You are on page 1of 8

ARTICLE IN PRESS

Energy Policy 35 (2007) 5901–5908


www.elsevier.com/locate/enpol

A real option analysis of investments in hydropower—


The case of Norway
Frode Kjærland
Bodø Graduate School of Business, Bodø University College, Mørkvedtråkket, Bodø, Norway
Received 25 April 2007; accepted 11 July 2007
Available online 27 August 2007

Abstract

This paper presents a valuation study of hydropower investment opportunities in the Norwegian context. According to NVE
(Norwegian Water Resources and Energy Directorate, the regulator), there is a potential of 39 TWh not yet developed (generation in a
normal year is approximately 120 TWh).
By using the conceptual real option framework of Dixit and Pindyck [1994. Investment Under Uncertainty. Princeton University
Press, Princeton, NJ] one can estimate the value of investment opportunities to NOK 11 million/GWh (EUR 1.4 million/GWh).
Furthermore, the optimal trigger price for initiating an investment based on electricity forward prices is calculated to NOK 0.32/kWh
(EUR 0.04/kWh). The analysis shows consistency between real option theory and aggregate investment behaviour in Norwegian
hydropower.
r 2007 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

Keywords: Real options; Irreversible investments; Hydropower

1. Introduction increase in electricity prices, there is a focus on the


possibility of introducing more electricity generation
Norway is considered as one of the pioneers concerning capacity in Norway. Large-scale hydropower projects are
deregulation of the electricity market by implementing the reckoned as passé, but there is increasing focus on small-
Energy Act (‘‘Law of production, transformation, trans- scale hydropower plants (99% of Norwegian electricity
mission, sale, distribution and use etc.’’ of 29 June 1990, generation is at present hydro). In recent reports from the
no. 50) in 1991, making electricity a competitive commod- Ministry of Petroleum and Energy (2006) and NVE
ity (Al-Sunaidy and Green, 2006). This opened up a (Norwegian Water Resources and Energy Directorate,
profound restructuring of the industry, like separation of the regulator) (2006) the potential of small-scale hydro-
generation and transmission and mergers and acquisitions power plants and improvements and expansion of existing
of companies. An implication of this liberalisation was that plants are estimated to 39 TWh1 in total (Fig. 2). This must
both prices and investment decisions were set by the be viewed as significant even if only parts of this potential
market (Nord Pool was established in 1991, but became a are realistic to develop within the next decade (NVE, 2004).
fully integrated Nordic power exchange for all the Nordic However, it is definitely relevant to ask why more
countries in 2000). There have therefore been considerable projects have not been initiated earlier. The major
challenges in the decisions and timing of new investments explanation is that NVE has limited the availability of
in the uncertain environment of the sector, like highly
1
volatile electricity prices. The numbers of the capacity in TWh are based on years with normal
The investment level in more hydropower capacity has precipitation (middle years). Because of the volatility in amount of
precipitation there are large differences from ‘‘dry’’ years to ‘‘wet’’ years.
been low in the last decade (Fig. 1). Due to a significant This is referred to as a ‘‘theoretical potential’’ (Ministry of Petroleum and
Energy, 2006). The potential is separated as 23.8 TWh concerning new
Tel.: +47 75517856; fax: +47 75517268. small-scale hydropower plants and as 15.2 TWh concerning improvements
E-mail address: Frode.Kjaerland@hibo.no and extensions of existing plants.

0301-4215/$ - see front matter r 2007 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2007.07.021
ARTICLE IN PRESS
5902 F. Kjærland / Energy Policy 35 (2007) 5901–5908

4.00 is involved. This aspect contributes to explain the aggregate


3.50 investment behaviour of hesitance despite an emerging
3.00 shortage of generation capacity.
2.50 The remainder of the paper is organised as follows:
Section 2 gives an introduction of the theoretical frame-
TWh

2.00
1.50 work of Dixit and Pindyck (1994) and a discussion of the
1.00 relevance of this model on investment opportunities in
0.50
Norwegian hydropower. Section 3 describes the applica-
0.00
tion of this model, including a discussion of the input
1989 1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 parameters and the numerical analysis. Section 4 draws the
ear conclusions and implications.
Fig. 1. Hydropower plants under construction 1989–2004 (SSB (Statistics
Norway), 2006). 2. Methodology

