You are on page 1of 8

European View (2012) 11:55–62

DOI 10.1007/s12290-012-0208-4

ARTICLE

Preserving social models while


regaining competitiveness: can
Europe do both?
Marek Góra

Published online: 13 June 2012


Ó Centre for European Studies 2012

Abstract European social models have many advantages and some disad-
vantages—both have been widely discussed. However, disputes on whether the
European welfare state is a good or bad idea have become less relevant since
the demographic dividend that used to fuel the institutions of the welfare state
has disappeared. Having fewer resources, Europeans must spend less. In order to
adjust to the new situation it is crucial to rethink the essence of social goals, to
explain conclusions to the public, and to then neutralise certain elements of
social models in order to withdraw them from political bargaining and downsize
them. All this is necessary in order to save the social models, which have become
overused. Not having the demographic dividend available, politicians have had
to increase the burden put on production factors, reducing net remunerations.
European social models still have a lot of potential for the future. If they focus on
the key social goals and are of a reasonable scale then they will once again
contribute to higher productivity and competitiveness among European
economies.

Keywords Welfare  Demographic dividend  Ageing  Competitiveness 


Europe

Introduction

The current difficult situation in Europe is commonly perceived as a crisis, part of


the worldwide financial and economic one. In fact the situation is worse. A crisis

M. Góra (&)
Warsaw School of Economics, Al. Niepodległosci 162, 02-554 Warsaw, Poland
e-mail: Marek.Gora@sgh.waw.pl

123
56

has an optimistic component—it eventually ends. However, the recent crisis has
also triggered a downward shift in welfare, from which it will probably not
recover. This shift stems from the eventual loss of the illusion that twentieth-
century institutions can remain unchanged now that the demographic dividend
that fuelled them has disappeared.
The dividend used to be generated within a financial pyramid as each
subsequent generation of the population was significantly larger than the
previous one. As in a Ponzi scheme, it was easy to generate income ‘from
nothing’.1 Running large deficits, both explicit and implicit, did not lead to any
substantial economic or social problems, and paying debts back was easy since
repayment was spread over a constantly increasing number of tax/contribution
payers. This was the basis for financing European social models, in other words,
the welfare state.
A Ponzi scheme is illegal if it is run by a private person or firm—and there are
good reasons for this. However, government-run institutions designed in a
similar way are completely legal. Yet, the same reasons for caution also apply to
them. We are now living at a time when government-run financial pyramids
have not yet collapsed in cash terms but have already collapsed in actuarial
terms. In order to keep them alive, benefits need to be reduced or the cost of
participation (contributions/taxes) needs to be increased. This applies not only
to pension systems but to the whole of public finance.2
This is the familiar landscape of the world (but mostly Europe) now that the
demographic ‘Santa Claus’ has passed away. Santa kindly used to pay the bills of
our social welfare systems, but since his demise we must pay the bills ourselves.
There are not and will not be enough resources to do this, which means that the
great idea of the European social model is exposed to huge risk. The European
economies and their competitiveness are also exposed to risk, since to develop
they need well-remunerated workers and innovative technologies. Both require
proper financing, which is impossible since the resources are locked in an
attempt to hide the loss of the demographic dividend.

Remuneration of production factors versus financing transfers

There are many controversies surrounding the idea of the welfare state.3
However, they mostly refer to the past when the demographic dividend was still
at the disposal of European governments.4 Nowadays, irrespective of whether
the idea was right or wrong in the past, societies do not have the resources to
maintain the welfare state in its twentieth-century form. In the past the cost of

1
Today few people remember Ponzi but many remember Madoff.
2
Pension systems are most exposed to the collapse of the Ponzi scheme.
3
There is a long list of pros and cons regarding the concept of the welfare state—see Atkinson
(1999), Barr (2001), Lindbeck et al. (1994) and Ringen (2009).
4
For a broad picture of the good ideas and their implementation in the twentieth century, see Jude
(2012).
European View 57

