given
extent as a form of place-based policy (Bailey their potential economic gains (Humphrey and
et al., 2015). Schmitz, 1996; Rodriguez-Clare, 2007). Some

403
Barbieri et al.

scholars have also warned that without proper key elements, in particular the existence of a
design and implementation, cluster policies community of firms and people giving rise to
might even produce negative consequences the industrial atmosphere (Becattini, 1987). In
(Brakman and van Marrewijk, 2013). Within Guangdong, in fact, clusters often result from

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/cjres/article-abstract/12/3/401/5581697 by Universidad EAN user on 17 May 2020


such literature, some papers use case studies to a joint action of planned policies and external
analyse the effect of clustering policies (Elola forces, such as foreign capitals and migrations.
et al., 2017; Kiese, 2017). However, the evidence In this context, STs can be classified as ex-
is still too limited and difficult to interpret given ogenous or endogenous (Barbieri et  al., 2009;
the complex design of these schemes and the Di Tommaso and Bazzucchi, 2013; Lyu and
variety of their effects (Uyarra and Ramolgan, McCarthy, 2015; Zeng, 2010; Zhu et al., 2017).
2016; Vicente, 2018). The exogenous clusters mainly grew attracting
Within this debate, China is particularly FDI, and policies aimed at facilitating the rela-
interesting for the widespread use of spatially tar- tionships between foreign and local firms. The
geted initiatives (Wang, 2013), heterogeneous for endogenous clusters stemmed from either the
types and aims (Barbieri et al., 2012). In the case development of local firms, the evolution of
of the STs, Chinese policymakers have drawn on ancient productive systems, the privatisation
previous international clustering experiences to of town and villages enterprises or some loca-
enhance existing industrial agglomeration and tional and geographical advantages.
specialisation, typical of clustering policies (Ketels, The few studies on STs in English illustrate the
2013). rationale and the content of the policy (Barbieri
In doing so, policymakers have been et al., 2012; Bellandi and Di Tommaso, 2005; Eng,
focussing on promoting upgrading, starting 1997; Long and Zhang, 2012) but not its possible ef-
from local production contexts. In this sense, fects on the territory and, in particular, the possible
the STs’ experience recalls the current de- heterogeneity of endogenous versus exogenous
bate about place-based policies (Bailey et  al., clusters. In particular, we expect two integrated
2015; Barca et  al., 2012; Hildreth and Bailey, processes to be at stake in endogenous STs:
2014; OECD, 2011), which recognises the im-
portance of places’ context in shaping and pro- 1. Being rooted in the local territory, history
moting development (Garretsen et  al., 2013; and values, cluster actors are more likely to
Hildreth and Bailey, 2013). The recognition engage in mutual trust relationships and col-
of local productive specialties at the centre of laboration—key success factors of industrial
the ST programme is in line with place-based districts (Becattini, 1987; Mistri and Solari,
and space-tailored programmes. However, STs 2003 and many others);
detach from place-based policies in many re- 2. Instituting some forms of collective action
gards. While the interaction between local and initiatives, such as innovation platforms, will
provincial governments is consistent with the reasonably have higher additional impact in
multilevel governance strategy of place-based terms of collective action on endogenous ra-
approaches, there is no proof that other rele- ther than exogenous clusters, thanks to the
vant stakeholders, such as firms and workers, embeddedness of relevant actors to the local
participate in the design and implementa- context.
tion of the STs scheme. Additionally, although
Guangdong policymakers have considered the
experiences of Italian districts in designing the A note on data and methodology
programme (Di Tommaso et al., 2013), the evo- The remainder of the paper adopts a mixed-
lution of these places misses some districts’ method approach (Cairns, 2018; Goertz, 2017;

404
Industrial policy in China

Hesse-Biber and Johnson, 2015) by using both technologies and upgrading production. They
qualitative and quantitative data. also encourage cooperation among the town’s
To analyse the STs, we built a novel data- firms, private and public engineering centres
base, containing information about the year and public research institutions in innova-

