You are on page 1of 12

Decision Support Systems 59 (2014) 274–285

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Decision Support Systems


journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/dss

IT governance and business value in the public sector


organizations — The role of elected representatives in IT
governance and its impact on IT value in U.S. state governments
Min-Seok Pang ⁎
Fox School of Business, Temple University, 1801 Liacouras Walk, Philadelphia, PA 19122, USA

a r t i c l e i n f o a b s t r a c t

Article history: This paper studies IT business value in the public sector organizations, to which the information systems (IS)
Received 19 March 2013 literature so far has paid little attention. Specifically, we investigate the moderating effect of IT governance on
Received in revised form 26 December 2013 the relationship between IT investments and government performance. Drawing upon the theory of political con-
Accepted 27 December 2013
trol on bureaucracy from the political sciences literature, we hypothesize that the presence of legislative controls
Available online 4 January 2014
on IT management increases returns to IT spending, which are measured by cost efficiency. Our empirical analysis
Keywords:
in the context of U.S. state governments shows that formal establishment of a chief information officer (CIO) po-
Business value of IT sition by legislation is a key prerequisite to positive returns from IT expenditures in state governments. Also, the
IT governance impact of IT spending on state cost efficiency increases when a state senate approves appointment of CIO nom-
U.S. state government ination than when it does not. This study contributes to the IS literature by demonstrating the importance of
Cost efficiency elected representatives as part of IT governance in the public sector organizations.
Theory of political control © 2014 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
Principal–agent model

1. Introduction marketing or supply chain capabilities [7,74], innovative, responsive IT


management practices [31,64], and analytic capabilities [66]. These
The public sector organizations are large consumers of information studies demonstrate that firms that possess such complementary fac-
technologies (IT). Vivek Kundra, the former CIO of the U.S. federal gov- tors can better exploit IT resources to improve organizational perfor-
ernment, stated that it spends as much as $80 billion every year in IT mance and to achieve sustainable competitive advantages.
[21, p. 56]. Governments in the U.S. at all levels – federal, state, and In line of this research stream, considering IT governance a comple-
local levels – are strategically using IT for a variety of purposes ranging mentary practice in the relationship between IT and organizational
from maintaining operational infrastructures to delivering responsive performance, we examine the moderating effect of IT governance on
public services and interacting with citizens [49]. For instance, state the relationship between IT spending and performance, measured by
governments extensively utilize IT in administrating Medicaid, the cost efficiency, in U.S. state governments. In particular, this study focuses
healthcare benefit programs for low-income residents [54], which con- on the role of elected representatives in IT governance. Our reading of IT
sume a substantial share of state expenditures [48]. Thus, information governance studies indicates that they have mainly focused on the agen-
systems (IS) researchers as well as citizens, who pay taxes for IT spend- cy side — the role of CIOs, CEOs, or other senior executives [3,28,61,62].
ing, may ask a fundamental question; Does every dollar spent in IT help To the best of our knowledge, most IT governance studies have notably
governments fulfill their objectives and create sufficient value for the missed the other key part of IT governance, which the principal–agent
public? To the best of our knowledge, however, IS researchers have model calls principals — board of directors in business firms or elected
shed little light on the IT value in the government sector, compared to lawmakers in the public sector. Thus, we ask: what is the role of legisla-
a sheer number of the studies at the for-profit business setting. ture in IT governance in the public sector organizations?
IS researchers have been interested in identifying complementary Drawing upon the theory of political control on bureaucracy from
organizational practices with IT investments [42]. In this research the political sciences literature [5,11,38], we maintain that IT gover-
stream, scholars aim to identify the specific context in which firms are nance is more effective when legislative branches are involved in con-
able to realize greater value from their IT investments. A broad range trolling and monitoring IT management. Rooted in the principal–agent
of studies have identified a variety of factors such as improved human model [45], the political control theory explains how elected represen-
resource practices [8], business process reengineering [63], enhanced tatives (i.e. principals) control unelected bureaucrats (i.e. agents). In
contemporary government administration, politicians do not have as
⁎ Tel.: +1 215 204 7676. sufficient information and expertise in administration as agency officials
E-mail address: mins.pang@gmail.com. do [6,40]. Thus, there exist information asymmetry and moral hazards

0167-9236/$ – see front matter © 2014 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.dss.2013.12.006
M.-S. Pang / Decision Support Systems 59 (2014) 274–285 275

in this setting, in which the agents may pursue their self-interests which governance misalignment, a discrepancy between an appropriate
are divergent from those of the principals and their constituents [39]. As IT governance scheme and an actual governance mode, neutralizes
we will discuss below, such information asymmetry and moral hazards the contribution of IT to firm performance. Preston et al. [62] show
may exist in IT management as well. We consider the following control that a CIO's structural power within an organization and a strong
mechanisms that are available to lawmakers in supervising bureaucratic partnership between the CIO and top management team (TMT) posi-
IT management — direct oversight on IT management and operation, tively contribute to the CIO's strategic decision making authority,
establishment of a chief information officer (CIO) position by legislation, which in turn positively affects the perceived contribution of IT to
and approval of a CIO appointment. We hypothesize that the impact of firm performance. Banker et al. [3] reveal that alignment of a CIO–CEO
IT spending on state cost efficiency is greater in the presence of these reporting structure with a firm's strategic position has a positive impact
controls on IT management. on firm performance. Specifically, they find that a CIO–CEO reporting
Our empirical analysis proceeds in two stages. First, we measure cost relationship leads to higher firm performance under a differentiation
efficiency of U.S. state governments with stochastic cost frontier estima- strategy, while a CIO–CFO relationship is positively associated with
tion [1,40]. In the second stage, we estimate the effect of IT spending on firm performance under a cost leadership strategy.
cost efficiency and the moderating effects of legislative controls. This Our study differs from these previous studies on IT governance in
two-stage estimation produces several interesting findings. First, it re- two ways. First, we study the impact of IT governance on performance
veals that legislative establishment of a CIO position accentuates the im- in the public sector, which is a new setting in IT governance research.
pact of IT investments on cost efficiency significantly. Further, the We explain why cost efficiency is a valid indicator for government per-
approval of a CIO appointment by a legislative body increases efficient formance in Section 2.2. Second, while most prior work in IT governance
returns from IT spending as well. Finally, contrary to the predictions focuses on the agency side of IT governance as in the power of CIO or IT
from theory, we find that the presence of an IT-related committee in management centrality, we take a closer look at the principal side of IT
the legislature attenuates the impact of IT spending on cost efficiency. governance with a lens of the principal–agent theory and investigate
This study contributes to the literature on IT business value and IT the performance effect of legislative controls on IT management and in-
governance on several fronts. First, we expand the boundary of IT vestments. In Section 2.3, we elaborate how the principals in govern-
value research to the public sector organizations, an unchartered ments can supervise IT management.
territory in the IS literature. We also find that IT governance is a key
moderator in the performance effect of IT investments. Specifically, we
examine the role of principals (i.e. legislatures) in IT governance, 2.2. Cost efficiency as government performance
compared to other IT governance studies that mainly focus on agents
(i.e. chief executive, CIO, or other business executives) in IT manage- State governments have been experiencing fiscal crises since the
ment. We offer a new finding to the IS literature that the involvement early 1990s. By 1991, the total deficits in the U.S. state and local govern-
of principals in IT management helps organizations utilize IT resources ments reached at $43.1 billion and have continued to rise since then
more effectively. We also contribute to the literature by recombining [60,65]. This is attributed to, among others, growing senior population,
research from two distant literatures (IS and political sciences) [15], mounting healthcare costs, and rising crime rates, all of which have
an approach that, to the best of our knowledge, few IS studies have caused expenditure growth in such areas as public welfare and correc-
attempted. tions [60]. Furthermore, Reschovsky [65] reports that state tax revenues
This study also offers several important managerial implications for had declined by 20% from 2001 to 2003, while the real U.S. GDP had in-
the public sector organizations. Our findings emphasize that elected creased by about 15% for the same period. The expansion in federally
lawmakers be a key part of IT governance. They need to control and mandated programs that are not fully subsided by the federal govern-
supervise bureaucracy in IT management, so that IT resources are de- ment has exacerbated this problem [2].
ployed and used at the areas that are mostly needed from the strategic In addition, in most U.S. states, state laws enact a variety of measures
standpoint in a timely manner. It is also their responsibility to legitimize to limit expenditure growth such as balanced budget requirements and
the CIO position and to put a right person in that position who is capable debt limitations [14,33]. For example, the Idaho State Constitution
of fulfilling the roles charged by the legislatures. requires that its legislature pass a balanced budget. Louisiana state
The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. The next section laws mandate that “if a deficit exists in any fund at the end of the fiscal
presents our literature review and hypotheses. Section 3 introduces our year, that deficit shall be eliminated no later than the end of the next fis-
empirical approach. The result is presented in Section 4. Section 5 con- cal year.” According to the National Association of State Budget Officers,
cludes the paper with discussions, limitations, and future research governors in 44 states must submit a balanced budget [47].
directions. Therefore, these factors – accumulated budget deficits, declining tax
revenues, increasing demands for public services, and balanced budget
2. Literature review and hypotheses requirements – pose elected executives, public officials, and politicians
in U.S. states an enormous challenge to improve cost efficiency in state
2.1. Prior studies on IT governance and organizational performance administration. In other words, the states have to provide a range of
public services that various laws and policies mandate to deliver with
Weill and Ross [73] define IT governance as “specifying the decision as limited resources as possible. This motivation to minimize costs is
rights and accountability framework to encourage desirable behavior in in contrast to for-profit firms, whose primary interests are to maximize
using IT” (p. 2). Several prior studies have focused on identifying an sales revenues or profits, both of which are not a primary concern of the
appropriate framework of IT governance in business organizations public sector organizations.
[43,71–73]. For example, Brown and Magill [9], Sambamurthy and In addition, while it may be possible to measure outputs or quality
Zmud [68], and Xue et al. [77] identify the antecedents for IT governance of individual government services with such indicators as crime rate
arrangement choices among various IT governance archetypes. Such (public safety) or dropout rate (education), to the best of our knowl-
antecedents include corporate governance models, corporate strategies, edge, the literature in public economics or public administration does
IT knowledge of business divisions, and power of an IT organization. Xue not offer a single quantitative measure, similar to sales or value-added,
et al. [78] study the relationship between environmental uncertainty that accounts for diverse state government outputs such as transporta-
and IT governance centrality. tion or public welfare, each of which has widely different characteristics
Several studies in IT governance examine the impact of IT from each other. Given our interest to examine the impact of IT invest-
governance on firm performance. Gu et al. [27] demonstrate that IT ments and governance on overall government performance, we posit
276 M.-S. Pang / Decision Support Systems 59 (2014) 274–285