servicing the growing aggregated debt was spread among the growing
population of active citizens (workers and entrepreneurs). However, today the
cost of servicing the still-growing debt is spread among a shrinking population
of active contributors.5 A new approach is needed.6
We all have to live on the current gross domestic product (GDP), so the
essence of the problem is how to divide its value between various goals.7 The
two main goals are remunerations and transfers (in both cases in a broad sense),
thus the real choice we face is how to divide the GDP between these two items.
It is a difficult task.
On one hand we have a socially devastating extreme, that is, no transfers at
all. This is hard to imagine. On the other is pure communism (people working
without any remuneration but being given everything for free according to set
rules). The latter extreme would be as socially devastating as the former. Thus we
have to seek an optimum balance between Scylla and Charybdis. In public
debate there is a hidden contest about which extreme would be less devastating
to society.8
There is no analytical method we could apply that would be unquestionable
and commonly accepted. In practice we can apply methods of public choice, but
unfortunately any outcome of public choice is constantly affected by
demographic developments. Whatever is decided today will cease to be close
to the social optimum tomorrow because of the changing proportions of those
who work and should be remunerated, and those who do not work and receive
transfers. This is complicated even further if we take into account that in many
cases those who are active as workers are also transfer recipients. In fact,
societies are trapped in the constant demographic bias of a public decision
taken many decades ago. For various—mostly political—reasons, instead of a
constant adjustment following societal and population developments, we can
observe an almost entirely frozen outcome as the result of very ‘ancient’
decisions.
One could say that the rich should pay for transfers to the poor, and it is easy
to agree with this. However, this does not solve the problem that we have,
namely the loss of the demographic dividend. As an entire society, the rich, the
poor and those in between, we have fewer resources than we would have had if
the population structure in terms of age had remained similar to that observed
many decades ago.9 The ‘golden age’ of welfare without work is over.
On top of the above, it is worth noting that traditional oppositions, such as
the rich versus the poor or capital versus labour, have been supplemented with a

5
An analysis of the availability of resources for financing the welfare state goes beyond the scope of
this paper. See, for instance, European Commission (2009).
6
For a discussion of new challenges, see Esping-Andersen (2002).
7
I use the term GDP throughout this article, despite the fact that it is often criticised. In this context
its criticisms are irrelevant as it is used to mean any measure of the outcome of a working society.
8
One of the extremes is often advanced as ‘evil’, giving the proponents of the other the chance to
promote their views.
9
Issues related to fair distribution of welfare go beyond the scope of this paper.

123
58

new one, namely the economically active versus the recipients of benefits. This
opposition has recently become significant. The economically active are now
becoming increasingly underpaid due to the need to fund transfers.

Rethinking goals, changing methods

Europe has a great heritage of social models supporting both economic growth
and social development (Barr 1992). At the same time, Europe cannot afford to
finance these models on their current scale. The cost of running the institutions is
already very high and is projected to increase substantially in the decades to come
(European Commission 2009, 2012); these costs must be borne by the working
generation. By generating positive outcomes the institutions also generate
increasing costs, thus reducing the competitiveness of European economies.
Inevitably increasing costs will strengthen the latter and undermine the former.
It looks as if there are just two options. The first one is to simply ‘keep the
values’ and try to hide the costs. The longer this option dominates in Europe the
higher the cost of the eventual collapse. In the mean time, the competitiveness
of European economies will incrementally decrease vis-a-vis the rest of the
world. The second option is to ‘give up the values’ and try to become as efficient
as the new powers. Is this possible? Maybe. Will it be a success? I rather doubt it.
Are we caught in a trap between these two undesirable options? Hopefully
not. One solution is to rethink the real meaning of the values. For instance,
retiring workers in their sixties and paying them benefits financed by the
younger generation—is this really a social goal that corresponds with the values
behind the European social models? The value is to support the very old,
which—given current and projected longevity and health—corresponds to
helping people in their late seventies and eighties. If Europeans are able to take
this into account and adjust regulations within the pension systems then huge
resources will be unlocked. This funding will then become available for the
greater remuneration of labour and/or for investment in fields such as education,
research and development, poverty alleviation and so on. The retirement age
adjustment is only one example of possible changes to the institutional
infrastructure.10 A full analysis of the possibilities goes beyond the scope of this
paper. In principle we can say (travestying Talleyrand) that a lot must change in
order to preserve the European social models.
This is easy to say, but difficult to implement. However, it is worth trying. The
social models developed in Europe have a lot of potential for the future. They are
the great idea; the pipe work has simply become slimed and blocked through
overuse. Europe can preserve its social model and become competitive again if
(a) the scale of the burden it generates for the working part of societies is
reduced, and (b) the real meaning and relative importance of its goals is
rethought. When these two goals are achieved then the social models will again
increase the strength of European economies rather than create a burden.