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/cjres/article-abstract/12/3/401/5581697 by Universidad EAN user on 17 May 2020


of recognition, location and specialisation on tive activities to improve the reputation of the
399 towns established by 2016.9 It results from town’s entire productive system (Barbieri et al.,
several fieldwork visits, from 2004 to mid-2017, 2010; DSTGG, 2003, 2006a, 2017; Guangdong
allowing us to collect official documents and Academy of Social Sciences (GDASS), 2017;
statistics; to interview provincial and local pol- Wang, 2004). The policymakers we interviewed
icymakers, economic actors, scholars and think have stressed that, to increase efficiency, the
tanks as well as to visit some STs.10 DSTGG has pushed the innovation centres to
In the empirical part, we matched this data- operate following a competitive market logic:
base with county- and district-level data on several centres are created and encouraged to
economic performances from the Guangdong compete in serving the companies in the town.
Statistical Yearbooks [National Bureau of Meanwhile, their general strategies are policy
Statistics (NBS) 2001–2016]. The result was a driven: the political funding actors keep con-
panel data set of 75 counties and districts in trol over their operations through the board
Guangdong from 2000 to 2015. of directors, which is in charge of defining the
strategic priorities and areas of intervention. In
2015, the innovation platforms have developed
The experience of Guangdong’s 620 projects for a total value of above 3 million
specialised towns yuan (Su and Sun, 2016).
The STs programme consists of an ex-post offi- According to the most recent data, the
cial certification by the provincial government, average degree of specialisation of the ex-
provided that the applicant town meets three isting 416 towns exceeded by about 10% the
criteria (Di Tommaso et al., 2013): minimum 30% required by law (GDASS, 2017).
Figure 1 shows their localisation and some data
1. It must be a township from an administrative about their growth in numbers over time.
point of view or, less frequently, a county or
urban district;
2. At least 30% of its industrial output (or
Specialised towns’ development
employment) must be concentrated in one and growth
“specialized sector” (defined to the three- We identify four phases in the STs programme’s
digit-level equivalent of international classi- evolution. The first dates back to the 1990s, be-
fication systems); fore the initiative’s official launch. The pro-
3. The annual industrial output value has to gramme stemmed from a previous national
exceed 2 billion yuan. government intervention—the Spark Plan—
which founded several Technology Investment
With the certification, the specialised town re- Zones in rural areas to upgrade agriculture
ceives a 30,000 yuan subsidy from the DSTGG, production and promote a gradual structural
provided an additional proportion be financed shift towards manufacturing (Barbieri et  al.,
by the local government11 (Wang and Yue, 2010). 2009; DSTGG, 2006b; Zhang and Ling, 2003).
These funds are to establish the so-called tech- The underlying idea was that strengthening
nology innovation platforms—the core of the the innovative capacity of agriculture would
STs policy—to assist firms in developing new have positive spill-over effects on the whole

405
Barbieri et al.

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/cjres/article-abstract/12/3/401/5581697 by Universidad EAN user on 17 May 2020


Figure 1.  Specialised towns in Guangdong.
Source: Authors’ elaborations on data from Guangdong Provincial ST Development Promotion Association.

economy, including industrial production (Di at the centre of Guangdong industrial growth
Tommaso et al., 2013). In the Spark Plan zones, since the beginning of China’s open-door policy
firms could benefit from subsidies and loans (Figure 2(a)) (Zheng et al., 2016).
(Barbieri et  al., 2010). Some DSTGG experts The concentration of STs in the PRD re-
realised that most of them tended to specialise flected policymakers’ effort to rationalise this
in specific sectors—a process now known as area’s fast—and often chaotic—growth (Chen,
“one city, one product” (Su and Sun, 2016; 2007; Enright et  al., 2005). Such economic ex-
Wang and Yue, 2010), which rests at the foun- pansion must be related with the career incen-
dation of the ST programme. tives given by national rules to local officials.
From 2000 to 2003, the second phase—a Indeed, up to the beginning of the 2000s, local
pilot development of the programme—took officials were mainly promoted according to
place, introduced by two formal documents: their ability to produce economic improve-
“Plan for the ST Technological Innovation: ments (mainly GDP growth) at the local level
Pilot Test” and “Managerial Methods for (Li, 2014). To this aim, local officials often used
the ST Technological Innovation: Pilot Test” transactions in the land market, which indeed
(DSTGG, 2008). Most of the STs recognised in boomed between 1988 and 1992. Land con-
this phase are in the Pearl River Delta (PRD), veyance fees generated by such transactions