here that cost efficiency is a key performance measure that state The integration project between the systems in the U.S. Department of
governments aim to improve. Defense and Department of Veterans' Affairs for seamless sharing of
The literature and anecdotal evidence point out that IT can be an disabled veterans' information had experienced a long delay and con-
effective means for governments to improve cost efficiency by automat- siderable budget overrun, because of failure in upgrading the outdated
ing and streamlining manual, laborious business processes. Pandey and systems and insufficient coordination between the two departments
Bretchneider [58] and Moon and Bretchneider [46] show that inefficien- [44]. Similar IT management bureaucracy was reported in state
cy is a primary motivation for governments to adopt and invest more in governments as well [25].
IT. For example, in 2005, the State of Arizona developed the Arizona 2-1-
1 Online (http://www.az211.gov) to offer comprehensive, statewide in- 2.4. Hypotheses
formation on health services and emergency operations to state citizens
[50], so that the citizens can easily access the information and deal with The theory of political controls on bureaucracy asserts that it is a
urgent matters. The state reports that the immediate return on this responsibility of elected representatives to curb bureaucracy and to con-
investment is substantial. The development and five-year maintenance trol agencies' decision makings and activities, so that policies and public
costs are approximately $1 million [52], while annual savings in operat- services fulfill the needs and desires of citizens, not of bureaucrats
ing costs of the 911 centers exceed $1.37 million [52]. Many state [11,38,45,75]. Specifically, by bureaucracy, it refers to a moral-hazard
governments widely utilize decision support systems (DSS) equipped situation in which unelected bureaucrats (agents) seek to pursue their
with business intelligence capabilities in public welfare programs such own self-interests that conflict with preferences of politicians and
as Medicaid or food banks [51,54]. Such DSS based on data warehouses their constituencies (principals). This occurs because of information
and analytic capabilities are used to streamline benefit application asymmetry, where the principals do not have perfect information
processes, to determine the eligibility of benefit provision in a speedy on the agents' behavior and decisions, since the principals do not pos-
manner, and to detect fraudulent benefit claims. It is reported that sess complete knowledge and expertise in policy implementation.
these systems help the states save a substantial amount of operating According to this literature, there are three major mechanisms with
costs in salaries and expenses that the states otherwise would incur which politicians control bureaucrats — (i) monitoring and oversight,
with outdated, paper-based processes. (ii) statutory controls, and (iii) approval of nomination of agency
executives.
2.3. Bureaucracy in IT management The legislature can exercise controls by directly monitoring and
overseeing executive agencies on an ongoing basis. Usually, monitoring
The studies on IT management report that bureaucracy in IT organi- and oversight are conducted by a legislative committee focusing on spe-
zations does exist in many forms. For example, IT managers may stick to cific policy and service areas such as education or transportation. The
an obsolete, inflexible IT infrastructure that is costly to maintain. They committee can carry out such activities as performance evaluation, bud-
may have vested relationships with certain vendors and offer them a get analysis and approval, formal hearings, issuing policy guidelines,
special treatment in IT procurement processes. It may take several and carrying out a sanction or a punishment in case of a misconduct
months or years for them to make a critical decision in IT investment or violation [40]. These supervising activities aim to make sure that
and deployment because of hierarchical organizational structures and the decisions and activities of executive agencies are congruent with
complex reporting processes. Incompetent, underperforming IT staff the goals and priorities put forth by the legislature and to detect and
may not be disciplined or replaced at the right time [29]. IT managers correct any incompliance from the legislative purposes and guidelines.
may refuse or fail to accommodate evolving needs of business managers As of 2004, legislatures in 37 states have IT-related committees that
and customers. Mark and Rau [36] state that “Business units can become oversee state IT management [49]. The state legislature records reveal
frustrated by long delays in the deployment of needed capabilities, and that such IT-related legislative committees can be an effective
IT may be viewed as an unresponsive bureaucracy, a black hole for busi- mechanism to exert controls over IT management and operations. For
ness requests” (p. 23). Bureaucracy may lead to a failure in managing a example, the Kansas Legislature Joint Committee on Information
large-scale system development project, resulting in escalated develop- Technology, which is intended to review IT strategic plans, IT budgets,
ment costs and long delays [55]. and the state enterprise IT architecture,1 recommended in 2008 the
Bureaucracy in IT management may take place in the business side standardization of technology use and existing standards in Kansas hos-
of an organization as well. For example, uncoordinated IT investments pitals (Page 4-1). It also requested that “all agencies will be expected to
and deployment are made by business units without close alignment participate in the new statewide Financial Management System (FMS).
with enterprise architectures or long-term strategies. Business man- Without full participation, multiple agencies will continue to incur sub-
agers may spend IT budgets in duplicate or incompatible systems, stantial, unnecessary costs” (Page 4-1). This demonstrates that the
which do not contribute to organization-wide synergies [69]. A partner- Kansas Legislature requests utilization of IT to improve the quality and
ship between IT and business functions, which is intended to curb efficiency of public health and financial management and demands
bureaucracy in the IT function, can be a different manifestation of the establishment of a standard in technology use and communication
bureaucracy [16]. Lohmeyer et al. [34] state that “Partnership between across the state agencies to prevent wasteful spending in incompatible,
IT and business … can become too complicated when technology com- silo systems. The Oregon Statutes Chapter 171 stipulates that the duties
mittees proliferate and lengthy business plans accompany each IT of Joint Legislative Committee on Information Management and Tech-
request. …With decision making so fragmented, few concrete decisions nology include establishing “statewide goals and policy regarding” IT
were reached and finger-pointing was rampant” (p. 41). Our premise in and making “recommendations regarding established or proposed in-
this study is that involvement and supervision of political principals in formation resource management programs and information technology
IT governance is an effective way to restrain such IT management acquisitions.”2 It further mandates that the enterprise management in IT
bureaucracy in the public sector organizations. “implement a state government-wide approach for managing distribut-
To the best of our knowledge, there has been little research in IT ed information technology assets to minimize total ownership costs …
management bureaucracy in the public sector organizations. However, while realizing maximum benefits for transacting the states business
anecdotal evidence suggests that it does exist in government agencies and delivering services to its citizens.”3
as well. For example, it has been reported that the recent failure in the 1
http://skyways.lib.ks.us/ksleg/KLRD/2008CommRepts/jcit-cr.pdf (accessed on May. 9,
rollout of the U.S. federal healthcare exchange (healthcare.gov) was 2011).
attributed to poor project management, last-minute changes in require- 2
http://www.oregonlaws.org/ors/171.855 (accessed on Jun. 25, 2012).
ments, and failure in anticipating the number of users in the site [70]. 3
http://www.oregonlaws.org/ors/184.477 (accessed on Jun. 25, 2012).
M.-S. Pang / Decision Support Systems 59 (2014) 274–285 277