The theoretical platform is the model framework of


Hydropower potential (TWh) Dixit and Pindyck (1994). When a firm decides to make an
irreversible investment, it exercises an option. The lost
Not developed; 39
option value is an opportunity cost that must be included
in the assessment of the investment cost, which is an
essential feature in explaining the lack of consistency
Protected; 44,2
Already between neoclassical investment theory and actual invest-
developed; 119,7
ment behaviour (Pindyck, 1991). Permission from the
Approved licenses;
1 regulator is not infinite, but in practice many of the
potential projects do not apply for a licence before they are
Under
economically feasible. It is not unrealistic to assume that a
construction; 1,3
company can postpone the licence application process in
Fig. 2. Hydropower potential in TWh (Ministry of Petroleum and order to consider timing of the investment and hence can
Energy, 2006; NVE, 2006). choose to invest immediately or at an optional time in the
future. New information can then be revealed before
profitable projects (Bye et al., 2003). When prices have commitment of the investment. The time lag from
been relatively low, there have been few projects with investment decision to a plant can generate is though
sufficiently low costs to be implemented. But this does not ignored in this analysis.
give the overall explanation of the low level of investments The basic model of Dixit and Pindyck (1994) is an
(Bye and Hope, 2006). There are a number of factors that extension of the model developed by McDonald and Siegel
influence expectations of electricity prices, making future (1986). One version of this framework is to treat the price
profitability highly uncertain in this industry and hence (P) of the project’s output as a geometric random walk.
holding back investments. This relationship has always The interesting variable is V(P), the value of the project as
been known intuitively, but with the introduction of real a function of P. To obtain this value one can view the
option theory one has a tool for calculating and more project as a set of options (McDonald and Siegel, 1986). In
precisely measuring the impact that uncertainty has on this version of the model, it is also a goal to find a critical
aggregate investment behaviour. This paper applies real P*, where the firm only invests if P4P*.
option theory2 both to assess the value of investment An important assumption for making such an approach
opportunities and to use this powerful tool to find the is whether the stochastic changes in P are spanned with
relation between price level of electricity and optimal existing assets. This assumption means that it has to be
timing of investment decisions. These kinds of investments possible to construct a dynamic portfolio of assets, where
are irreversible. To understand aggregate investment the price perfectly correlates with P. This has been applied
behaviour one has to consider the opportunity cost that on electricity markets by several authors (Deng et al.,
2001). This means that the investment opportunity can be
2 solved by the use of contingent claim valuation (Schwartz,
The value of flexibility, as for instance growth opportunities, is
incorporated in a real option analysis, which by a number of scientists has 1997). One major advantage is that this excludes the
been pointed out as a weakness of traditional NPV analysis (Berkovitch difficult and complex discussion of risk preferences and
and Israel, 2004; Black and Scholes, 1973; Brennan and Schwartz, 1986; discount rates. An additional advantage is that this
Myers, 1987; Pindyck, 1991). These techniques were conventionally excludes the need of any forecast for long-term electricity
developed to value ‘‘passive’’ financial instruments as bonds and stocks prices (Schwartz, 1998).
(Trigeorgis, 1996). Some therefore call NPV a ‘‘naive rool’’ (Milne and
Whalley, 2000) when applied to project and business valuation. Ross There are factors making electricity not comparable to
(1995) even says that ‘‘optionality is ubiquitous and unavoidable’’ most other commodities (Clewlow and Strickland, 2000;
concerning valuation issues. Koekebakker and Sødal, 2001). From the physics of
ARTICLE IN PRESS
F. Kjærland / Energy Policy 35 (2007) 5901–5908 5903

