You are on page 1of 48

Journal of Economic Literature 2011, 49:4, 1152–1199

http:www.aeaweb.org/articles.php?doi=10.1257/jel.49.4.1152

Economic Liberalization and


Indian Economic Growth:
What’s the Evidence?
Ashok Kotwal, Bharat Ramaswami, and Wilima Wadhwa*

India’s growth and poverty performance over the last three decades has been a subject
of great curiosity. Unlike the East Asian countries, India’s growth spurt is not associ-
ated with exceptionally high domestic savings or foreign capital inflows or manufac-
turing exports. So what triggered the change in the growth trajectory? Did the market
liberalization policies of the 1990s help? How have the initial conditions shaped the
process? And how has the “Indian model” impinged on India’s central problem of
mass poverty? This paper surveys the literature and offers its own assessment of the
drivers of change. (JEL I32, O13, O14, O15, O21, O47)

1.  Introduction policy changes in diverse sectors all aimed at


opening up the economy to greater private

B y the end of the 1970s, India had


acquired a reputation as one of the most
protected and heavily regulated economies
sector entrepreneurship as well as to foreign
trade and investment.
These two decades (1980–2000) have been
in the world. Starting in the mid-1970s and quite special in the course of Indian eco-
then later on in the 1980s, a few tentative nomic development. The growth rate of gross
steps were taken to liberalize the regulatory domestic product (GDP), which had stayed
regime. More extensive reforms followed in around 3.5 percent per annum for twenty
1991. Since then, there have been further years prior to 1980, shot up to about 5 percent

* Kotwal: University of British Columbia. Ramaswami:


Indian Statistical Institute. Wadhwa: Indian Statistical Iyer, Ashwini Kulkarni, Annemie Maartens, Srijit Misra,
Institute and ASER Centre. This paper was written at the Milind Murugkar, Dilip Nachane, Manoj Panda, Arvind
Indian Statistical Institute, New Delhi. Kotwal’s stay at the Panagariya, Avinash Paranjape, K. V. Ramaswamy, Mar-
Indian Statistical Institute was made possible by the gener- tin Ravallion, Mark Rosenzweig, M. R. Saluja, Kunal Sen,
ous support of the Indo–Canadian Shastri Institute and the Nirvikar Singh, E. Somanathan, Rohini Somanathan, and
Indian Statistical Institute. The project has also been gener- Rajendra Vaidya. We are grateful for comments received
ously supported by a MCRI Grant by SSHRC (Canada). We from participants of seminars at the University of Mel-
are grateful for fruitful discussions with Siwan Anderson, bourne, the University of Adelaide, the University of Auck-
Pulapre Balakrishnan, Laveesh Bhandari, Pratap S. Birthal, land, and Clare­mont McKenna College. We would also like
Satya Das, Patrick Francois, Subhashish ­Gangopadhyay, to thank Roger Gordon and four anonymous referees for
Chetan Ghate, B. N. Goldar, Tim Hazeldine, Lakshmi their very helpful suggestions.

1152
Kotwal, Ramaswami, and Wadhwa: Economic Liberalization and Indian Economic Growth 1153

in the 1980s (1980 to 1989), and increased questions and come up with a plausible story
further in the 1990s (1990 to 1999) to 6 per- of Indian development during the period of
cent.1 Over the last few years, it has reached 1980–2004.
as high as 9 percent. Moreover, the growth in India makes a fascinating case study. On
the postreform period has also been stable. the face of it, the improved growth perfor-
In the decade of the 1970s, the variance in mance in India seems to have been achieved
GDP growth rate was 15.8. It came down to by following the orthodox prescription of
4.6 in the 1980s (i.e., 1981–82 to 1990–91) removing the constraints on entrepreneur-
and further down to 1.5 in the 1990s (1992– ship. However, Indian economic growth,
2002) (Arvind Panagariya 2004).2 during 1980–2004, seems to have little in
Most importantly, GDP growth has been common with the so-called “Asian Model.”
accompanied by a poverty decline. The pro- Its savings rate has improved over time but
portion of the population below the pov- has not reached the East Asian level.4 Its
erty line (at $1.08 a day in 1993 PPP USD) growth so far has not been driven by manu-
declined from about 44.5 percent in 1983–84 factured exports. Nor has it attracted mas-
to 27.5 percent in 2004–05.3 Consequently, sive inflows of foreign investment. There is
India’s growth performance has generated no industrial policy targeted toward develop-
tremendous worldwide interest as attested ing specific industries. On the contrary, it is
by the titles of a spate of new books on India: the service sector that has led the charge in
India’s Emerging Economy (Kaushik Basu the Indian growth experience. Another aspect
2004), India: Emerging Power (Stephen of the Indian experience that makes it very
P. Cohen 2001), India Arriving (Rafiq different from that of other Asian countries
Dossani 2008), India: The Emerging Giant is that, despite a fast growing nonagricultural
(Panagariya 2008), and Propelling India part of the economy, the share of agriculture in
(Arvind Virmani 2006). the total labor force has declined very slowly.
The fast and stable growth accompanied In fact, the agricultural labor force in abso-
by a decline in poverty has also raised many lute numbers has increased since the 1980s,
questions: What triggered growth in India? dampening the process of poverty decline.
What is the Indian model? Is it replicable Why do we expect economic liberalization
in other developing countries? Is it sustain- to produce growth? First, import liberaliza-
able? How does it compare with the East tion provides domestic firms access to capital
Asian model in its growth as well as dis- equipment embodied with new technolo-
tributional consequences? How does the gies, better intermediate inputs and expands
growth process impinge on India’s central their choice set to act. A freedom to invest
problem—its mass poverty? Our objective in and enter the market increases the extent
this paper is to take stock of what progress of competition and puts pressure on the
the literature has made in answering these incumbents to upgrade their technologies,
often through imported machinery. With
1 GDP is measured on a rainfall corrected basis. the entry of new firms in a more competitive
(Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Develop- market, the process of creative destruction
ment 2007, table 1.3, p. 31).
2 A corroborative account can be found in Ajit Sinha and
Shirin Tejani (2004).
3 According to the latest revised estimates based on new 4 Gross domestic savings as a percentage of gross
purchasing power poverty norms released by the World national income rose steadily from 15.1 percent in the
Bank, at the poverty rate of $1.25 (2005 PPP) a day, the 1960s to 32.1 percent in 2004, while total capital formation
poor as a share of the total population went down from 59.8 rose from 16.9 percent to 33.2 percent (Barry Bosworth,
percent in 1981 to 41.6 percent in 2005. Susan M. Collins, and Virmani 2007).
1154 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XLIX (December 2011)

goes to work. Efficient firms drive out inef- Section 7 discusses the role of agriculture
ficient firms, factors gets reallocated to more in the growth and poverty decline process.
productive use, and the overall productivity Section 8 concludes by examining vari-
of factors in the economy increases. Due ous hypotheses proposed in the literature
to technology transfer, productivity in the to explain different aspects of the pattern of
industry and service sectors grows rapidly Indian growth experience since 1980 with
and attracts labor from agriculture. The real- a view to piece together a coherent story
location of labor from agriculture to more about the movement of the Indian economy
productive sectors contributes further to from 1980 to 2004. Given the quality of
growth. This process also makes the workers the available data and the usual difficulties
left behind in agriculture better-off because in establishing causality, the story can only
the real wage rises as labor markets tighten be suggestive. Hopefully, it will throw up
in agriculture. Is this what has been happen- hypotheses spurring further research.
ing in India? One might think so. But do we
see this in the data? These are the motivating
2.  Why Disaggregation is Necessary:
questions for this paper.
The Unorganized Sector
We highlight the structural features of the
economy that are relevant for thinking about In a handbook chapter titled “Growth
the growth process at work in India in sec- Theory through the Lens of Development,”
tion 2. We argue that these features justify Abhijit V. Banerjee and Esther Duflo (2005)
attention toward a disaggregated picture of argue against the aggregate production
the Indian economy. approach of growth theory to study develop-
We outline the main constraints on entre- ment. They point out that such an approach
preneurs in the prereform period and the presumes well-functioning and complete
most significant of the reform measures that markets while underdevelopment is synony-
loosened them in section 3. mous with underdeveloped markets. Those
In section 4, we present the growth perfor- with potentially high returns to capital may
mance of the Indian economy (at the aggre- not have access to credit. Wage gaps can per-
gate level) over the last four decades and the sist for a long time among workers with the
debate about what may have triggered the same human capital across different occupa-
growth acceleration in the 1980s. tions or different industries. For instance,
Sectoral growth rates of output and even illiterate farmers growing food staples
employment (agricultural, industry, and ser- can earn much higher incomes in horticul-
vices) are compared across sectors and time ture or animal husbandry but do not do so
periods in section 5. This section also pur- because of lack of access to credit or infor-
sues the impact of economic reforms on the mation. Workers with higher education may
manufacturing and services sector. It lays out command considerably higher salaries and
the pattern of growth in the Indian economy yet very few from amongst the poor are
and the features that distinguish it from able to acquire higher education. Wage gaps
other countries. The section also attempts to can persist across different states without
answer the question of why the fast growth generating a substantial migration perhaps
in GDP in India has not been accompanied because of ethnic and linguistic gaps. In
by fast growth in employment. such an economy, the constraints on entre-
In section 6, we examine how the growth preneurial freedom can stem not just from
process in India impinges on poverty decline government overregulation but also from the
in the economy. lack of well-functioning markets and other
Kotwal, Ramaswami, and Wadhwa: Economic Liberalization and Indian Economic Growth 1155

Table 1
Organized versus Unorganized Manufacturing

Organized manufacturing Unorganized manufacturing


Year 1999–2000 2000–2001
Total number of enterprises (million) 0.13 17
Total number of workers (million) 6.2 37
Average enterprise size (number of workers) 52 2.2
Annual wages per worker (Rupees) 44,842 4,087
Total loans outstanding (Rupees billion) 25,132 868
Value of output (Rupees billion) 87,391 18,718

Source: Nilachal Ray (2004).

institutions. Reforms that get rid of overreg- Table 1 compares the organized and unor-
ulation will set free those who have access to ganized sectors of manufacturing at the
the requisite factors. They will contribute to end of the 1990s. In terms of enterprises
growth in a significant way but those lacking and workers, most manufacturing is carried
in access will not participate in this growth. out in the unorganized sector. On the other
These observations of Banerjee and Duflo hand, the organized manufacturing sector
are relevant because a distinctive feature of accounts for most of the output and credit.
the structure of the Indian economy is the In carrying over the distinction based on
predominance of small production units, enterprise size to the rest of the economy,
including household enterprises. Under the government statistics on employment define
law, factories greater than a certain size have the organized sector as all establishments
to register themselves with the government belonging to the government (and the public
and are subject to the Factories Act, which sector) and all nonagricultural establishments
regulates safety, health, and work hours of in the private sector employing ten or more
employees at the workplace. This regulation persons. The rest constitute the unorganized
does not apply to factories that either employ sector. The national survey on employment
fewer than ten workers or employ fewer than estimated total employment at 457 million in
twenty workers and do not use electricity 2004–05. Of this organized sector, employ-
in the manufacturing process. The facto- ment is about 27 million, i.e., about 6 per-
ries not under the purview of the Factories cent of the total.6 Virtually all employment
Act are called unregistered or unorganized in agriculture is within the unorganized
manufacturing, while those subject to the sector. But even if agriculture is excluded,
law are called registered or organized sector unorganized sector employment is as much
manufacturing.5 as 83 percent of all nonfarm employment.

6 A different survey-based estimate pegs the organized


5 Subsequent to registration under the Factories Act, sector employment (in 1999–2000) higher at 54 million—
some firms may shrink to less than ten workers. However, i.e., about 14 percent of total employment (National
they continue to be classified as part of the registered man- Commission for Enterprises in the Unorganized Sector
ufacturing sector. 2008). The proportion is about the same for 2004–05.
1156 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XLIX (December 2011)

In terms of value-added, the unorganized to improve its technology rapidly while the
sector contributes 58 percent of national unorganized sector does not?
domestic product and 45 percent of nonfarm New imported technology is likely to be skill
domestic product (Kolli and Hazra, cited in intensive. The investment in new technology
National Commission for Enterprises in the is thus associated with an increased demand
Unorganized Sector 2008). for skilled workers driving their wages up.
If liberalization led India to switch to a Through collective bargaining, the wages of
higher growth path, the conduit is likely to the unskilled workers in the organized sectors
have been technology transfers from devel- may also rise. But how would the majority of
oped countries. Firms can import capital the workforce employed in the unorganized
equipment and intermediate inputs that sector benefit from reforms? There are sev-
they did not have access to earlier. Having eral possible channels. First, the part of the
access to foreign technology and equip- unorganized sector that is able to absorb new
ment, and the freedom to use it, would give technology benefits directly. For example, it
Indian firms an opportunity to first jump the is possible that even small units benefit from
technology gap and then grow at the rate at improved communications such as due to cell
which total factor productivity (TFP) grows phones. Second, cheaper products from the
in the developed world. However, in the con- organized sector increase the real wage of the
text of a large part of the economy being in workers in the unorganized sector who con-
the unorganized sector, the question arises sume these products. Third, the increased
whether such small firms also had access to incomes of those employed in the organized
superior technology. If not, how could they sector may spill over into demand for goods
have gained from reform measures? and services produced by the unorganized
Banerjee and Duflo (2004) have shown sector. The strength of this “trickle down”
that Indian bank managers show an abnormal effect would depend on the income elastic-
amount of risk aversion in lending to even ity of the relatively better off for the unorga-
medium-sized firms. Many firms do not get nized sector goods and services. The parts of
adequate credit (i.e., the marginal product of the unorganized sector for which the income
capital exceeds the interest rate) and capital elasticity is relatively high (e.g., trade, con-
does not get channeled to where it could be struction, and transportation) would grow
best used. It is possible that this is so because relatively fast. Note, however, that the growth
of the existing incentive structure for the bank in this case may not be associated with TFP
managers. Whatever the reason, the point to growth; all inputs could increase as demand
note is that, if this is what medium-sized firms grows. However, even such a growth process
have to face, how difficult it must be for tiny in the unorganized sector will draw labor from
units in the unorganized sector to get cred- the less productive sectors—especially “crop
it.7 A credit constrained unorganized sector agriculture.” And moving labor to a sector
may therefore not be able to take advantage with higher productivity makes a contribution
of superior technology available off the shelf. to the overall growth in the economy. In fact,
What is likely to be the pattern of growth in an for a developing country with a large share of
economy where the organized sector ­manages its labor force in agriculture, this is a major
source of growth. If all the above channels
are weak and if the growth is largely confined
7 Priority sector lending—a government initiative that
to the organized sector, the economy can still
required nationalized banks to lend a certain proportion of
their deposits to the rural and small scale sector was moti- grow rapidly because the organized sector still
vated by the desire to overcome this problem. accounts for 42 percent of the value added
Kotwal, Ramaswami, and Wadhwa: Economic Liberalization and Indian Economic Growth 1157

Table 2
Effective Rates of Protection for Manufactured Goods (percent)

Industry group 1980–85 1986–90 1991–95 1996–2000


Intermediate inputs 147 149 88 40
Capital goods  63  79 54 33
Consumer goods 102 112 81 49

Source: Das (2007).