10
For more discussion on the retirement age and the need to increase it, see Guillemard (2005).
European View 59

Redistribution via the budget is already carried out on a large scale. It will be
even larger when societies have to repay debts that are currently still hidden and
not presented in official statistics. The real problem is not just the current scale
of redistribution, but its tendency to increase. While spending more on transfers
we have no choice but to reduce remunerations in terms of GDP. By doing this
the interests of the working population are neglected. Their remuneration is not
only an incentive to work but also a social goal.
In order to preserve social models and become competitive again, Europe has
a number of reform options. The largest single item on the list of expenditure via
the state budget is old-age pensions. People in their sixties are now no longer
old, yet they receive benefits, while new entrants to the labour market are
underpaid or cannot even find a job (Góra 2008).
It is worth noting here that the ‘Occupy’ protestors who appeared in many
places in 2011 are a part of the story. At first glance they are protesting against
the ruthless behaviour of the financial markets and governments, whom they
blame for their situation. The young protestors are unable to enjoy such good
opportunities at the beginning of their adult lives as their parents had. Jobs—if
available—are not well paid, usually only temporary and do not offer even basic
social protection. Moreover, there is little hope that the situation will improve
soon. Why is this? The demographic dividend has vanished and the whole of
society is less affluent. However, older workers cannot have their various social
privileges taken away for legal and political reasons. The situation of this social
group, which is already rooted in social institutions, is virtually unchanged. It is
the young that are weak; they have simply not been given the privileges. Even if
they do not know it, the young are protesting against the loss of the
demographic dividend and the unfair distribution of the cost derived from this
loss. The downward shift of welfare should be generationally more just. A
downsizing of the scale of social models is needed in order to offer the young an
acceptable standard of life. The welfare of the young should be treated as
seriously as the welfare of older generations.

The politics behind the problem and the possible options

Politics is inevitably involved in providing people with welfare. Politicians win


elections if they are credible in promising welfare improvements. Unfortunately,
responsible politicians should today tell people the truth, that is, they should
state that it is most probable that the amount of traditionally understood
welfare will shrink in the future. However, after such a statement—given their
‘terms of reference’—they would almost certainly be sacked immediately and, at
the very least, their ratings in opinion polls would fall substantially.11
The problem with political ‘terms of reference’ is that they address a relatively
short time span, namely a couple of years, while the horizon that matters for

11
Note, for instance, the case of the Swedish prime minister, who said that the retirement age in
Sweden should be increased to 75 years.

123
60

people is a couple of decades. Even optimal decisions taken within the political
time span do not necessarily correspond to the social optimum, which requires
politicians to take into account not only today but also tomorrow. Democracy
remains the best of the available political systems but does not solve this ‘time
inconsistency’ problem, which is particularly challenging now, after the change
in the welfare growth trend following the loss of the demographic dividend.
Public education can help a lot in reducing the problem. While leaving this issue
to another study, it is worth noting here two hints that might help. The first is to
stop using the terms ‘state’ and ‘budget’ when referring to financing social goals in
public debate. These terms are commonly used as useful shortcuts. Unfortunately,
their use confuses public perception, resulting in them often being understood as
an incarnation of Santa Claus. While the state cannot finance anything via its
institutions, it can enable society to produce public goods. It can organise and
supervise the financing of goals by the active population, as, in fact, we already
know. However, when it comes to formulating views on social issues we often
forget such obvious things. Consequently, the public is generally against reducing
the generosity of social systems, even if such reductions are focused on
expenditure on policies that are not crucial to fulfilling any social goals.
Given politicians’ terms of reference in democratic countries, it looks as if once
we increase expenditure we cannot reduce it unless there is a real financial
disaster. In the case of social models this increase was partially unintentional, but
the damage was done automatically as a result of the ageing population. This,
however, does not change the essence of the problem.
A mechanism that goes beyond politics is needed to bring back some control
over the division of GDP between remunerations and financing transfers. The time
inconsistency makes the existing democratic procedures ineffective. The mech-
anism was sufficient when the population was growing, but it is insufficient now
that this trend has changed. The goal is to extend the democratic mechanism in a
way that will allow long-term and possibly undesirable developments to be taken
into account. The ability to choose such extensions is on the way. For instance, the
Stability and Growth Pact (SGP), some early steps towards fiscal integration in
Europe, and the increasingly discussed idea of establishing fiscal boards at the
national level will bring long-term issues into political systems.
There is also another option, namely an automatic adjustment instead of a
discretional one. This would lead to the neutralisation of the elements of social
models that do not contribute to social goals. European societies spend a lot on
pensions paid to the not-yet-old while old-age care is commonly underfinanced.
A possibly fruitful solution to this problem could be the reform of pension
systems along the lines of the Swedish and Polish systems, which are based on
the full individualisation of participation and the iron rule that the present value
of benefits is equal to the present value of contributions. Such a system plays the
role of an automatic stabiliser,12 leading to the ‘neutralisation’ of the mandatory
pension system and leaving redistribution and help for the very old to tax-based

12
This should not be confused with the privatisation of the systems. For a detailed discussion of the
approach, see Góra (2003).
European View 61

systems. This could really unlock the huge resources bound up in pension
systems without any loss to our ability to reach social goals. Neutralisation is
possible only in selected areas, such as the old-age pension system. However, as
that system is the largest, it matters most for public finance.