We argue that efficiency returns from IT spending are greater in resources across business units in multi-business organizations
states whose legislatures have an IT-specific legislative committee such as state governments.
than in others. It is not necessarily the case that state legislatures with- The CIO position and duties can be instituted by an executive order
out an IT committee do not play a controlling role for state IT functions. as well. For instance, the Michigan Executive Order 2001-3 creates the
However, the political control theory points out that oversight and Department of Information Technology, which is headed by the state
monitoring are a challenging task for politicians. It is particularly the CIO. Mayer [37] defines an executive order as “a presidential directive
case in IT management, where information asymmetry between that requires or authorizes some action within the executive branch”
politicians and managers is more severe. Thus, if state IT management (p. 445). It has been used by the U.S. presidents to establish policy and
is overseen by a non-IT-specific committee such as government opera- to set up and alter administrative and regulatory processes [37]. Like
tion or economic development, the committee members, with limited presidents, governors in U.S. states also have an authority to issue
time, information, and expertise, would not be able to exert as much executive orders and generally are not required to seek an action or
control over IT management as they would be if they are in a committee approval of state legislatures in doing so. Nonetheless, even though
exclusively devoted to IT management. This leads us to propose the executive orders carry an equal legal weight with legislation,4 their
following hypothesis. impact and authority is more transient and provisional than legislation.
An executive order can be revoked by succeeding governors without
Hypothesis 1. All others being equal, the association between IT spending legislative consent, and Mayer [37] demonstrates that they are issued
and cost efficiency is stronger in states whose legislature has an IT-related more frequently in the absence of public support.
legislative committee than in ones without such a committee. To be in charge of statewide IT management, the state CIO needs
sufficient authority and power granted by the legislative branch. It is a
Another instrument for political controls is a statutory control [6] or prerequisite to overcome resistance from business units which had
an administrative procedure [38], in which politicians use legislation to had discretion in managing their own IT resources and investments.
stipulate rules and procedures that public officials are mandated to Legislative establishment of the CIO position, a type of statutory control
follow in policy making and implementation. In effect, it takes a form on agency executives, offers such authority and power to the CIO. Thus,
of behavioral control on bureaucrats [20]. As mentioned above, direct we hypothesize the moderating role of legislative establishment of CIO
oversight and monitoring is expensive and imperfect for elected politi- position as follows.
cians because of information asymmetry and their limited resources.
Thus, instead of costly intervention, the legislature uses statutory Hypothesis 2. All others being equal, the association between IT spending
controls to dictate with what specific steps the agencies must take in and cost efficiency is stronger in states whose CIO position is established by
fulfilling legislative goals and directions. Bawn [6] explains that statuto- legislation than otherwise.
ry controls specify “how the agency is organized, how the agency will
make the policy choice, who participates in agency decisions, what A legislative branch controls bureaucracy by appointing agency
information is used, and what qualifications are required for key executives [11,75]. Although it does not directly appoint an executive,
personnel” (p. 62). it may have an authority to approve appointment made by a chief exec-
We argue here that establishing the position and duties of a CIO is a utive. This approval authority of the legislature discourages the chief ex-
form of statutory control against a chief executive (governor) and senior ecutive from nominating an appointee who is not likely to be approved
managers in executive agencies and propose that efficiency returns to IT by the legislature. In this way, the elected lawmakers are able to choose
spending are greater when the position and duties of CIO are formally a nominee who is expected to be more capable of fulfilling their policy
established by legislation than otherwise. By codifying the role and preferences, and more importantly, they can select those who are not
responsibilities of CIO for statewide IT management and investments, likely to pursue their self-interests. Wood and Waterman's [75] empir-
the legislature constrains the discretion of other non-IT agency execu- ical investigation shows that appointment approval is a more effective
tives, who might otherwise procure and deploy IT resources in an instrument of political control than others such as direct oversight and
uncoordinated manner without taking an enterprise perspective and a statutory controls.
long-term strategic goal into account. Based on the principal–agent model, Calvert et al. [11] set up a nom-
As of 2004, 34 states establish the CIO positions by legislation, while ination game between a chief executive and a legislature, the latter of
nine use an executive order to formalize the position. For example, the which has a veto power for an appointee. According to their model, in
Iowa Code Chapter 8A specifies the duties of the Director of Information equilibrium, there exists a pool of appointees whose preferences are
Technology Services including “prescribe and adopt information tech- not too far from the preference of the legislature. It is mutually benefi-
nology standards and rules” and “develop and recommend legislative cial for both the chief executive and the legislature to appoint and
proposals deemed necessary for the continued efficiency of the depart- approve one from the pool, respectively. In the absence of the veto
ment in performing information technology functions.” The Minnesota power, the chief executive would appoint a nominee whose preference
Statutes Chapter 16E charges the state CIO to approve IT development is closer to his than to the legislature's. This model suggests that if the
projects in state agencies and to develop cost-effective IT infrastructure legislature is to approve a CIO nominee, he or she is likely to better rep-
and services to be shared across the state agencies. The CIO of North resent its interests in regard to the state's strategic goals and directions
Carolina is also empowered by the General Statutes Chapter 147 to than the one who is unilaterally appointed by the governor. Meanwhile,
suspend any IT project in executive agencies that does not conform to the appointing authority functions as a latent control as well [11], in
the quality standard and enterprise architecture. which mid-level agency managers, who themselves are in the pool of
All of this legislation above codifies that the state CIO take greater perspective appointees, voluntarily avoid to deviate from the prefer-
responsibilities in statewide IT management vis-à-vis other senior ences of the legislature in their actions and decision makings.
executives. This enables the CIO to control IT resources across the As of 2004, appointment of a state CIO requires legislative approval
organization and to formulate IT-related policies and principles for in 19 states. As the political control theory predicts, state CIOs and IT
the entire business functions to follow. The CIO will be a leader managers are more likely to pursue the goal of legislatures in efficiency
and a facilitator in the efforts to achieve statewide efficiency improvement in IT management without bureaucracy when the CIO
improvement with IT resources. With support and legitimacy con- appointment is approved by state legislatures than otherwise. This
ferred by legislation, he or she will be able to effectively coordinate leads us to offer the following hypothesis.
statewide IT operations and facilitate a standardized IT architecture.
This will lead to greater inter-organizational synergies [69] from IT 4
http://www.thisnation.com/question/040.html (accessed on Jul. 11, 2011).
278 M.-S. Pang / Decision Support Systems 59 (2014) 274–285

Table 1
Data sources.

Source Data Variable

National Association of State CIOs Compendium of Digital Governments in the States (2002, 2005) IT budget (IT1 and IT2) and IT governance
U.S. Census Bureau State Government Finances Operation expense (C), Capital price (w2), Federal grant (z4)
State Government Employment & Payroll Labor price (w1)
State Annual Population Estimate Population (z1)
State Household Income Household income (z2)
State governments' Web sites Comprehensive Annual Financial Reports (CAFR) Capital depreciation (C)
Alternative capital price (w2)
Bureau of Economic Accounts State Gross Domestic Product (GDP) GDP (z3)
Price Indexes for GDP
National Conference of State Legislature State legislature and gubernatorial election results Governor (z5), Legislature (z6)
State Higher Education Executive Officers State Higher Education Finance Survey Education (Y1)
Centers for Medicare & Medicaid Services National Health Expenditure Data by State of Resident Public Welfare (Y2)
Federal Highway Administration Annual Highway Statistics Transportation (Y3)
Bureau of Justice Statistics National Prisoner Statistics Public Safety (Y4)

Hypothesis 3. All others being equal, the association between IT spending given. This is the case in our context because state government produc-
and cost efficiency is stronger in states whose legislature approves a state tion is regulated by various federal and state laws, and it generally takes
CIO nominee than otherwise. considerable time to amend such laws. Thus, compared to private-
sector firms, governments cannot easily adjust the amount of outputs
3. Empirical methodology in response to changes in demands or input prices. In this regard, it is
appropriate to assume that outputs (Yi,k,t) are exogenous, as in Eq. (1).
3.1. The two-stage estimation approach The stochastic frontier model assumes a frontier to be stochastic, as
even the maximum production level may be influenced by various
The estimation approach is based on Pang [59]. We estimate the re- unobserved factors, random shocks, or statistical noises. Following this
lationship between IT investments and cost efficiency and the moderat- rationale, Aigner et al. [1] and Meeusen and van den Broeck [41] assume
ing effect of IT governance with a two-stage estimation approach based that a residual εk,t in Eq. (1) is given by εk,t = vk,t + uk,t. Here, vk,t repre-
on a multi-product translog cost function [12,13]. Several studies in sents a random error and is assumed to follow a normal distribution of
public economics have used this method to measure government N(0,σ2v ). uk,t refers to an inefficiency factor, which by definition is greater
efficiency [18,23,76]. For example, Geys [23] measures the cost efficien- than or equal to zero, and is assumed to follow a half-normal distribu-
cy of 304 Flemish local governments with a cost function model. tion truncated below zero. The coefficients in Eq. (1) and the standard
Worthington [76] also adopts a similar two-stage approach to explain deviation of the two error terms (vk,t and uk,t) are estimated using
the cause of inefficiency in Australian local governments. maximum likelihood estimation.6 Technical cost inefficiency (the ratio
The two-stage approach proceeds as follows. In the first stage, we es- of the actual cost to the cost frontier) is given by exp(uk,t). We use an
timate cost efficiency of each state-year observation with a stochastic unbiased estimator for exp(uk,t) proposed by Battese and Coelli [4] to
frontier model [1,40]. In the second stage, we regress the estimated cost obtain technical inefficiency Ineffk,t, of each state-year observation.
efficiency on IT spending and governance measures and control variables. For ease of interpretation, we reverse Ineff k,t by taking Eff k,t =
Our key interest in measurement is technical cost efficiency. Formal- 2 − Ineffk,t as the dependent variable for the second stage estimation.
ly, Koopmans [30] defines a producer as being technically efficient if and This estimated technical efficiency (Effk,t) is regressed on IT spending
only if it cannot increase production of an output without increasing any (IT), IT governance (g), and control variables (z) as shown in Eq. (2).
input or decreasing any other outputs. Kumbhakar and Lovell [32] de- In addition, the interaction terms of IT spending and governance vari-
fine a cost frontier as the least amount of inputs that can produce the ables are included to test our hypotheses.
given amount of outputs. Technical cost inefficiency is measured as
the ratio of actual cost to the cost frontier. We estimate this technical Ef f k;t ¼ δ0 X
þ δIT IT k;t−2 X X
cost inefficiency with a stochastic frontier model in the first stage. þ δgi g i;k;t−2 þ δITgi g i;k;t−2  IT k;t−2 þ δzi zi;k;t þ ξk;t : ð2Þ
A multi-product translog cost function with n outputs and m input
prices is given by Following the notion in the IT value literature that it takes time for IT
value to materialize [10], we use two-year lagged IT spending (ITk,t − 2)
and governance (gi,k,t − 2) variables.7 Since the hypotheses are tested
X
n
1X n Xn Xm
lnC k;t ¼ α0 þ αi lnY i;k;t þ αij lnY i;k;t lnY j;k;t þ βi lnwi;k;t with a cross-sectional panel dataset and there may be unobserved
2
i¼1 i¼1 j¼1 i¼1 heterogeneity in state government production, we estimate Eq. (2)
1X m X m Xm X n
with a fixed-effects estimation model with Driscoll and Kraay standard
þ β lnwi;k;t lnw j;k;t þ γij lnwi;k;t lnY j;k;t þ εk;t
2 i¼1 j¼1 ij i¼1 j¼1 errors [19], which account for interstate correlation in residuals.
ð1Þ
3.2. Measures and data sources

where k and t are subscripts for state and year, respectively. Ck,t is the Our first stage estimation with the cost function (Eq. (1)) adopts two
total cost that state k incurs at year t, Yi,k,t are the amount of outputs, input measures (m = 2) and four output measures (n = 4). First, a
and wi,k,t are the input prices. Following Caves et al. [12], we impose con- total cost (C) is measured by the sum of per capita operation expenses
straints for homogeneity of degree one in price on Eq. (1).5 and capital depreciation (buildings and equipments). Operation
The use of a cost function in modeling state government production expenses are obtained from the U.S. Annual State Government Finances
is warranted as it implicitly assumes that outputs are exogenously
6
More details in the estimation process are available in Aigner et al. [1].
5 7
This ensures that when all input prices wi are multiplied by x, the total cost C is We re-estimated Eq. (2) with different lag lengths (from 0 to 4 years) and did not
multiplied by x as well. obtain qualitatively different results.
M.-S. Pang / Decision Support Systems 59 (2014) 274–285 279

Table 2
States in the second-stage estimation.
Geographic region and division are from the 2000 U.S. Census.