but it will have little impact on employment before 1991.9 There were four major ele-
and hence on poverty. ments of the prereform regime that were
This is why we need to examine the dis- addressed by the reforms starting in 1991:
aggregated picture. What processes were (1)  Restrictions, in the form of tariff and
unleashed by the reform measures that nontariff barriers on imports. Import duties
would move labor to more productive activi- were among the highest in the world and rates
ties? What are the skill intensities in the above 200 percent were common (Ahluwalia
organized and unorganized sectors? What 1999). Table 2 displays the effective rates of
was the impact on unskilled employment? protection for the period 1980–2000. There
What is happening to the structure of the is a clear fall in the level of protection in the
labor force? Is the educational system trans- 1990s. The tariff revenue relative to import
forming unskilled labor into skilled labor at a values fell from over 55 percent in the late
fast enough rate? 1980s to about 22 percent by the end of the
An important caveat to our observations 1990s and to close to 10 percent in 2005
(and a challenge to subsequent analysis) is (Organisation for Economic Co-operation
that the output statistics on the unorganized and Development 2007).
sector suffer from incomplete coverage, indi- Nontariff barriers worked through import
rect estimation methods, frequently outdated licenses that automatically restricted the
benchmark surveys, and unknown biases (C. amount that could be imported. Items that
Rangarajan 2001; S. L. Shetty 2007). could be imported without a license were
placed under the Open General License
(OGL). Table 3, from D. K. Das (2007),
3.  The License–Permit–Quota Raj and
displays the percentage of imports that
Economic Reforms8
were subject to nontariff barriers over the
The “license–permit–quota raj” is a short- period 1980–2000. Like tariffs, the nontrade
hand description of the licenses and quotas barriers also began to fall in the 1990s. The
that characterized Indian economic policies import restrictions were first removed for

8 There is a great deal of literature that documents drawn from the literature, it is not comprehensive but is
the License Raj and the subsequent reforms in detail. rather meant to give the reader a basic understanding of
Some of these references include Montek S. Ahluwalia the restrictions on Indian entrepreneurs and the scope of
(1999), Ahluwalia (2002), Basu (2004), Organisation for the reforms.
Economic Co-operation and Development (2007), Vijay 9 The phrase was coined by C. Rajagopalachari, a one-
Joshi and I. M. D. Little (1996), Panagariya (2008), Kirit time political colleague and contemporary of Nehru, to
S. Parikh (2006), and Virmani (2007). While this section is convey his distaste for state planning mechanisms.
1158 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XLIX (December 2011)

Table 3
Percent of Manufactured Imports Subject to Nontariff Barriers

Industry group 1980–85 1986–90 1991–95 1996–2000


Intermediate inputs 98 98 42 28
Capital goods 95 77 20  8
Consumer goods 99 88 46 33

Source: Das (2007).

the capital goods and intermediate goods was first lifted to 51 percent in 1991 and later
sector in 1992. The quantitative restrictions to 100 percent in most sectors. In addition,
on consumer goods were lifted only in 2000. sectors such as mining, banking, insurance,
Despite the fall in both tariffs and nontariff telecommunications, airlines, ports, roads
barriers, import penetration rates increased and highways, and defense equipment were
substantially only in the second half of the opened up to FDI.
1990s (Das 2007). Restrictions on the domestic sector were
Although the data in tables 2 and 3 show implemented via investment licensing by
substantial trade liberalization only in the which central government permission was
1990s, it has been pointed out that some needed for investment by incumbents as well
amount of loosening occurred in the 1980s as by prospective entrants. In addition, indus-
as well. The OGL, which was introduced trial groups that were designated as “large”
in 1976, contained only 79 capital goods in could not expand without permissions that
1976. By 1988, it covered 1,170 capital goods had to be obtained under the Monopolies
and 949 intermediate inputs. By 1990, about and Restrictive Trade Practices (MRTP) Act.
30 percent of imports happened through the Some industry segments were “reserved” for
OGL route (Panagariya 2008). production by small-scale units to protect
The import policy in the prereform regime them from competition from large-scale units.
was supported by a policy of fixed exchange Price and distribution controls were often
rates and administrative allocations of for- applied to industries such as steel, cement,
eign exchange. The reforms of 1991 led to fertilizers, petroleum, and pharmaceuticals.
a transition to market determined exchange Selective exemptions from industrial
rates that came into being in 1993. The rupee licensing were granted even before 1991.
became convertible on the current account In 1975 and then again in 1980, auto-
in 1994 (Virmani 2007). Restrictions on capi- matic expansion of capacity and changes in
tal transactions, however, remain. product mix were allowed to some indus-
(2)  Restrictions on both the domestic and tries. In 1985–86, further reform mea-
foreign private sector. Restrictions on the sures were undertaken under Rajiv Gandhi
latter took the form of prohibition of foreign (Prime Minister between 1984 and 1989):
direct investment (FDI) in many sectors of broadbanding of licenses by allowing firms
the economy. Where it was allowed, foreign to switch between similar product lines, deli-
equity in a company was capped at 40 per- censing of thirty industries, further relaxation
cent. Permission was essential for higher of capacity constraints for larger firms, and
stakes. The threshold level of foreign equity raising of the ceiling on the asset size in plant
Kotwal, Ramaswami, and Wadhwa: Economic Liberalization and Indian Economic Growth 1159

and machinery of small scale enterprises The driving principle of the License Raj
(Panagariya 2008, p. 83). And of course, in regime was “self-reliance.” This meant that
1991, there was comprehensive delicensing anything that could be produced at home
and, by the end of the 1990s, approval was should not be imported irrespective of the
only required for investment in certain sec- cost. Consequently, strong incentives were
tors such as alcohol, tobacco, and defense- given to capital-intensive industrial sectors
related industries. The 1991 reforms also did where India had no comparative advantage.
away with special permission needed under The policy also had implications for the
the MRTP for large industrial houses. On educational priorities. Educational expendi-
the other hand, “dereserving” the industries ture was heavily biased toward postsecond-
set aside for small enterprises proceeded at ary education rather than toward primary
a slower pace and it was only in 2002 that education and mass literacy. As we will see
industry reservations were reduced substan- later, this lopsided educational structure
tially. The early 1990s also saw the abolition happened to play an important role in the
of price controls in several industries includ- mid-1990s in the surprising development
ing iron and steel, coal, and phospatic and of the software and other high-tech sec-
potassic fertilizers. tors in India. However, the undesirable
(3) State control of banking and insur- consequence was perhaps the disappoint-
ance. Fourteen leading private banks were ing development of India’s labor-intensive
nationalized in 1969 and six more banks manufacturing sector.
were also taken over by the state in 1980.
This was accompanied by a strategy of mas-
4.  Growth Acceleration
sive expansion of the banking network espe-
cially into rural unbanked locations, targets Figure 1 presents five-year averages of
for lending to “underbanked” sectors, such annual GDP growth rates from 1951 to
as agriculture, and extensive regulation of 2004.10 Except for the period 1960–64 when
interest rates. In addition, bank deposits average GDP growth is just below 5 per-
were substantially preempted by the state cent, the period from 1951–79 saw average
in the form of stiff stipulations on invest- growth rates of less than 4 percent. In the
ment in government securities. Through period since 1980, however, the economy
the 1990s, reforms have sought to dilute or has shifted to a higher growth path. Five-
reverse these policies. In addition, bank- year average growth rates are higher than 5
ing licenses were granted to several private percent in each of the subperiods. During
players. the entire period, GDP declined on three
(4)  Public sector monopolies. In the pre- occasions—1957, 1965, and 1979. Such
1991 policy regime, eighteen important contractions have not been observed in the
industries, including iron and steel, heavy post-1980 period.11
plant and machinery, telecommunications The growth acceleration can also be seen
and telecom equipment, mineral oils, min- from figure 2. In this figure (inspired by J.
ing of various ores, air transport services,
and electricity generation and distribution, 10 The first period is the four year period of 1951–54.
were reserved for the public sector. With 11 The growth in the period up to 1980 was itself
reforms, sectors reserved for public sector substantially higher than that achieved during the previ-
enterprises were reduced to atomic energy, ous half-century (Pulapre Balakrishnan 2007; Panagariya
2008). But it is the growth acceleration around 1980 that
defense aircrafts and warships, and railway has received recent attention from scholars and others and
transport. which is of interest to us.
1160 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XLIX (December 2011)

6
Rate of growth of GDP (percent)

0
1950–54 1955–59 1960–64 1965–69 1970–74 1975–79 1980–84 1985–89 1990–94 1995–99 2000–04
Year

Figure 1. Growth in GDP, 1950–2004

Source: Authors’ calculations using National Accounts Statistics.

Bradford DeLong 2003), GDP per capita is Balakrishnan and M. Parameswaran (2007)
plotted for the period 1951–2005 together also used the Bai and Perron procedure and
with the trend line in this variable from the they too locate a single structural break in
period 1951–80. The departure from the GDP in 1978–79. The authors also estimate
trend is clearly visible in the early 1980s. structural breaks for sectoral GDP. Their
Formal econometric tests also indicate principal finding is that a structural break
a structural break around 1980. Using an in agricultural output occurs in the mid-
F-test, Jessica Seddon Wallack (2003) finds 1960s while it occurs in the early to mid-
the highest value of the F-statistic in 1980. 1970s for various subsectors of services.12
Dani Rodrik and Arvind Subramanian
(2004) use a procedure of Jushan Bai 12 They find multiple structural breaks for the service
and Pierre Perron (1998, 2003) and they subsectors including in the late 1950s or early 1960s and
report a single structural break in 1979. as well in the 1990s.
Kotwal, Ramaswami, and Wadhwa: Economic Liberalization and Indian Economic Growth 1161

280

240

Actual
200
Per capita GDP, 1980=100

160

120
Trend

80

40
1955 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005
Year

Figure 2. Growth Acceleration in GDP since the 1980s

Source: Authors’ calculations using National Accounts Statistics.

On the other hand, the first positive struc- Is the timing of the structural break impor-
tural break in manufacturing occurs after tant? The discussion in the l­iterature about
the GDP break in 1982–83. the structural break takes place in the belief
Basu (2008) and Kunal Sen (2007), how- that it could offer clues about what policies
ever, point out that GDP fell by 5.2 per- led to the shift in the economy’s growth rate.
cent in 1979–80 (due to a combination of Such inference is problematic because statis-
a drought and the second oil price shock). tical methods alone are unlikely to provide a
If this outlier is disregarded, then the precise timing. Judgments about outliers, the
trend break occurs in 1975–76. The aver- period of analysis, and the sectors that are con-
age annual growth rate during the period sidered matter. An additional complication is
1975–78 is 5.8 percent—a rate more in line that policy measures do not have instanta-
with the post-1980 experience than with the neous results. The delay would be ­especially
earlier period. pronounced if the benefits flow from a
1162 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XLIX (December 2011)

structural change. It is therefore unwise this period is excluded, the average eco-
to correlate the changes in economic vari- nomic growth during 1981–88 is 4.8 per-
ables to the policy changes that immediately cent—a rate that is higher than growth in
preceded them. These caveats notwithstand- earlier periods but much lower than the
ing, the economy does seem to have moved rate in the post-1991 period.
to a higher growth trajectory sometime in the
4.2 Fiscal Expansion
mid to late 1970s or early 1980s, well before
the economic reforms of 1991.What could The period from 1984 to 1991 saw large fis-
have triggered the growth acceleration in the cal deficits as government debt (internal and
1980s (or earlier) when extensive reforms external) ballooned. By 1990–91, the gross
such as the abolition of the industrial licens- fiscal deficit stood at 10 percent of GDP (not
ing system and trade liberalization happened including the losses of public sector enter-
only in 1991 and later? If liberalization leads prises). Interest payments rose from 2 percent
to growth because it encourages competition of GDP and 10 percent of government expen-
and entrepreneurship, then what about the diture in 1980–81 to 4 percent of GDP and 20
1980s when reforms were so minimal that percent of government expenditure in 1990–
the business environment of entrepreneurs 91. Joshi and Little (1994), T. N. Srinivasan
was hardly much freer than in the earlier and Suresh D. Tendulkar (2003), Nirupam
two decades. Yet the average annual growth Bajpai and Jeffrey D. Sachs (1999) among
rate from 1980–81 to 1990–91 was not others have pointed to fiscal expansion as a
much different from that between 1991–92 cause of unsustainable growth in the 1980s.
and 2004–05 (5.8 percent and 6.1 percent Rodrik and Subramanian (2004) accept that
respectively). What was driving growth in the the fiscal stimulus could have led to greater
1980s? This is the puzzle, and the debate on demand for domestic goods and services and
Indian economic growth has thrown up vari- hence economic growth but argue that this
ous explanations. does not explain the sustained rise in TFP that
is also observed during this period (Bosworth,
4.1 Creeping Liberalization
Collins, and Virmani 2007).
Panagariya (2008) argues that policies
4.3 Changing Attitudes
in the period since 1975 were marked by
a gradual retreat from the closed econ- For Rodrik and Subramanian (2004), the
omy license raj model. The rigors of the minor reforms of the 1980s were impor-
industrial licensing system were moder- tant for what they signaled—an “attitudi-
ated by policies in 1975, 1976, 1980, and nal change” on the part of the government
1984. Similarly, import controls on capital in favor of private business. They date
goods and on imports by exporters were this change to 1980 when Indira Gandhi
made easier. These reforms were piece- returned to a second stint as Prime Minister
meal and limited compared to what came after losing power in 1977. As evidence,
later in 1991. Yet, Panagariya contends that they show that states where governments
they lifted business activity but in a mod- were allied with the central government
est manner appropriate to the piecemeal grew faster than other states—a pattern not
nature of reforms. In particular, he argues found in earlier periods. However, this find-
that the impressive growth performance of ing could be consistent with other explana-
the 1980s stems only from the three-year tions as well—for instance when some states
period from 1988–89 to 1990–91 when are favored over others for infrastructure
­economic growth averaged 7.6 percent. If investment.
Kotwal, Ramaswami, and Wadhwa: Economic Liberalization and Indian Economic Growth 1163

Table 4
Saving and Investment as a Percentage of GDP, 1950–2004

Period Savings Gross capital formation


1950–54  9.63 10.01
1955–59 11.16 13.89
1960–64 12.96 15.18
1965–69 13.97 15.60
1970–74 16.89 17.50
1975–79 21.11 21.30
1980–84 19.69 21.49
1985–89 22.12 25.75
1990–94 24.63 26.23
1995–99 25.77 26.79
2000–03 30.32 29.50

Source: Authors’ calculations using National Accounts Statistics.