406
Industrial policy in China

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/cjres/article-abstract/12/3/401/5581697 by Universidad EAN user on 17 May 2020


Figure 2.  Geographical distribution of specialised towns.
Source: Authors’ elaborations on data from Guangdong Provincial ST Development Promotion Association.

were used for infrastructural financing and to encourage development of lagging areas
upgrading, ending in GDP growth (Ahmad (Barbieri et al., 2012; Sarcina et al., 2014). The
et  al., 2018; Cao and Zhao, 2011). Hence, this new STs were established in the so-called Great
phase of the STs programme served the pro- PRD and on the coast and peripheral areas
motion of industrial growth and upgrading, through 2006 (Figure 2(b)), with rural bases and
while rationalising industrial development mountainous territory through 2009 (Figure
(Barbieri et  al., 2009). The sectoral specialisa- 2(c)). They had different productive peculi-
tion of these first towns reflected the features of arities, such as being focussed on agriculture-
Guangdong’s—and the PRD’s—manufacturing related, resource-based activities or services
systems at the time, mainly based on low-tech (Figure 3).
production (Figure 3). Some official documents12 highlighted the
In the third phase (2003–2008), the STs pro- double path behind the policy implementa-
gramme extended to some non-PRD cities tion of this phase and recognised the strategic
and, along with upgrading, started to be used value of STs in Guangdong’s development

407
Barbieri et al.

100%
5
26 34 56
90%

80%
69

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/cjres/article-abstract/12/3/401/5581697 by Universidad EAN user on 17 May 2020


43
70% 27 64

60%
34 96
50%
39
40% 19
13 46
30% 17
6 62
20% 102
46
10% 9
8 17 29
0% 2
2003 2006 2009 2015

Services Agriculture High-Tech Medium-Tech Low-Tech Resource Based

Figure 3.  Sectoral distribution of specialised towns.


Source: Authors’ elaborations on data from Guangdong Provincial ST Development Promotion Association.

(Barbieri et  al., 2010; Lin, 2006; Su and Sun, 1. to further decentralise the economic man-
2016). They stressed how provincial and local agement of STs to local authorities;
institutions started to collaborate in clus- 2. to optimise the industrial and urban struc-
tering processes to avoid sectoral overlap and ture of STs;
to coordinate the regional innovation system. 3. to restore public accounts and realise infra-
This is reflected also in the establishment of structural investments;
the Guangdong Provincial ST Development 4. to promote quality upgrading of traditional
Promotion Association (POTIC) (Su and Sun, industries and
2016). Furthermore, many of these documents 5. to increase GDP, innovation potential and,
pointed to the diffusion of good practices re- more generally, competitive capacity (Tsai,
lated to knowledge diffusion and protection and 2013).
territorial branding. Finally, they emphasised
collaboration between local actors and univer- Similar to this is the “One Town, One Institute”
sities and research institutions. initiative (2012), aimed at founding a third-
Since 2008, a fourth phase has begun, with level degree institution in each township (Su
a new emphasis on endogenous growth and and Sun, 2016). Finally, the initiatives issued
innovation, in line with the whole change in by the provincial agencies stress two elem-
post-crisis Chinese policy orientation. The ents to empower endogenous sources: (i) pro-
most important measure in this framework is moting micro, small and medium enterprises
the “One Town, One Policy” (2010), incentiv- (SME)  and establishing dedicated public
ising each town to find its own developmental innovation services, and (ii) enhancing the
path while supporting the coordinated eco- quality and innovative performances of those
nomic development of Guangdong Province towns specialised in locally rooted productions
(DSTC, 2011a, 2011b). This implies the fol- (Di Tommaso et  al., 2013; DSTGG, 2017; Su
lowing actions: and Sun, 2016).