Region Division States

Northeast (1) New England Maine(4), New Hampshire(5), Vermont(3), Massachusetts(5), Rhode Island(5), Connecticut(3)
(2) Mid-Atlantic New York(5), Pennsylvania(2), New Jersey(3)
Midwest (3) East North Central Wisconsin(4), Michigan(5), Indiana(3), Ohio(5)
(4) West North Central Missouri(5), North Dakota(5), South Dakota(5), Kansas(5), Minnesota(5), Iowa(5)
South (5) South Atlantic Maryland(5), Virginia(3), West Virginia(2), North Carolina(5), South Carolina(3), Georgia(4), Florida(2)
(6) East South Central Kentucky(5), Tennessee(5), Mississippi(5), Alabama(5)
(7) West South Central Oklahoma(2), Texas(5), Arkansas(5)
West (8) Mountain Idaho(5), Montana(5), Wyoming(3), Nevada(5), Utah(3), Arizona(5), New Mexico(5)
(9) Pacific Washington(5), Oregon(3), California(3), Hawaii(5)

The number in parentheses next to a state is the number of years that the state appears in the second-stage estimation.

reports published by the U.S. Census Bureau. Capital depreciation The public economics literature provides economic, sociological, and
figures are acquired from the Comprehensive Annual Financial Reports political factors that affect technical efficiency in government produc-
posted at states' Web sites (Table 1). Capital depreciation is reported tion. Davis and Hayes [17] and Grossman et al. [26] suggest that the
from fiscal-year 2001 to 2009, and some states do not post all nine- size of jurisdiction (population) affects government efficiency. Geys
year reports at their Web sites, limiting our sample size to 428 state- [23] and De Borger and Kerstens [18] argue that per capita income
years (Table 2). All dollar terms are adjusted for 2005 dollar. level is related to efficiency as well. Following these studies, we include
For output measures, we choose the four most representative public population, median household income, and per capita state GDP as con-
services that state governments supply — education, public welfare, trol variables in the second-stage estimation (Eq. (2)). The fiscal illusion
transportation, and public safety.8 Following prior studies in public eco- hypothesis [23,26] suggests that a large influx of external revenues from
nomics, we selected four proxy variables to measure the four outputs as a higher level of governments is a source of inefficiency. Hence, we also
shown in Table 3. We also selected two input price measures in the cost control for per capita inter-government grants from the federal govern-
function estimation — capital and labor (Table 3). The correlations ment to each state in Eq. (2). We also include Garand's [22] political in-
among the variables in the first-stage estimation are presented in dicators – a governor's party affiliation and party control of legislatures
Table 4. – because they represent important political and institutional factors
The measures in the second-stage estimation (Eq. (2)) are shown in that may affect state government efficiency. Eq. (2) also includes other
Table 5. IT spending, our key independent variable, is measured in two IT governance indicators – centrality of IT management, reporting rela-
ways — per capita IT budget of central IT offices (IT1) and the ratio of tionship of a CIO, and the size of central IT functions – as control vari-
IT budget to total general expenditures (IT2). These figures were obtain- ables. Lastly, we include year dummies in our second-stage estimation
ed from the NASCIO Compendium of Digital Governments in States pub- to account for nation-wide changes in economic and political trends.
lished in 2003 and 2005 [49]. This publication reports IT budgets Tables 5 and 6 show the summary statistics and correlations in the
(central IT offices and executive branches) in more than 40 states second-stage estimation, respectively.
from the fiscal year 2001 to 2005. However, there are many missing
values in executive branch IT budget data.9 Thus, we use the IT budget 4. Results
of central IT offices for our IT budget measures. The IT budget figures
are available in 193 state-years between 2001 and 2005, but combining Table 7 shows the result of the first-stage stochastic frontier estima-
them with the sample in the first-stage estimation left us 188 state-year tion. Here, the variance of inefficiency term (u) is positive and statisti-
observations. In addition, we had to drop three observations of cally significant, indicating possible presence of inefficiency in state
Delaware, which reports an unusually large amount of per capita IT government production. The estimated cost inefficiency (the ratio of ac-
spending (greater than 6σ). Hence, our sample size in the second tual costs to the cost frontier) ranges between 1.0165 and 1.9844.10 This
stage becomes 185. t-tests indicate that with respect to population, indicates that the most efficient and inefficient states spend 1.65% and
GDP, and total state expenditures, the states in our sample do not differ 98.44% more in operational expenses and capital depreciation than the
significantly from those that are not in the sample. minimum possible costs, respectively.
Data on the three IT governance variables – Committee (H1), Estab- The second-stage estimation results are presented in Table 8. In
lish (H2), and Appoint (H3) – were also obtained from the Compendium Columns (2) and (5), the coefficients of IT spending (IT1 and IT2) are
(Table 5). Committee is a dummy variable whose value is one if there is positive and statistically significant. This shows that the more a state
an IT-specific legislative committee in either state senate, house of rep- government spends in IT, the more efficient it becomes. In both
resentatives, or both. Establish is measured by one if a CIO position is Columns (3) and (6), we add the three interaction terms. The
established by legislation. It is also equal to one in five states where coefficients of IT1 × Establish and IT1 × Approve (Column 3) are posi-
the CIO position is established by both legislation and an executive tive and significant at the 1%-level of significance, supporting
order. Approve is equal to one if a state senate approves the nomination Hypotheses 2 and 3, respectively. This is the case with IT2 × Establish
of a state CIO. Hypotheses 1, 2, and 3 will be supported if the coefficients and IT2 × Approve (Column 6), showing that this result is robust to
of IT × Committee, IT × Establish, and IT × Approve are positive and the use of different denominators for normalization. It suggests that
significant, respectively. when a state legislature establishes a CIO position by legislation or
approves a CIO appointee, the impact of IT budget on cost efficiency
becomes stronger.
8
Surprisingly, the coefficients of IT1 × Committee and IT2 ×
According to the U.S. Census Bureau, the four service areas occupy as much as 65% of
Committee (Columns 3 and 6, respectively) are negative and significant,
the total state general expenditures in the fiscal year 2008.
9
Executive branch IT budgets are available only for 29 states. Measuring IT spending
10
with the total IT budget in both a central IT organization and executive branches leaves Eff (the dependent variable in the second stage estimation) is obtained by
us only 92 observations in the second stage estimation, which are too few observations Eff = 2 − Inefficiency. Thus, as in Table 5, Eff ranges from 0.0156(= 2–1.9844) to
to obtain statistically significant estimations. 0.9835(= 2–0.0165).
280 M.-S. Pang / Decision Support Systems 59 (2014) 274–285

Table 3
Variable definition and summary statistics for the first-stage estimation.

Variables N Avg. Std. dev. Min. Max.

Cost (C) 428 2901.758 1036.556 1565.577 8842.813


The sum of per capita annual current operation expense and capital depreciation (building and equipments)
Education (Y1) 428 33576.33 6776.81 17778.46 57650.29
The number of enrolled students in public postsecondary educational institutions per thousand population
Public Welfare (Y2) 428 141.0861 42.92587 55.55066 251.1516
The number of Medicaid recipients per million population [18]
Transportation (Y3) 428 4152.837 3765.729 266.9315 18963.43
The length (mile) of state-maintained highways and roads per million population [76]
Public safety (Y4) 428 4332.148 1691.575 281.1109 8811.179
The number of inmates in state correctional facilities per million population
Labor price (w1) 428 3684.533 524.7327 2918.602 5231.4
The monthly total payroll ($) divided by the number of fulltime-equivalent employees [17,76]
Capital price (w2) 428 4.962733 0.891754 3.0647 8.7823
The annual interest payments divided by mean debt level (average of beginning-of-fiscal-year debt and end-of-fiscal-year debt) [17,76]

Fiscal year 2001–2008; annual capital depreciation (part of C) is missing at 22 state-year observations.