But if attitudes were so important, why 1970s. Public savings also rise in the 1970s but
did such small changes lead to big shifts the overall rise in the savings rate is driven by
in growth? Here Rodrik and Subramanian household savings. However, the methodol-
draw on a cross-country regression of per ogy of computing savings in India is such that
capita income on its “deep” determinants— household savings is estimated as a residual
namely measures of geography, openness, and therefore contains the errors and omis-
economic or political institutions (but not sions in the other components. Therefore the
both). They show that India is an outlier in composition of savings is much less certain
the sense that India’s income was about a than the overall trend in savings.
quarter of what it should be given its eco- Basu and Annemie Maertens (2007) con-
nomic institutions. India is even more of jecture that this could have been because
an underachiever with respect to political of nationalization of major banks in 1969.
institutions. Its income is only about 15 per- Between 1971 and 1981, the number of
cent of what is predicted by the regression. bank branches nearly tripled. The popula-
By unleashing the “animal spirits” of the tion per bank branch declined from 65,000
private sector and by exploiting the qual- in 1969 to 15,000 in 1984. Prema-chandra
ity of its existing institutions, the attitudinal Athukorala and Sen (2002) estimate that a 1
change was enough to shift the economy percent increase in bank density resulted in
closer to the efficiency frontier. a 0.03 percent increase in the private saving
rate.13 A related study is by Robin Burgess
4.4 Savings and Investment
and Rohini Pande (2005), who argue that
Table 4 displays five-year averages of sav-
ings and investment rates over the period
13 The increase in bank branches is also associated with
1950–2004. In the 1970s, the savings rate
an increase in bank deposits as a percentage of national
jumped up substantially. Figure 3 shows income (from 15.2 percent to 37.9 percent of national
household savings taking off in the early income).
1164 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XLIX (December 2011)

0.30

0.25

0.20
Saving as a proportion of GDP

0.15

Household

0.10

Public
0.05

0.00
Private corporate

−0.05
1950 1955 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000
Year

Figure 3. Sectoral Saving Rates, 1950–2004

Source: Authors’ calculations using National Accounts Statistics.

the branch expansion did in fact decrease The rise in the savings rate is closely
rural poverty. From 1977 to 1991, the cen- matched by the rise in investment rates. Gross
tral bank (Reserve Bank of India) followed capital formation rises from 15.6 percent of
a policy that forced banks to favor branch GDP during the period 1965–69 to 21.5 per-
openings in areas that were unbanked. As cent in the period 1980–84. As figure 4 shows,
a result, bank expansion during this period it is public investment that picks up in the
followed a pattern very different from what mid-1970s while private corporate investment
was observed when this regulation was not in begins to shift up only in the early 1980s.
effect. Burgess and Pande use this variation Sen (2007) shows that the increase in capital
to analyze the impact on poverty outcomes. formation in the mid-1970s was due to a rise in
This impact presumably works through equipment (machinery) investment. Until the
greater access to credit for rural households. late 1970s, the investment rate in structures
However, this paper does not throw light was higher than in equipment. The relation-
on the mechanisms by which rural banking ship reversed in subsequent periods. The sig-
could have raised household savings. nificance of this result is the conclusion from
Kotwal, Ramaswami, and Wadhwa: Economic Liberalization and Indian Economic Growth 1165

0.16

0.14
Public

0.12
Investment as a proportion of GDP

0.10

0.08

0.06
Household

0.04

0.02
Private corporate

0.00
1950 1955 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000

Year

Figure 4. Sectoral Investment Rates, 1950–2004

Source: Authors’ calculations using National Accounts Statistics.

cross-country research that, among different hold savings, they could also extend credit
types of investment, it is equipment invest- to households as well as to corporations.
ment that matters most for economic growth The fall in the relative price of machinery is
(DeLong and Lawrence H. Summers 1991). explained by the limited trade liberalization
By estimating an investment function, of the 1980s. Relaxation of import controls
Sen explains the increase in private equip- increased access to imported machinery.
ment investment as due to (1) a fall in the Given that the informal sector forms
relative price of capital equipment, (2) finan- such a large part of the Indian economy, it
cial deepening as measured by real domestic is important to know something about its
credit to the private sector, and (3) public sources of credit. Many of these are informal
investment (measured as a proportion of sources of credit for which microfinance has
GDP). Sen attributes financial deepening emerged as a possible alternative. Since the
to the banking expansion of the 1970s and mid-1980s, the National Bank for Agriculture
1980s. As banks were able to access house- and Rural Development (NABARD)—a
1166 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XLIX (December 2011)

development bank set up by the government spent primarily on food staples (consistent
of India and financed by the Reserve Bank of with Engel’s law) and where land is a con-
India—has been actively engaged in a pro- straint to food production, an increase in
gram to link mainstream banks with “Self food productivity necessarily reduces food
Help Groups” (SHGs). Recently the fund- prices, increases agricultural wages and
ing for this program has gone up significantly rents, and increases the size of the nonfarm
in thirteen priority states that account for 70 sector through greater demand for its prod-
percent of India’s poor. By March 2006, 2.2 ucts. Could this have played a role?
million SHGs had been linked to mainstream Rodrik and Subramanian (2005) dismiss
banks and 33 million poor households had this possibility because the terms of trade for
gained access to microfinance. NABARD is agriculture did not deteriorate in the 1980s.
also assisting other partner organizations like However, agricultural terms of trade did
NGOs and cooperative banks in promoting decline from about the early 1970s (when
SHGs. By 2006, a cumulative assistance of Rs. the Green Revolution’s impact became
334.6 million for the promotion of 250,000 apparent) to about the mid-1980s. More
groups has been granted by NABARD (http:// strikingly, relative prices of wheat and rice—
www.nabard.org/). the staple foods—declined from the mid-
1970s to 1991 (see figure 6). The decline is
4.5 Green Revolution
particularly pronounced for wheat, which
From about the mid-1960s, high-yielding was the greater success story of the Green
fertilizer responsive varieties of wheat and Revolution. The decline was not sustained
rice (the principal food staples in India) dif- beyond 1991 partly because of exhaustion of
fused through the agricultural economy. This this source of technological change and also
formed the basis for the Green Revolution. because of government interventions in the
By 1992–93, the diffusion was complete— immediate prereform period that increased
with about 90 percent of wheat area and 70 these prices.
percent of rice area occupied by these high
4.6 Conclusion
yielding varieties (HYVs). In the case of
wheat, much of the diffusion had happened Although it is clear that GDP growth rates
by 1975 when diffusion exceeded 60 percent increased sometime in the 1970s or early
(see figure 5). In the case of rice, the diffu- 1980s, the precise timing is hard to establish
sion was slower and similar thresholds were and depends on one’s prior. Various explana-
reached only in the early 1990s. tions have been proposed and it is impossible
The productivity impact of these varieties to be sure which of these is the most impor-
has been much discussed in the literature tant one. The economic orthodoxy would
(Robert E. Evenson, Carl E. Pray, and Mark favor one that credits trade liberalization,
W. Rosegrant 1999; Michael Lipton 1989). limited as it was, that decreased the cost of
As these varieties increased the productivity capital equipment but it is hard to disentan-
of inputs such as fertilizers and water, it was gle the effects of this from more heterodox
the combined impact of HYVs together with factors such as public investment and a rise
these inputs that led to higher yields. In the in savings rate (due to bank nationaliza-
period since the mid-1960s, output growth tion), the diffusion of agricultural technology
in food crops has been powered by increases (entirely due to public research and dis-
in yield rather than in area of cultivation. semination) or indeed to rule out the role of
In a closed economy (as India was during political attitudes toward business. It is also
the 1970s and 1980s) where low incomes are indisputable that there was an unsustainable
Kotwal, Ramaswami, and Wadhwa: Economic Liberalization and Indian Economic Growth 1167

100

80

Wheat

60

40
Paddy

20

0
1966 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990
Year

Figure 5. Share under High Yielding Varieties (percent)

Source: Evenson, Pray, and Rosegrant (1999).

fiscal expansion through the 1980s and any In principle, the removal of licensing and
income growth resulting from it should be the barriers to trade should allow greater
considered qualitatively different from the competition as well as access to cheaper
much more sustainable growth that occurred factor services. TFP should rise and as inef-
in the next decade. ficient firms exit, factors should get reallo-
cated to their most productive use further
increasing TFP. Did this happen?
5.  The Impact of Reforms
It should be noted that an entrepreneur
The reforms that began in 1991 com- in the prereform period was subject to
pletely changed the direction of economic many controls that operating together would
policies. As explained in section 3, India have been more restrictive than the sum
moved away from a state-led closed econ- of the effect of any one of them separately.
omy framework in favor of greater inte- Therefore, the success of a reform measure
gration with the world economy, lesser that lifts a constraint depends crucially on
controls on private business activity espe- the existence of other constraints that may
cially in manufacturing, and substantially still persist.
lower entry barriers to prospective entrants, The impact of liberalization of any one
whether domestic or foreign. of the controls (say an industrial license)
1168 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XLIX (December 2011)

140

120
Price relative to whole price index of all commodities

100
Rice

80

60
Wheat

40

20

0
1955 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995
Year

Figure 6. Relative Price of Rice and Wheat, 1952–98

Source: Misra (2004).

would be limited unless the other controls 5.1 Manufacturing Sector


(such as import licenses) were relaxed as
well. Similarly, lowering of tariff on inputs GDP and its components are depicted
to a particular industry may not pay the in figure 7. It can be seen that, since the
same dividend if the industry is still under 1980s, it is the services sector that is both
small-scale reservation policy that disallows the dominant sector as well as the fastest
large manufacturing plants. According to growing sector in the economy. Table 5
the theory of second best, under certain presents sectoral shares in value-added
circumstances, even the coefficient of and employment, while similar information
a reform measure could have a wrong for growth rates is displayed in table 6. In
sign. It is therefore important to consider 2004–05, manufacturing accounted for only
the interaction among controls and their 17 percent of value-added and 12 percent
liberalization in analyzing the impact of of employment not materially different
reforms. from the scenario in 1993–94. Panagariya
Kotwal, Ramaswami, and Wadhwa: Economic Liberalization and Indian Economic Growth 1169

20,000
Rs. Billion in 1993–94 prices

16,000

12,000

GDP

8,000 Services

4,000
Agriculture

Manufacturing

1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005

Year

Figure 7. Sectoral GDP, 1960–2004

Source: National Accounts Statistics.

(2004) argued that the main reason why However, in a regression of the change in
Indian growth was slower than in China the share of manufacturing (in value added)
was the lackluster performance of India’s on initial GDP and GDP growth rate, the
manufacturing sector. Kalpana Kochhar et India indicator is negative prompting the
al. (2006) make the same point by examining authors to conclude that “the data suggest
the performance of manufacturing across a relative slowing in manufacturing growth”
two points in time—1981 and 2002. They (p. 996). A similar paradox comes through
find that the share of manufacturing in GDP in TFP estimates. TFP growth rates in
in India was higher in 1981 (although not manufacturing are sensitive to a variety of
strongly significant) than what would be measurement issues; however, estimates
predicted by a cross-country regression of by different authors agree that TFP grew
the sectoral share on income and country slower in the 1990s compared to the 1980s
size. Repeating the regression for 2002, (Bishwanath Goldar 2006).
the authors find the coefficient of the The less than sparkling performance of
India dummy to be smaller than in 1981. the manufacturing sector has provoked a
1170 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XLIX (December 2011)

Table 5
Sectoral Shares in Value Added and Employment, 1983–2004*

Year Value added as a percent of GDP Percent of total employment


Agriculture Manufacturing Services Agriculture Manufacturing Services
1983–84 38.69 14.90 42.28 68.44 10.59 20.02
1993–94 30.97 16.06 47.97 64.87 10.44 23.60
1999–2000 24.99 16.71 53.45 62.03 10.50 26.63
2004–05 20.21 17.08 58.31 58.50 11.73 28.93

Notes: GDP figures are at constant 1993–94 prices from National Account Statistics.
Employment figures are calculated using the usual primary plus subsidiary status from the employment surveys of
the NSSO, adjusted for population.
Agriculture: agriculture, forestry, and fishing.
Manufacturing: registered and unregistered (does not include electricity, gas, and water).
Services: construction; trade, hotels and restaurants; transport, storage and communication; financing, insurance,
real estate and business services; community, social and personal services.
GDP rates of growth are average trend growth over the relevant period. Employment rates are annualized from the
point to point rates of growth.
* The reason for choosing these years and periods is that the employment figures are taken from NSSO (National
Sample Survey Organisation) employment surveys. These surveys are carried out every five years and they are
reliable for the years of the survey (e.g., 1983, 1987, 1993, 1999–00, and 2004–05). The data for the in-between
years are based on “thin rounds” (with smaller samples) and interpolation. Output figures are taken from National
Accounts Statistics (NAS) and are more reliable for the organized sector than for the unorganized sector.. The data
for the organized sector come from the annual reports filed by the firms in the organized sector (Annual Survey
of Industries (ASI) data). However, about 44 percent of the value added and 88 percent of the employment in the
nonfarm sectors come from the unorganized sector (with fewer than ten workers in a plant with power or twenty
workers in a plant without power). The method by which the output in the unorganized sector is computed is a bit
circuitous. Output per worker is taken from “enterprise surveys” also conducted by NSSO once every few years.
(The unorganized sector has no legal requirement to submit a report and it is widely believed that there is under
reporting of the value added. CSO adjusts these figures upwards using its own rules of thumb and we do not know
whether the available figures have an upward or downward bias.) Labor input is available for the NSS years. With
those years as benchmark years, labor input in the in-between years is computed by interpolation. Output for those
years is computed as a product of output per worker and labor input. It is needless to say that this computation
procedure makes the output figures for the unorganized sector much less reliable than those for the organized
sector. The numbers are relatively more reliable for the years of the quinquennial surveys since the labor input
values are more reliable for those years. It is therefore preferable to look at changes across these points in time.
However, often the time spans such as 1980s and 1990s are used in the literature partly for convenience and partly
because some policy changes took place at the beginning of those decades. For example, the 1980s began with the
Industrial Policy Statement (July 1980) and of course 1991 was the year of the IMF induced reforms.

l­iterature seeking to explain it. Timothy where s indexes the state and t indexes year,
Besley and Burgess (2004) examine the y is an outcome variable (such as output
role of labor market regulation to explain of organized manufacturing sector), α ​ ​s​ is a
manufacturing performance in Indian states state fixed effect, β
​ ​t​ is a year fixed effect, r
between 1958 and 1992. Their basic regres- is the labor regulatory measure lagged by
sion is of the following form: one year, and x are other control variables.
The regulatory measure is constructed on
y​st​  = ​αs​​  + ​βt​​  +  μ  ​r​st−1​  +  ξ  ​xst​ ​  + ​εst​ ​,
​ the basis of coding state-level amendments
Kotwal, Ramaswami, and Wadhwa: Economic Liberalization and Indian Economic Growth 1171

Table 6
Average Sectoral Rates of Growth 1973–2004

Period Value Added Employment


Agriculture Manufacturing Services Agriculture Manufacturing Services
1973–83 2.48 4.72 4.80
1983–93 3.02 6.11 6.48 1.61 2.01 3.85
1993–99 3.22 7.88 8.07 0.44 1.29 3.25
1999–2004 1.57 6.00 7.55 1.71 5.21 4.62
1993–2004 2.12 5.86 7.79 1.02 3.05 3.87

Notes: GDP figures are at constant 1993–94 prices from National Account Statistics.
Employment figures are calculated using the usual primary plus subsidiary status from the employment surveys of
the NSSO, adjusted for population.
Agriculture: agriculture, forestry, and fishing.
Manufacturing: registered and unregistered (does not include electricity, gas, and water).
Services: construction; trade, hotels and restaurants; transport, storage and communication; financing, insurance,
real estate and business services; community, social and personal services.
GDP rates of growth are average trend growth over the relevant period.
Employment rates are annualized from the point to point rates of growth.

to a key central government legislation—the unregistered manufacturing output is posi-


Industrial Disputes Act.14 Each amendment tively affected by greater labor regulation
is coded as being either neutral, pro-worker, suggesting that regulation encourages firms
or pro-employer and assigned a numerical to remain small and be within the unorga-
value of zero, one, and minus one, respec- nized sector.
tively. The state level scores are cumulated The Besley and Burgess study does not
to obtain a regulatory measure that evolves examine the impact of economic reforms
over time. Besley and Burgess find that reg- on the manufacturing sector. However, the
istered manufacturing (which is the target of idea of Besley and Burgess to use variation
regulation) output is negatively affected by in labor regulations across states to examine
the regulatory measure. On the other hand, their influence on manufacturing output and
employment has been carried forward in
14 Under the constitution, both the central and state many studies. In these studies, manufacturing
governments have the power of legislating labor laws. output or productivity (usually disaggregated
The Industrial Dispute Act is a central government leg- at a three digit level) is regressed against
islation and it provides the machinery and procedure for
the investigation and settlement of industrial disputes. a policy variable (industrial delicensing
The Industrial Dispute Act has been amended by the cen- dummy or trade tariffs) and other controls.
tral government a number of times although none have Often the major point of interest is not the
occurred after 1984. A key amendment that is often cited
as causing rigidity in the labor market was in 1976. This direct impact of labor regulation but the
amendment specified that prior approval of the govern- impact of economic reforms conditioned
ment was necessary in the case of layoffs, retrenchment, on labor market institutions. Therefore, the
and closure in industrial establishments employing more
than 300 workers. The threshold level was later lowered to policy variable is interacted with a variable
100 by an amendment in 1982 (T. C. A. Anant et al. 2006). that measures labor market regulation.
1172 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XLIX (December 2011)