408
Industrial policy in China

Nowadays, almost all Guangdong coun- To identify the two groups, we referred to
ties host at least one ST, and while a high Becattini’s (2015) contribution about industrial
number is still in the PRD (particularly in districts as originated by the historical profile of
Dongguan), many others are also localised in the production atmosphere of the hosting areas.

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/cjres/article-abstract/12/3/401/5581697 by Universidad EAN user on 17 May 2020


the north-eastern peripheral prefectures of We classified each township as endogenous
Meizhou and Chaozhou (Figure 2(d)). While if its specialisation had at least one of these
keeping a good proportion of agriculture- features:13
related STs, the sectoral distribution of towns
has changed towards low-, medium- and 1 . rooted in the history of the town;
high-tech specialisation (Figure 3). 2. based on local resources (for example, aqua-
The programme has inspired a 2-fold sec- culture in townships next to water);
toral specialisation of the townships: on the 3. traditional, typical or mainly oriented to-

one hand, the specialisation in resource-based wards national markets (for example, rice
and agriculture-related activities, consistent cookers or pottery);
with the policy’s aim to upgrade trad- 4. derived from a production rooted in town’s
itional production in areas less involved in history (for example, machinery for stones
manufacturing development; on the other, the processing in areas previously used as quar-
growth of mid- to high-tech manufacturing to ries) and
promote technological upgrading and innova- 5. linked to the territory’s physical character-
tive activities in core manufacturing clusters istics (for example, port logistics on coastal
in Guangdong. areas).

Some specific productions [such as Information


Endogenous and exogenous and Communication Technologies (ICT)] are
specialised towns considered per se exogenous, as they stemmed
Notwithstanding the common policy frame- from the activity of foreign actors. Conversely,
work, STs are heterogeneous for size, urban- it is likely that some activities, naturally
isation degree, development period, etc. An oriented to serve the local or national market
in-depth analysis of the townships shows that (as the agriculture related), are automatically
some of them, which we call endogenous, fol- endogenous. Nonetheless, the distinction be-
lowed an industrial development rooted in tween these two groups only partially overlaps
their own economic and cultural history; in with sectoral distribution (Table 1).
some others, which we call exogenous, external Endogenous STs are 209 out of the total 399
forces such as foreign capital and national pol- and have grown since the mid-2000s in cor-
icies triggered their growth. respondence with the shift of policy towards

Table 1.  Sectoral distribution of endogenous versus exogenous specialised towns.

Sectors

Agriculture-related High-tech Low-tech Mid-tech Resource-based Services Total

Endogenous 102 3 37 8 41 18 209


Exogenous 0 43 32 88 15 12 190
Totals 102 46 69 96 56 30 399

Source: Authors’ elaborations.

409
Barbieri et al.

45 PRD Non-PRD
40
35

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/cjres/article-abstract/12/3/401/5581697 by Universidad EAN user on 17 May 2020


30
25
20
15
10
5
0

Shaoguan
Dongguan

Jiangmen

Heyuan

Jieyang

Qingyuan
Foshan

Huizhou (PRD)

Zhaoqing (PRD)

Shantou

Yangjiang
Guangzhou

Huizhou (non-PRD)

Meizhou

Shanwei

Yunfu
Zhanjiang
Zhaoqing (non-PRD)
Zhongshan

Chaozhou
Zhuhai

Maoming
Exogenous STs Endogenous STs

Figure 4.  Geographical distribution of endogenous and exogenous specialised towns, year 2015.
Source: Authors’ elaboration.