electricity, one can learn that demand and generation must prices that are used in this analysis are the longest contracts
match each other continuously. If not in balance the that can provide reliable data, and thus are the best
transmission network will collapse. Current technology estimates of value of both generation assets-in-place and
gives no possibility of storing electricity.3 This non- investment opportunities.
storability aspect implies that electricity cannot be con- The described modelling implies that hydro generation
sidered a financial asset, eliminating the possibility for the basically behaves like a base load producer. This neglects
traditional arbitrage approach. The implication of this is the flexibility characteristics that are associated with hydro
that a megawatt hour of power cannot be held as an generation, and represents a shortcoming.
investment in a portfolio. Electric power can be neither
borrowed nor shortened, and then bought back and 3. Application of the Dixit and Pindyck model on
returned later. This violates the important spanning Norwegian hydropower investment opportunities
assumption in the Dixit and Pindyck framework, and the
traditional non-arbitrage approach for the valuation of 3.1. Data for applying the model
options. Finance-based asset pricing does therefore not
apply to power spot price dynamics. But efficient markets 3.1.1. Sigma, s
do apply to the pricing of derivatives on power. Therefore s is the standard deviation of the underlying asset. In
this study relates to forward contracts, which not are under this context,it implies that s is the standard deviation of the
the same restrictions. observed forward prices. The forward contract structure at
Because of these special properties of electricity, there Nord Pool has gone through a transition phase. The
are strong reasons for dealing with forward prices directly previous structure was based on the distinction of three
rather than endogenously through spot prices (Koekebak- seasons: winter 1 (1 January–30 April), summer (1 May–30
ker and Sødal, 2001). If one relates to the observed forward September) and winter 2 (1 October–31 December). There
and futures prices one deals with a tradable asset, and does were also year forward contracts. The new forward
not need to struggle with the complicated area of electricity contract structure is based on calendar month, quarter
spot price as a non-asset. While electricity is non-storable, (3 calendar months) and year contracts. This was
forward contracts are. Hence by relating to forward prices, introduced in 2004 (Nord Pool, 2005).
there should be no violation of the essential spanning To obtain an overview of the term structure and
assumption in the Dixit and Pindyck framework. volatility, it should be sufficient to concentrate on the
The model relies on a geometric random walk. This is a tertial/quarterly and yearly contracts. These are the longest
convenient assumption because it yields an analytical contracts that give the most relevant information when the
solution. The modelling of stochastic process is nonetheless purpose is to focus on the valuation of investment
controversial. The recommendation of Ronn (2002) is opportunities. The tertial (from 2004 quarterly) contracts
geometric Brownian motion (GBM) for forward priced- are tradable for the 2 following years after trading, while
based models of electricity prices. the yearly contracts are tradable for 3 years ahead. By
This model is in continuous time. In practice however, analysing these 9/11 contacts one can obtain a term
observed forward prices are restricted to discrete values. structure and a long-time volatility trend.
Nevertheless, the underlying factors in the industry, like the From the FTP server of Nord Pool, one can obtain a
market mechanisms in an industry with many participants, simple descriptive analysis of the tertial, quarterly and
the sensitivity of national reservoir level information and yearly contracts. Since the volatility parameter in GBM is
downpour and temperature forecasts as well as the an annualised volatility, the annualised standard deviations
regulators’ constant monitoring of the industry, are for the price return of the relevant contracts are shown in
continuous in nature. Therefore, it should not be con- Table 1 (from 2004 the prices are in euro. The change into
troversial to apply a continuous time model for the the Norwegian currency has been based on the average
stochastic process of forward electricity prices. currency in the actual year). These numbers reveal the
The value of investment opportunities in hydropower seasonal pattern and also the term structure of the
generation is for obvious reasons strongly related to future volatility (Lucia and Schwartz, 2002; Ronn, 2002). The
expected prices of electricity. Hydropower plants are numbers also reveal an increase in volatility after the shock
normally assumed to last for several decades. Investors winter of 2002–2003.
are thus looking way ahead of 3–4 years’ forward prices The results are consistent with earlier studies (Bjerksund
that can be observed at Nord Pool. However, there is no et al., 2000; Koekebakker and Ollmar, 2005). There is also
efficient market for longer forward prices. The observed consistency with the assumption of Ronn (2002). The
volatility is high for contracts with short time to maturity
3
and is convex decreasing for contracts with longer time to
There are some possibilities of storing. Advanced, expensive technol- maturity. An overall analysis of the development of the
ogies like pumped/storage hydro, high-pressure air facilities and batteries
can convert electricity into potential energy in other forms and convert it forward prices (Fig. 3) shows, however, an increase in both
back. This is, however, a rare opportunity and involves significant loss in price level and volatility level after the winter of 2002–2003.
conversion. This is ignored in the analysis. Overall this gives support to allow the level of s be about
ARTICLE IN PRESS
5904 F. Kjærland / Energy Policy 35 (2007) 5901–5908