Philippe Aghion et al. (2003), study the to those located in pro-worker states. The
impact of industrial delicensing on out- implication is that market reforms such as
put using data from the Annual Survey of delicensing work only with complemen-
Industries (ASI).15 They estimate a regres- tary institutions. Results similar to Aghion
sion of the form et al. are also reported by Sumon Kumar
Bhaumik, Shubhashis Gangopadhyay, and
​y​ist​  = ​αis​ ​  + ​ηit​ ​  + ​βst​ ​  +  θ(​dit​ ​)(​rst​ ​)  + ​εist
​ ​, Shagun Krishnan (2006), who find that,
while entry by firms was related to industry
where i indexes industry (at three-digit level), level factors during the 1980s, unobserved
s indexes state, and t indexes year (during state-level factors explain much of the entry
the period 1980–97), y is log of output, α is during 1992–97. The authors conjecture
a state-industry fixed effect, η is an industry- that these state-level factors relate to “qual-
year interaction, β is a state-year interaction, ity of governance,” which presumably also
r is the labor regulation index, and d is the includes labor market institutions.
delicensing dummy. The delicensing dummy The shortcomings of the Besley and
takes the value 1 in the year that the industry Burgess measure of labor regulation have
is delicensed and retains that value for subse- been pointed out by some researchers. Anant
quent years. The labor regulation measure is et al. (2006) and Aditya Bhattacharjea (2006)
the Besley and Burgess index that is updated point out that the application of the law has
to 1997.16 Note that the delicensing dummy a greater bearing on labor outcomes than
does not vary across states and the regulation the written law. How the law works on the
index does not vary across industries. Hence ground depends on how it is enforced and
their average impacts cannot be estimated on judicial interpretation of its provisions.
in the above specification. Replacing the η  s Bhattacharjea has also disputed how Besley
and β  s by a year fixed effect and dropping and Burgess have coded some of the amend-
the interaction terms between delicensing ments and he shows that the procedure of
dummy and the regulation index, Aghion et assigning and cumulating numerical scores
al. find that delicensing and regulation have leads to several anomalies. Finally, both the
opposite and almost equal effects on the central and state governments have several
number of factories. Thus, delicensing does other laws that matter to labor flexibility that
have a positive effect on entry and competi- are not captured by the index.
tion but the effect is masked by labor regula- Rana Hasan, Devashish Mitra, and K. V.
tion. This result motivates estimates of the Ramaswamy (2007) propose a modified ver-
general specification above. The coefficient sion of the Besley and Burgess index. Firstly,
on the interaction between delicensing and the authors consider a binary partitioning of
labor regulation is negative. The regulation states into those that have flexible markets
index is larger for legislation that is more (i.e., those that are rated as antiworker by
favorable to workers. Therefore, a negative the Besley and Burgess index) and those that
coefficient implies that industries in states have rigid markets (i.e., all other states). The
with more pro-employer regulation expe- Besley and Burgess index classifies the states
rienced larger increases in output relative of Gujarat and Maharashtra as pro-worker
and the state of Kerala as pro-employer.
This is at variance with the commonly held
15 The coverage of the ASI data is restricted to the orga-
perceptions of these states and the authors
nized manufacturing sector.
16 The original index was computed for the period up point to a World Bank survey that highly
to 1992. rated the investment climate in Gujarat and
Kotwal, Ramaswami, and Wadhwa: Economic Liberalization and Indian Economic Growth 1173

Maharashtra but awarded a poor rating to The productivity impact of trade liberal-
Kerala. Therefore, the second modification is ization was also estimated by Petia Topalova
to classify Kerala as a state with rigid markets (2004). She computes firm-level TFP for a
and the states of Gujarat and Maharashtra as panel data set of publicly listed firms for the
states with flexible markets.17 The result is period 1989–2001. The firms in the panel
their FLEX dummy that is one for the states account for 70 percent of the organized man-
with flexible markets. ufacturing sector. The productivity indices
Beyza P. Ural and Mitra (2007) use the are regressed on lagged industry tariffs, firm
FLEX dummy to investigate the impact characteristics, year dummies, and indus-
of economic reforms on labor and TFP in try fixed effects. The results suggest that a
Indian manufacturing using ASI data. The reduction in protection had a positive impact
labor productivity equation is of the follow- on TFP and this was driven not by the exit
ing form: of inefficient firms but by an improvement
in TFP of existing firms. Unlike the earlier
​y​ist​ = ​αi​​  +  ​ηt​​  +  ​γ1​ ​ ​r​s​  +  ​γ​2​ ​xi​t​  papers, Topalova does not find any differ-
ences between states on the basis of labor
+  ​γ​3​(​rs​​ ​xi​t​)  +  ​γ4​ ​ ​z​st​  regulation.
Surveys of managers in manufacturing
+  ​γ5​ ​(​xi​t​ ​zs​t​)  +  ​εi​st​, firms show that taxation and infrastructure
issues are the ones most frequently cited as
where i indexes industry (at two-digit level), being obstacles to growth. Access to finance
s indexes state and t indexes year (during the is also seen as an important issue; however,
period 1989–2000), y is log labor produc- labor regulations is not seen as a problem
tivity, r is the time-invariant labor flexibility of primary importance.19 This motivates
dummy (FLEX), x​ i​t​is the time varying tariff Poonam Gupta, Hasan, and Utsav Kumar
rate for the ith industry, and zst is the log of (2008) to widen the search for factors that
real per capita development expenditures. constrain Indian manufacturing. Using
The coefficient on the tariff rate is nega- three-digit industry data from ASI, they
tive, that on flex dummy is positive (but sig- define industry characteristics along three
nificant only in the base regression) and that dimensions: dependence on infrastructure,
on the interaction of tariff rate and FLEX dependence on external finance and labor
dummy is negative (and significant). These intensity. They estimate a regression of the
results mean that lower tariffs increase pro- following form:
ductivity in all industries but the increase is
larger in industries that are located in states Yi​t​  =  ​α​i​  +  ​βt​​  +  γ ​dit​ ​  +  δ ​xi​​ ​dit​ ​  +  ​εit​ ​,

with flexible labor markets. An extension of
the results to delicensing throws up a result where i indexes industry, t indexes year, Y is
similar to Aghion et.al (2003).18 log of value-added, αs and βs are industry
and year fixed effects, d is a dummy for deli-
censed status, and xs are the set of industry
17 The danger with such ex post classifications is that
the FLEX dummy could be picking up other state char-
acteristics that make Maharashtra and Gujarat excellent
investment destinations and make Kerala a state with poor Mitra, and Ramaswamy (2007) confirm this and show that
investment prospects. it is related to trade liberalization. The increase is greater in
18 A related implication of trade liberalization is that com- states with more flexible labor market institutions.
petitive pressures working through different channels will 19 It is possible, of course, that the responses of pro-
make labor demand in manufacturing more elastic. Hasan, spective entrants are different from that of incumbents.
1174 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XLIX (December 2011)

Table 7
Manufacturing Sector Employment: 1983–2004–05

Employment (millions) Annualized growth rates (percent)


1983 1993–94 2004–05 1983 to 1993–94 1993–94 to 2004–05
Organized manufacturing 7.82 8.71 8.38 1.08 −0.38
Unorganized manufacturing 23.8 29.9 45.3 2.30 4.26
Total manufacturing 31.6 38.6 41.7 2.01 3.36

Source: Authors calculations using ASI data for organized manufacturing employment and NSS data for unorganized
manufacturing employment.

characteristics. They find that the coefficient exists for the organized sector.20 There are,
of the delicense dummy is positive and sig- however, some clues about how the dynam-
nificant but it is counteracted by the coeffi- ics of organized manufacturing affect the
cients on the interaction terms, all of which unorganized sector.
are negative. In other words, industries that Table 7 reports employment in organized
grow slowly in the delicensed period are and unorganized manufacturing and their
those that are either relatively more depen- rates of growth over the periods 1983 to
dent on infrastructure, or more dependent 1993–94 and 1993–94 to 2004–05. Overall
on external finance or are more labor-inten- employment growth is greater in the 1990s
sive. The paper does not identify what fac- and this happens despite a fall in employ-
tors constrain the growth of labor-intensive ment in the organized segment. The 1990s
manufacturing firms. are a period of robust employment growth
The evidence from the disaggregated in the unorganized sector. What could have
industry (and in some cases firm-level) data happened to bring this about?
therefore shows significant impacts of eco- Various explanations can be given why
nomic reforms on manufacturing in terms organized employment did not expand dur-
of greater firm entry, higher industry output, ing the reform period in spite of the growth
value added, and productivity. However, it in output and value added in this sector. For
seems that weaknesses in infrastructure, one, firms may have shifted to a more capital-
lack of adequate financing, and labor-mar- intensive technology requiring fewer work-
ket rigidity have come in the way of faster ers. Firms may also have increasingly shifted
growth of the manufacturing sector. to contract workers or to subcontracts with
It should be noted, however, that these
findings are based on the organized manu- 20 One source of information on the informal sector
facturing sector alone. What about firms is the set of surveys conducted by the National Sample
in the unorganized manufacturing sector? Survey Organization in 1989–90 and 1994–95 as the
­follow-up surveys to the Economic Censuses of 1980 and
How have they been affected by economic 1990 respectively. Shanthi Nataraj (2009) uses these data-
reforms? These questions do not have good sets to examine the impact of tariff cuts on productivity
answers because there is no comparable improvement in the manufacturing sector as a whole. She
finds that overall productivity has risen mostly due to the
time series data set on unorganized enter- productivity improvement in informal sector through the
prises and their level of output and inputs, as exit of the inefficient firms.
Kotwal, Ramaswami, and Wadhwa: Economic Liberalization and Indian Economic Growth 1175

10 –
Annual growth (five-year moving average)

Unorganized employment

5–

0–

Organized employment

−5 –
1981–82

1982–83

1983–84

1984–85

1985–86

1986–87

1987–88

1988–89

1989–90

1990–91

1991–92

1992–93

1993–94

1994–95

1995–96

1996–97

1997–98

1998–99

1999–00

2000–01

2001–02

2002–03

2003–04
Year

Figure 8. Growth of Organized and Unorganized Sector Employment

Source: Dougherty (2008).

labor-intensive unorganized firms as a means Value added in constant prices increased


of avoiding costly labor regulations.21 by almost 6 percent per annum during the
Figure 8 (reproduced from Sean M. period 1997 to 2004–05. Yet, organized sec-
Dougherty 2008) shows clearly how employ- tor employment declined during this period.
ment in the organized sector went down after On the other hand, the organized manufac-
1997 while that in the unorganized sector turing sector did increase the use of contract
rose. One conjecture is that competition had labor (not counted as part of regular work-
intensified in India’s manufacturing sector by ers). Figure 10 plots contract labor as a per-
the late 1990s as a result of easier entry and centage of person days worked for the period
declining tariffs through the decade. Firms since the late 1970s. While this proportion
looked for ways to cut costs and, given the has been increasing throughout the period,
rigid labor laws, subcontracting and use of the rise is sharp since the late 1990s.
contract labor afforded firms lower labor Using plant level data from the ASI,
costs and greater flexibility. Dougherty (2008) computes the job cre-
Figure 9 shows that the period since 1997 ation rate and job destruction rate at the
was not one of contraction for the organized three-digit industry level and five-digit
sector. Profits, output, material, and service industry level. The ideal measure would
input all increased (relative to value added). be at the plant level but ASI does not allow
plants to be tracked over time. Therefore,
these measures displayed in table 8 are
21 We thank Roger Gordon for suggesting this point. lower bounds.
1176 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XLIX (December 2011)

1.0

0.8
Output and material input as a ratio of value added

Profits and service input as a ratio of value added


Service input
0.6

0.4
Profits
7
0.2

6
0.0

5 Output

4
Material input

2
1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000
Year

Figure 9. Organized Manufacturing Ratios

Source: Authors’ calculations using ASI data.

The turnover rates in the 2000s are surpris- lower ­productivity, Dougherty concludes that
ingly high for a labor market where regulations “Despite strong gains in employment across
are thought to restrain the ability of employers the economy in recent years, a dichotomy has
to dismiss workers. The key to the puzzle lies emerged with net increases in employment
in table 9 also from Dougherty (2008). The occurring almost exclusively in the least pro-
table shows that for large units (defined as ductive, unorganized and often informal part
those with more than 100 workers), the only of the economy.”
category of workers that has seen an increase Subcontracting could be the other
is contract labor. For small units (less than possible explanation for the inverse
100 workers and therefore exempt from the correlation between the growth in organized
provisions of the Industrial Disputes Act), the sector employment and unorganized sector
net employment rate is positive for all worker employment. Subcontracting is widespread
types. Job flows are therefore concentrated on in some industries, such as for instance
contract labor in large units and on all work- garments. Ramaswamy (1999) has estimates
ers in small units. As the smaller units are of subcontracting in the 1980s and early
characterized by lower capital intensity and 1990s but estimates for a more recent period
Kotwal, Ramaswami, and Wadhwa: Economic Liberalization and Indian Economic Growth 1177

25 –
Share of contract workers: percent

20 –

15 –

10 –

5 –


1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005
Year

Figure 10. Contract Intensity in the Manufacturing Sector

Source: Ramaswamy (2008).

are not available. He finds subcontracting services (which includes software and infor-
practices to be concentrated in labor-intensive mation-technology-enabled services), bank-
industries. It is possible that the dramatic ing, and communications have grown on
improvements in telecommunications in the average at more than 10 percent per year in
1990s could have facilitated more efficient the 1990s. On the other hand, some other
supply chains, greater specialization, and services, such as railways and public admin-
more subcontracting. However, we lack istration, have grown more slowly (Rupa
evidence on whether and how cell phones Chanda 2007). 23 The other striking feature
and better communications changed the way of figure 7 and tables 5 and 6 is the relatively
in which firms conduct business. slower growth of employment in the services
sector. As a result, while the services share
5.2 Services
of GDP is nearly 60 percent, its share of
Figure 7 and tables 5 and 6 make it appar- employment is barely 30 percent.
ent that the service sector has grown faster
than other sectors and is the dominant sector
in the economy.22 Within the sector, ­business administration, personal services, education and health,
business services, research and scientific services, and rec-
reation and entertainment.
23 The data quality on service sector output has been
22 In our three-fold division of the economy into agri- questioned. While the estimate for the public sector com-
culture, manufacturing, and services, we include the fol- ponent is regarded as reliable, this is not equally so for the
lowing in services—trade, construction, transportation, components relating to either the private corporate sector
communications, banking and financial services, public or the unorganized sector (Shetty 2007).
1178 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XLIX (December 2011)

Table 8
Job Flows in the Organized Manufacturing Sector

Year Job creation rate Job destruction rate Turnover rate


Based on three-digit industries
Average, 1985–1988 5.3 –4.1 9.4
Average, 1999–2004 3.9 –5 8.9
Based on five-digit industries
1999–2000 18.9 –21.2 40.1
2000–01 11.4 –13.7 25.0
2001–02 8.0 –10.8 18.8
2002–03 16.5 –13.1 29.6
2003–04 15.8 –16.1 31.9

Source: Dougherty (2008).

Table 9
Job Flows by Size of Plant Workforce and Type of Worker
Average for 1999–2004 (for Organized Manufacturing Sector)

Job creation rate Job destruction rate Net employment rate


Large Small Large Small Large Small
All employees 11.5 24.2 –17 –8.4 –5.5 15.8
Workers 13.3 26.7 –18.7 –10.4 –5.4 16.3
Contract 26.7 31.0 –22.9 –13.7 3.8 17.3
Supervisors 16.8 27.8 –27.4 –14.6 –10.6 13.2
Others 15.9 31.5 –25.2 –13.7 –9.3 17.8

Note: Large plants have more than 100 workers, and small plants have 100 or less workers.
Source: Dougherty (2008).