rejecting Hypothesis 1. This means that when state legislatures have an two governance controls is zero (Point [01] or [10]). It is interesting
IT-related committee, efficiency returns from IT investments diminish. to see that in Fig. 1-(a), the expected cost savings from IT when
One possible explanation for this is that the IT-specific legislative com- Approve = Committee = 1 (Point [11], $9.16) are similar to the case
mittee may create another layer of bureaucracy in IT governance. The of Approve = Committee = 0 (Point [00], $9.93). In Fig. 1-(b), the
actions and processes of the committee such as legislative hearings expected cost savings with Approve = Committee = 1 (Point [11],
and formal evaluation may hinder effective, timely IT investment and $8.28) are higher than with Approve = Committee = 1 (Point [00],
deployment. Elected representatives in such a committee may not pos- $7.03). However, in both Fig. 1-(a) and (b), the 95% confidence internals
sess sufficient knowledge and information to supervise state IT are narrower at Point [11] than at Point [00].
management. We have several explanations for this finding. First, as we mention
In order to better explain this counterintuitive finding, we add the above, in comparison between Points [00] and [01] in Fig. 1-(a) and
three-way interaction term of IT × Committee × Approve to the (b), the presence of a legislative committee on IT management may
model. As shown in Columns (4) and (7) of Table 8, the coefficients of exacerbate complexity in IT management. Second, in comparison be-
this three-way interaction term are found to be positive and signifi- tween Points [00] and [10], it appears that the approval of CIO
cant.11 In both Columns (4) and (7), the coefficients of IT1 × Approve appointment by elected lawmakers weaken returns from IT spending
and IT2 × Approve become insignificant. This suggests that the positive slightly, as shown by the negative but statistically insignificant coeffi-
moderating effect of legislative approval for CIO (H3) disappears if the cients of IT × Approve in Columns (4) and (7). It may be because
legislature does not have a legislative committee devoted to IT manage- most elected representatives do not possess sufficient expertise in IT
ment (Committee = 0). Likewise, in Column (4), the coefficient of management. A way to overcome these adverse effects is for them
IT1 × Committee is 0.0015(=0.0048–0.0033) if Approve is equal to 1, both to engage in a CIO selection and to oversee IT management via a
but it becomes −0.0033 if Approve is 0. This is the case in Column (7) legislative committee at the same time. For approval of CIO nomination
as well. Hence, the presence of an IT-specific legislative committee to be effective, there must be a group of lawmakers dedicated to over-
strengthens the relationship between IT spending and cost efficiency seeing IT management. Lastly, it can be shown that when Establish is
only if the lawmakers approve a CIO appointment. 0, the expected cost savings are less than $1, regardless of the values
To illustrate the effect of IT spending and IT governance on cost of Approve and Committee, suggesting that formalizing the CIO position
efficiency, we calculated an average cost reduction from a $1 in- by legislation is a key prerequisite to the positive impact of IT spending
crease in IT budget as follows. First, the cost frontier (the minimum on state cost efficiency.
possible costs) of each observation is calculated by dividing the ac-
tual costs by the estimated technical inefficiency. For instance, if an 5. Discussions and conclusion
actual per capita cost is $3000 and the estimated cost inefficiency
(the ratio of actual cost to the cost frontier) is 1.5, the cost frontier It has been reported that due to severe fiscal crises for the last several
for this state is $3000 / 1.5 = $2000. By averaging this cost frontier years, IT investments in many governments became an early target of
for all state-year observations, we obtained $2545.33. When all of budgetary cuts in an attempt to close the budget gaps. For example,
Approve, Committee, and Establish are equal to 1, the sum of the the NASCIO 2010 State CIO Survey reports that 64% of the state CIOs ex-
coefficients of IT1 and all interactions terms from Table 8, Column pect reduction in IT budget [53]. In 2011, the State of Washington cut
(4) is (− 0.0001 + 0.0040 − 0.0018 − 0.0033 + 0.0048) = 0.0036, the size of personnel in the Department of Information Services by
meaning that a one dollar increase in per capita IT spending reduces more than 10% [24]. Given this fiscal environment, elected officials
cost inefficiency by 0.0036. Thus, in a state with the average cost frontier and public sector managers will ask how declining IT budgets should
($2545.33), reduction in per capita cost from a $1 increase in per capita IT
spending amounts to $2545.33 × 0.0036 = $9.16, as shown in Fig. 1-(a). Table 4
Fig. 1-(b) is obtained from Table 8, Column (7) in a similar manner. Correlation table for the first-stage estimation.
Fig. 1-(a) and (b) illustrate the average cost reduction in each case
C Y1 Y2 Y3 Y4 w2
with 95% confidence intervals when Establish is equal to one. This
shows that average cost savings are higher when both Approve and Y1 −0.1413
Y2 0.1856 0.0566
Committee are equal to one (Point [11]) than when only one of these Y3 0.2122 0.3592 0.0023
Y4 0.1163 0.0682 0.2186 0.0167
11
w1 0.1862 −0.3096 −0.0720 −0.5308 −0.1816
We also tried to add other three-way interaction terms (IT × Establish × Approve and
w2 0.1568 −0.0781 −0.0820 −0.0857 0.0237 −0.0198
IT × Committee × Establish), which were estimated to be insignificant.
M.-S. Pang / Decision Support Systems 59 (2014) 274–285 281

Table 5
Variable definition and summary statistics for the second-stage estimation.

Variables N Avg. Std. dev. Min. Max.

Technical efficiency (Eff) 185 0.8485 0.1677 0.0156 0.9835


2 − (the ratio of actual cost to the cost in the frontier)
Population (z1) 185 5.8545 6.2962 0.5065 35.9903
Annual state population estimate (in millions)
Household income (z2) 185 46.4493 7.1465 32.6138 65.7097
State median household income (in thousand dollar)
GDP (z3) 185 39.2285 6.2065 26.7714 57.0583
Per capita state annual gross domestic product (in thousand dollar)
Federal grant (z4) 185 1.4170 0.4356 0.6854 3.6973
Per capita annual intergovernmental revenues from the federal government (in thousand dollar)
Governor (z5) 185 0.5405 0.4997 0 1
1 if governor is Republican, 0 otherwise
Legislature (z6) 185 0.9837 0.3195 0.2438 1.6143
The sum of the proportion of Republican lawmakers in state senate and that of state house of representatives
Centrality (z7) 185 5.5676 3.1514 0 13
The number of IT management areas that a state CIO is directly in charge of statewide
Reporting (z8) 185 0.5297 0.5005 0 1
1 if the state CIO directly reports to the governor, 0 otherwise
ITEmp (z9) 185 0.4578 0.4591 0.0016 2.2331
The ratio of central IT organizational personnel to total state personnel (%)
IT1 185 19.8044 17.5104 0.0411 89.2275
Per capita central IT office budget (in dollar)
IT2 185 0.5023 0.4564 0.0014 2.5388
The ratio of a central IT office budget to total general expenditure (%)
Committee (g1) 185 0.6649 0.4733 0 1
1 if either state senate, house of representative or both has an IT-specific legislative committee, 0 otherwise
Establish (g2) 185 0.8162 0.3884 0 1
1 if a state CIO position is established by legislation, 0 otherwise
Approve (g3) 185 0.3405 0.4752 0 1
1 if a state senate approves nomination of a state CIO, 0 otherwise

Fiscal year 2003–2007 with a two-year lag of IT budget and governance (2001–2005).

be managed and used more judiciously for the governments' attempt to establishment demonstrates the strongest moderating effect (Table 8).
overcome the fiscal stress. This paper seeks to provide an answer to this Furthermore, we find that supervision of state legislatures on IT man-
question. agement and approval of a CIO appointee complement each other. The
We draw upon the theory of political control on bureaucracy to impact of IT expenditures on state efficiency is greater when the state
articulate the role of elected lawmakers in IT governance and to hy- legislature both has an IT-specific legislative committee and approves
pothesize the moderating effects of three legislative controls to IT nomination of a state CIO than when it plays only one of the two roles
management on the cost-efficiency returns from IT expenditures. (Fig. 1).
Our theoretical reasoning proposes that by exerting controls over Our study carries some limitations. First, it bears the weaknesses of
bureaucracy in IT management, politicians can ensure that IT man- stochastic frontier estimation and two-stage estimation approach
agement and investments accomplish the required purposes more [32,35,57], such as inconsistency of technical inefficiency estimators or
effectively, one of which is to provide public services for citizens possible biases from functional misspecification. However, despite these
with as limited resources as possible, i.e. enhancing cost efficiency. shortcomings, we believe that this approach is one of the most feasible
Our empirical analyses demonstrate that IT spending in U.S. state ways to estimate the relationship between IT investments and govern-
governments positively affects cost efficiency in state governments. ment performance. Second, due to data limitation, we could use only IT
We further find that this relationship between IT and cost efficiency is budget data of central IT organizations, as the NASCIO Compendium does
greater when the CIO position and duties are formalized by legislation. not report the entire IT budget across state agencies and departments in
Indeed, among our three indicators for IT governance, the legislative many states. But we still believe that our IT budget measure reflects the

Table 6
Correlation table for the second-stage estimation.

Eff z1 z2 z3 z4 z5 z6 z7 z8 z9 IT1 IT2 g1 g2

z1 0.2138
z2 −0.2194 0.0765
z3 −0.0037 0.2811 0.6479
z4 −0.1726 −0.1839 −0.3602 −0.0614
z5 −0.1184 0.0063 0.1262 0.0496 −0.0100
z6 0.3946 0.0139 −0.1652 −0.1481 −0.0506 −0.1092
z7 0.1055 0.1358 0.1824 0.1787 −0.1234 0.0215 0.0204
z8 0.2437 0.3190 −0.1883 −0.0023 −0.1570 −0.0429 0.1902 0.3218
z9 0.1893 −0.2895 0.0472 0.0168 −0.0595 0.0467 0.1813 0.3301 0.0951
IT1 0.1942 −0.2595 −0.1515 0.0097 0.1859 0.1350 0.2273 0.0432 0.1237 0.5117
IT2 0.2277 −0.2025 −0.1586 −0.0222 0.0400 0.1134 0.2453 0.0371 0.1835 0.4964 0.9594
g1 0.2085 −0.0029 0.0018 0.0261 −0.0756 −0.2639 0.0410 0.2120 0.2258 −0.0035 −0.0663 −0.1094
g2 0.1713 −0.1738 −0.0724 −0.0430 0.0364 −0.0174 −0.0152 −0.0475 0.0562 0.0791 −0.0461 −0.0394 0.2840
g3 0.0765 −0.0561 −0.0629 −0.1733 0.0456 0.0674 0.0127 0.2985 0.2429 0.0324 −0.0629 −0.0993 0.1236 0.1054
282 M.-S. Pang / Decision Support Systems 59 (2014) 274–285

Table 7
The first-stage stochastic cost frontier estimation results.