20–25% as a base case volatility input parameter in the The P variable should be a measure of the level of
model. In the analysis later in this paper, the starting point forward prices. The choice of this paper is to let P be the
for the calculations is set with a s of 25%. average forward price of the six tertial (eight quarterly) and
3-year ahead forward prices. If one relates to these 9/11
3.1.2. Price, P contracts, one can calculate an average forward price at
s is derived from an analysis of the structure of a each trading day. The development of this representative
portfolio of forward contracts. Hence the P for forward forward price is shown in Fig. 3.
prices, which has to be the X-axes concerning valuation
of the investment opportunities and the trigger for
investments in the Dixit and Pindyck model frame- 3.1.3. Delta, d
work, has to be obtained from the same portfolio of In the theoretical introduction of the Dixit and Pindyck
forward contracts. model, d represented the net marginal convenience yield
from storage. The assumption was that the output was a
storable commodity. As pointed out, this is a complex issue
Table 1 concerning electricity. But in the hydropower-dominated
Average annualised standard deviation on yearly and tertial/quarterly
system of Norway, the water reservoir levels can serve as a
forward contracts 1999–2006
kind of inventory, leading to high reservoir levels
Year Average annualised std. deviation (%) (inventory) in the summer and low levels in the winter
(Fig. 4).
1999 15.0
2000 8.5
The definition of convenience yield is ‘‘the flow of
2001 18.7 services which accrues to the owner of a physical inventory
2002 25.5 but not to the owner of a contract for future delivery’’
2003 38.1 (Brennan, 1991). As already pointed out, electricity has
2004 16.9 some peculiar properties. Because of this some careful
2005 21.1
2006 26.6 considerations should be made. Botterud et al. (2002) point
out that there are asymmetry aspects between the supply

Fig. 3. Development of average forward price (øre/kWh/NOK/MWh), 7 September 1998–27 December 2006.

100
90
80
% of reservoir capacity

2006
70 2005
60 2004
2003
50
2002
40 2001
30 2000
20 1999

10
0
1 4 7 10 13 16 19 22 25 28 31 34 37 40 43 46 49 52
Week

Fig. 4. Reservoir-level statistics, 1999–2006 (NVE, 2007).


ARTICLE IN PRESS
F. Kjærland / Energy Policy 35 (2007) 5901–5908 5905

and demand side of a hydropower-based electricity market. Table 2


Their argument is that there is some flexibility in Relative convenience yield based for the next 2 years quarterly (CY
1q1–CY 2q4) contracts, 2004–2006, and the next 3 years yearly (CY 1–CY
generation, which can be used for profit purposes at price
3) contracts, 2003–2006
peaks in the day-ahead spot market. But the situation is
not the same on the demand side, with limited possibility to Relative Number of Min. Max. Mean Std.
adjust demand according to price level. Therefore, there are convenience observations deviation
strong incentives for a risk-averse demand side to lock in as yield
much as possible of the expected future demand in the Cy 1 993 0.56 0.76 0.0351 0.17191
forward/futures market. This leads to a hypothesis of Cy 2 1001 0.53 0.78 0.0813 0.18509
negative convenience yield consistent with the contango Cy 3 1001 0.50 0.77 0.0894 0.18733
hypothesis. CY 1q1 501 0.73 0.23 0.1946 0.15616
CY 1q2 502 0.53 0.41 0.0190 0.15279
Another aspect is the seasonal influence on the CY 1q3 502 0.48 0.48 0.0671 0.16094
convenience yield. As with spot and forward prices, the CY 1q4 502 0.65 0.40 0.0529 0.18020
convenience yield also varies throughout the year (Gjølberg CY 2q1 752 0.72 0.35 0.1092 0.16757
and Johnsen, 2001). In the winter when reservoir levels are CY 2q2 753 0.48 0.46 0.0768 0.15090
low and hence prices are high, the alternative cost of CY 2q3 753 0.41 0.51 0.1175 0.15044
CY 2q4 753 0.64 0.42 0.0149 0.16191
generation is high, yielding a higher d. In the summer when
reservoir levels are high and hence prices are lower, the d is
lower and assumably negative (Botterud et al., 2002).
The convenience yield is therefore not a constant as the The weighed average of the calculations shown in
Dixit and Pindyck model calls for. However, this is also the Table 2 gives a parameter of d about 2.2%. If one focuses
case for most other commodities. It should not be a serious more on the longest contracts, this would give a slightly
obstacle for the study to assume a constant convenience higher estimate. So for the base case in the analysis, it
yield. The d can be interpreted as an opportunity cost of seems appropriate to set d as 2.5%. This parameter shows
delaying the construction of investment projects. By then the advantage of possessing hydropower in reservoirs
delaying a project, the firm loses a certain time of (as inventory) compared with locked future delivery in
production that could have yielded profit. This can be forward contracts.
termed an opportunity cost of delaying investment projects
for keeping the real option alive. d hence represents the 3.1.4. Risk-free rate, r
level of this opportunity cost. This parameter can be The model only calls for the risk-free rate. This can be
obtained from the average convenience yield for the most determined by 10-year Norwegian Government bonds
recent forward contracts that are included in the analysis.4 (Norges Bank, 2007). The r used in the model is the
However, as shown in Table 5, V(P) is sensitive even with monthly average of these bonds, as the focus is on long-
slight changes in d. term investments. But in Eqs. (1) and (2), the monthly
The formula for measuring the convenience yield, ct,T average 12 months’ interest rate is used (in early 2007 this is
(Pindyck, 2001), over a period t to t+T is approximately 4.5%) (determined by NIBOR, Norwegian
InterBank Offered Rate, Norges Bank, 2007).
ct;T ¼ ð1 þ rT ÞPt  F t;T þ kT , (1)