Some of the service sectors clearly grew exports, which grew faster (at 17.3 percent
on account of domestic demand: trade (i.e., annually) than either GDP (at 7.5 percent)
distribution of goods and services from pro- or the services GDP through the 1990s (at
ducers to consumers), construction, trans- 9.2 percent) (Chanda 2007).
portation, public administration, education Between 1995 and 2000, India’s services
and health, personal services, and recre- exports grew nearly six times faster than
ation and entertainment. However, the most world exports of services (Chanda 2007).
noticeable feature of service sector growth In 2001–02, software accounted for about a
has been the remarkable expansion of its third of all services exports. Until the most
Kotwal, Ramaswami, and Wadhwa: Economic Liberalization and Indian Economic Growth 1179

recent financial crisis, this sector has been in time zones between India and the United
growing at 35 percent per annum. Though States was used by Indian companies to offer
as yet software sector is only a small part of a 24-hour virtual workday (Murthy 2007).
the GDP and a negligible part of the total During the earlier period (1983–93), there
employment, it has been the most dynamic is little reason to believe that new technologies
sector in India and has facilitated continu- played any role in the service sector growth.
ing growth by generating foreign exchange The service sector was growing mostly due to
averting a financial crisis. From a growth the growing demand for it by the fast growing
accounting exercise, Barry Eichengreen manufacturing sector or by other factors that
and Gupta (2010) conclude that domestic did not even depend on policy reforms. For
demand and exports are the major drivers of example, as mentioned earlier, there was a
service sector growth (as opposed to inter- steady expansion of the banking system from
mediate demand from other sectors).24 1975 through 1985 that slowed down in the
The services sector has gained from reforms late 1980s. However, aggregate deposits and
in two sorts of ways. The direct impact came credit increased very fast due to the increased
from the opening up of several service sectors economic activity. Public administration is in
to the private sector and FDI. These include a league of its own. When wages of public
telecommunications, banking, and insurance. servants are revised upwards, the output fig-
The share of services in FDI rose from 10.5 ures reported in the statistics go up as long
percent in the early 1990s to nearly 30 per- as the wage hikes exceed the cost of living
cent in the second half of the decade (Chanda index. Thus, the indicated output growth rate
2007). However, FDI is still not permitted in in “public administration” can be somewhat
some sectors, the most prominent of them fictitious. Trade, construction, and transpor-
being retail distribution. The indirect impact tation all grew in response to an increased
came about because of easier and cheaper demand. Education has two components:
access to factor services. N. R. Narayana “public” is autonomous while “private” can
Murthy (2004) cites import delicensing (that move in response to a change in demand.
permitted immediate purchase of imported The beginning of the new communica-
computers), financial liberalization (that tions era was made in 1992 when the govern-
allowed firms to raise capital through pub- ment opened the sector to the private sector
lic offerings that were market determined by relinquishing its monopoly control over
rather than by state regulators), and current the provision of communication services.
account convertibility (that made it easier to The years between 1995 and 1999 saw a lot
travel, hire foreign consultants and establish of churning in the telecom sector but, dur-
sales offices abroad). Murthy also credits FDI ing this period, cell phones became more
by software majors as reasons why the indus- affordable to common people. In a country
try adopted world-class quality processes, with poor infrastructure for communications,
tools, and methodologies. Improvement in this development had an enormous impact.25
telecommunications and the use of Internet After the arrival of cellular technology, the
facilitated the off-shoring of information service sector in India took off. The two fast-
technology services by U.S. and European est growing sectors in the period 1993–2004
corporations to Indian firms. The difference were business services (24.3 percent), and

24 Intermediate demand from manufacturing accounts 25 See Robert Jensen (2007) on how the use of cell
for about one-third of value added in services which is phones by Kerala fishermen eliminated the price volatility
down from about 40 percent in 1991. in the fish market.
1180 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XLIX (December 2011)

communications (20.7 percent).26 If we constitutes a relatively small part of GDP


examine a slightly later period of 2001–07, and therefore cannot be considered as having
we find further acceleration of these high- contributed significantly to the overall growth
end services. Given that the growth accelera- of GDP during 1993–2004. However, at the
tion of these activities in this period coincides compound growth rate of 22.5 percent that it
exactly with the entry of information tech- is growing, it is expected to rise over 7 percent
nology, it is very likely that the advent of of GDP in 2007–08. It will then certainly start
information technology is the main trigger having an impact on GDP. The sector that
for growth acceleration in these sectors. The contributes the most to the overall nonfarm
coincidence of educated manpower and the growth is trade as it forms a sizable part of
presence of a huge international demand for GDP in 1993 (18 percent). This means that
information technology services launched the almost one fifth of the economy is engaged
Indian software industry. Software and ser- in trading and distributing goods and services
vices exports grew at an astronomical speed produced in the economy. Its growth rate
from USD 754 million in 1995–96 to USD though not in the fastest twelve sectors never-
23,600 million in 2005–06 (Gangopadhyay, theless rose from 5.4 percent during 1983–93
Manisha G. Singh, and Nirvikar Singh 2008). to 8.5 percent during the period 1993–2004.
An improvement in communication tech- The expansion of trade also indicates increas-
nologies has enormous externalities for ing specialization and expanding markets.
other sectors, especially “services.” “Trade” Gangopadhyay, Singh, and Singh (2008)
includes distribution of goods and services study the impact of information technology on
from the producers to consumers and it is the organized manufacturing sector in India.27
the largest component of the service sector They find that the penetration of information
in India. Its efficiency depends on the quality technology in Indian manufacturing has been
and timeliness of the information flows and less than satisfactory. Some sectors like phar-
the advent of new communications technol- maceuticals have adopted it much more than
ogy facilitated both. It is not a surprise there- others. However, they also find that the use of
fore that there was a quantum jump in the information technology has a positive impact
growth rate of the service sector after the on productivity as well as employment. It
arrival of cell phones and the Internet. It also not only increases both skilled and unskilled
had an impact on banking, insurance, and employment but also increases the skill inten-
social services such as health and education. sity of the workforce. Their most interesting
Interestingly, the ASI data show that the ser- finding is that the use of information technol-
vice sector input into the organized manu- ogy is subject to a coordination problem due
facturing sector went up considerably from to network externalities. A firm is more likely
1997–98 to 2001–02 and so did the value of to use it if its suppliers and customers use it.
total input (figure 9). This is consistent with They cite the example of the state of Haryana
our conjecture that improvement in the where a government subsidy had a strong
communications technology may have cre- impact on the spread of information technol-
ated incentives for subcontracting to smaller ogy through the industries in Haryana.
specialized units in the unorganized sector.
Note that the fastest growing sector dur-
ing the 1990s was business services, but it 27 Also, Singh (2006) has pointed out many spillovers
from information and communication technology to the
rest of the economy and especially to the manufacturing
26 These are average annual rates of growth over sector. These crucial services reduce transaction costs and
1994–2004. speed up innovation.
Kotwal, Ramaswami, and Wadhwa: Economic Liberalization and Indian Economic Growth 1181

5.3 Why Services?: The Bias Toward Skill- China (68.7 percent), India (68.1 percent),
Intensity and Thailand (70.8 percent) had very simi-
lar figures in 1980. By 2000, the picture had
Kochhar et al. (2006) have argued that, changed significantly: China (46.95 percent),
because of the prior emphasis on tertiary India (59.3 percent), and Thailand (48.8 per-
education and a diversified skill set developed cent). As a result, the contribution in India
during the long import substitution phase, (to the total growth rate) from the process
skill-intensive services based on information of reallocating labor from the agricultural
technologies took root in India.28 In addi- sector (characterized by low productivity) to
tion, Indian engineers resident in the United industry and services (characterized by high
States, who had played an important role in productivity) is extremely low compared to
the high tech sector there, were induced to other Asian countries (Bosworth, Collins,
invest their human and financial capital in and Virmani 2007).
India by the reforms that relaxed controls The main reason for this is that the fast
on imports and investments. Of course, the growing nonfarm sectors are all skill-intensive
advent of new technologies was felt by the sectors while most of the labor in agriculture
whole world but it is possible that the reputa- is unskilled. How little unskilled employment
tion of Indian engineers in the United States growth was created by the fastest growing
helped them create a brand name that is sectors is clear from figures 11 and 12 that
normally not available for a developing coun- plot the contribution to the overall (GDP)
try’s foray into a new high-tech activity. This growth rate and to the overall skilled and
sequence of fortuitous events launched India unskilled employment growth rate for each
as a name to reckon with in software exports. of the forty-one nonfarm sectors during the
The extraordinarily high growth rate of 24.3 1980s and the 1990s.29 The computations
percent for business services would not have displayed in these figures use a very minimal
been possible if a vast export market had not definition of skill. All workers who have
opened for custom designed software prod- a middle-school education or higher are
ucts. It also helped to have a large pool of considered to be skilled. All others are
English-speaking young population with unskilled workers. In the figures, the sectors
some education to provide other business are sorted in a descending order by their
services such as “call centers.” All this is of contribution to the rate of growth of GDP.
course rather special due to India’s historical We then plot the cumulative contribution of
background and therefore not quite repli-
cable in other countries.
29 For value added and output, there are two main
Kochhar et al. (2006) compare the sectoral
sources of data—ASI and NAS. The level of disaggrega-
shares of GDP and employment in India tion is much greater in ASI than in NAS. However, the ASI
with those in other comparable countries covers only registered manufacturing, which constitutes
and examine whether India is an outlier in less than 20 percent of GDP. More importantly, it does not
cover services that are not only dominant in GDP but also
any respect. The most noteworthy statistic included some of the fastest growing sectors in the 1990s.
they present is the change in the employ- Therefore, for output we have no choice but to use NAS.
ment share of agriculture from 1980 to 2000: For employment, the only source is NSS and the recent
rounds give data disaggregated up to five-digit industry
codes. However, as stated before, NSS data are available
only at five-year intervals. On the other hand, NAS gives
28 Kochar et al. show that, in 1981, the contribution of a time series, but with very limited disaggregation—forty-
skill-intensive industries to total value-added in India was one nonfarm sectors. Therefore, we are restricted to forty-
above the international norm (controlling for the country’s one nonfarm sectors over the NSS time periods—1983–93
GDP and size). This effect persists in 2000. and 1993–2004.
1182 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XLIX (December 2011)

120
Cumulative contribution to the rate of growth (percent) 1983–93

100

80

60

40 GDP
Unskilled emp

20
Skilled emp

−20

−40
5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40
Sectors sorted by their rate of growth (1983–93)

Figure 11. Contribution of the Fastest Growing Sectors to Employment: 1983–93

Source: Authors’ calculations using NAS and NSS data.

these sectors to the rate of growth of GDP, 1980s accounted for only about 4 percent of
skilled and unskilled employment. Figure 11 the growth in unskilled employment. On the
shows these cumulative contributions for the other hand, the sectoral contribution to GDP
1983–93 period and figure 12 for the 1993– is very similar to their contribution to skilled
2004 period. employment. However, as far as unskilled
During the 1980s (figure 11), the fastest employment is concerned, there are just a few
growing fourteen sectors hardly provide any sectors that make abundant use of unskilled
unskilled labor employment. In fact, they workers and much of the unskilled employ-
seem to be shedding unskilled labor. The ini- ment in nonfarm sectors is clustered in three
tial dip in figure 11 occurs because unskilled main sectors—trade, construction, and trans-
labor employment in textile products—the portation. The three vertical segments of the
second fastest growing sector in the 1980s— graph correspond to these sectors.
dropped by 39 percent. Even if this sector is As is clear from figure 12, 1993–2004 is
excluded, the ten fastest growing sectors in the certainly a better decade from the point
Kotwal, Ramaswami, and Wadhwa: Economic Liberalization and Indian Economic Growth 1183

120
Cumulative contribution to the rate of growth (percent) 1993–04

100
Skilled emp

80

GDP

60
Unskilled emp

40

20

−20
5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40
Sectors sorted by their rate of growth (1993–2004)

Figure 12. Contribution of the Fastest Growing Sectors to Employment: 1993–2004

Source: Authors’ calculation using NAS and NSS data.

of view of employment generation for The increase during 1993–2004 was much
the unskilled as compared to the earlier larger at 60.20 million. In fact, two-thirds of
decade. The main reason why the picture the increase happened in the latter half of
for 1993–2004 looks more favorable to the decade—while the increase was 20.86
unskilled labor is because the sectors that million during 1993–99, it was 39.34 million
used unskilled labor abundantly (e.g., trade during 1999–2004.
and construction) grew faster in the 1990s. Why has Indian growth created much
In addition, the labor-shedding seen in less employment in its nonfarm sectors
the earlier decade does not happen in the than have China and other Asian countries
1990s. As a result, the 1990s are better for that also experienced fast growth? First, as
the growth of overall nonfarm employment the goal of “self-reliance” guided Indian
as well. Between 1983 and 1993, nonfarm industrialization in the prereform period,
employment increased by 35.59 million. the principle of comparative advantage
1184 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XLIX (December 2011)

was deliberately sidestepped, giving rise of poverty are reported only for the thick
to capital and skill intensive growth. While rounds. These estimates are reproduced in
this favored skill-intensive exports in the table 10.
later liberalization phase, it also left a leg- The poverty ratio in both rural and urban
acy of restrictive labor laws, prohibitions populations has approximately halved over
on large-scale units in labor intensive sec- three decades from 1973–74 to 2004–05.
tors (through the small scale reservation About 61 percent of the decline in the rural
policy), and inadequate infrastructure that head-count ratio occurred in the first four-
constrained the expansion of the corporate teen years of this period (1973–74 to 1987–
sector into labor-intensive manufacturing. 88). On the other hand, the rate of decline
The flip side is that much of India’s labor in urban poverty has been more even—46
force is in the unorganized sector. Reversing percent of the reduction happened in the
the regulatory impediments would aid the first fourteen years and the remainder in the
expansion of the organized sector in labor- next seventeen years. For the period prior
intensive manufacturing. However, given to 1973–74, there is no officially released
that the unorganized sector employs 83 per- consistent series on poverty. However, from
cent of the nonfarm labor force, it is diffi- the estimates put together by researchers
cult to imagine that the present picture can (Guarav Datt and Martin Ravallion 2002), it
change rapidly on the strength of organized can be seen there is no trend in the poverty
sector expansion alone. The underprovision ratio during this period.
of infrastructural facilities and credit are The poverty lines used in the official
the biggest impediments to overall entre- estimates have often been criticized for
preneurial activity. not corresponding adequately to a desired
In sum, the fastest growing sectors in caloric norm, for not capturing nonfood
India are capital and skilled labor-intensive subsistence, and for the use of incorrect
sectors. Despite the speeding up of employ- price deflators across survey years.30 Figure
ment growth in 1999–2004, the labor share 13 displays the all India empirical cumu-
of agriculture has fallen at a relatively slower lative distribution of per capita consumer
rate than other comparable countries as the expenditure for the years 1983 and 2004–
increase in demand for unskilled labor by 05. As the 2004–05 distribution dominates
nonfarm sectors has still not matched the the 1983 distribution by first-order stochas-
increases in labor force during this period. tic dominance, the choice of a poverty line
This has obvious implications for poverty would not alter the finding of a decline in
decline as we discuss in the next section. poverty. However, the choice matters in
other ways. In the figure, we draw vertical
lines at a per capita expenditure level cor-
6.  Poverty Decline
responding to the poverty line and twice
Official poverty estimates in India are the poverty line. While the fall in poverty
based on nationally representative con- is substantial when measured by the pov-
sumer expenditure surveys conducted by erty line, the decrease in the proportion of
the National Sample Survey Organization. population below twice the poverty line is
While such surveys are now undertaken very modest. Furthermore, even in 2004,
every year, the so-called “thick rounds,” this proportion was as high as 0.8.
which take place approximately every five
years, are regarded as more reliable. The 30 Angus Deaton and Valerie Kozel (2005) is a good ref-
official estimates of the head-count ratio erence for a recent survey of measurement issues.
Kotwal, Ramaswami, and Wadhwa: Economic Liberalization and Indian Economic Growth 1185

Table 10
Trends in Poverty, 1973–2004

Head count ratio (percent) Number of poor (millions)

Rural Urban Combined Rural Urban Combined Total population (millions)


1973–74 56.4 49 54.9 261.3 60.0 321.3 585.25
1977–78 53.1 45.2 51.3 264.3 64.6 328.9 641.13
1983 45.6 40.8 44.5 252.0 70.9 322.9 725.62
1987–88 39.1 38.2 38.9 231.9 75.2 307.0 789.20
1993–94 37.3 32.4 36.0 244.0 76.3 320.4 890.00
2004–05 28.3 25.7 27.5 220.9 80.8 301.7 1097.09

Source: Planning Commission, Government of India.