Stochastic frontier estimation (dependent variable: log C)

Model w/o interaction terms Model with interaction terms

(1) (2) (3)

ln Y1 0.2883⁎⁎⁎ ln Y1 29.6629⁎⁎⁎ ln w1 −1.6574⁎


(0.0478) (4.4878) (1.0035)
ln Y2 0.2556⁎⁎⁎ ln Y2 −6.2116⁎⁎ ln w2 2.6574⁎⁎⁎
(0.0216) (2.8412) (1.0035)
ln Y3 0.1367⁎⁎⁎ ln Y3 −10.0623⁎⁎⁎ ln w1 ln w1 0.6751⁎⁎⁎
(0.0134) (1.1195) (0.1360)
ln Y4 0.0153 ln Y4 −4.9570⁎⁎ ln w2 ln w2 0.0452
(0.0270) (2.2712) (0.1296)
ln w1 0.6901⁎⁎⁎ ln Y1 ln Y1 −0.2212 ln w1 ln w2 −0.3601⁎⁎⁎
(0.0441) (0.1867) (0.1057)
ln w2 0.3098⁎⁎⁎ ln Y1 ln Y2 −0.6930⁎⁎⁎ ln w1 ln Y1 −2.2131⁎⁎⁎
(0.0441) (0.1336) (0.2951)
Controls Year/geographic divisions ln Y1 ln Y3 −0.1661⁎⁎ ln w1 ln Y2 0.8995⁎⁎⁎
(0.0656) (0.2629)
ln Y1 ln Y4 −0.2156⁎⁎ ln w1 ln Y3 0.8960⁎⁎⁎
(0.1040) (0.1293)
ln Y2 ln Y2 0.1303⁎⁎ ln w1 ln Y4 0.4176⁎⁎
(0.0677) (0.1954)
ln Y2 ln Y3 0.2409⁎⁎⁎ ln w2 ln Y1 −0.1894
(0.0387) (0.1169)
ln Y2 ln Y4 0.4186⁎⁎⁎ ln w2 ln Y2 −0.2236⁎
(0.0628) (0.1270)
ln Y3 ln Y3 0.1449⁎⁎⁎ ln w2 ln Y3 −0.0002
(0.0176) (0.0471)
ln Y3 ln Y4 0.1352⁎⁎⁎ ln w2 ln Y4 0.4133⁎⁎⁎
(0.0294) (0.1065)
ln Y4 ln Y4 0.0013 Controls Year/Geographic divisions
(0.0186)
σva 0.0446⁎⁎⁎ σva 0.0697⁎⁎⁎
(0.0077) (0.0089)
σub 0.2192⁎⁎⁎ σub 0.1171⁎⁎⁎
(0.0135) (0.0123)
ln L 146.2038 ln L 286.8115
Wald χ2 1891.57⁎⁎⁎ Wald χ2 2545.13⁎⁎⁎

N = 428; Standard errors are in parentheses.


⁎ p b 0.1.
⁎⁎ p b 0.05.
⁎⁎⁎ p b 0.01.
a
The variance of idiosyncratic errors (vk,t);
b
The variance of technical inefficiency terms (uk,t, significance from a log-likelihood test).

extent to which state governments perceive IT as strategic resources for unresponsive to strategic needs of business units in IT, fall behind
statewide performance improvement. Lastly, we cannot rule out the pos- emerging trends in technology, or fail to manage capable employees
sibility that IT spending improves state cost efficiency by compromising and vendors. In a large, multi-divisional organization such as a state
the quality of public services, although we do not expect that this is the government, IT bureaucracy may hamper coordination and standardi-
case. Further studies are warranted to examine whether government IT zation in IT infrastructures and platforms across business units, which
spending leads to an improvement in public service quality. is instrumental for cross-unit synergies [69]. For instance, effective im-
This study contributes to the literature on IT business value and IT plementation of a large-scale information systems, such as decision sup-
governance as follows. First, we expand the scope of IT value research port systems for public welfare administration that consist of data
into the public sector domain. Although the public sector organizations warehouses and business analytics tools (Section 2.1), requires state-
have adopted IT in almost every aspect of administration as for-profit wide data collection and integration across state executive agencies,
firms do, the literature does not illuminate whether IT spending does strong leadership of a state CIO, and cooperation of state agencies, all
contribute to performance improvement in government. Second, we of which can hardly be achievable in the presence of IT bureaucracy.
investigate how involvement of a legislative body in IT governance af- Our findings suggest that for bureaucracy in IT management to be over-
fects returns to IT spending. To the best of knowledge, the studies in IT come, the IT function be accompanied with adequate supervision and
governance to date have paid less attention to the role of “principals” – guidance from elected representatives. The politicians should play a
board of directors in for-profit firms or legislatures in governments – key role in IT governance for achieving greater returns to IT by selecting
whose primary responsibility is to make sure that the activities and a right person for a CIO position, by legitimizing the CIO position and
decisions of managers are in accordance with the principals' interests. duties, and by monitoring IT operation on an ongoing basis. The caveat,
For this purpose, we bring the political control theory to theorize the however, is that involvement of the lawmakers in IT management may
role of the principals in IT governance and to hypothesize its moderat- unintentionally create another layer of bureaucracy. Thus, the IT gover-
ing effect. We believe that ours is the first to adopt this interdisciplinary nance needs to strike the right balance between effective oversight on IT
approach marrying the IS and political sciences literature. management and speed investments and deployment in state-of-the-
This paper also offers several meaningful implications for managers art IT systems.
in the public sector organizations. Whether in the public or the business We believe that there are numerous research opportunities in IT
sector, there may exist IT bureaucracy; an IT function could be governance and management in the public sector organization. First,
M.-S. Pang / Decision Support Systems 59 (2014) 274–285 283

Table 8
The second-stage estimation results.

Dependent variable — technical efficiency

Method Fixed effects regression with Driscoll–Kraay standard errors

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7)

Population −0.0041 −0.0019 −0.0080 −0.0089 −0.0022 −0.0085 −0.0093


(0.0086) (0.0084) (0.0086) (0.0092) (0.0083) (0.0097) (0.0104)
GDP 0.0013 0.0013 0.0006 0.0008 0.0013 0.0009 0.0009
(0.0023) (0.0022) (0.0024) (0.0026) (0.0022) (0.0022) (0.0024)
Income −0.0016⁎⁎ −0.0014⁎⁎ −0.0019⁎⁎ −0.0022⁎⁎ −0.0014⁎⁎ −0.0018⁎⁎ −0.0020⁎⁎
(0.0007) (0.0007) (0.0008) (0.0008) (0.0007) (0.0008) (0.0009)
Federal grant −0.1573⁎⁎⁎ −0.1559⁎⁎⁎ −0.1680⁎⁎⁎ −0.1694⁎⁎⁎ −0.1569⁎⁎⁎ −0.1690⁎⁎⁎ −0.1711⁎⁎⁎
(0.0192) (0.0195) (0.0205) (0.0204) (0.0195) (0.0189) (0.0187)
Governor 0.0072⁎⁎⁎ 0.0033 0.0039⁎⁎⁎ 0.0023⁎⁎⁎ 0.0036⁎ 0.0046⁎⁎⁎ 0.0030⁎⁎
(0.0020) (0.0022) (0.0013) (0.0013) (0.0019) (0.0012) (0.0014)
Legislature −0.1381⁎⁎⁎ −0.1385⁎⁎⁎ −0.1278⁎⁎⁎ −0.1200⁎⁎⁎ −0.1374⁎⁎⁎ −0.1272⁎⁎⁎ −0.1156⁎⁎⁎
(0.0214) (0.0215) (0.0198) (0.0189) (0.0215) (0.0192) (0.0187)
Centrality 0.0011⁎⁎⁎ 0.0016⁎⁎⁎ 0.0015⁎⁎⁎ 0.0015⁎⁎⁎ 0.0016⁎⁎⁎ 0.0016⁎⁎⁎ 0.0016⁎⁎⁎
(0.0002) (0.0002) (0.0002) (0.0002) (0.0002) (0.0001) (0.0001)
Reporting 0.0021 0.0000 −0.0186⁎⁎ −0.0222⁎⁎⁎ 0.0004 −0.0165⁎⁎ −0.0196⁎⁎
(0.0049) (0.0046) (0.0069) (0.0069) (0.0047) (0.0081) (0.0086)
ITEmp −0.0006 −0.0012⁎⁎ −0.0013⁎⁎ −0.0012 −0.0011⁎⁎ −0.0017⁎⁎⁎ −0.0015⁎⁎
(0.0006) (0.0005) (0.0005) (0.0005) (0.0005) (0.0006) (0.0006)
Establish 0.0350⁎⁎⁎ 0.0346⁎⁎⁎ 0.0070 0.0017 0.0349⁎⁎⁎ 0.0248⁎⁎⁎ 0.0204⁎⁎⁎
(0.0053) (0.0052) (0.0065) (0.0071) (0.0052) (0.0065) (0.0067)
Approve −0.0164⁎⁎⁎ −0.0140⁎⁎ −0.0276⁎⁎⁎ −0.0279⁎⁎⁎ −0.0146⁎⁎ −0.0287⁎⁎⁎ −0.0295⁎⁎⁎
(0.0056) (0.0054) (0.0065) (0.0064) (0.0056) (0.0067) (0.0067)
Committee −0.0460⁎⁎⁎ −0.0426⁎⁎⁎ −0.0176⁎⁎ −0.0181⁎⁎ −0.0425⁎⁎⁎ −0.0238⁎⁎ −0.0219⁎⁎
(0.0051) (0.0055) (0.0087) (0.0084) (0.0054) (0.0112) (0.0104)
IT1a 0.0003⁎⁎⁎ 0.0000 −0.0001
(0.0001) (0.0001) (0.0001)
IT1 × Establish 0.0034⁎⁎⁎ 0.0040⁎⁎⁎
(0.0010) (0.0009)
IT1 × Approve 0.0026⁎⁎⁎ −0.0018
(0.0006) (0.0012)
IT1 × Committee −0.0027⁎⁎⁎ −0.0033⁎⁎⁎
(0.0008) (0.0008)
IT1 × Approve × Committee 0.0048⁎⁎⁎
(0.0010)
IT2b 0.0102⁎⁎⁎ −0.0030 −0.0038
(0.0013) (0.0026) (0.0024)
IT2 × Establish 0.0911⁎⁎⁎ 0.1165⁎⁎⁎
(0.0311) (0.0332)
IT2 × Approve 0.0888⁎⁎⁎ −0.0316
(0.0197) (0.0509)
IT2 × Committee −0.0629⁎⁎ −0.0871⁎⁎⁎
(0.0289) (0.0312)
IT2 × Approve × Committee 0.1395⁎⁎⁎
(0.0564)
Controls Year Year Year Year Year Year Year
F 68.56⁎⁎⁎ 70.98⁎⁎⁎ 47.88⁎⁎⁎ 53.19⁎⁎⁎ 70.02⁎⁎⁎ 52.42⁎⁎⁎ 51.74⁎⁎⁎
Within R2 0.3667⁎⁎⁎ 0.3715⁎⁎⁎ 0.4149⁎⁎⁎ 0.4223⁎⁎⁎ 0.3707⁎⁎⁎ 0.4078⁎⁎⁎ 0.4142⁎⁎⁎