where Pt is the spot price at time t, Ft,T is the future price 3.1.5. Investment, I
for delivery at time t+T, rT is the risk-free T-period The general picture when examining this sector is the
interest rate and kT is the per unit cost of physical storage. high entry barrier of high investment costs and the
This equation can be proved by normal non-arbitrage relatively low level of variable cost. Concerning invest-
reasoning (Pindyck, 2001). Storage cost is assumed to be ments, the reports from NVE seem to level 3 and
zero in this context (storage costs are vital in a normal 5 NOK/kWh as standard intervals concerning classification
discussion of convenience yield, but storage of forward of the potential new hydropower plants.
contracts seems reasonable to set as zero). The relative According to NVE (2004) reports, there is an overall
convenience yield becomes estimation that the economical limit for investment is
considered as 3 NOK/kWh. This limit has been increased
ct;T since then. An NVE report also shows the increased
¼ ½ð1 þ rT ÞPt   F t;T . (2)
Pt knowledge of small-scale hydropower plants leading to a
significant upside change in potential (NVE, 2005). In this
To obtain a current real option value, the focus is on the
model framework, it therefore seems appropriate to use
latest quarterly and yearly contracts, which determine d. By
these numbers as the investment expenditure in the analysis.
using Eq. (2) one obtains the results shown in Table 2.
4
This parameter is under GBM related to the expected growth in the 3.1.6. Variable cost, c
current estimate of the forward curve P. If one e.g. calls the growth a, we There is low cost in production in this industry. The level
can set that a ¼ rd. of c is dependent on aspects like age, size and complexity
ARTICLE IN PRESS
5906 F. Kjærland / Energy Policy 35 (2007) 5901–5908

(NVE, 2002). An approach for new investments according 400


to the same report is estimating the variable cost as 1% of
350
the investment (excluded financial cost in building period).
This must be considered as extremely low compared with
300
other commodities and industries. Nevertheless, these
estimates can be referred to as maintenance, which would 250
be of no relevance in short-term operating decisions. This is

V(P)
an argument for letting this part of the costs be included in 200
the investments cost (which NVE refers to as ‘‘conserva-
150
tive’’) and letting the c parameter be closer to zero.
100
3.2. Analysis of option value and trigger price
50

The above discussion of parameter values gives a way of σ = 0.25 δ = 0.025 r = 0.045 I = 300 c = 3
0
calculating the option value in this sector according to the 0 2 4 6 8 10 12
following equations in the model framework of Dixit and P
Pindyck (1994):
Fig. 5. Value of investment opportunity as a function of average forward
V ðPÞ ¼ A1 Pb1 if Poc, (3a) price.

V ðPÞ ¼ A2 Pb2 þ P=d  c=r if P  c, (3b) Table 3


Option value as a function of average forward price (s ¼ 0.25, d ¼ 0.025,
where r ¼ 0.045, I ¼ 300, c ¼ 3)

b1 ¼ 1=2  ðr  dÞ=s2 Average forward price (øre/kWh) 15 20 25 30 35 40


Value of option (øre/kWh) 545 742 940 1139 1338 1538
þ f½ðr  dÞ=s2  1=22 þ 2r=s2 g1=2 , ð4aÞ

b2 ¼ 1=2  ðr  dÞ=s2
Table 4
 f½ðr  dÞ=s2  1=22 þ 2r=s2 g1=2 . ð4bÞ Sensitivity analysis of the option value when the d parameter is changed