Table 10 also contains numbers on the 1998 and 2002; Ravallion and Datt 2002)31,  32
absolute number of the poor in rural and Their principal findings were that (1) while
urban populations. While the number of both urban and rural poor gained from
rural poor has dropped by about 40 mil- rural growth, the rural poor did not benefit
lion, the number of urban poor went up from urban growth. Rural to urban migra-
by 20 million between 1973 and 2004. tion is not a major driver of poverty decline
So the net gain is only about 20 million. in India; (2) similarly, primary and tertiary
However, these changes happened at a sector growth mattered much more to pov-
time when the population nearly doubled erty than secondary sector growth (primar-
from 585 million to 1.1 billion. If the pov- ily manufacturing); (3) higher farm yields
erty ratio had not dropped below its lev- increase real agricultural wages and reduce
els in 1973–74, India would have more rural poverty; and (4) rural nonfarm output
than 600 million poor people. Against also reduces rural poverty; however its impact
this counterfactual, economic growth has varies across states depending on initial condi-
lifted about 300 million out of poverty. tions. The impact is lower in states with ini-
Clearly, however, other counterfactuals tially low levels of farm productivity, low rural
can be constructed. living standards relative to urban areas, poor
Like the growth story then, the decline basic education and high infant mortality.
in poverty also dates to the 1970s. The In a cross-sectional analysis, Palmer-Jones
leading candidate among rival explana- and Sen (2003) related rural poverty (in the
tions is agricultural growth. The plausibil- late 1980s and early 1990s) to agricultural
ity of this is illustrated by the figure 14,
which graphs crop yields and the head 31 The data was drawn from Berk Özler, Datt, and
count ratio measure of poverty for the Ravallion (1996) who assembled poverty measures from
period 1949–98. twenty-one household expenditure surveys of the NSSO
In a series of papers, Datt and Ravallion for the period 1957–58 to 1990–91.
32 Richard Palmer-Jones and Sen (2007) survey the
used time-series data to examine the corre- older studies prior to Datt and Ravallion that also address
lates of poverty decline (Datt and Ravallion the impact of agricultural growth on poverty.
1186 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XLIX (December 2011)

0.86

0.80
1983
Cumulative density

0.445

2004

0.275

250 Z 500 2Z 750 1,000 1,250


Per capita expenditure, rupees, 1999 prices

Figure 13. Distribution of Consumer Expenditure

Source: Authors’ calculations using NSS data.

growth and several control variables. Their a nontraded service sector, and a traded
results confirm the Datt and Ravallion find- factory sector. Capital is mobile and is used
ing of a strong positive correlation between by the factory sector alone. As capital seeks
agricultural growth and poverty decline. villages with low wages, a key prediction of
Palmer-Jones and Sen emphasize the role their model is that rural industrialization
of agro-ecological conditions in determining may bypass regions with high agricultural
agricultural growth suggesting that agricul- productivity (and, therefore, high wages).
ture driven poverty reduction is not available The model is estimated for a panel of villages
to all regions. and households over the period 1982–99.33
A contrary finding is from Andrew D.
Foster and Mark R. Rosenzweig (2003, 2004), 33 The panel consists of 250 villages surveyed twice—in
who model a village economy as consisting 1982 and in 1999. The survey is conducted by the National
of three sectors: a traded agricultural sector, Council of Applied Economic Research.
Kotwal, Ramaswami, and Wadhwa: Economic Liberalization and Indian Economic Growth 1187

5 – – 70

4.8 – Food crop


Log index, 1979–81 = 100

yield index – 60

HCR, percent
4.6 – – 50

4.4 – – 40

Rural HCR
4.2 – ––– 30

1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000


Year

Figure 14. Crop Yields and Poverty in India, 1949–98

Source: Palmer-Jones and Sen (2006).

The important findings of their empirical of the nonfarm sector in rural employment.
application are (1) agricultural productivity In the period from 1987–88 to 1999–2000,
negatively affects the factory sector but this ratio fluctuates between 26 percent and
positively affects the nontraded sector and 29 percent (Yoko Kijima and Peter Lanjouw
(2) both agricultural productivity and factory 2005). It is unclear how the nonfarm sector
sector growth have had positive impacts would be largely responsible for increasing
on rural wages but the size of the latter the agricultural wage without causing a sub-
effect is larger. This result emerges from stantial increase in nonfarm employment.
the impressive growth in the rural factory In a land constrained agricultural econ-
sector during this period. The percentage omy, a rapidly growing nonfarm sector can
of villages with factories increased from 17 draw labor from land, increase labor produc-
to 51 percent and the average number of tivity and agricultural wages, and thus reduce
factory workers per village increased ten-fold poverty. For the fifteen major Indian states,
from 5.6 to 56.7. The clear implication is that figure 15 (from Mukesh Eswaran et al. 2009)
a dynamic nonfarm sector increased rural plots the average real daily wages (in 1999
wages and cut rural poverty in the sample of rupees) in agriculture against the labor–land
villages studied in the paper. ratio (days per hectare of gross cropped area)
It should be noted, however, that the for 1983 and 2004. It can be seen that, for
nationally representative NSS data do not all but four states (Kerala, Haryana, Punjab,
show even a modest rise in the ­relative share and Rajasthan), the labor use per hectare of
1188 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XLIX (December 2011)

90

1983 2004
80

70
Real daily wage, 1999 rupees

60

50

40

30

20

10

0
0 100 200 300 400 500 600
Labor–land ratio

Figure 15. Agricultural Earnings and Labor–Land Ratios: 1983–04

Source: Eswaran, Kotwal, Ramaswami, and Wadhwa (2009).

land has increased over this period. Yet, in to nonfarm TFP growth would depend,
all states, real wages have increased during of course, on the amount of labor drawn
this period. At the all-India level, real daily away from agriculture. Because of the lim-
wages increased by 74 percent between 1983 ited extent to which nonfarm employment
and 2004. Quite clearly, if either farm TFP has grown (relative to the agricultural work
or agricultural inputs such as fertilizers had force), Eswaran et al. (2008) estimate that
not increased during this period, agricultural nonfarm sector TFP growth could not be
wages would have declined. responsible for more than 22 percent of the
It becomes interesting, therefore, to ask wage growth during 1983–99.
how much the nonfarm sector growth has The analysis of Eswaran et al. (2009) also
contributed to the growth of agricultural shows that it is the younger and more edu-
wages. The extent of wage increase due cated male cohorts that are most mobile
Kotwal, Ramaswami, and Wadhwa: Economic Liberalization and Indian Economic Growth 1189

across sectors.34 Older males and females of themselves against consumption contingen-
all ages are directly affected by a slowdown cies (Dean Karlan and Jonathan Morduch
in agricultural growth. The stock of labor 2009). Moreover, microfinance is much
force already locked into agriculture is large more than microcredit. The poor also put a
(relative, in particular, to new employment great deal of value on having access to a safe
opportunities in other sectors) and so non- way to save.
farm employment would have to grow sub- In India, some NGOs are engaged in
stantially faster if it has to make a dent into microfinance schemes in rural communities,
poverty. It seems reasonable to suppose that as well as urban slums, and often the results
agricultural productivity would have to con- are encouraging. Banerjee et al. (2010) per-
tinue to increase in order to improve the liv- formed a randomized experiment on one
ing standards of much of the rural poor. such NGO engaged in group-lending in the
For the young and mobile, access to edu- slums of Hyderabad. The impact on the bor-
cation would determine their prospects of rowers was positive, though not necessarily
nonfarm jobs. Ravallion (2009) points out through an increase in their average con-
that educational inequalities in India are sumption. There was greater investment in
much worse than in comparable large coun- business durables as well as an increase in
tries such as Brazil and China. It is only in new businesses started. By necessity, such
2005 that India’s enrollment and literacy studies are microstudies of particular cases.
percentages have equaled or surpassed We are not aware of any study that has tried
China’s record at the beginning of its reform to evaluate the overall role of microfinance
period (1981). in the Indian economy.
Recent work (Daryl Collins et al. 2009)
has revealed how important consumption
7.  Determinants of Agricultural Growth
smoothing is for the poor who seldom have a
steady source of income. When we are con- The change in labor productivity in agricul-
sidering the well-being of the poor, it is not ture is the sum of change in land productivity
enough to take their wages or daily earnings (yields) and the land–labor ratio. Figure 16
into account. It is also necessary to ask if they summarizes the changes in all three vari-
have access to any means of consumption ables (for crop agriculture) from the mid-
smoothing. The poor may save for this pur- 1960s to mid-1990s. This picture shows that
pose or may resort to locally available infor- despite continuous decline in the land–labor
mal credit. Patron–client relationships, in ratio, labor productivity has registered posi-
which workers take loans from their employ- tive growth driven by land productivity. The
ers or from the local rich, survive precisely adverse movement in the land–labor ratio
because of the informal insurance arrange- reflects the limited absorption of unskilled
ments they make possible. Microfinance labor by the nonfarm sector. At the aggre-
has emerged as a possible alternative. Even gate level, this pictue is an explanation of the
though it originated as a tool to facilitate wage trends oberved in figure 15.
creation of self-employment for the poor, In the period from early 1960s to early
it is now well accepted that the poor use it 1970s, the rate of growth of labor productiv-
for various purposes including for insuring ity was miniscule (0.26 percent per annum)
as land productivity increase (1.6 percent
34 Education and access to nonfarm jobs are strongly
per annum) was almost neutralized by the
correlated. For a recent analysis, see Kijima and Lanjouw adverse change in land–labor ratio (–1.3
(2005). percent per annum). The land productivity
1190 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XLIX (December 2011)

Output/hectare

Hectare/worker
3
Output/worker
Annualized rate of growth (percent)

−1

1962–65 to 1970–73 1970–73 to 1980–83 1980–83 to 1992–95


−2

Figure 16. Agricultural Productivity: 1962–95

Notes: Crop output is measured in terms of 1990–93 prices and workers refer to male workers in crop
agriculture.
Source: Authors’ calculations using data in Bhalla and Singh (2001).

growth was slightly higher in the 1970s and residual term. Figure 17 presents their results
much higher in the 1980s. The land–labor for the 1980s and 1990s. In both periods, the
ratio continues to decline through all three value of crop output grew at roughly the same
decades but the rate of decline is highest in rate (3.5 percent). The figures show that out-
the 1980s. However, because of a substantial put growth owes very little to area expansion.
step-up of yields in the 1980s, this is also the So these figures could also be interpreted as
period with the highest rate of increase of accounting for the change in land productiv-
labor productivity. ity. In the 1980s, the major sources of higher
P. K. Joshi, Pratap Singh Birthal, and land productivity were technology (higher
Nicholas Minot (2006) decomposed the crop yields) and diversification (shift to higher
change in value of crop output into changes value crops). In the 1990s, technology, diver-
in crop area, crop yields, crop prices, shifts in sification, and real price changes are all about
crop output (toward higher value crops), and a equally responsible. Since crop output grew
Kotwal, Ramaswami, and Wadhwa: Economic Liberalization and Indian Economic Growth 1191

Yields
Yields 29%
Area 54%
10%
Area 4% Prices
35%
Diversification Diversification
27% 31%
8%
Prices

1980–81 1991–92
to to
1990–91 1999–00

Figure 17: Decomposition of Crop Output Growth

Source: Joshi, Birthal, and Minot (2006).

at the same rate in both these decades, the (especially the high yielding seed varieties
figures imply that growth due to technology of the Green Revolution), irrigation, and
has slowed in the 1990s. This is corroborated ­infrastructure (roads, markets) as well subsi-
by the leveling of yields in rice, wheat, cot- dies on irrigation and electricity charges and
ton, and sugarcane. The slowdown is particu- fertilizer prices.37 Subsidies for fertilizers,
larly marked after 1995 (Ramesh Chand, S. canal irrigation, and electricity have grown
S. Raju, and L. M. Pandey 2007).35 over time and now account for nearly 10 per-
Rising urban incomes and the diversifi- cent of agricultural GDP (V. S. Vyas 2008).
cation of diets toward fruits and vegetables About 73 percent of subsidy expenditure is
explains the diversification component of because of subsidies to electricity. Figure 18
crop output growth in both periods. The plots the movement of public and private
share of fruits and vegetables in crop output investment in agriculture and that of input
rose from 13.7 percent in 1982–83 to 20.5 subsidies.
percent in 1999–2000. Although the diversi- Compared to the economywide rate of
fication is component is larger in the 1990s, investment of 27 percent in the late 1990s,
this process was well underway in the 1980s investment in agriculture is only about 16
as well.36 percent of agricultural GDP of which on-
Public spending on agriculture has con- farm investment is only about 6 percent
sisted of public investments in technology, and the remainder is in agriculture-related

35 Even crop output growth is slower in this period. 37 The modern Green Revolution varieties achieve their
36 Although exports are rising, it is domestic demand high yields because they are more responsive to fertilizers
that is primarily driving diversification (Praduman Kumar, than traditional varieties. Increasing fertilizer use is there-
Mruthyunjaya, and Madan M. Dey 2007). fore a cornerstone of increasing crop yields.
1192 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XLIX (December 2011)

500

Input subsidies
400
Rupees billion, constant prices

300

Private

200

100

Public

0
1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004
Year

Figure 18: Investment in Agriculture, 1980–2004

Source: National Accounts Statistics—public and private investment in 1999–2000 prices.