N = 185; standard errors are in parentheses.


Year dummies are omitted. AR(2) and spatial (interstate) correlation in residuals are assumed.
⁎ p b 0.1.
⁎⁎ p b 0.05.
⁎⁎⁎ p b 0.01.
a
Per capita budget of the central IT function.
b
The ratio (%) of the central IT function budget to total expenditures.

future research may directly study bureaucracy in IT management. Lastly, future research may investigate the effect of IT spending and
What's the nature of IT management bureaucracy and what causes it? IT governance mechanisms on other performance indicators in the pub-
We do not expect that bureaucracy in IT management exists only in gov- lic sector. Governments pursue far more diverse goals than for-profit or-
ernments; it may take place in for-profit firms as well. Future research ganizations. In addition to efficiency, they aim at providing quality
may study how chief executives, business managers, and board of direc- public services, promoting economic development, and preserving
tors or legislatures can address IT management bureaucracy. Second, re- equity, fairness, and rule of law. Interesting research questions to IS re-
searchers may study the relationship between the legislature and the searchers include what impact IT spending and IT governance together
CIO. Specifically, it would be interesting to study how involvement of have on effectiveness in administration and public service delivery or
politicians in IT management affects the power and authority of the overall social welfare. For example, it would be interesting to see how
CIO. Third, researchers may generalize our study by investigating how IT investments improve the satisfaction of Medicaid beneficiaries or
board-of-directors in business firms, who play a role of principals as affect the effective operation of the Health Insurance Exchange that,
elected politicians do in governments, affect IT management and busi- mandated by the Affordable Care Act, state governments will be in
ness value from IT investments [56,67]. charge of.
284 M.-S. Pang / Decision Support Systems 59 (2014) 274–285

[14] B.A. Chaney, P.A. Copley, M.S. Stone, The effect of fiscal stress and balanced budget
(a) From Table 8, Column (4) requirements on the funding and measurement of state pension obligations, Journal
Average Cost Reduction of Accounting and Public Policy 21 (2002) 287–313.
15 [15] J.A. Colquitt, G. George, From the editors: publishing in AMJ — Part 1: topic choice,
Academy of Management Journal 54 (2011) 432–435.
[16] S. Cramm, How to cut through IT bureaucracy, HBR Blog Network, available at
12 http://blogs.hbr.org/hbr/cramm/2009/03/how-to-cut-through-it-bureaucr.
html2009(accessed on Jul. 12, 2012).
[17] M.L. Davis, K. Hayes, The demand for good government, The Review of Economics
9
and Statistics 75 (1993) 148–152.
[18] B. De Borger, K. Kerstens, Cost efficiency of Belgian local governments: a compara-
6 tive analysis of FDH, DEA, and econometric approaches, Regional Science and
Urban Economics 26 (1996) 145–170.
[19] J.C. Driscoll, A.C. Kraay, Consistent covariance matrix estimation with spatially
3 dependent panel data, The Review of Economics and Statistics 80 (2006) 549–560.
[20] K.M. Eisenhardt, Control: organizational and economic approaches, Management
0 Science 31 (1985) 134–148.
[21] Fortune, Uncle Sam's First CIO, 164July 2011. 56–61.
[22] J.C. Garand, Explaining government growth in the U.S. states, The American Political
-3 Science Review 82 (1988) 837–849.
[23] B. Geys, Looking across borders: a test of spatial policy interdependence using local
-6 government efficiency ratings, Journal of Urban Economics 60 (2006) 443–462.
[24] Government Technology, Washington State Shrinks IT Department's Head Count, avail-
(b) From Table 8, Column (7) able at http://www.govtech.com/policy-management/Washington-State-Shrinks-IT-
Department-Head-Count.html2011(accessed on Jul. 16, 2012).
Average Cost Reduction [25] Government Technology, California DMV Cancels IT Modernization Project Contract,
15 available at: http://www.govtech.com/e-government/DMV-IT-Modernization-
Project.html2013(accessed on Nov. 19th, 2013).
[26] P.J. Grossman, P. Mavros, R.W. Wassmer, Public sector technical inefficiency in large
12 U.S. cities, Journal of Urban Economics 46 (1999) 278–299.
[27] B. Gu, L. Xue, G. Ray, IT governance and IT investment performance: an empirical
analysis, in: R. Boland, M. Limayem, B. Pentland (Eds.), P Twenty Ninth Inter Conf
9
on Inform Syst, Association for Information Systems, Paris, France, 2008.
[28] G.S. Kearns, R. Sabherwal, Antecedents and consequences of information systems
6 planning integration, IEEE Transactions on Engineering Management 54 (2007)
628–643.
[29] P. Kimmel, More you might be suffocating in a constipated bureaucracy, Datamotion,
3 available at http://www.datamation.com/career/article.php/3517211/2005(accessed
on Jul. 12, 2012).
0 [30] T.C. Koopmans, An analysis of production as an efficient combination of activities,
in: T.C. Koopmans (Ed.), Activity Analysis of Production and Allocation, John Wiley
and Sons, Inc., New York, 1951.
-3 [31] R. Kumar, A framework for assessing the business value of information technology
infrastructures, Journal of Management Information Systems 21 (2004) 11–32.
-6 [32] S.C. Kumbhakar, C.A.K. Lovell, Stochastic Frontier Analysis, Cambridge University
Press, New York, 2000.
Establish = 1; The verticalaxis indicates an average cost reduction in operation [33] S. Leland, Fiscal characteristics of public expenditure, in: D. Robbins (Ed.), Handbook
expenses and capital deprecations from a $1 increase in IT budget; Dashed lines of Public Sector Economics, CRC Press, Boca Raton, FL, 2005, pp. 271–289.
are 95% confidence intervals. [34] D. Lohmeyer, S. Progreb, S. Robinson, Who's accountable for IT? The McKinsey
Quarterly (December 2002) 38–47.
Fig. 1. The average cost reduction from IT spending. [35] C.A.K. Lovell, Production frontiers and productive efficiency, in: H.O. Fried, C.A.K.
Lovell, S.S. Schmidt (Eds.), The Measurement of Productive Efficiency, Oxford
University Press, New York, 1993, pp. 3–67.
References [36] D. Mark, D.P. Rau, Splitting demand from supply in IT, The McKinsey Quarterly
(September 2006) 22–29.
[1] D. Aigner, S.F. Chu, On estimating the industry production function, American [37] K.R. Mayer, Executive orders and presidential power, Journal of Politics 61 (1999)
Economic Review 58 (1968) 826–839. 445–466.
[2] J.E. Alt, R.C. Lowry, Divided government, fiscal institutions, and budget deficits: [38] M.D. McCubbins, R.G. Noll, B.R. Weingast, Administrative procedures as instruments
evidence from the states, The American Political Science Review 88 (1994) 811–828. of political control, Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 3 (1987) 243–277.
[3] R.D. Banker, N. Hu, P.A. Pavlou, J. Luftman, CIO reporting structure, strategic posi- [39] M.D. McCubbins, R.G. Noll, B.R. Weingast, Structure and process, politics, and policy:
tioning, and firm performance, MIS Quarterly 35 (2011) 487–504. administrative arrangements and the political control of agencies, Virginia Law Re-
[4] G.E. Battese, T.J. Coelli, Prediction of firm-level technical efficiencies with a general- view 75 (1989) 431–482.
ized frontier production function and panel data, Journal of Econometrics 38 (1988) [40] M.D. McCubbins, T. Schwartz, Congressional oversight overlooked: police patrols
387–399. versus fire alarms, American Journal of Political Science 28 (1984) 165–179.
[5] K. Bawn, Political control versus expertise: congressional choices about administra- [41] W. Meeusen, J. van den Broeck, Efficiency estimation from Cobb–Douglas produc-
tive procedures, The American Political Science Review 89 (1995) 62–73. tion functions with composed error, International Economic Review 18 (1977)
[6] K. Bawn, Choosing strategies to control the bureaucracy: statutory constraints, over- 435–444.
sight, and the committee system, Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 13 [42] N. Melville, K. Kraemer, V. Gurbaxani, The productivity impact of information
(1997) 101–126. technology across competitive regimes: the role of industry concentration and
[7] S. Bharadwaj, A. Bharadwaj, F. Bendoly, The performance effects of complementar- dynamism, Decision Support Systems 41 (2007) 229–242.
ities between information systems, marketing, manufacturing, and supply chain [43] V. Midha, A. Bhattacherjee, Governance practices and software maintenance: a
processes, Information Systems Research 18 (2007) 437–453. study of open source projects, Decision Support Systems 54 (2012) 23–32.
[8] T.F. Bresnahan, F. Brynjolfsson, L. Hitt, Information technology, workplace organiza- [44] Military Times, Lawmakers Pessimistic on VA-DoD E-Records Plan, available
tion, and the demand for skilled labor: firm-level evidence, Quarterly Journal of at: http://www.militarytimes.com/article/20130228/BENEFITS/302280333/
Economics 117 (2002) 339–376. 2013(accessed on Nov. 19th, 2013).
[9] C.V. Brown, S.L. Magill, Alignment of the IS functions with the enterprise: toward a [45] T.M. Moe, The new economics of organization, American Journal of Political Science
model of antecedents, MIS Quarterly 18 (1994) 371–403. 28 (1984) 739–777.
[10] E. Brynjolfsson, The productivity paradox of information technology, Communica- [46] M.J. Moon, S. Bretchneider, Does the perception of red tape constrain IT innovativeness
tions of the ACM 36 (1993) 67–77. in organizations? Unexpected results from a simultaneous equation model and impli-
[11] R.L. Calvert, M.D. McCubbins, B.R. Weingast, A theory of political control and agency cations, Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory 12 (2002) 273–291.
discretion, American Journal of Political Science 33 (1989) 588–611. [47] NASBO, Budget Processes in the States — Summer 2008, Washington, D.C., available at
[12] D.W. Caves, L.R. Christensen, M.W. Tretheway, Flexible cost functions for multiprod- http://www.nasbo.org/sites/default/files/BP_2008.pdf2008(accessed on Jul. 15th,
uct firms, The Review of Economics and Statistics 62 (1980) 477–481. 2011).
[13] D.W. Caves, L.R. Christensen, J.A. Swanson, Productivity growth, scale economies, [48] NASBO, Fiscal Survey of States, Fall 2012, Washington, D.C., available at http://www.
and capacity utilization in U.S. railroads, American Economic Review 71 (1981) nasbo.org/sites/default/files/Fall%202012%20Fiscal%20Survey.pdf2012(accessed on
994–1002. Jul. 17th, 2013).
M.-S. Pang / Decision Support Systems 59 (2014) 274–285 285