The constants A1 and A2 are expressed as Average Value of option (øre/kWh) (s ¼ 0.25, r ¼ 0.045,
forward price I ¼ 300, c ¼ 3)
r  b2 ðr  dÞ ð1b Þ (øre/kWh)
A1 ¼ c 1 , (5a) d ¼ 0.01 d ¼ 0.02 d ¼ 0.03 d ¼ 0.04
rdðb1  b2 Þ
20 1937 940 612 454
r  b1 ðr  dÞ ð1b Þ 25 2436 1189 776 575
A2 ¼ c 2 . (5b)
rdðb1  b2 Þ 30 2935 1438 941 698
35 3435 1687 1107 821
Fig. 5 shows the results on the basis of the previously
discussed volatility (s), convenience yield (d), risk-free rate
(r) and investment level of 300 (øre/kWh), and hence (Table 5). A lower d would result in a considerably higher
variable cost 3 (øre/kWh). option value.
P represents the average forward price of the included If a local company then possesses a potential of
forward contracts. The value V(P) is the value of an 100 GWh in its area, this gives a value of NOK 1.1 billion
investment opportunity in øre (0.01 NOK) per kWh. The according to this approach. This can be a qualified estimate
figure shows the significant value this option has depending for the value of the company beyond assets-in-place, and
on the forward price level. A change in input parameter I hence can be an estimate for a bid premium if such a
and hence c, to 500 and 5 as discussed earlier, reveals no company is involved in a merger or an acquisition.5
big difference in the results. What about the optimal timing of investing? The model
The option value of investment opportunities is mainly framework of Dixit and Pindyck (1994) has developed
the intrinsic in-the-money value, close to max{(P/d) the following equation that reveals P* when solved
(c/r);0}. The option value to stop producing when prices numerically:
are decreasing (‘‘time value’’) is low because of the low A2 ðb1  b2 Þ  b2 ðb1  1Þ  c
variable cost (c). ðP Þ þ P   I ¼ 0, (6)
b1 db1 r
With the first set of parameters, at a present (late 2006)
level of forward prices of about 30, this gives an option 5
There are a number of other aspects involved in such an assessment
value of about 11 NOK/kWh (Table 3). This option value such as quota regulations, the relationship with private fall rights owners
is,however, sensitive to changes in both d (Table 4) and s (land owners) and the uncertainty of obtaining permission from NVE.
ARTICLE IN PRESS
F. Kjærland / Energy Policy 35 (2007) 5901–5908 5907

Table 5 2000
Option value as a function of average forward price including different
volatilities as input parameters
1500
Average Value of option (øre/kWh) (d ¼ 0.025, r ¼ 0.045,
forward price I ¼ 300, c ¼ 3) P* = 32.22
(øre/kWh)

F(P), V(P)-I
s¼0 s ¼ 0.20 s ¼ 0.225 s ¼ 0.30 1000

20 733 737 739 749


25 933 936 938 946 500
30 1133 1135 1137 1145
35 1333 1335 1336 1344
0

σ = 0.25 δ = 0.025 r = 0.045 I = 300 c = 3


Table 6
Optimal trigger price for different input parameters -500
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50
I c Sigma, s Delta, d r P* P

300 3 0.25 0.025 0.045 32.22 Fig. 6. Graphical solution of P* with basic parameters.
400 4 0.25 0.025 0.045 42.96
300 3 0.20 0.025 0.045 27.43
300 3 0.225 0.025 0.045 29.74
300 3 0.25 0.03 0.045 33.25 leading to a possible investment decision at some lower
300 3 0.25 0.02 0.045 31.24 trigger price.
300 3 0.25 0.025 0.03 29.52
300 3 0.30 0.02 0.06 35.46 4. Conclusions and implications