Mullen, Orden, and Gulati (2005)—input subsidies in 2000–01 prices.

a­ctivities (Rip Landes and Ashok Gulati have encouraged certain kinds of private
2004). Public investment has been a declin- investment in agriculture.38
ing force since the 1980s while private Yet, private investment cannot fully sub-
investment picked up in the late 1980s. stitute for some forms of public investment.
Input subsidies on the other hand have Besides infrastructure investments such as
moved smoothly upwards throughout the roads and market facilities, many agricultural
period. This has led many to argue that it is technologies are themselves public goods.
the rising subsidies that have led to declining
allocations for public investment (Landes 38 For instance, subsidies to electricity charges have
and Gulati 2004; C. H. Hanumantha Rao encouraged investment in tube-wells and pumpsets to
2003). On the other hand, input subsidies extract groundwater.
Kotwal, Ramaswami, and Wadhwa: Economic Liberalization and Indian Economic Growth 1193

The best instance of this are the Green is evidence that the productivity of the
Revolution seed varieties. Among seeds, an research system has declined. For instance,
important distinction is between hybrids and according to government estimates (India
open-pollinated varieties. Once the seeds of Planning Commission 2008), an index
open-pollinated varieties have been distrib- of yields of new varieties of the major
uted, they can be reproduced for several gen- field crops has shown no change between
erations by farmers without serious loss of 1996–97 and 2005–06 after growing at
quality. The dissemination of these seeds can about 3 percent per year from 1980–81 to
therefore take place rapidly through informal 1996–97. The review by Jha and Pal (2008)
exchange of seeds between farmers. For this highlights poor financial management, the
reason, the private sector has little interest proliferation of bureaucratic procedures,
in developing new open-pollinated variet- and the absence of accountability in R&D
ies. Like in the rest of the world, the Indian projects.40 The problem of low-quality insti-
private seed sector works mostly on hybrid tutions has also been cited in many other
varieties. These seeds cannot be reproduced areas of public investment and spending,
without a loss in yields and hence provides including the construction and manage-
the seed company with some measure of pro- ment of canal irrigation systems and in the
tection for its innovation. However, hybrids provision of agricultural extension services
are unimportant for the major food staples of (Ramaswamy R. Iyer, K. V. Raju, and Jinxia
rice and wheat and as well as for many other Wang 2008; Katharina Raabe 2008; Prakash
field crops.39 Shingi et al. 2004; A. Vaidyanathan 1999).
Among other areas that must be addressed The wide-ranging economic reforms of
by public investments are initiatives to com- the 1990s and the limited policy changes
bat degradation of land resources (soil ero- preceding it were principally directed at
sion, salinity, and water logging, some of trade, industry, and financial markets. It has
which occurs because of negative externali- been argued that, since it was industry that
ties from poorly planned canal irrigation proj- was protected during the earlier regime,
ects), measures to harness and conserve water the dismantling of tariffs (and the associ-
resources to reverse the depletion of under- ated exchange rate devaluation) was pri-
ground aquifers, and immunization programs marily responsible for the improvement in
to control disease in the livestock sector. the terms of trade for agriculture and hence
Paucity of resources is not always the the sizable price effect in the 1990s seen in
constraint, however. Studies point to poor figure 17 (Ahluwalia 2002; Balakrishnan,
governance as well. A case in point is the Golait, and Kumar 2008; Landes and Gulati
public sector research system. Although 2004). It should be noted, however, that the
expenditures on research have not grown as early 1990s also saw sharp increases in gov-
rapidly in the 1990s as in the earlier decades ernment support prices for rice and wheat
(Balakrishnan, Ramesh Golait, and Kumar and so the movement in terms of trade
2008; Dayanatha Jha and Suresh Pal 2008), in favor of agriculture cannot be entirely
there is no precipitous decline and the attributed to trade liberalization. Indeed,
expenditure as percentage of agricultural the terms of trade begin to move against
GDP at the end of the 1990s was higher
than at any point earlier. Nonetheless, there
40 Despite these problems, the median rate of return
to agricultural research investments was 58 percent in the
39 The major hybrid seed markets are in vegetables, cot- twenty-eight studies reviewed by Pal and Derek Byerlee
ton, maize, sorghum, and pearl millet. (2003). The payoff from institutional reforms is large.
1194 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XLIX (December 2011)

agriculture after the mid-1990s even though to imported machinery that was made pos-
import tariffs on nonfarm goods were fall- sible by trade liberalization. Improved com-
ing right through the decade. For this rea- munications (especially cell phones) and the
son, the price effect identified in the Joshi diffusion of the Internet were other technol-
et al. study is unlikely to have lasted beyond ogies that played a big role in driving growth
this decade.41 from the mid-1990s on. It is inconceivable
The principal contribution of economic that, without the breakup of government
reforms to agricultural growth is likely to monopolies and the advent of competition
have been the diversification effect as ris- in the communication sector, there would
ing incomes have led consumers to demand have been a revolution in communication
more of edible oils, milk, fruits, and vegeta- technology in India. And, without such a
bles than of staple food cereals.42 The techno- revolution, the fastest growing sectors (e.g.,
logical component of agricultural growth is, business services) would not have taken off
however, determined by the internal dynam- in India. The sustained growth that we have
ics of the sector—by public spending on seen since the mid-1990s would clearly not
investment and subsidies and by the capacity have been possible without the liberalizing
of public institutions to manage investments reforms of 1991. The importance of liber-
and push technologies effectively. The econ- alization measures can be appreciated by
omywide reforms have left this aspect of the imagining the counterfactual that India had
agricultural economy largely untouched. stayed in its prereform state of constraints
on entrepreneurial freedoms to invest and
import. New technologies would not have
8.  What is Distinct about India’s
diffused at such a speed and growth would
Experience?
have been much slower.
It is clear from the earlier sections that At the same time, as stressed by Kochhar
the growth episode in India since the 1980s et al. (2006), it should be acknowledged that
is not another instance of state-driven some aspects of the earlier economic regime
growth in Asia. Instead, it is the coincidence played a positive role in the pattern of devel-
of the ready availability of new technolo- opment later. For example, the creation of
gies and having the skilled manpower that a diverse set of skills through import sub-
would be necessary to take advantage of stitution, an emphasis on tertiary education
these new technologies. Technology trans- creating a pool of university graduates for
fers in the 1980s and early 1990s took place sophisticated service sector jobs, and a gov-
mostly through easier and cheaper access ernment induced expansion of banking net-
work that helped in mobilizing savings. The
41 This is confirmed by an updated analysis from Birthal initial conditions and their interaction with
et al. (2008). This paper compares the period 1981–82 to the fortuitous arrival of new technologies
1995–96 with the period 1995–96—2004–05. Crop output created a distinctive pattern of growth that
growth decelerates from 3.8 percent in the first period
to 2.1 percent in the second period. In the first period, would have been hard to predict at the time
about 62 percent of output growth is due to rising yields, of liberalization.
20 percent due to diversification, and 12 percent due to Another distinctive feature of the Indian
the price effect. In the second period, these figures are 45
percent, 43 percent, and 7 percent, respectively. growth experience is the dominance of the
42 In the decade of the 2000s, several Indian states service sector. In East and Southeast Asia,
carried out reforms of their agricultural marketing sector it was the manufacturing sector. One could
that allowed new marketing institutions including contract
agriculture. These reforms are particularly helpful to the look at this in several different ways. If we
horticultural sector. compare China with India, it is indeed the
Kotwal, Ramaswami, and Wadhwa: Economic Liberalization and Indian Economic Growth 1195

manufacturing sector that grew the fastest in infrastructure, restrictive labor laws, and small
China and vice versa in India. However, both scale reservation policy have been identified
sectors grew faster in both countries than in as the main reasons (e.g., Panagariya 2008). It
the rest of the world and both sectors grew is very possible that these factors reduced the
faster in China than in India. Yes, even ser- possibility of India emerging as an exporter of
vices grew faster in China than in India. The labor intensive manufacturers—a possibility
main distinction is in terms of what com- that would have hastened the decline in pov-
prised their exports. Here it is services for erty. Finding export markets in high-income
India and manufacturing for China. Indeed, countries makes the choice set of production
it is the software exports to the developed activities independent of domestic demand
countries that spread the word that India composition. The growth in domestic
was unique as a developing country to have demand will depend on the composition of
developed a comparative advantage in high- income growth. In other words, if the growth
end services. In a curious way, this was the in incomes is skewed in favor of high skilled
reason for it being accepted as a develop- and therefore high-income groups, it will be
ment success story despite the fact that it the kind of goods and services catered to by
continues to house more of the world’s poor the rich that will be found lucrative by inves-
than any other country. tors. Few of them will be unskilled labor
What are the implications of the fast grow- intensive. As a result, the trickle down to the
ing component of the exports being high- unskilled (and hence the poor) will be weak.
end services as opposed to manufacturing? One possible bottleneck for the Indian
For one thing, manufacturing uses unskilled pattern of growth is “educated workforce.”
labor more intensively. In the Indian context, Given that the educational premia have
this is especially true of unorganized manu- been rising rapidly, it does seem like a real
facturing and it is conceivable that manufac- possibility. Most of the fast growing sectors
turing exports would have generated a great are completely dependent on skilled man-
deal of subcontracting to the unorganized power. If they run into a serious bottleneck,
sector. This, in turn, would have drawn labor growth may get choked. A related question is
out of agriculture to a greater extent. that of quality. According to a report by the
Indeed, one major feature of India’s Diana Farrell et al. (2005), “India’s vast sup-
development pattern is that the share of ply of graduates is smaller than it seems once
agriculture in employment has not come their suitability for employment by multina-
down rapidly. In fact, the absolute amount tional companies is considered.” The report
of labor in agriculture has risen continuously stresses that the government must “adjust
in India while it fell in all countries now the country’s educational policy to ward off
developed during their comparable devel- the looming squeeze on talent.” Farrell et
opment phases. An important component of al. estimate that India has 14 million young
growth—moving labor from low to high pro- university graduates (those with seven years
ductivity activities—has been conspicuous or less of work experience). This pool is 1.5
by its absence in India. Also, as the labor to times the size of China’s and almost twice
land ratio grows, it becomes that much more that of the United States. Every year, 2.5
difficult to increase agricultural wages and million new graduates are added to this pool.
reduce poverty. However, according to the report, while the
There has been much discussion in the numbers seem encouraging at first glance, a
literature as to why the manufacturing sec- closer look reveals that India is likely to face
tor has not grown faster in India. Inadequate a talent crunch in the coming years.
1196 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XLIX (December 2011)

The problem might get further exacerbated level (Rs. 356 per capita per month or approx-
with the current state of primary schooling imately $1.08 per day). If we consider double
in India. The Annual Status of Education the poverty level ($2.16 per day), a stagger-
Report 2010 (Assessment Survey Evaluation ing 80 percent of India’s population was poor
Research Centre 2011), a unique survey of in 1983 and the number is about the same
learning in rural India, estimates that about in 2004. This is a startling fact and indicates
47 percent of rural Indian children in class 5 that there are two Indias: one of educated
cannot read a simple class 2 level text. Even, managers and engineers who have been
in class 8, about 17 percent of children cannot able to take advantage of the opportunities
read a class 2 level text. Many of these chil- made available through globalization and the
dren may never reach university, but those other—a huge mass of undereducated peo-
who do not go to university will join the labor ple who are making a living in low productiv-
force and ASER’s results are indicative of the ity jobs in the informal sector—the largest of
future quality of the labor force. The Right of which is still “agriculture.” The most direct
Children to Free and Compulsory Education impact on the second India could only come
Act, which was passed by the Parliament in about through improvements in agricultural
April 2010, makes sure that no child will be productivity. But unfortunately, agricul-
held back until the age of 14 (approximately ture is dependent on well-functioning rural
class 8), regardless of how they perform. This institutions. In general, the productivity
will mean that children could easily pass mid- improvements in the informal sector depend
dle school (class 7/8) without being tested crucially on access to credit, know-how, and
on any learning indicators. Even if they drop skills and therefore on the quality of institu-
out after class 8, they would enter the skilled tions. India’s future will depend a great deal
labor force (by our definition) and could be on how these institutional improvements
potentially unemployable. Therefore, it is shape up.
quite possible that the so-called demographic
dividend may disappear if the quality of the References
labor force is not improved, even if the non-
farm sector creates sufficient jobs to absorb Aghion, Philippe, Robin Burgess, Stephen Redding,
and Fabrizio Zilibotti. 2003. “The Unequal Effects
the increase in labor force. of Liberalization: Theory and Evidence from India.”
A larger point is that India’s economic Unpublished.
growth is not accompanied by an equally Ahluwalia, Montek S. 1999. “India’s Economic
Reforms: An Appraisal.” In India in the Era of
fast improvement in the functioning of Economic Reforms, ed. Jeffrey D. Sachs, Ashutosh
India’s institutions such as the legal system Varshney, and Nirupam Bajpai, 26–80. New Delhi:
and the educational system (Subramanian Oxford University Press.
Ahluwalia, Montek S. 2002. “Economic Reforms in
2007). Indeed, it is easier and faster to trans- India since 1991: Has Gradualism Worked?” Journal
fer technology and bring about productivity of Economic Perspectives, 16(3): 67–88.
improvements. But it is harder and slower to Anant, T. C. A., Rana Hasan, P. Mohapatra, R. Nagaraj,
and S. K. Sasikumar. 2006. “Labor Markets in India:
bring about institutional improvements for Issues and Perspectives.” In Labor Markets in Asia:
sustaining and stabilizing the growth process. Issues and Perspectives, ed. Jesus Felipe and Rana
One important lesson from the Indian Hasan, 205–300. Houndmills, U.K. and New York:
Palgrave Macmillan.
experience and especially from its compari- Assessment Survey Evaluation Research Centre. 2011.
son with other Asian countries is that a coun- Annual Status of Education Report 2010. New Delhi:
try can neglect agriculture at its own peril. Pratham Resources Centre.
Athukorala, Prema-chandra, and Kunal Sen. 2002. Sav-
The growth process in India was accompa- ing, Investment, and Growth in India. Oxford and
nied by a reduction in poverty at the lower New York: Oxford University Press.
Kotwal, Ramaswami, and Wadhwa: Economic Liberalization and Indian Economic Growth 1197