[49] NASCIO, NASCIO 2004–05 Compendium of Digital Governance in the States, 2005. [65] A. Reschovsky, The impact of state government fiscal crises on local govern-
(Lexington, KY, available at http://www.nascio.org/publications/compendium.cfm, ments and schools, State and Local Government Review 36 (2004) 86–102.
accessed on Jan. 10th, 2009). [66] N. Roberts, V. Grover, Leveraging information technology infrastructure to facilitate
[50] NASCIO, Best Practices in the Use of Information Technology in State Government, a firm's customer agility and competitive activity: an empirical investigation, Journal
Lexington, KY, available at http://www.nascio.org/publications/documents/ of Management Information Systems 28 (2012) 231–270.
NASCIO-2006Awards.pdf2006(accessed on Jul. 15th, 2011). [67] J.W. Ross, P. Weill, Six IT decisions your IT people shouldn't make, Harvard Business
[51] NASCIO, Best Practices in the Use of Information Technology in State Government, Review 80 (2002) 85–91.
Lexington, KY, available at http://www.nascio.org/publications/documents/ [68] V. Sambamurthy, R.W. Zmud, Arrangement for information technology governance:
NASCIO-2007Awards.pdf2007(accessed on Jul. 17th, 2013). a theory of multiple contingencies, MIS Quarterly 23 (1999) 261–290.
[52] NASCIO, Compendium of 2006 Best Practices in the Use of Information Technology in [69] H. Tanriverdi, Performance effects of information technology synergies in
State Government, Lexington, KY, available at http://www.nascio.org/publications/ multibusiness firms, MIS Quarterly 30 (2006) 57–77.
documents/NASCIO-2006RecognitionAwardsCompendium.pdf2006(accessed on Jul. [70] Washington Post, What Went Wrong with HealthCare.gov, available at: http://
15th, 2011). www.washingtonpost.com/national/health-science/what-went-wrong-with-
[53] NASCIO, The 2010 State CIO Survey, Lexington, KY, available at: http://www.nascio. healthcaregov/2013/10/24/400e68de-3d07-11e3-b7ba-503fb5822c3e_graphic.
org/publications/documents/NASCIO-2010StateCIOSurvey.pdf2010(accessed on Jul. html2013(accessed on Nov. 19th, 2013).
16th, 2012). [71] E.T.G. Wang, J.H.F. Chen, The influence of governance equilibrium on ERP project
[54] NASCIO, The Health IT Landscape: Through the Lens of State CIO, Lexington, KY, success, Decision Support Systems 41 (2006) 708–727.
available at http://www.nascio.org/publications/documents/The_Health_ [72] H.J. Watson, C. Fuller, T. Ariyachandra, Data warehouse governance: best practices at
IT_Landscape_in_the_States_NASCIO_HIMSS.pdf2013(accessed on Jul. 17th, Blue Cross and Blue Shield of North Carolina, Decision Support Systems 38 (2004)
2013). 435–450.
[55] K.S. Nash, FBI CIO's mission: modernize, CIO Magazine, (January 2011). [73] P. Weill, J. Ross, IT Governance: How Top Performers Manage IT Decision Rights for
[56] R. Nolan, F.W. McFarlen, Information technology and the board of directors, Harvard Superior Results, Harvard Business Press, Boston, MA, 2004.
Business Review 83 (2005) 97–106. [74] C.W.Y. Wong, K. Lai, T.C.E. Cheng, Value of information integration to supply chain
[57] J. Ondrich, J. Ruggiero, Efficiency measurement in the stochastic frontier model, management: roles of internal and external contingencies, Journal of Management
European Journal of Operational Research 129 (2001) 434–442. Information Systems 28 (2011) 161–200.
[58] S.K. Pandey, S. Bretchneider, The impact of red tape's administrative [75] B.D. Wood, R.W. Waterman, The dynamics of political control of bureaucracy, The
delay on public organizations' interest in new information technologies, American Political Science Review 85 (1991) 801–828.
Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory 7 (1997) 113–129. [76] A.C. Worthington, Cost efficiency in Australian local governments: a compar-
[59] M.-S. Pang, Information Technology and Value Creation in the Public Sector ative analysis of mathematical programming and econometric approaches,
Organizations, (Doctoral Dissertation) University of Michigan, 2011. Financial Accountability and Management 16 (2000) 201–224.
[60] J.M. Poterba, State responses to fiscal crises: the effects of budgetary institutions and [77] Y. Xue, H. Liang, W.R. Boulton, Information technology governance in information
politics, Journal of Political Economy 102 (1994) 799–821. technology investment decision processes: the impact of investment characteristics,
[61] A. Prasad, J. Heales, P. Green, Towards a deeper understanding of information external environment, and internal context, MIS Quarterly 32 (2008) 67–96.
technology governance effectiveness: a capabilities-based approach, in: H. Chen, [78] L. Xue, G. Ray, B. Gu, Environmental uncertainty and IT infrastructure governance: a
S.A. Slaughter (Eds.), P Twenty Ninth Inter Conf on Inform Syst, Association for curvilinear relationship, MIS Quarterly 22 (2011) 389–399.
Information Systems, Phoenix, Arizona, 2009.
[62] D.S. Preston, D. Chen, D.E. Leidner, Examining the antecedents and consequences of
CIO strategic decision-making authority: an empirical study, Decision Sciences 39 Min-Seok Pang is an assistant professor of management information systems at Temple
(2008) 605–642. University's Fox School of Business. He has a Ph.D. in Business Administration from the
[63] R. Ramirez, N. Melville, E. Lawler, Information technology infrastructure, organiza- Stephen M. Ross School of Business at the University of Michigan, as well as an M.S. in
tional process redesign, and business value: an empirical analysis, Decision Support Management and B.S. in Industrial Engineering from the Korea Advanced Institute of Sci-
Systems 49 (2010) 417–429. ence and Technology. His research has been published in such journals as Information Sys-
[64] G. Ray, W.A. Muhanna, J.B. Barney, Information technology and the performance of tems Research, MIS Quarterly, and International Journal of Electronic Commerce. His research
the customer service process: a resource-based analysis, MIS Quarterly 29 (2005) interests include IT business value, IT governance, Electronic Governments, and Online
625–652. and Network Services.

You might also like