This paper has applied the real option model framework


of Dixit and Pindyck (1994) to potential hydropower
where A2, b1 and b2 are defined as in (5b), (4a) and (4b), investments in Norway to quantify the option value and to
respectively. understand the timing and aggregate investment behaviour
With the initial parameters (s ¼ 0.25, d ¼ 0.025, in this industry. The option value is quantified according to
r ¼ 0.045, I ¼ 300, c ¼ 3), this gives a P* according to the input parameters of the model. Option values are a
the equation in the model framework of about 32 øre/kWh. crucial but difficult part of business valuation (Ross, 1995).
The model suggests that the representative forward price The existence of option values is beyond debate, but the
should be at 32 øre/kWh before it is optimal to make an quantification can be complicated. This study uses option
irreversible investment in more hydropower capacity. methodology to estimate the value per kWh of potential
Table 6 shows the effect on P* when different parameters hydropower investments.
are changed, one at time. The results show that the trigger On the basis of reasonable input parameters, the value of
price is sensitive to changes in parameter values. Especially such investment opportunities is calculated to about 11
the trigger price is vulnerable for the level of volatility (s). NOK/kWh or 11 million NOK/GWh. This makes an
One message from a real option approach is that adequate estimate concerning valuation of this potential
uncertainty reduces investment. The increasing level of according to relevant input parameters. This framework
volatility in electricity forward prices increases the option can thereby contribute to assess a bid premium in
value and hence makes investors hesitant due to the high connection with mergers and acquisitions when hydro-
level of the alternative cost in irreversible investments. The power potential is involved. This model framework
model reveals that optimal investment timing is not before establishes a solid foundation for the valuation beyond
the average forward price has exceeded 30 øre/kWh (NOK assets-in-place.
30/MWh). Historically this is a very high level. This level The results shown here can also give one explanation as
has not been reached before late 2005 (see Fig. 4). If the to why there has been a low level of new investments in the
volatility was at 20% (instead of at 25%) the optimal hydropower sector. The nature of investments in more
trigger forward price would be about 27 øre/kWh. hydropower capacity is irreversible, making the option
Fig. 6 shows these results graphically. The tangency component a substantial alternative cost. The analysis
point of F(P) (option value) with V(P)I gives the optimal shows that the implications are that the price level has to be
trigger price for an investment. If there is no volatility, the quite high, way up in the 30s (øre/kWh), before optimal
traditional NPV rule can be applied. For any positive s the investment timing is reached, and the value of the
NPV rule must be modified to include the relevant investment exceeds the projects full cost. This is a price
opportunity cost of the option value. Note that the curves level that has not been seen before late in 2005 (Fig. 3).
are very close from approximately P ¼ 25 and upward, According to SSB (2006) there have in 1994–2004 each year
ARTICLE IN PRESS
5908 F. Kjærland / Energy Policy 35 (2007) 5901–5908