Bai, Jushan, and Pierre Perron. 1998. “Estimating and ­ anufacturing Sector.” William Davidson Institute
M
Testing Linear Models with Multiple Structural Working Paper 822.
Changes.” Econometrica, 66(1): 47–78. Birthal, Pratap Singh, P. K. Joshi, Sonia Chauhan, and
Bai, Jushan, and Pierre Perron. 2003. “Computation Harvinder Singh. 2008. “Can Horticulture Revitalise
and Analysis of Multiple Structural Change Models.” Agricultural Growth?” Indian Journal of Agricultural
Journal of Applied Econometrics, 18(1): 1–22. Economics, 63(3): 310–21.
Bajpai, Nirupam, and Jeffrey D. Sachs. 1999. “Fiscal Bosworth, Barry, Susan M. Collins, and Arvind Virmani.
Policy in India’s Economic Reforms.” In India in 2007. “Sources of Growth in the Indian Economy.”
the Era of Economic Reforms, ed. Jeffrey D. Sachs, National Bureau of Economic Research Working
Ashutosh Varshney, and Nirupam Bajpai, 81–120. Paper 12901.
New Delhi: Oxford University Press. Burgess, Robin, and Rohini Pande. 2005. “Do Rural
Balakrishnan, Pulapre. 2007. “The Recovery of India: Banks Matter? Evidence from the Indian Social
Economic Growth in the Nehru Era.” Economic and Banking Experiment.” American Economic Review,
Political Weekly, 42(45–46): 52–66. 95(3): 780–95.
Balakrishnan, Pulapre, Ramesh Golait, and Pankaj Chand, Ramesh, S. S. Raju, and L. M. Pandey. 2007.
Kumar. 2008. “Agricultural Growth in India since “Growth Crisis in Agriculture.” Economic and Politi-
1991.” Reserve Bank of India Department of Eco- cal Weekly, 42(26): 2528–33.
nomic Analysis and Policy Study 27. Chanda, Rupa. 2007. “Services.” In Oxford Compan-
Balakrishnan, Pulapre, and M. Parameswaran. 2007. ion to Economics in India, ed. Kaushik Basu, 472–79.
“Understanding Economic Growth in India: A Pre- New Delhi: Oxford University Press.
requisite.” Economic and Political Weekly, 42(27– Cohen, Stephen P. 2001. India: Emerging Power.
28): 2915–22. Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution Press.
Banerjee, Abhijit V., and Esther Duflo. 2004. “What Do Collins, Daryl, Jonathan Morduch, Stuart Rutherford,
Banks (Not) Do?” Economic and Political Weekly, and Orlanda Ruthven. 2009. Portfolios of the Poor:
39(38): 4212–13. How the World’s Poor Live on $2 a Day. Princeton
Banerjee, Abhijit V., and Esther Duflo. 2005. “Growth and Oxford: Princeton University Press.
Theory through the Lens of Development Econom- Das, D. K. 2007. “Trade Barriers in Manufacturing.”
ics.” In Handbook of Economic Growth, Volume 1A, In Oxford Companion to Economics in India, ed.
ed. Philippe Aghion and Steven N. Durlauf, 473–554. Kaushik Basu, 531–34. New Delhi: Oxford Univer-
Amsterdam and San Diego: Elsevier, North-Holland. sity Press.
Banerjee, Abhijit V., and Esther Duflo. 2007. “The Eco- Datt, Gaurav, and Martin Ravallion. 1998. “Farm Pro-
nomic Lives of the Poor.” Journal of Economic Per- ductivity and Rural Poverty in India.” Journal of
spectives, 21(1): 141–67. Development Studies, 34(4): 62–85.
Banerjee, Abhijit V., Esther Duflo, Rachel Glennerster, Datt, Gaurav, and Martin Ravallion. 2002. “Is India’s
and Cynthia Kinnan. 2010. “The Miracle of Micro- Economic Growth Leaving the Poor Behind?” Jour-
finance? Evidence from a Randomized Evaluation.” nal of Economic Perspectives, 16(3): 89–108.
http://econ-www.mit.edu/files/6093. Deaton, Angus, and Valerie Kozel. 2005. The Great
Basu, Kaushik, ed. 2004. India’s Emerging Economy: Indian Poverty Debate. New Delhi: Macmillan.
Performance and Prospects in the 1990s and Beyond. DeLong, J. Bradford. 2003. “India since Independence:
Cambridge and London: MIT Press. An Analytic Growth Narrative.” In In Search of Pros-
Basu, Kaushik. 2008. “The Enigma of India’s Arrival: A perity: Analytic Narratives on Economic Growth, ed.
Review of Arvind Virmani’s Propelling India: From Dani Rodrik, 184–204. Princeton and Oxford: Princ-
Socialist Stagnation to Global Power.” Journal of eton University Press.
Economic Literature, 46(2): 396–406. DeLong, J. Bradford, and Lawrence H. Summers.
Basu, Kaushik, and Annemie Maertens. 2007. “The 1991. “Equipment Investment and Economic
Pattern and Causes of Economic Growth in India.” Growth.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 106(2):
Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 23(2): 143–67. 445–502.
Besley, Timothy, and Robin Burgess. 2004. “Can Labor Dossani, Rafiq. 2008. India Arriving: How This Eco-
Regulation Hinder Economic Performance? Evi- nomic Powerhouse Is Redefining Global Business.
dence from India.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, New York: AMACOM.
119(1): 91–134. Dougherty, Sean M. 2008. “Labour Regulation and
Bhalla, G. S., and Gurmail Singh. 2001. Indian Agri- Employment Dynamics at the State Level in India.”
culture: Four Decades of Development. New Delhi: Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Devel-
Sage Publications. opment Economics Department Working Paper 624.
Bhattacharjea, Aditya. 2006. “Labour Market Regula- Eichengreen, Barry, and Poonam Gupta. 2010. “The
tion and Industrial Performance in India: A Critical Service Sector as India’s Road to Economic Growth?”
Review of the Empirical Evidence.” Indian Journal Indian Council for Research on International Eco-
of Labour Economics, 49(2): 211–32. nomic Relations Working Paper 249.
Bhaumik, Sumon Kumar, Shubhashis Gangopad- Eswaran, Mukesh, Ashok Kotwal, Bharat Ramaswami,
hyay, and Shagun Krishnan. 2006. “Reforms, Entry and Wilima Wadhwa. 2008. “How Does Poverty
and Productivity: Some Evidence from the Indian Decline? Suggestive Evidence from India, 1983–
1198 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XLIX (December 2011)

1999.” Bureau for Research in Economic Analysis of and Contemporary Issues.” In The Dragon and the
Development Policy Paper 14. Elephant: Agricultural and Rural Reforms in China
Eswaran, Mukesh, Ashok Kotwal, Bharat Ramaswami, and India, ed. Ashok Gulati and Shenggen Fan, 160–
and Wilima Wadhwa. 2009. “Sectoral Labour Flows 179. New Delhi: Oxford University Press.
and Agricultural Wages in India, 1983–2004: Has Joshi, P. K., Pratap Singh Birthal, and Nicholas Minot.
Growth Trickled Down?” Economic and Political 2006. “Sources of Agricultural Growth in India: Role
Weekly, 44(2): 46–55. of Diversification towards High-Value Crops.” Inter-
Evenson, Robert E., Carl E. Pray, and Mark W. Rose- national Food Policy Research Institute Markets,
grant. 1999. “Agricultural Research and Produc- Trade and Institutions Division Discussion Paper 98.
tivity Growth in India.” International Food Policy Joshi, Vijay, and I. M. D. Little. 1994. India: Macroeco-
Research Institute Research Report 109. nomics and Political Economy, 1964–1991. Washing-
Farrell, Diana, Martha Laboissière, Jaeson Rosenfeld, ton, D.C.: World Bank.
Sascha Stürze, and Fusayo Umezawa. The Emerging Joshi, Vijay, and I. M. D. Little. 1996. India’s Economic
Global Labor Market: Part II—The Supply of Off- Reforms, 1991–2001. Oxford and New York: Oxford
shore Talent in Services. New York: McKinsey Global University Press, Clarendon Press.
Institute. Karlan, Dean, and Jonathan Morduch. 2009. “Access
Foster, Andrew D., and Mark R. Rosenzweig. 2003. to Finance.” In Handbook of Development Econom-
“Agricultural Development, Industrialization and ics, Volume 5, ed. Dani Rodrik and Mark Rosenz-
Rural Inequality.” Unpublished. weig, 4703–84. Amsterdam and San Diego: Elsevier,
Foster, Andrew D., and Mark R. Rosenzweig. 2004. North-Holland.
“Agricultural Productivity Growth, Rural Economic Kijima, Yoko, and Peter Lanjouw. 2005. “Economic
Diversity, and Economic Reforms: India, 1970– Diversification and Poverty in Rural India.” Indian
2000.” Economic Development and Cultural Change, Journal of Labour Economics, 48(2): 349–74.
52(3): 509–42. Kochhar, Kalpana, Utsav Kumar, Raghuram Rajan,
Gangopadhyay, Shubhashis, Manisha G. Singh, and Arvind Subramanian, and Ioannis Tokatlidis. 2006.
Nirvikar Singh. 2008. Information Technology and “India’s Pattern of Development: What Happened,
Skilled Labour Complementarities in Indian Indus- What Follows?” Journal of Monetary Economics,
try: A Micro-econometric Analysis. New Delhi: 53(5): 981–1019.
FICCI. Kumar, Praduman, Mruthyunjaya, and Madan M. Dey.
Goldar, Bishwanath. 2006. “Productivity Growth in 2007. “Long-Term Changes in Indian Food Basket
Indian Manufacturing in the 1980s and 1990s.” In and Nutrition.” Economic & Political Weekly, 42(35):
India: Industrialisation in a Reforming Economy: 3567–72.
Essays for K L Krishna, ed. Suresh D. Tendulkar, Landes, Rip, and Ashok Gulati. 2004. “Farm Sector
Arup Mitra, K. Narayanan, and Deb Kusum Das, Performance and Reform Agenda.” Economic and
31–53. New Delhi: Academic Foundation. Political Weekly, 39(32): 3611–19.
Gupta, Poonam, Rana Hasan, and Utsav Kumar. 2008. Lipton, Michael. 1989. New Seeds and Poor People.
“What Constrains Indian Manufacturing.” Indian Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.
Council for Research on International Economic Misra, V. N. 2004. “Terms of Trade.” In State of the
Relations Working Paper 211. Indian Farmer: A Millennium Study, Volume 15, 89.
Hasan, Rana, Devashish Mitra, and K. V. Ramaswamy. New Delhi: Academic Foundation.
2007. “Trade Reforms, Labor Regulations, and Mullen, Kathleen, David Orden, and Ashok Gulati.
Labor-Demand Elasticities: Empirical Evidence 2005. “Agricultural Policies in India: Producer Sup-
from India.” Review of Economics and Statistics, port Estimates 1985–2002.” International Food
89(3): 466–81. Policy Research Institute Markets, Trade and Insti-
India Planning Commission. 2008. Eleventh Five Year tutions Division Discussion Paper 82.
Plan (2007–2012): Volume 3. Agriculture, Rural Murthy, N. R. Narayana. 2004. “The Impact of Eco-
Development, Industry, Services and Physical Infra- nomic Reforms on Industry in India: A Case Study
structure. New Delhi: Oxford University Press. of the Software Industry.” In India’s Emerging Econ-
Iyer, Ramaswamy R., K. V. Raju, and Jinxia Wang. 2008. omy: Performance and Prospects in the 1990s and
“Policy and Institutional Reforms in the Water Sec- Beyond, ed. Kaushik Basu, 217–22. Cambridge and
tor: Experiences and Lessons from China and India.” London: MIT Press.
In The Dragon and the Elephant: Agricultural and Murthy, N. R. Narayana. 2007. “Software Exports.”
Rural Reforms in China and India, ed. Ashok Gulati In Oxford Companion to Economics in India, ed.
and Shenggen Fan, 180–206. New Delhi: Oxford Kaushik Basu, 490–93. New Delhi: Oxford Univer-
University Press. sity Press.
Jensen, Robert. 2007. “The Digital Provide: Informa- Nataraj, Shanthi. 2009. “The Impact of Trade Liberal-
tion (Technology), Market Performance, and Wel- ization on Productivity and Firm Size: Evidence from
fare in the South Indian Fisheries Sector.” Quarterly India’s Formal and Informal Manufacturing Sectors.”
Journal of Economics, 122(3): 879–924. Unpublished.
Jha, Dayanatha, and Suresh Pal. 2008. “Agricultural National Commission for Enterprises in the Unorga-
Research and Technology in India: Status, Impact, nized Sector. 2008. Definitional and Statistical Issues:
Kotwal, Ramaswami, and Wadhwa: Economic Liberalization and Indian Economic Growth 1199

Task Force Report. New Delhi: National Commis- Organized Manufacturing Sector in India.” Paper
sion for Enterprises in the Unorganised Sector. presented at the Seminar Series of the Minis-
Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Develop- try of Statistics and Programme Implementation,
ment. 2007. OECD Economic Surveys: India 2007. ­November. http://mospi.nic.in/mospi_seminarseries_
Paris and Washington, D.C.: Organisation for Eco- nov04_3_6_final.pdf.
nomic Co-operation and Development. Rodrik, Dani, and Arvind Subramanian. 2004. “Why
Özler, Berk, Gaurav Datt, and Martin Ravallion. India Can Grow at 7 Percent a Year or More: Pro-
1996. “Database on Poverty and Growth in India.” jections and Reflections.” Economic and Political
Unpublished. Weekly, 39(16): 1519–26.
Pal, Suresh, and Derek Byerlee. 2003. “The Funding Rodrik, Dani, and Arvind Subramanian. 2005. “From
and Organization of Agricultural Research in India: ‘Hindu Growth’ to Productivity Surge: The Mystery
Evolution and Emerging Policy Issues.” National of the Indian Growth Transition.” IMF Staff Papers,
Centre for Agricultural Economics and Policy 52(2): 193–228.
Research Policy Paper 16. Sen, Kunal. 2007. “Why Did the Elephant Start to
Palmer-Jones, Richard, and Kunal Sen. 2003. “What Trot? India’s Growth Acceleration Re-examined.”
Has Luck Got to Do with It? A Regional Analysis Economic and Political Weekly, 42(43): 37–47.
of Poverty and Agricultural Growth in Rural India.” Shetty, S. L. 2007. “Status Paper on Database Issues of
Journal of Development Studies, 40(1): 1–31. the Services Sector.” Economic and Political Weekly,
Palmer-Jones, Richard, and Kunal Sen. 2007. “Did 42(37): 3723–26.
Agricultural Growth Trickle Down in India? What Do Shingi, Prakash, Vijay R. Gaikwad, Rasheed Sulaiman,
We Really-Really Know?” In India Macroeconomics and J. Vasanthakumar. 2004. State of the Indian
Annual: 2006, ed. Sugata Marjit, 126–67. London Farmer: A Millennium Study, Volume 6. New Delhi:
and Thousand Oaks, Calif.: Sage Publications. Academic Foundation.
Panagariya, Arvind. 2004. “Growth and Reforms during Singh, Nirvikar. 2006. “Services-Led Industrialization
1980s and 1990s.” Economic and Political Weekly, in India: Assessment and Lessons.” Unpublished.
39(2): 2581–94. Sinha, Ajit, and Shirin Tejani. 2004. “Trend Break in
Panagariya, Arvind. 2008. India: The Emerging Giant. India’s GDP Growth Rate: Some Comments.” Eco-
Oxford and New York: Oxford University Press. nomic and Political Weekly, 39(52): 5634–39.
Parikh, Kirit S. 2006. “Indian Economy: A Shining Star Srinivasan, T. N., and Suresh D. Tendulkar. 2003. Rein-
or a Passing Comet?” In India–ASEAN Economic tegrating India with the World Economy. Washing-
Relations: Meeting the Challenges of Globalization, ton, D.C.: Institute for International Economics.
ed. Naghesh Kumar, Rahul Sen, and Mukul Asher, Subramanian, Arvind. 2007. “The Evolution of Institu-
15–39. New Delhi: Research and Information Sys- tions in India and Its Relationship with Economic
tem for Developing Countries; Singapore: Institute Growth.” Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 23(2):
of Southeast Asian Studies. 196–220.
Raabe, Katharina. 2008. “Reforming the Agricultural Topalova, Petia. 2004. “Trade Liberalization and Firm
Extension System in India: What Do We Know about Productivity: The Case of India.” International Mon-
What Works Where and Why?” International Food etary Fund Working Paper 04/28.
Policy Research Institute Discussion Paper 00775. Ural, Beyza P., and Devashish Mitra. 2007. “Indian
Ramaswamy, K. V. 1999. “The Search for Flexibility in Manufacturing: A Slow Sector in a Rapidly Grow-
Indian Manufacturing: New Evidence on Outsourc- ing Economy.” World Bank Policy Research Working
ing Activities.” Economic and Political Weekly, 34(6): Paper 4233.
363–68. Vaidyanathan, A. 1999. Irrigation Management in
Ramaswamy, K. V. 2008. “Wage Inequality in Indian India: Role of Institutions. New Delhi: Oxford Uni-
Manufacturing: Is it Trade, Technology or Labour versity Press.
Regulations?” Indira Gandhi Institute of Develop- Virmani, Arvind. 2006. Propelling India from Socialist
ment Research Working Paper 2008-021. Stagnation to Global Power, Volume 1: Growth Pro-
Rangarajan, C. 2001. “National Statistical Commission: cess. New Delhi: Academic Foundation.
An Overview of the Recommendations.” Economic Virmani, Arvind. 2007. “Balance of Payments” In
and Political Weekly, 36(42): 4007–16. Oxford Companion to Economics in India, ed.
Rao, C. H. Hanumantha. 2003. “Reform Agenda for Kaushik Basu, 201–03. New Delhi: Oxford Univer-
Agriculture.” Economic and Political Weekly, 38(7): sity Press.
615–20. Vyas, V. S. 2008. “Market Reforms in Indian Agricul-
Ravallion, Martin. 2009. “A Comparative Perspective ture: One Step Forward, Two Steps Back.” In The
on Poverty Reduction in Brazil, China and India.” Dragon and the Elephant: Agricultural and Rural
World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 5080. Reforms in China and India, ed. Ashok Gulati and
Ravallion, Martin, and Gaurav Datt. 2002. “Why Has Shenggen Fan, 264–82. New Delhi: Oxford Univer-
Economic Growth Been More Pro-Poor in Some sity Press.
States of India than Others?” Journal of Development Wallack, Jessica Seddon. 2003. “Structural Breaks in
Economics, 68(2): 381–400. Indian Macroeconomic Data.” Economic and Politi-
Ray, Shri Nilachal. 2004. “Unorganized vis-à-vis cal Weekly, 38(41): 4312–15.

You might also like