endogenous sources (Supplementary Figure 2. RQ2: Can the policy contribute to territorial
A1). Their geographical distribution confirms rebalancing within the province?
different specialisation paths between PRD
and non-PRD (Figure 4). Endogenous town- We use data at the most detailed territorial
ships are mainly concentrated in non-PRD level—that is, counties and districts—which
inner and mountainous areas, testifying to a is yet above the township one. We mainly
larger policymaking investment to promote use panel fixed-effects models to test for
these prefectures by focussing on the local robust correlations between the policy
market and existing productions. The predom- and local economic performance. Given
inance of exogenous specialisation in the PRD, the structure of the data and considering
conversely, clearly indicates its exogenous eco- that policy implementation continuously
nomic growth path, based on foreign capital changes through time and involves the great
and national migrations, although with some majority of Guangdong counties, there are
notable exceptions that founded their eco- obstacles in building proper counterfactuals
nomic growth on traditional productions. to explore causality. 14 However, to address
some causal interpretation, we add a ro-
bustness check based on latest techniques
Empirical analysis to estimate dose-response effects, particu-
We now turn to investigate the two empirical larly fit for analysing non-binary treatments
research questions: as in our case. We use the Cerulli (2015)15
fixed-effect dose-response method, which,
1. RQ1: Is the ST programme associ-
compared with usual General Propensity
ated with improved territorial economic Scores methods (Bia and Mattei, 2008;
performances? Hirano and Imbens, 2004), allows to include

410
Industrial policy in China

non-treated units in the analysis and to con- 3  years.20 Summary statistics for the relevant
sider increasing treatment intensity across variables are in Supplementary Table A1.
time. Our outcome variables are industrial To analyse the association between STs
and agricultural output in county i at time t and territorial rebalancing (RQ2), we divide

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/cjres/article-abstract/12/3/401/5581697 by Universidad EAN user on 17 May 2020


(INDOUTi,t and AGROUT i,t) used as a proxy the counties into four groups (low, medium
of economic performance.16 low, medium high and high) according to the
We test the association of clusters with eco- level of industrial output in 2000 (t0) using the
nomic performances at the local level (RQ1) distribution’s quartiles as thresholds. We ob-
first with panel data fixed effects with robust serve through a fixed-effects panel subgroup
standard errors.17 Our independent variables of analysis whether the effects of SP_TOWN and of
interest are: RATIO_ENDOG is heterogeneous according
to the initial level of local output. Specifically,
1. the number of STs in county i (SP_TOWNi) if we find that the effects are stronger on lower
and than on higher groups, we may conclude that
2. the ratio of endogenous towns on the total STs help territorial rebalancing. We also sup-
number of STs (RATIO_ENDOGi). port these results with the evidence found in
relation to RQ1. We summarise information on
Finally, we introduce the number of full-time the subgroups in Supplementary Table A2.
workers in county i (WORKERSi), to control
for the economic activity, and year dummies.
The variables enter the model with one or The effects of specialised towns and
three lags to account for lagged effects. We also endogenous specialised towns on
perform a subgroup analysis (Boyd-Swan et al. economic performances (RQ1)
2016) to study possible heterogeneous effect Table 2 shows the results of the fixed-effects es-
between PRD and non-PRD areas. timation. For industrial performances for the
We then support the results with the dose- whole sample, there is a positive association
response analysis,18 including the variable of between the ratio of endogenous towns, at t-1,
interest: and industrial output. Additionally, in the PRD,
endogenous towns show positive effects at t-3.
1. as a dummy variable (value = 0 if the unit is For the whole sample, there is also quite robust
not treated and 1 otherwise) and evidence that agricultural output benefits from
2. as intensity of the treatment—the dose— higher levels of endogenous STs 1-year lagged.
normalised in order to range from 0 The gains related to endogenous towns, in this
(minimum dose in the sample) to 100 (max- case, appear to be stronger in non-PRD coun-
imum dose in the sample). ties. In all such cases, there is no observable ef-
fect of specialisation per se.
The latter is assumed to have a parametric Figures 5 and 6 show graphically the results
polynomial form (Cerulli, 2015; Filippetti of the dose-response models (the coefficients
and Cerulli, 2018) that can be investigated are in Supplementary Tables A3 and A4). The
through graphical representation. We run two first focuses on STs total number. Regarding in-
series of models, one for specialized towns dustrial output, both at t-1 and t-3, the response
(SP_TOWNi) and the other for endogenous is (rather) flat or non-significant up to a certain
towns (ENDOGi).19 The outcomes of interest dose of the treatment, and then it increases.
are industrial output (INDOUT) and agricul- The curves shapes for agricultural output are
tural output (AGROUT),  forwarded by 1 and similar, although flatter in correspondence with

411

You might also like