Conclusions: rethink, explain, neutralise and downsize to save

The European Union is still a project in progress. Much has already been achieved,
but the final shape of the Union has not yet even been designed. Further
development of the project will continue in tough times. We face a mixture of
various global problems and population ageing. The latter is very advanced in
Europe, which makes the situation of the Union difficult vis-à-vis the rest of the
world. If we just try to protect what we have already achieved, without continuing
the intellectual, organisational and political efforts to design and create a truly
advanced Union, then many or all of the achievements will be lost.
If we try to preserve the social models in Europe in their current shape we
expose the goals of these models to the risk of being totally given up when the
accumulated debt exceeds a certain level. Furthermore, this level cannot be
precisely predicted. It is certain, however, that there must be a real limit to the
spending of non-existent resources. This is perfectly understood with respect to
the explicitly accounted for amounts. The aim of the SGP is to prevent the Union
from reaching this limit. However, social institutions are commonly financed in a
way that is not explicitly accounted for. In such cases the current version of the
SGP cannot provide much help. Should European accounting standards be
modernised? Should the SGP be extended in order to cover the finances of social
models’ institutions? Yes, they probably should.13
Population ageing is one of the most often used expressions in public debate.
Not only experts but a growing part of the public understands that the ageing
population is the factor most strongly affecting our social life. Rationally we
know we need new ideas and methods, but intuitively we are still dreaming
about restoring the ‘good old times’ when welfare was a form of gift from ‘the
state’ rather than the result of our own hard work. The public discussion is still
looking to the past.
The theoretical background for our view of the welfare state was developed
at a time when a large demographic dividend was available. This means that we
need to have a thorough rethink of our social system. We still have the same
goals, but many of the methods used to achieve them now need to be
exchanged for newly designed ones.
In addition to a change of methods, we should also rethink the terms of
reference for politicians in democratic states. The time inconsistency built into
their terms of reference was much less distortive in the past. Nowadays time
inconsistency makes taking the steps needed to reform European societies very
difficult.

13
Further discussion of these issues can be found in Góra (2011).

123
62

The longer Europeans postpone the acknowledgement of the truth, the more
socially costly will be the eventual collapse of the illusion that welfare state
institutions can be run on nothing. Europe is less affluent than we tend to perceive
it as. Welfare is not given forever. There is no choice but to work for welfare in the
future. The basis of the great European heritage and the establishment of forward-
looking social institutions designed with the loss of the demographic dividend in
mind will help with the acceptance and implementation of this.

References

Atkinson, A. B. (1999). The economic consequences of rolling back the welfare state. Cambridge, MA,
London: MIT Press.
Barr, N. (1992). Economic theory and the welfare state: A survey and interpretation. Journal of
Economic Literature, 30(2), 741–803.
Barr, N. (2001). The welfare state as a piggy bank: Information, risk, uncertainty and the role of the state.
New York: Oxford University Press.
Esping-Andersen, G. (2002). Why do we need a new welfare state? Oxford: Oxford University Press.
European Commission. (2012). An agenda for adequate, safe and sustainable pensions. White Paper
COM (2012) 55 final, 16 Feb, Brussels.
European Commission, Directorate General of Economic and Financial Affairs. (2009). Sustainability
report 2009. European Economy 9/2009.
Góra, M. (2003). Reintroducing intergenerational equilibrium: Key concepts behind the new Polish
pension system. William Davidson Institute Working Paper No. 574. Ann Arbor.
Góra, M. (2008). Retirement decisions, benefits and the neutrality of pension systems. European Network
of Economic Policy Research Institutes, Research Report No. 51. Brussels.
Góra, M. (2011). Three pension issues: A framework for rethinking the basics, economic reinterpretation
of the concept of public debt, and pension systems’ impact on labour mobility in the EU. Report for
the Directorate General for Economic and Financial Affairs. Brussels [mimeo].
Guillemard, A.-M. (2005). The advent of a flexible life course and the reconfigurations of welfare. In J.
G. Andersen, A.-M. Guillemard, P. H. Jensen, & B. Pfau-Effinger (Eds.), The changing face of welfare:
Consequences and outcomes from a citizenship perspective (pp. 55–74). Bristol: The Policy Press.
Jude, T. (2012). Thinking the twentieth century. New York: Penguin Press.
Lindbeck, A., Molander, P., Persson, T., Sandmo, A., Swedenborg, B. & Thygesen, N. (1994). Turning
Sweden around. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Ringen, S. (2009). The possibility of politics. A study in the political economy of the welfare state. New
Brunswick, NJ: Transaction Publishers.

Marek Góra is a professor at the Warsaw School of Economics


(SGH), where he teaches macroeconomics, pension economics,
labour economics and economic policy, and a visiting professor at
the College of Europe, where he teaches social policy. He is a co-
designer of the new Polish pension system (based on intergenera-
tional equilibrium) implemented in 1999 and the leader of the
pension reform team.

You might also like