been under construction plants with generation capacity Botterud, A., Bhattacharya, A.K., Ilic, M., 2002. Futures and spot
less than 1.2 TWh (Fig. 2), lower than granted licences and prices—an analysis of the Scandinavian electricity market. Paper
presented at the 34th Annual American Power Symposium (NAPS),
much lower than applied licences. This reality gives support
Tempe, AZ, USA.
to the results of this real option approach. Brennan, M.J., 1991. The price of convenience and the valuation of
The analysis also shows that the s in the model, the commodity contingent claims. In: Lund, D., Øksendal, B. (Eds.),
volatility of the forward price, has a profound impact on Stochastic Models and Option Values. North-Holland, Amsterdam.
the option value and hence the hesitation in making Brennan, M.J., Schwartz, E.S., 1986. A new approach to evaluating
irreversible investments. There have always existed un- natural resources. In: Stern, J.M., Chew, D.H. (Eds.), The Revolution
in Corporate Finance. Blackwell, Oxford.
certainty factors for investor’s in this sector. The un- Bye, T., Hope, E., 2006. Electricity market reform—the Norwegian
certainty has been linked to aspects like demand, experience. In: Sørgard, L. (Ed.), Competition and Welfare—The
international fuel prices, transmission constraints and Norwegian Experience. The Norwegian Competition Authority,
climate. But there seems to be an increase in uncertainty pp. 21–50.
and hence volatility in electricity price development. This Bye, T., von der Fehr, N.-H.M., Riis, C., Sørgard, L., 2003. Kraft og
Makt—en analyse av konkurranseforholdene i kraftmarkedet. Minis-
significant increase in volatility can possibly be linked to a try of Labour and Administration.
number of controversial and partly unsettled political Clewlow, L., Strickland, C., 2000. Energy Derivatives: Pricing and Risk
issues as the possible introduction of green certificates,6 the Management. Lacima Publications, London, UK.
introduction of CO2 allowances, the home fall institute7 Deng, S.-J., Johnson, B., Sogomonian, A., 2001. Exotic electricity options
and the valuation of electricity generation and transmission assets.
and the emerging awareness of low levels of new
Decision Support Systems 30, 383–392.
investments, higher demand and transmission constraints. Dixit, A., Pindyck, R.S., 1994. Investment Under Uncertainty. Princeton
The increase in oil, gas and coal prices is also interfering. University Press, Princeton, NJ.
Anyway, the model shows that by reducing the uncertainty Gjølberg, O., Johnsen, T., 2001. Electricity Futures: Inventories and Price
one can lower the option value (alternative cost) and hence Relationships at Nord Pool. Department of Finance and Management
trigger the investments at a lower price. More stability and Science, Norwegian School of Economics and Business Administra-
tion, Norway.
more predictable framework conditions will thus decrease Koekebakker, S., Ollmar, F., 2005. Forward curve dynamics in the Nordic
the uncertainty and possibly make electricity prices less electricity market. Managerial Finance 31 (6), 72–93.
volatile. This encourages more investments in small-scale Koekebakker, S., Sødal, S., 2001. The Value of an Operating Electricity
hydropower plants and probably other electricity genera- Production Unit. Agder University College.
Lucia, J., Schwartz, E.S., 2002. Electricity prices and power derivatives:
tion facilities.
evidence from the Nordic power exchange. Review of Derivatives
This real option analysis gives deeper insight into a Research 5, 5–50.
controversial issue. An option approach explains invest- McDonald, R., Siegel, D., 1986. The value of waiting to invest. Quarterly
ment behaviour in a way that is not captured by a Journal of Economics 101 (4), 707–727.
neoclassical NPV approach. Even if there are factors in the Milne, A., Whalley, A.E., 2000. ‘Time to build, option value and
application of the Dixit and Pindyck framework that are investment decisions’: a comment. Journal of Financial Economics 56
(2), 325–332.
disputable, the analysis shows that real option theory gives Ministry of Petroleum and Energy, 2006. Fakta 2006 (in Norwegian).
insight into the value of investment opportunities and Myers, S.C., 1987. Finance theory and financial strategy. Midland
aggregate investment behaviour in this industry. Corporate Finance Journal 5 (1), 6–13.
Nord Pool, 2005. Trade at Nord Pool’s Financial Market.
Norges Bank, 2007. NIBOR. From /http://www.norges-bank.no/stat/
References valutakurser/S.
NVE, 2002. Kostnader ved produksjon av kraft og varme.
Al-Sunaidy, A., Green, R., 2006. Electricity deregulation in OECD NVE, 2004. Beregning av potensial for små kraftverk i Norge (No. 19/
(Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development) coun- 2004).
tries. Energy 31 (6–7), 769–787. NVE, 2005. Kraftbalansen i Norge mot 2020 (No. 20/2005).
Berkovitch, E., Israel, R., 2004. Why the NPV criterion does not maximize NVE, 2006. Vannkraftpotensial.
NPV. Review of Financial Studies 17 (1), 239–255. NVE, 2007. Water reservoir statistics. From /http://www.nve.no/
Bjerksund, P., Rasmussen, H., Stensland, G., 2000. Valuation and Risk vannmagtall/vannmagtall98_06.aspS.
Management in the Norwegian Electricity Market. NHH. Pindyck, R.S., 1991. Irreversibility, uncertainty, and investment. Journal
Black, F., Scholes, M., 1973. The pricing of options and corporate of Economic Literature 29 (3), 1110–1148.
liabilities. Journal of Political Economy 81, 637–659. Pindyck, R.S., 2001. The dynamics of commodity spot and futures
markets: a primer. The Energy Journal 22 (3), 1–29.
6
For several years there were expectations of a common Norwegian Ronn, E.I., 2002. Real Options and Energy Management. Risk Books.
Swedish market of green certificates which would make investments in Ross, S.A., 1995. Uses, abuses, and alternatives to the net-present-value
renewable electricity generation like hydropower plants more profitable. rule. Financial Management 24 (3, Autumn), 96–102.
This was abandoned by the Norwegian Government in 2006. Schwartz, E.S., 1997. The stochastic behavior of commodity prices:
7
The home fall institute is founded in the Norwegian legislation of implications for valuation and hedging. Journal of Finance July, 923–973.
possessing and operating hydropower plants. Home fall essentially means Schwartz, E.S., 1998. Valuing long-term commodity assets. Financial
that private owned plants will without compensation be passed over to the Management 27 (Spring), 57–66.
authorities when the licence expires. The length of a licence is 60 years, but SSB (Statistics Norway), 2006. Nyttbar, utbygd og ikkje utbygd vasskraft
will possibly be 75 years. There has been considerable dispute on this issue etter fylke. 2003 og 2004. GWh.
since 2001, especially whether publicly owned plants should also be under Trigeorgis, L., 1996. Real Options: Managerial Flexibility and Strategy in
the same legislation. Resource Allocation. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA.

You might also like